You are on page 1of 9

Energy Policy 73 (2014) 269–277

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Energy Policy
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/enpol

Distributional effects of a carbon tax on Chinese households:


A case of Shanghai
Zhujun Jiang a,b,n,1, Shuai Shao c,nn,1
a
Institute for Advanced Research, Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, Shanghai 200433, China
b
Key Laboratory of Mathematical Economics, Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, Ministry of Education, Shanghai 200433, China
c
Institute of Finance and Economics Research, School of Urban and Regional Science, Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, Shanghai 200434, China

H I G H L I G H T S

 The direct distributional effect of carbon tax presents a weak progressivity.


 The indirect distributional effect of carbon tax is significantly regressive.
 The comprehensive distributional effect of carbon tax is regressive.
 The Suits index of carbon tax is  0.078.
 Imposing carbon tax on fossil fuels can intensify income inequality.

art ic l e i nf o a b s t r a c t

Article history: As an effective policy instrument to reduce CO2 emissions, the effects of a carbon tax on distribution
Received 8 February 2014 have been the critical factor in determining whether a carbon tax will be acceptable in China. Taking
Received in revised form Shanghai as an example, which is the economic center and front-runner of China, this paper estimates
2 May 2014
the distributional effect of a carbon tax on households in various income groups by using the input–
Accepted 4 June 2014
Available online 7 July 2014
output model and the Suits index. The results indicate that the comprehensive distributional effect of the
carbon tax is regressive. The expenditure of the low-income group caused by the carbon tax accounts for
Keywords: 0.853% of the total expenditure, while that of the high-income group 0.712%. The direct distributional
Carbon tax effect presents a weak progressivity, while the indirect one is significantly regressive, and the latter is
Distributional effect
much larger than the former. Moreover, the Suits index of the carbon tax is  0.078, implying that the
Suits index
carbon tax burden on the low-income group is the highest and thus that a carbon tax can intensify
income inequality. Therefore, when introducing a carbon tax, some rational associated redistribution or
compensation measures, such as purposive transfer payments, should be implemented to restrict or
even eliminate the regressivity of the carbon tax.
& 2014 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction emission-reduction measure (Baranzini et al., 2000). As an envir-


onmental tax imposed on CO2 emissions, the carbon tax can
As a major issue of human survival and development, global reduce CO2 emissions and thus mitigate climate warming by
climate warming has paid extensive attention all over the world. increasing tax burden. Theoretically, the essential role of a carbon
Among the various climate-change mitigation policies, the carbon tax is to correct distorted price signals and optimize the resource
tax is extensively advocated since it is regarded as the lowest cost allocation by internalizing the environmental externality caused
by anthropogenic CO2 emissions. Therefore, the carbon tax is
considered as one of the most market-efficient economic mea-
n
Corresponding author at: Institute for Advanced Research, Shanghai University sures in reducing CO2 emissions. Supporters of the carbon tax
of Finance and Economics, Shanghai 200433, China. Tel.: þ 86 2165902562. argue that it has three main advantages. First, a carbon tax can
nn
Corresponding author. Tel.: þ 86 2165902562. enhance the competitive power of renewable energy in cost and
E-mail addresses: jiang.zhujun@mail.shufe.edu.cn (Z. Jiang),
shao.shuai@mail.shufe.edu.cn (S. Shao).
thus promote the utilization of renewable energy. Second, the
1
Authors contributed equally to this work and are listed in alphabetical order revenue from a carbon tax can be used to subsidize environmental
by surname. protection project and energy-saving and emission-reducing

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2014.06.005
0301-4215/& 2014 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
270 Z. Jiang, S. Shao / Energy Policy 73 (2014) 269–277

technology. Finally, compared with carbon emissions trading, a Su et al. (2009) analyzed the effects of a carbon tax on China's
carbon tax has lower administrative cost, more convenient imple- macro-economy, industrial development, and income distribution
mentation process, and more predictable effects. in various scenarios of tax rate. However, Su et al. (2009) focused
A carbon tax has been carried out in some countries and has on the effect of a carbon tax on the income inequality of urban and
achieved some desired results. However, until now, there are only rural dwellers and did not analyze the influential mechanism of
a few developed countries actually imposing carbon taxes, such as the carbon tax on distribution.
Finland, Sweden, Denmark, Norway, Netherlands, and Italy. Most In view of limitations above, taking Shanghai as an example,
countries are cautious about the carbon tax considering that it which is an international metropolis and China's economic center
may produce some negative impacts on national economy by and whose economic growth and energy consumption are all on
affecting energy price and supply–demand relationship, increasing the top in China, this paper estimates the distributional effect of a
enterprises' costs, and generating the regressive effect of taxation. carbon tax on different income groups and discusses the influen-
Discussions on mechanisms and channels of a carbon tax affecting tial mechanism and channels by using the input–output model to
national economy have been academic focus issue as well as the provide some theoretical basis and decision-making reference for
crucial basis for governments to determine whether to levy a the implementation of a carbon tax in China.
carbon tax. Among various potential impacts of a carbon tax on As the economic center and front-runner of China, Shanghai is
economy, the influential direction and degree of a carbon tax on expected to play a leading role in climate change mitigation. With
distribution are the critical factor in determining whether a carbon the rapid development, the dependence of Shanghai's economy on
tax will be accepted by the public. Hence, it is also a key issue energy consumption is increasing. According to Shanghai Statistical
focused on by both governments and academic circles. Yearbook, the total energy consumption in Shanghai has increased
Related studies mainly focus on whether a carbon tax will from 394.67 million tons of coal equivalent (tce) in 1993 to
become a regressive tax or not. Whereas, the consensus on this 1292.61 million tce in 2011, with a average annual growth rate
issue is not reached since different conclusions are drawn by using of over 10%. Moreover, with the deepening of energy dependence,
different samples. Empirical evidences from most developed Shanghai's CO2 emissions also present an increasing trend. The
countries indicate that a carbon tax has a regressive effect on total CO2 emissions from production sectors in Shanghai have
distribution (Poterba, 1991; Jacobsen et al., 2003; Kerkhof et al., increased from 525.02 million tons in 1993 to 1292.61 in 2011,
2008; Shammin and Bullard, 2009), while some researchers argue with an average annual growth rate of above 8% (Yang and Shao,
that the distributional effect of a carbon tax is proportional or 2013). Obviously, Shanghai is encountering the great pressure to
progressive (Symons et al., 2000; Tiezzi, 2005; Dissou and realize the target of energy saving and emission reduction (Shao et
Siddiqui, 2014). Bureau (2011) found that a carbon tax was al., 2011). Therefore, Shanghai is a representative sample in China,
regressive before revenue recycling. However, Gonzalez (2012) and the study on Shanghai can attain some necessary decision-
argued that carbon taxes were not necessarily regressive and making references to the policy design of a carbon tax in China.
whether the way revenue was recycled became a major determi- The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2
nant of how the carbon tax costs were distributed. Most existing addresses the fossil energy consumption of households in various
studies focus on developed countries and there are fewer studies income groups in Shanghai. Section 3 estimates direct and indirect
on developing countries. In developing countries, many factors, effects of a carbon tax on various income groups. In Section 4, the
such as market forces, price regulation, and import restriction, are progressivity of a carbon tax is measured and discussed. Conclu-
likely to generate the distributional effect of environmental policy. sions and policy implications are provided in Section 5.
The results of Brenner et al. (2007) and Yusuf and Resosudarmo
(2007) on China and Indonesia, respectively, indicate that a carbon
tax has the progressive impact on distribution. 2. Energy consumption in various income groups
In 2009, the Chinese government announced its emission–
reduction target that CO2 emissions per unit of GDP would be As reported in Shanghai Statistical Yearbook, in 2010, the
reduced by 40–45% in 2020 than 2005 level. As a part of this primary energy consumption in Shanghai reached 111.61 million
target, China's 12th “Five-Year Plan” explicitly proposed an obli- tce, in which coal, oil, and natural gas consumptions were 58.76
gatory indicator that CO2 emissions per unit of GDP should decline million tons, 32.98 million tons, and 4.50 billion cubic meters,
by 17% compared with 2010 level. As an effective policy instru- respectively. As the main source of CO2 emissions, the share of
ment to reduce CO2 emissions, the pleas to implement a carbon fossil fuels in the total primary energy consumption is about 85%
tax are becoming louder in China, but the understanding of the in Shanghai. According to the Word Bank Report, above 70% of the
Chinese government in the potential effects of a carbon tax is not total CO2 emissions are from fossil fuels in the world. Moreover, it
clear, especially in the distributional effect of the carbon tax. As a is a consensus that imposing the carbon tax upstream is more
developing great power characterized by obvious imbalance effective than downstream. On one hand, it is more practicable to
among regions in natural resource endowment and economic impose on fossil fuels than on CO2 emissions per se. On the other
development, the distributional effect of a carbon tax is particu- hand, the administrative costs of a carbon tax could be lower
larly complex in China. The issue has become one of the vital through its upstream implementation (Metcalf, 2009). Hence, like
references in determining whether to implement a carbon tax in some countries where a carbon tax has been imposed (e.g.,
China. Hence, the distributional effect of the carbon tax should be Sweden, Norway, Denmark), we treat fossil fuels as the carbon
paid more attention to. tax base.
In recent years, although studies on China's economic effect of In addition, it is necessary to classify the households to discuss
a carbon tax have become plentiful, most existing literature focus the distributional effect of a carbon tax. Similar to most related
on the impact of a carbon tax on the macro-economy or the studies, we employ the classification by income levels of house-
competitive power of various industries, while the potential effect holds. According to the recent classification standard of the
of a carbon tax on distribution is paid little attention to. Based on National Bureau of Statistics of China, the Tabulation on the 2010
the CGE model, Cao (2009) carried out a comparative analysis on Population Census of Shanghai Municipality shows that in 2010, the
transfer payment effects of different allocation modes of the urban population of Shanghai is 20.56 million, accounting for
carbon tax revenue in various proportional taxation scenarios, 89.3% of the total population of Shanghai, while the rural popula-
but did not directly discuss the distribution effect of a carbon tax. tion only accounts for 10.7%. Furthermore, due to the limitation of
Z. Jiang, S. Shao / Energy Policy 73 (2014) 269–277 271

data availability, we cannot attain the detailed data about the Table 1
energy consumption of various income levels of rural households. Per capita energy consumptions of various income groups in 2010 (Unit: kgtce).
Source: Authors calculate by using related statistical data.
Therefore, we focus on the urban households which contain
almost 90% of the total population of Shanghai. According to Group Transport fuela Residential fuelb
Shanghai Statistical Yearbook, the urban households can be divided
into five groups: low, mid-low, mid, mid-high, and high income Low 20.67 56.37
groups. Mid-low 20.87 67.44
Mid 67.27 69.86
The energy consumption types of households include coal, Mid-high 105.93 69.86
petrol, diesel, liquefied petroleum gas (LPG), fuel gas, and elec- High 233.47 85.08
tricity.2 We estimate various types of energy consumptions of
a
different income groups in Shanghai by using the related data Transport fuels contain petrol and diesel.
b
Residential fuels contain coal, natural gas, pipeline gas, and LPG.
because it is unavailable directly from the statistical data. The
estimation process is as follows.
With respect to the consumption of petrol and diesel, we can 350
first obtain the per capita traffic expenditure of each group from Transport fuels Residential fuels
Shanghai Statistical Yearbook, which contains four aspects: family
300
vehicle, transport fuels, the services of vehicle, and traffic fees
according to China Urban Life and Price Yearbook. Compared the

Per capita energy consumption/kgtce


expenditure of each group of Shanghai with the corresponding 250
data of China, we can estimate the share of transport fuel
expenditure of each group in the total traffic expenditure and
200
then get the per capita expenditure of each group on transport
fuels in Shanghai. Considering that the majority of transport fuels
in China are petrol and diesel, the expenditure on transport fuels 150
can be treated as that on petrol and diesel. Multiplying the per
capita expenditure of each group on transport fuels by the
100
corresponding population of each group, the share of the expen-
diture of each group on petrol and diesel in the total expenditure
of five groups on them can be calculated. The share is equal to the 50
share of real petrol and diesel consumption of each group in the
total petrol and diesel consumption since all the households in
0
Shanghai face the unified oil prices. Furthermore, China Energy Low Mid-low Mid Mid-high High
Statistical Yearbook reports the various energy consumption of
Fig. 1. Per capita energy consumption of various income groups in 2010.
urban households in Shanghai, including the petrol and diesel
consumption. At last, multiplying the total petrol and diesel
consumption in Shanghai by the share above and then divided ladder” theory, the households with a low income usually rely on
by the population of each group, we can attain the per capita more traditional fuels like coal, while those with a high income
petrol and diesel consumption of each group. mainly use more modern fuels, such as natural gas and transport
With respect to residential fuels like coal and gas, the related fuels (petrol and diesel) (Barnes et al., 1997; Masera et al., 2000).
statistical data do not report their detailed categorical data. Our results are consistent with this theory (see Fig. 1). The
However, we can obtain the per capita expenditure of each group transport fuels consumption raises rapidly with the rise of house-
on residential fuels from Shanghai Residents' Life and Price Year- holds' income. The per capita transport fuels consumption of the
book, which can be regarded as a whole of all kinds of residential low-income group is only 20.67 kgtce, while that of the high-
fuels. Multiplying the per capita expenditure of each group on income group reaches 233.47 kgtce, which is ten times more than
residential fuels by the corresponding population of each group, the former, resulting from the more possession of private vehicles
the share of the expenditure of each group on them in the total of the high-income group. In the low-income group, the con-
expenditure of five groups can be estimated. Since all the house- sumption of transport fuels is obviously less than that of residen-
holds in Shanghai face the unified fuel prices, the share can also be tial fuels, while in the high-income group, the corresponding
treated as the share of real residential fuels consumption of each situation is reverse. The results indicate that the greater the
group. Based on the related data from China Energy Statistical income gap, the more obvious the energy ladder phenomenon.
Yearbook, summing up the consumptions of coal, natural gas,
pipeline gas, and LPG in the unit of coal equivalent, we can obtain
the total residential fuels consumption of urban households in 3. Distributional effects of carbon tax
Shanghai. Furthermore, multiplying the total residential fuels
consumption by the share above and then divided by the popula- Since the households in different income groups present
tion of each group, the per capita residential fuels consumption of different lifestyles and consumption patterns, they are likely to
each group in Shanghai can be calculated.3 substantially differ from the carbon tax payments. A carbon tax
Estimated per capita energy consumptions of various groups can affect prices of fossil fuels and consumers' expenditure in two
in 2010 are reported in Table 1 and Fig. 1. According to “energy channels. On one hand, due to the rise of fuel prices caused by a
carbon tax, households' expenditure on fuels as basic means of
subsistence (e.g., coal, petrol, and gas) will directly increase.
2
Since electricity is a secondary energy source and does not emit CO2 in its On the other hand, since a carbon tax will push up the prices
utilization process, it is not been taken into account in this paper. of products and services, especially energy-intensive ones, by
3
The evidence from the micro-level data, such as the survey data of China's
urban residents, may be more accurate and credible, but the energy data in China,
increasing the cost of production factor and raw material, house-
especially the micro-level energy data, are very limited. Hence, we mainly use the holds' expenditure on those products and services will indirectly
data released by the related statistical yearbook. increase. Such a channel can be regarded as the indirect effect of
272 Z. Jiang, S. Shao / Energy Policy 73 (2014) 269–277

a carbon tax on households' expenditure (Symons et al., 1994; Table 2


Rapanos, 1995; Cornwell and Creedy, 1996; Labandeira and Direct effect of a carbon tax.
Labeaga, 1999). Therefore, the distributional effect of a carbon
Group Per capita tax Share of the tax payment
tax can be divided into the direct effect and the indirect effect. payment (RMB) in expenditure (%)
Wier et al. (2005) pointed out that using the total households'
expenditure may be more preferable than using the income to Low 3.062 0.024
analyze the regressivity of the carbon tax. First, the tax base is Mid-low 3.508 0.022
Mid 5.472 0.025
expenditure, making it relevant to measure the regressivity Mid-high 7.029 0.026
relative to expenditure. Second, since households seek to smooth High 12.767 0.031
consumption over their life cycle according to permanent income
hypothesis, actual income may be inappropriate to measure the
regressivity. Thus, we adopt the impact of a carbon tax on the
households' expenditure to estimate its distributional effect,
which is measured by the households' tax payments relative to 15 0.035
Per capita tax payment
expenditure for the deciles. Proportion of carbon tax

3.1. Direct effect of carbon tax 12


0.030

Proportion of tax payment/%


Per capita tax payment/CNY
The direct effect of a carbon tax refers to affecting the house-
holds' expenditure through the direct fuel consumption. Assuming 9
that there is no energy substitution and households' energy
demand keeps constant when introducing a carbon tax,4 the direct 0.025

effect can be expressed as follows: 6

TAX direct
i ¼ ∑ TAX direct
ij ¼ ∑ Q j CEF j T ð1Þ
j j
0.020
where subscript i denotes various groups of households, subscript j 3

refers to various fuels, TAX direct


i denotes the direct effect of a
carbon tax of the ith group, TAX direct
ij is the direct effect of a carbon
tax of the ith group based on the jth fuel, Q j and CEF j are the 0 0.015
Group Low Low-mid Mid Mid-high High
consumption and CO2 emissions coefficient of the jth fuel, respec-
tively, and T is the carbon tax per unit of CO2 emissions, i.e., the Fig. 2. Direct effect of a carbon tax.
carbon tax rate.
We estimate CEF j by using the reference method and para- carbon tax rate should be 19–46 RMB per ton of CO2 for China's
meters in 2006 IPCC Guidelines for National Greenhouse Gas industry in 2009–2020. Referring to the studies above, the middle
Inventories together with China's released relevant parameters level of their purposed carbon tax rates, i.e., 20 RMB per ton of CO2
(see the detailed below). is chosen in this paper. The estimated results of the direct effect of
With respect to the CO2 emissions coefficient of transport fuels, a carbon tax on various income groups are presented in Table 2
according to China Energy Statistical Yearbook, we can first calcu- and Fig. 2.
late the shares of petrol and diesel in the total transport fuels The direct distributional effect of a carbon tax mainly relies on
consumption of urban residents in Shanghai, respectively. Then, households' fuels consumption and its structure, which are closely
multiplying their shares by the CO2 emissions coefficients of petrol related to households' income level. It is easily seen that the direct
and diesel, respectively, and summing them up, we can obtain the carbon tax payment increases with the income level, and its level
weighted CO2 emissions coefficient of transport fuels. With respect is relatively low. Even for the high-income group who bears the
to the CO2 emissions coefficient of residential fuels, because their largest direct impact, the carbon tax payment is only 12.767 RMB,
consumptions are measured in the standard unit of coal equiva- accounting for about 0.031% of the total household expenditure.
lent, we first convert the CO2 emissions coefficient measured in Hence, the direct effect of a carbon tax presents a weak progres-
the physical quantity into that in the standard unit of coal sivity and the tax burdens on various income groups are all
equivalent. Then, multiplying their CO2 emissions coefficients by relatively small.
their shares in the total residential fuels consumption, respec-
tively, and summing them up, we can get the weighted CO2
emissions coefficient of residential fuels. 3.2. Indirect effect of carbon tax
The Research Group of Ministry of Finance of China suggested
that China's carbon tax rate should be 10 RMB per ton of CO2 at the 3.2.1. Methods
beginning of its implementation, while the Planning Institute of As mentioned above, the indirect effect of a carbon tax roots
Ministry of Environmental Protection of China proposed 20 RMB in the increasing production cost of commodity induced by the
per ton of CO2. Chen (2011) argued that the rational range of the carbon tax. Since it involves industrial linkage, the input–output
model reflecting industrial relationship is a prevalent method to
4 simulate the indirect distributional effect of a carbon tax on
The fact may not be so. However, we focus on households’ consumption of
conventional fuels, which are difficult to be substituted by new fuels in the short households (Symons et al., 1994, 2000; Cornwell and Creedy,
term. Moreover, considering that the change of fuels demand depends on their 1996; Labandeira and Labeaga, 1999; Wier et al., 2005; Ahmad
price elasticity per se and cross-price elasticity, levying a carbon tax will push up and Stern, 2009; Grainger and Kolstad, 2010; Datta, 2010; Sun and
the prices of fuels with high carbon emissions and thus lead to more demand for Ueta, 2011; Fan and Zhang, 2013; Mathur and Morris, 2014). The
fuels with low carbon emissions. Such an increase in demand may in turn cause the
rise of prices of low-carbon fuels. Undoubtedly, it is very difficult to precisely
existing research samples cover developed and developing coun-
forecast the change of various fuels consumption of various groups. Hence, we tries, e.g., US, UK, France, Italy, Spain, Danish, Australia, India,
make the simplifying assumptions above. Pakistan, and China.
Z. Jiang, S. Shao / Energy Policy 73 (2014) 269–277 273

This approach generally assumes that no energy substitution used in our previous study (Shao et al., 2011) to estimate the CO2
takes place in the production process when introducing a carbon emissions of each industry, i.e., the reference method and para-
tax, and the tax burdens on producers are fully transmitted into meters in the 2nd Volume (Energy Volume) of 2006 IPCC Guide-
final commodity prices. Thus, those households that demand a lines for National Greenhouse Gas Inventories together with China's
commodity will eventually pay the carbon tax paid by the released relevant parameters. To obtain more accurate results, we
producer of this commodity (Labandeira and Labeaga, 1999; consider all types of final fossil fuels consumption reported in the
Wier et al., 2005; Ahmad and Stern, 2009; Sun and Ueta, 2011). statistical data except electricity and heat since CO2 is not directly
We will employ this approach, although the degree of transmis- emitted in the utilization of electricity and heat. The 15 kinds of
sion will depend on technological development and substitution involved energy source include raw coal, cleaned coal, coke, coke
possibilities in industries as well as in households. Moreover, oven gas, other gases, crude oil, petrol, kerosene, diesel, fuel oil,
because the estimate of indirect carbon tax payments may suffer liquefied petroleum gas, refinery gas, natural gas, other petroleum
from some uncertainty, the tax payments are assumed to be linear products, and other coking products. As we know, this paper takes
in the production of each sector (Labandeira and Labeaga, 1999; into account the most types of energy source among the related
Wier et al., 2005; Grainger and Kolstad, 2010; Fan and Zhang, studies on Shanghai. The estimation formula is as follows:
2013). Thus, the carbon tax payments from the indirect energy
C i ¼ ∑ C ij ¼ ∑ Eij  N j  CC j  Oj  M ð3Þ
demand of households can be expressed as follows: j j

TAX indirect
i ¼ TEðI  AÞ  1 Cei ð2Þ where subscript i denotes the industrial sector, subscript j refers to
various fuels, C i stands for the gross energy-related CO2 emissions
where subscript i denotes various groups of households, TAX indirect
of the ith sector, C ij is the CO2 emissions of the ith sector based on
is the total indirect carbon tax payments of households as a
the jth fuel, Eij denotes the total energy consumption of the ith
consequence of the consumption of goods and services, T is the
sector based on the jth fuel, N j , CC j , and Oj are the net calorific
carbon tax per unit of CO2 emissions, E is a vector of the CO2
value, carbon content, and the carbon oxidation factor of the jth
emission intensity (i.e., CO2 emissions per unit of economic out-
fuel, respectively, and M is the molecular weight ratio of CO2 to
put) of each sector in the input–output table, ðI  AÞ  1 is the
carbon (44/12).
Leontief inverse matrix, I is a unit matrix and A is a coefficient
The use of special parameters of each country is encouraged by
matrix describing inter-sector commodity flows, C is a matrix of
the IPCC (2006) based on its methods. Therefore, we adopt the
the composition of consumption commodity aggregates, i.e.,
principle of priority to select the related parameters announced
the private consumption commodity aggregates apportioned by
officially in China and the second choice of the defaults provided
production sectors, and e is a vector including the households'
by the IPCC (2006) to assure the accuracy of the results. The
expenditure of each commodity consumption.
involved data are derived from Shanghai Statistical Yearbooks on
Industry, Energy, and Transport, China Energy Statistical Yearbook,
3.2.2. Data and The People's Republic of China National Greenhouse Gas
To get the CO2 emission intensity of each industry, the CO2 Inventory.
emissions should be estimated. Since we assume the carbon tax According to the classification of industrial sectors in the China
levying upon fossil fuels, we consider the CO2 emissions of each Energy Statistical Yearbook, we re-classify and integrate 133 sectors
industry from the fossil fuels combustion rather than those from in the 2007 Input–Output Tables of Shanghai into 42 sectors, whose
the production process. We employ the method and parameters output data can be derived from Shanghai Statistical Yearbooks on

Table 3
CO2 emission intensity of 42 sectors in 2007 (Unit: kg/RMB).

Sector CO2 emission Sector CO2 emission


intensity intensity

Production and supply of electric power and heat power 0.7369 Manufacture of textile wearing apparel, footwear and caps 0.0071
Processing of petroleum, coking, and nuclear fuel 0.1882 Other sectors 0.0065
Smelting and pressing of ferrous metals 0.1641 Manufacture of metal products 0.0062
Transport, storage, and post 0.1292 Manufacture of articles for culture, education, and sport activities 0.0053
Manufacture of raw chemical materials and chemical products 0.0558 Manufacture of general purpose machinery 0.0050
Agriculture, forestry, animal husbandry, and fishery 0.0511 Printing, reproduction of recording media 0.0049
Manufacture of non-metallic mineral products 0.0503 Manufacture of artwork and the recycling and disposal of waste 0.0042
Manufacture of paper and paper products 0.0349 Manufacture of leather, fur, feather and related products 0.0032
Manufacture of rubber 0.0291 Manufacture of transport equipment 0.0026
Manufacture of textile 0.0252 Manufacture of furniture 0.0021
Wholesale, retail trades, hotels, and catering services 0.0202 Manufacture of special purpose machinery 0.0021
Manufacture of medicines 0.0141 Manufacture of electrical machinery and equipment 0.0019
Processing of food from agricultural products 0.0129 Production and supply of fuel gas 0.0013
Manufacture of chemical fibers 0.0127 Production and supply of water 0.0011
Manufacture of beverage 0.0120 Manufacture of measuring instruments and machinery for 0.0006
cultural activity and office work
Extraction of petroleum and natural gas 0.0116 Manufacture of communication equipment, computers and other 0.0005
electronic equipment
Manufacture of foods 0.0109 Manufacture of tobacco 0.0003
Construction 0.0106 Mining and washing of coal N.A.a
Processing of timber and manufacture of wood, bamboo, rattan, 0.0099 Mining and processing of ferrous metal ores N.A.a
palm, and straw products
Smelting and pressing of non-ferrous metals 0.0085 Mining and processing of non-ferrous metal ores N.A.a
Manufacture of plastics 0.0082 Mining and processing of non-metal ores N.A.a

a
Expect the extraction of petroleum and natural gas, mining and processing industries in Shanghai have no actual output and fuel consumption in most years due to the
poor natural resources endowment in Shanghai.
274 Z. Jiang, S. Shao / Energy Policy 73 (2014) 269–277

Industry, Energy, and Transport. The calculated CO2 emission Table 4


intensity of each sector in 2007 is shown in Table 3. Indirect effect of a carbon tax.
Table 3 indicates that the production and supply sector of
Group Per capita tax Share of the tax payment
electric power and heat power in Shanghai presents the highest payment (RMB) in expenditure (%)
CO2 emission intensity as a result of 0.737 kg/RMB. This is mainly
because that the coal-fired power plants are dominant in Shang- Low 104.08 0.829
hai, which consume a large number of coal as the highest emitting Mid-low 130.46 0.817
Mid 160.43 0.742
fossil fuel. As expected, some energy-intensive sectors, such as Mid-high 195.90 0.732
processing of petroleum, coking, nuclear fuel, smelting and press- High 277.29 0.681
ing of ferrous metals, and transport, storage, and post also show a
relatively high CO2 emission intensity, while the manufactures of
tobacco, communication equipment, computers and other electro-
nic equipment, and measuring instruments and machinery for
cultural activity and office work have a remarkably low CO2 300 Direct effect Indirect effect 0.87
emission intensity. Proportion of tax payment

250 0.84
3.2.3. Results and discussion
According to Shanghai Statistical Yearbook, the expenditure of

Proportion of tax payment/%


Per capita tax payment/CNY
households in Shanghai includes eight categories: food, clothing, 200
0.81
residence, household facilities and articles, health care and med-
ical services, transport and communications, education, cultural
150
and recreation, other miscellaneous goods and services. As shown 0.78

in Fig. 3, there is an obvious difference in both scale and structure


of expenditure among various groups in Shanghai. The low- 100
0.75
income group pays more for food, with the highest Engel coeffi-
cient of 42%. With the rise of income level, the share of food in the
50
total expenditure decreases, while the transport and communica- 0.72
tions expenditure noticeably increases. Such results indicate that
the expenditure of the low-income and high-income groups is 0
Group Low Low-high Mid Mid-high High
mainly used for basic requirements and the high quality of life,
respectively. Fig. 4. Total distributional effect of a carbon tax.
Based on the input–output table released by the Shanghai
Statistics Bureau, we merge the input–output table into 42 sectors.
And then, we match the residential consumption categories to the group is 0.681%. Summing up the direct effect in Table 2 and the
corresponding sectors in the input–output table. According to indirect effect in Table 4, we can get the total distributional effect
Eq. (2), the indirect effects of a carbon tax on various income of a carbon tax (see Fig. 4).
groups are estimated and presented in Table 4. Similar to the results of the indirect effect, Fig. 4 suggests that
The estimated results indicate that although the indirect the total distributional effect of a carbon tax presents an evident
carbon tax payment increases with the income level, its share in regressivity. As income rises, the total carbon tax payment
the total expenditure presents a downward trend from low- increases, but it constitutes a smaller and smaller share in the
income group to high-income group. Hence, the indirect effect of total expenditure, decreasing from 0.853% of the low-income
a carbon tax shows a significant regressivity. Compared with the group to 0.712% of the high-income group. Hence, the low-
high-income group, the low-income group bears heavier tax. The income group bears more tax burden than other income groups.
share of the carbon tax payment in the total expenditure of the This finding is consistent with the conclusions of most current
low-income group is 0.829%, while this share of the high-income studies (Cornwell and Creedy, 1996; Brännlund and Nordström,
2004; Kerkhof et al., 2008; Shammin and Bullard, 2009; Mathur
45000 Food Clothing Residence Household Facilities and Services and Morris, 2014), i.e., the distributional effect of a carbon tax is
Health Care and Medical Services Transport and Communications regressive. In addition, we find that the indirect effect is much
Education, Cultural and Recreation Services
40000 Miscellaneous Goods and Services
larger than the direct. This means that the indirect distributional
effect of a carbon tax on households induced by pushing up the
35000 prices of products and services, especially energy-intensive ones,
is far greater than its direct distributional effect caused by
30000 consuming fuels.
Expenditure/CNY

25000

4. Measurement of carbon tax progressivity


20000

The tax progressivity is the most commonly used concept to


15000
study the tax distribution in different income groups. The Suits
10000
index proposed by Suits (1977) is widely adopted to examine the
progressivity and regressivity of taxes, which is based on the
5000 principle of the concentration curve and the Gini coefficient. Fig. 5
depicts an example of a concentration curve used to calculate the
0 Suits index, where the accumulated percent of the tax burden is
Group Low Low-mid Mid Mid-high High
plotted vertically while the accumulated percent of the income on
Fig. 3. Expenditure structure of various income groups in Shanghai in 2010. the horizontal axis.
Z. Jiang, S. Shao / Energy Policy 73 (2014) 269–277 275

100 B Table 5
Suits index of a carbon tax.

Effect Suits index

Direct 0.022
Accumulated percent of tax burden

Indirect  0.082
Total  0.078

50 100

C
80

Accumulated percent of tax burden (direct)


L

60

0 A
0 50 100
Accumulated percent of income 40
Fig. 5. An example of the concentration curve used to calculate the Suits index.

Following Suits (1977), the Suits index is specified as follows:


20
S ¼ ðK  LÞ=K ¼ 1  ðL=KÞ ð4Þ
where S denotes the Suits index (i.e., the index of tax progressiv-
ity), K refers to the area of the triangle OAB in Fig. 5, and L stands 0
0 20 40 60 80 100
for the area OABC between the curve and the horizontal axis OA.
The Suits index varies from  1 to 1. In the case of regressivity, Accumulated percent of income

L 4K and 1 rS o0, while a proportional tax implies L ¼K and Fig. 6. Concentration curve of the direct effect.
S ¼0, and a progressive tax yields LoK and 0 oS r1. Suggested in
Suits (1977):
1 n fossil fuels, the Suits index of the direct effect is 0.022, indicating
S ¼ 1 ∑ ½Tðyi Þ þTðyi  1 Þðyi  yi  1 Þ ð5Þ that the direct effect of the carbon tax is progressive, but the
10000 i ¼ 1
progressivity is small, approximately proportional. The Suits
where yi denotes the accumulated percent of the income, mea- indices of the indirect effect and the total effect are  0.082 and
sured on the horizontal axis, which ranges from 0 to 100, Tðyi Þ is  0.078, respectively. Therefore, on the whole, levying a carbon tax
the corresponding accumulated percent of the tax burden from a on fossil fuels appears regressive in Shanghai since the tax burden
given tax, and n stands for the number of households' income on low-income households is greater than that of high-
groups. income ones.
Since the 1980s, many studies employed the Suits index to Furthermore, we present the concentration curves of distribu-
measure the distribution effect of taxation or public expenditure. tional effects of a carbon tax in Figs. 6–8, which also consolidate
For instance, Kienzle (1981) empirically demonstrated that the the results in Table 5. Fig. 6 shows that the concentration curve
Suits measurement methodology applied in a broader and more is below the diagonal line but very close to it. This suggests that
useful sense in public taxation and expenditure analysis than the the progressivity of the direct effect of a carbon tax is weak in
previous methods. Sarte (1997) combined a dynamic equilibrium Shanghai. Figs. 7 and 8 show that the concentration curves are
model with the Suits index to analyze the effects of progressive above the diagonal line, further indicating that the indirect effect
taxation on the degree of income inequality in a competitive and the total effect of a carbon tax in Shanghai are all regressive.
economy and asserted that the Suits index is a helpful indication of
the tax burden borne by each agent type. Using the Suits index,
Metcalf (1999) assessed the distributional impact of a shift toward 5. Conclusions and policy implications
greater reliance on various environmental tax policies. Further-
more, Price and Novak (1999) and Hansen et al. (2000) employed China has become the largest CO2 emissions country in the
the Suits index to investigate the issue of the tax incidence of world, accounting for one-quarter of global CO2 emissions in 2011
lotteries. The studies for China were conducted by Liu and Nie and 80% of the world's rise in CO2 emissions since 2008 (Peters et
(2004, 2009), who used the Suits index to estimate the distribu- al., 2012; Liu et al., 2013). With the deepening of industrialization
tional impact of three major indirect taxes, including value added and urbanization, China's economic development has to encounter
tax, consumption tax, and business tax. Recently, Sterner (2012) the rigid energy demands and severe environmental constrains.
also adopted the Suits index to examine the distributional effects Energy saving and emission reduction have become the necessary
of transport fuels taxation in seven European countries and found way to resolve the conflicts among economy, energy, and the
some weak evidence of regressivity. environment, and to realize the sustainable development. As the
However, the study using the Suits index to measure the economic center of China, Shanghai should play a leading role in
distributional effect of a carbon tax in China is still absent. energy saving and emission reduction. Although a carbon tax is
According to Eq. (5), the Suits index of a carbon tax in Shanghai generally regarded as an effective policy instrument to reduce
is estimated and reported in Table 5. Once levying a carbon tax on CO2 emissions, it will inevitably generate the redistribution of
276 Z. Jiang, S. Shao / Energy Policy 73 (2014) 269–277

100 regressive and thus can intensify income inequality. The progres-
sivity of the direct distributional effect is approximately propor-
tional. However, the indirect and the total distributional effects are
all significantly regressive. Therefore, the tax burden on the low-
Accumulated percent of tax burden (indirect)

80
income group is the highest.
The distributional effect of a carbon tax is a key factor in
determining whether it can be accepted by the public and be
60 successfully implemented, especially under the special back-
ground of the widening income gap in China. This study indicates
that the high-income group consumes more transport fuels than
other groups. Barker and Köhler (1998) also argued that imposing
40 a carbon tax on transport fuels will result in a progressive effect.
Hence, at the beginning of implementing a carbon tax, it can be
considered to impose it first on transport fuels and then to
gradually expand the scope of taxation. Moreover, as pointed out
20
by Hammar and Jagers (2007), different carbon tax rates should be
applied to different energy products. For instance, petrol and
diesel should be imposed on by higher tax rates while those
0
essential energy sources for heating, which is generally used by
0 20 40 60 80 100 low-income households, should be imposed on by lower tax rates.
Accumulated percent of income Alternatively, households whose income level is below the stan-
dard line can be exempted from the carbon tax.
Fig. 7. Concentration curve of the indirect effect.
Undoubtedly, compared with other mitigation measures of
100
climate change, it is one of important features of a carbon tax to
increase tax revenue. Some researchers believe that a carbon tax
can generate a result of “double dividend” (Pearce, 1991; Goulder,
1995). If such a “double dividend” hypothesis is tenable, the
80 redistribution of the carbon tax revenue will play a key role in
Accumulated percent of tax burden(total)

its distributional effect. This means that the regressivity of a


carbon tax can be restricted or even eliminated by rationally
60
designing the redistribution mode of the tax revenue. Barker and
Köhler (1998) testified that different redistribution modes can lead
to different distributional effects of a carbon tax. When the carbon
tax revenue is used to reduce the payroll tax, a carbon tax will be
40 weakly regressive. When the revenue is used for transfer pay-
ments, it will be strongly progressive. Therefore, when introducing
a carbon tax, some associated redistribution or compensation
20 measures should be implemented pertinently to the greatest
extent, such as purposive transfer payments, reducing or exempt-
ing some distorting taxes, and subsidizing low-income groups, so
as to restrain potential economic distortion, negative impacts, and
0 the damage to the social welfare caused by a carbon tax and thus
0 20 40 60 80 100
to assure optimal economic results of implementing a carbon tax.
Accumulated percent of income
Moreover, the implementation of a carbon tax is more likely to be
Fig. 8. Concentration curve of the total effect. successful when wide economic reforms are carried out simulta-
neously, such as energy subsidies reform.
households' income. Thus, this paper estimates and discusses the
impacts of a carbon tax on the expenditure of households in
different income groups in Shanghai. The main conclusions are
summarized as follows. Acknowledgments
First, households' energy consumption accords with the
“energy ladder” theory. The distributional effect of a carbon tax This paper is supported by the National Natural Science Founda-
can be divided into two parts: the direct and indirect effects. The tion of China (Nos. 71003068 and 71373153), the Ministry of
expenditure resulting from a carbon tax increases with the rise of Education Foundation of China (No. 12YJC790081), the Program
households' income level. The expenditure from the indirect effect for New Century Excellent Talents in University (No. NCET-13-0890),
of a carbon tax is more than that from the direct effect. The direct Shanghai “Chen Guang” Program (No. 12CG45), the Shanghai Soft
distributional effect presents a weak progressivity, while the Science Research Program (No. 14692103900), and the Key Project of
indirect distributional effect is significantly regressive. Thus, the Zhejiang Statistics Research Program (No. 201416).
total distributional effect is also regressive, indicating that low-
income households bear more tax burden. The direct effect largely
depends on the quantity and structure of households' fuels References
consumption, while the decisive factors of the indirect effect are
the CO2 emission intensity of various economic sectors and Ahmad, E., Stern, N., 2009. Effective Carbon Taxes and Public Policy Options:
households' expenditure structure. Insights from India and Pakistan. Asia Research Centre Working Paper no. 28,
London School of Economics and Political Science, London, UK.
Second, both the Suits index and the concentration curve of the Baranzini, A., Goldemberg, J., Speck, S., 2000. A future for carbon taxes. Ecol. Econ.
carbon tax indicate that imposing a carbon tax on fossil fuels is 32 (3), 395–412.
Z. Jiang, S. Shao / Energy Policy 73 (2014) 269–277 277

Barker, T., Köhler, J., 1998. Equity and ecotax reform in the EU: achieving a 10 Metcalf, G.E., 1999. A distributional analysis of green tax reforms. Natl. Tax J. 52 (4),
percent reduction in CO2 emissions using excise duties. Fisc. Stud. 19 (4), 655–682.
375–402. Metcalf, G.E., 2009. Cost Containment in Climate Change Policy: Alternative
Barnes, D.F., Plas, R.V.D., Floor, W.M., 1997. Tackling the rural energy problem in Approaches to Mitigation Price Volatility. NBER (National Bureau of Economic
developing countries. Financ. Dev. 34 (2), 11–15. Research) Working Paper no. 15125, 〈http://www.nber.org/papers/w15125〉.
Brännlund, R., Nordström, J., 2004. Carbon tax simulations using a household Mathur, A., Morris, A.C., 2014. Distributional effects of a carbon tax in broader U.S.
demand model. Eur. Econ. Rev. 48 (1), 211–233. fiscal reform. Energy Policy 66, 326–334.
Brenner, M.D., Riddle, M., Boyce, J., 2007. A Chinese sky trust? Distributional Masera, O.R., Saatkamp, B.D., Kammen, D.M., 2000. From linear fuel switching to
impacts of carbon charges and revenue recycling in China. Energy Policy 35, multiple cooking strategies: a critique and alternative to the energy ladder
1771–1784. model. World Dev. 28, 2083–2103.
Bureau, B., 2011. Distributional effects of a carbon tax on car fuels in France. Energy Pearce, D.W., 1991. The role of carbon taxes in adjusting to global warming. Econ. J.
Econ. 33 (1), 121–130.
101 (407), 938–948.
Cao, J., 2009. Development of low carbon: the design of Chinese carbon tax policy
Poterba, J.M., 1991. Is the gasoline tax regressive? Tax Policy Econ. 5, 145–164.
and the analysis of CGE model. J. Financ. Res. 12, 19–29.
Peters, G.P., Marland, G., Quéré, C.L., Boden, T., Canadell, J.G., Raupach, M.R., 2012.
Chen, S.Y., 2011. Marginal abatement cost and environmental tax reform in China.
Rapid growth in CO2 emissions after the 2008–2009 global financial crisis. Nat.
Soc. Sci. China 3, 85–100.
Clim. Chang. 2, 2–4.
Cornwell, A., Creedy, J., 1996. Carbon taxation, prices and inequality in Australia.
Price, D.I., Novak, E.S., 1999. The tax incidence of the three Texas lottery games:
Fisc. Stud. 17 (3), 21–38.
Datta, A., 2010. The incidence of fuel taxation in India. Energy Econ. 32 (S1), regressivity, race, and education. Natl. Tax J. 52 (4), 741–751.
S26–S33. Rapanos, V.T., 1995. The effects of environmental taxes on income distribution.
Dissou, Y., Siddiqui, M.S., 2014. Can carbon taxes be progressive? Energy Econ. 42 Eur. J. Polit. Econ. 11 (3), 487–501.
(3), 88–100. Sarte, P.G., 1997. Progressive taxation and income inequality in dynamic competi-
Fan, Y., Zhang, H., 2013. Income distribution impacts of carbon tax Chinese urban tive equilibrium. J. Public Econ. 66, 145–171.
residents and the design of carbon subsidy scheme. Econ. Theory Bus. Manag. 7, Sterner, T., 2012. Distributional effects of taxing transport fuel. Energy Policy 41,
81–91. 75–83.
Gonzalez, F., 2012. Distributional effects of carbon taxes: the case of Mexico. Energy Suits, D.B., 1977. Measurement of tax progressivity. Am. Econ. Rev. 67 (4), 747–752.
Econ. 34 (6), 2102–2115. Shammin, R.M., Bullard, W.C., 2009. Impact of cap-and-trade policies for reducing
Goulder, L.H., 1995. Effects of carbon taxes in an economy with prior tax greenhouse gas emissions on U.S. households. Ecol. Econ. 68 (8–9), 2432–2438.
distortions: an intertemporal general equilibrium analysis. J. Environ. Econ. Su, M., Fu, Z.H., Xu, W., Wang, Z.G., Li, X., Liang, Q., 2009. The research of levying
Manag. 29 (3), 271–297. carbon tax in China. Rev. Econ. Res. 72, 2–16.
Grainger, C.A., Kolstad, C.D., 2010. Who pays a price on carbon? Environ. Resour. Symons, E.J., Proops, J., Gay, P., 1994. Carbon taxes, consumer demand and carbon
Econ. 46 (3), 359–376. dioxide emissions: a simulation analysis for the UK. Fisc. Stud. 15 (2), 19–43.
Hammar, H., Jagers, S.C., 2007. What is a fair CO2 tax increase? On fair emission Symons, E.J., Speck, S., Proops, J.L.R., 2000. The Effects of Pollution and Energy Taxes
reductions in the transport sector. Ecol. Econ. 61 (2–3), 377–387. Across the European Income Distribution. Keele Department of Economics
Hansen, A., Miyazaki, A.D., Sprott, D.E., 2000. The tax incidence of lotteries: Discussion Papers, Department of Economics, Keele University.
evidence from five states. J. Consum. Aff. 34 (2), 182–203. Sun, W., Ueta, K., 2011. The distributional effects of a China carbon tax: a rural–
IPCC, 2006. 2006 IPCC Guidelines for National Greenhouse Gas Inventories, 〈http:// urban assessment. Kyoto Econ. Rev. 80 (2), 188–206.
www.ipcc-nggip.iges.or.jp/public/2006gl/vol2.html〉. Shao, S., Yang, L.L., Yu, M.B., Yu, M.L., 2011. Estimation, characteristics, and
Jacobsen, H.K., Birr-Pedersen, K., Wier, M., 2003. Distributional implications of determinants of energy-related industrial CO2 emissions in Shanghai (China),
environmental taxation in Denmark. Fisc. Stud. 24 (4), 477–499. 1994–2009. Energy Policy 39 (10), 6476–6494.
Kienzle, E.C., 1981. Measurement of the progressivity of public expenditures and Tiezzi, S., 2005. The welfare effects and the distributive impact of carbon taxation
net fiscal incidence. South. Econ. J. 48 (1), 197–203. on Italian households. Energy Policy 33 (12), 1597–1612.
Kerkhof, C.A., Moll, C.H., Drissen, H., Wilting, C.H., 2008. Taxation of multiple Wier, M., Birr-Pedersen, K., Jacobsen, H.K., Klok, J., 2005. Are CO2 taxes regressive?
greenhouse gases and the effects on income distribution: a case study of the
Evidence from the Danish experience. Ecol. Econ. 52 (2), 239–251.
Netherlands. Ecol. Econ. 67 (2), 318–326.
Yang, L.L., Shao, S., 2013. Techno-economic Drivers of Energy-related Industrial CO2
Liu, Z., Guan, D.B., Crawford-Brown, D., Zhang, Q., He, K., Liu, J., 2013. A low-carbon
Emissions Growth in Shanghai (China) over 1994–2011. School of Urban and
road map for China. Nature 500, 143–145.
Regional Science Working Paper, Shanghai University of Finance and
Liu, Y., Nie, H., 2004. Effect of indirect tax incidence on income distribution. Econ.
Res. J. 5, 22–30. Economics.
Liu, Y., Nie, H., 2009. Effects of value added tax and business tax on income Yusuf, A.A., Resosudarmo, B., 2007. On the Distributional Effect of Carbon Tax in
distribution. Financ. Trade Econ. 6, 63–68. Developing Countries: The Case of Indonesia. Economics and Development
Labandeira, X., Labeaga, J., 1999. Combining input–output analysis and micro- Studies Working Paper no. 200705, Department of Economics, Padjadjaran
simulation to assess the effects of carbon taxation on Spanish households. Fisc. University.
Stud. 20 (3), 305–320.

You might also like