You are on page 1of 10

140 CAROLINE HOWARD GR0N AND HEIDI HOULBERG SALOMONSEN

Rhodes, Rod, and Heidi H. Salomonsen (2018). ‘Duopoly, court politics and the Danish Gore
Executive’, presented at Seminar on ‘Cabinet Government for the Twenty First Century’, CHAPTER 10
University of Cambridge, 17-18 September 2018.
Salomonsen, Heidi H„ and Tim Knudsen (2011). ‘Changes in public service bargains: Ministers
and civil servants in Denmark’, Public Administration, 89/3:1015-35.
Smith-Udvalget, Bo (2015). Embedsmanden i det moderne folkestyre. Copenhagen: Jurist- og
0konom for bundels Forlag. MUNICIPALITIES
Sorensen, Eva M. (2014). ‘0konomiskstyring afkommunerne i en krisetid’, in Caroline H. Gron,
Mads B. Kristiansen, and Hanne F. Hansen, eds, Offentlig styring: Forandringer i en krisetid. AND REGIONS
Copenhagen: Hans Reitzels Forlag.
Statistics Denmark (2017). ‘Kommuner og regioner star for trefjerdedele af det offentlige Approaching the Limit of Decentralization?
forbrug’ (Corrected 7 June 2018), https://www.dst.dk/da/Statistik/bagtal/2017/2017-13-10-
kommuner-og-regioner-staar-for-trefjerdedele-af-det-offentlige-forbrug (accessed 18
November 2019).
Transparency International (2018). ‘Corruption perceptions index, 2017’, https://www.transpar- KURT HOULBERG AND NIELS EJERSBO
ency.0rg/news/feature/corruption_perceptions_index_2017#table (accessed 18 November
2019).
Tynell, Jesper (2016). Morkelygten. Embedsmcend fortceller om politisk tilskcering af tal, jura og
fakta. Frederiksberg: Samfundslitteratur.
UNDP (2018). Human Development Indicies and Indicators. 2018 Statistical Report. United
Nations Development Program. Local Politics in the Eye of
van Thiel, Sandra (2012). ‘Comparing agencies across countries’, in Koen Verhoest, Sandra van
Thiel, Geert Bouckaert, and Per Laegreid, eds, Government Agencies: Practices and Lessons
Decentralization, a Big-Bang Local
from 30 Countries. London: Palgrave MacMillan: 18-26. Government Reform, and a Toughened
Verhoest, Koen, Sandra van Thiel, Geert Bouckaert, and Per Laegreid. (2012). ‘Introduction’, in
Koen Verhoest, Sandra van Thiel, Geert Bouckaert, and Per Laegreid, eds, Government National Spending Regime
Agencies: Practices and Lessons from 30 Countries. London: Palgrave Macmillan, 3-17.
White Paper (1993). Fagligt etiske principper i offentlig administration. Betcenkning afgivet af
DJOF’s fagligt etiske arbejdsgruppe, September. Copenhagen: DJ0F. Denmark is among the most decentralized countries in the world, both when it comes
Wind, Mariene (2010). ‘The Nordics, the EU and the reluctance towards supranational to fiscal decentralization (Ivanyna and Shah 2014; Kodden 2004) and local autonomy
judicial review’, Journal ofCommon Market Studies, 4/48:1039-63. (Ladner et al. 2016). The three-tier level of government today encompasses two levels of
Wivel, Anders (2013). ‘From peacemaker to warmonger? Explaining Denmark’s Great Power subnational governments besides the state level: regions and municipalities. After dec­
politics’, Sw/ss Political Science Review, 19/3:298-321.
ades of gradual consolidation and stabilization (Blom-Hansen 1999) and no dramatic
Zucker, Lynne G. (1986). ‘Production of trust: Institutional sources of economie structure,
changes in the Danish local government system (Elklit and Kjaer 2007), the turn of the
1840-1920’, Organizational Behavior, 8: 53-111.
millennium marked dramatic changes. In 2007, a quick and radical local government
reform was implemented (Mouritzen 2010). In 2002, the Minister of the Interior stated
that the government had no plans to change the structure of the local governments, but
four months later, a commission on administrative structure was formed, and after
another four years, the biggest local government reform in 35 years was implemented by
1 January 2007 (Mouritzen 2010). This included the amalgamation of 271 municipalities
into 98 municipalities and the replacement of 14 counties with 5 new regions as well as
simultaneous transfers of functions between the three tiers. As a consequence of the
mergers, the average population size of municipalities changed dramatically from
approximately 20,000 inhabitants to 55,000 inhabitants (Blom-Hansen et al. 2014), and
Danish municipalities are now relatively large in comparative terms (Baldersheim and
142 KURT HOULBERG AND NIELS EJERSBO
Rosé 2010). At regional level, the size of the jurisdictions simultaneously increased from
340,000 to 1.1 million inhabitants.
Less than two years after the local government reform, Denmark was hit by the
financial crisis, and in the wake of the crisis, the national government implemented a
strengthened spending regime on all three tiers of government, including spending
ceilings enforced by law for both municipalities and regions overall (Houlberg 2018;
Suenson et al. 2016). This so-called ‘Budget Law’ has been labelled the most important
public spending act ever (Suenson et al. 2016), and it has affected central-local relations,
the role of Local Government Denmark (LGDK), and the Danish Regions (DR), as well
as local discretion and fiscal management focus. Budget overruns usually characterized
the municipalities as well as the regions at large prior to the Budget Law, whereas budget
undenuns seem to be a permanent feature after the implementation of the sanction
regime (Houlberg 2018). Against this background, we ask: what are the consequences of
a major local government reform followed by a national spending regime for a highly
decentralized local government system?
First, the chapter briefly describes the administrative structure of Denmark after the
local government reform. Second, we describe and discuss the local political system and
the administrative and political structure of municipalities and regions. This is followed
by a discussion of local discretion in the light of changed central regulation. We then
look at local expenditures and revenues and how their distribution is influenced by the
reform and by changes in central-local relations. We conclude with a discussion of the
challenges and opportunities for the Danish local government system.
The Administrative
Structure of Denmark
Denmark is a unitary state consisting of central government, 5 regions, and 98 munici­
palities. As part of the local government reform in 2007, tasks were transferred from
counties to the state (e.g. youth education and larger roads) and to the municipalities
(e.g. environmental regulation and specialized institutions for the disabled), and from
municipalities to the state (e.g. tax assessment). Table 10.1 shows the functions of the
three tiers after 2007, including the subsequent transfer of responsibility for the insured
unemployed from central government to municipalities in 2009.
The local government reform was both a centralization and a decentralization reform.
On the one hand, the main direction of task transfers was from regional to local level, i.e.
increased decentralization. On the other hand, the main entities for local democracy
and provision of public services, the municipalities, got larger, thus increasing the dis-
tance between citizens and politicians. Transfers of tasks to central level from municipal
level (tax assessment) and regional level (youth education) represent other clements of
centralization.
144 KURT HOULBERG AND NIELS EJERSBO MUNICIPALITIES AND REGIONS 145

Table 10.1 shows that the municipalities are multi-purpose units responsible for large, between politicians and council officials. Denmark has formally prioritized a layman
expensive, politically salient and important tasks. Apart from hospitals, the municipal­ rule, dispersion of power, and consensus with the consequence that the power structure
ities are responsible for all citizen-related public services and account for 50 per cent of between the mayor, the committees, and the administration is rather opaque (Andersen
total public expenditure. In contrast in 2007, the regions were stripped of almost all 2010; Kjaer and Mouritzen 2003:204-5).
other tasks with the exception of hospitals and therefore resemble single-purpose juris- At regional level, the counties had a political system similar to the municipalities until
dictions today. In sum, the regional tasks account for 12 per cent of total public expend­ the 2007 reform, but important changes in the regional political system were imple-
iture (Mortensen 2014: 87). Thus, the municipal level is more than ever the focal pivot mented as part of the 2007 reform (Blom-Hansen and Heeager 2011). The regional coun­
for balancing between local democracy and implementing agency of the state (Blom- cil, which has 41 members, is the supreme body. In addition, there is a regional chairman
Hansen and Heeager 2011). holding a position comparable to the municipal mayor. However, the regions do not
have a committee system. They may, but are not obliged to, leave daily administrative
marters to an executive committee, but they cannot establish standing sectoral commit­
tees like the municipalities and the old counties (Blom-Hansen and Heeager 2011).
The Local Political System Elections for municipal and regional councils are held simultaneously every four
and Democracy years. The turnout has remained relatively stable and comparatively high at approxi-
mately 70 per cent (for a discussion on local elections and electoral turnout see Kjaer 2020;
Hansen 2020). As turnout has been stable for many years, Danish municipalities have
The political system in the municipalities consists of three bodies: a council, a set of not experienced a political crisis regarding local democratie legitimacy (Andersen 2010).
standing committees, and a mayor (Blom-Hansen and Heeager 2011). The political rule However, the historically high levels of political trust and political self-efficacy at local
of the system may be termed a committee-leader rule (Mouritzen and Svara 2002: 60). level as well as identification with the municipality have been showing declining ten-
The municipalities are governed by the city councils with between 9 and 31 members dencies, not least in the municipalities amalgamated in 2007 and the first years after the
(except Copenhagen with 55 members) elected every four years. The mayor is elected 2007 reform (Hansen and Hjelmar 2015; Kjasr et al. 2010; Lassen and Serritzlew 2011).
by and among local councillors on a simple majority basis and is the formal head of the Turnout, however, seems to be unaffected by the municipal amalgamations in 2007
administration as well as the chair of the Financial Committee. The mayor is the only (Olsen 2010).
full-time politician in the municipality.
The mandatory Financial Executive Committee is responsible for and supervises
the budget and other financial affairs of the municipality. The tasks of the Financial
The Administrative Structure of
Executive Committee are determined by statute. There are fewer legal restrictions to
the establishment of the standing committees; however, at least one in addition to the Municipalities and Regions
Financial Committee must be established. Most municipalities have between four and
seven such committees. These are typically the Financial Committee, a social committee,
a school and culture committee, and a technical committee responsible for public Util­ The administrative structure in Danish municipalities has always been subject to change
ities, roads, and environmental regulation (Blom-Hansen 2002:88). The members of the (Hansen et al. 2010), and there has been considerable variation in structural arrangements
standing committees are also elected by and among the council members but on a pro- (Baekgaard 2009; Ejersbo 1998).
portional basis. All councillors are guaranteed at least one committee seat. The administration of the municipalities typically follows one of two models. About
Power is dispersed between the committees, the Financial Executive Committee, and one third of the municipalities use the sector-based departmental model, while the
the mayor (Andersen 2010). The committees are responsible for the day-to-day admin­ other two thirds use either an executive board model or some mixed forms (Baekgaard
istration of the various policy areas and formally elect their chairman on a simple major­ 2011). The departmental model has been the traditional model for organizing the
ity basis (Blom-Hansen and Heeager 2011). In practice, however, chairmanships are administration in the municipalities but is subject to considerable local variation. In this
often an integral part of the negotiations of the winning coalitions. Although the chair- model, the administration is divided into a number of departments/sections represent-
men, in contrast to the mayor, are only part-time politicians and have few formal ing the major welfare services, each managed by a director with responsibility for the
powers, they can be quite powerful since considerable influence is often delegated to preparation of policy decisions as well as for subsequent execution (Christensen et al.
them. A consequence of the committee rule is that one central centre in the municipal­ 2017). The average number of departments in municipalities has changed over time,
ities cannot be identified. Power is dispersed between different political bodies as well as increasing since the 2007 local government reform (Baekgaard 2009). The departmental
146 KURT HOULBERG AND NIELS EJERSBO MUNICIPALITIES AND REGIONS 147

model provides a close relationship between the political committee (and especially the been a decrease in conditional grants/reimbursements rates for specific municipal
chairman) and the director of the department, and potentially increases the departmen- expenditures and a gradual conversion of these to general grants (Pedersen and Frandsen
talization of the political system. In the executive board model, a number of directors 2017). There are few formal or legal requirements regarding local economie activity. The
form a top management team that is collectively in charge of the administration. This most important constraint is that local revenues and expenditures are required to bal-
team prepares policy decisions and services the committee. The model is supposed to ance within some limits (Andersen 2010). Furthermore, budgets and accounts must be
increase coordination and collaboration across the departments and committees specified according to standards set by the Ministry of the Interior, and the local govern­
(Baekgaard 2011) and strengthen the overall management of the municipality. ment act stipulates the procedure for setting a budget (e.g. it must be debated twice in
the council and be presented and decided upon at a certain date) (Serritzlew and Blom-
Hansen 2014), and relatively restricted options for loans apply (Andersen 2010).
However, the economie activities of the municipalities are mainly regulated through
Local Discretion in the Light of informal procedures. The most important of these is the ‘budget cooperation system’.
Changed Central-Local Relations The high level of decentralization has made coordinating local economie activity with
national economie policies increasingly important, and since the beginning of the 19803,
the ‘budget cooperation system’ has been institutionalized in the form of annual negoti-
Within the framework of national regulation and the so-called ‘budget cooperation ations and agreements between the national government and the Local Government
system’, the municipalities—like municipalities in other Nordic countries—have a high Denmark (LGDK) and the Danish Regions (DR), respectively (Andersen 2010; Blom-
level of local autonomy (Ladner et al. 2016). Recent changes in central-local relations, Hansen et al. 2012: 117-38). These annual agreements set collective guidelines for the
however, have affected the level and content of local discretion. annual general expenditure and income for the municipalities and regions.
According to the Constitution, the right of municipalities to manage their own affairs Over the years, the agreements have changed from a few pages setting guidelines for
independently—under state supervision—shall be laid down by statute. The Constitution the overall taxation and expenditures to more voluminous documents of 25-30 pages
also prescribes that some of the public tasks should be allocated to the local governments setting not only the overall guidelines but also a number of common understandings
and that Parliament (Folketinget) decides how much should be allocated. Denmark has and agreements on the desired development of specific sectors or policies. The level of
no single local government act defining the tasks of the municipalities, but over time, detail varies from merely recommending a rate of real expenditure growth to specifying
Danish municipalities have been granted a wide scope of predefined tasks laid down by that taxes cannot be raised and to setting specific growth rates for particular sectors
law in various acts and legal statutes. In addition, municipalities can perform certain (Juul and Kyvsgaard 2004: 242-4) and/or setting specific aims for the level of outsour-
tasks based on the so-called municipal authority rules (kommunalfuldmagtsreglerne), cing of services or aims for efficiency gains to be achieved from more coordinated
which is a general term for the unwritten rules (principles) of the local non-statutory procurement of goods.
duties. The precise definition of the municipal authority rules is often complex as the The economie agreements are agreements on the tax and expenditure level for the
authority rules cover a series of inaccurate and often overlapping unwritten rules. In municipalities collectively (Blom-Hansen et al. 2012; Houlberg 2018). No frames are set
practice, the municipal authority rules imply that tasks the municipality wants to per­ for the individual municipality, and the agreement is not binding for the individual
form must be of some benefit to the community, must not be tasks delegated to other municipality (or region). In principal, each municipality is still able to set its own rates
levels of government, and must not provide support for individuals or individual com- and policies—as long as the collective limits for the municipalities at large are not vio-
panies without specific legal cover. Municipalities are basically not allowed to engage in lated. In order to keep the collective budgets of the municipalities within the agreed
trade or industry. Classic examples of tasks that municipalities may carry out according level, the LGDK has an active role in coordinating the budget processes of the individual
to the municipal authority rules are public transportation and initiatives in leisure, municipalities, especially since 2011 when a national sanction regime was implemented,
culture, and sport. and the coordination of the LGDK evolved into a phase-divided budget process involving
Within the framework of fiscal federalism, Denmark is among the most fiscally an increasing frequency of meetings and consultations with all or parts of the municipal
decentralized countries in the world (Ivanyna and Shah 2014; Kodden 2004), and over mayors, CEOs, and/or heads of finance.
the last four decades, an increasing number of tasks and responsibilities have been Until 2010, the municipalities at large were typically overrunning the agreed levels of
transferred to the municipalities (Blom-Hansen et al. 2012). Financial and budgetary taxes or expenditures, often in the approved budgets and even more so in the final
reforms during this period aimed to strengthen the financial responsibility of local gov­ accounts (Serritzlew and Blom-Hansen 2014; Houlberg 2018). Until 2010, the partners,
ernment as well as provide tools for assessing the total public budget by standardizing however, had an implicit common understanding that the approved budgets were the
budgets and accounts (Blom-Hansen et al. 2012). A general feature of many reforms has basis for evaluating whether the agreements were kept, and though the possibilities of
148 KURT HOULBERG AND NIELS EJERSBO MUNICIPALITIES AND REGIONS 149

sanctioning the local governments were articulated by the national government, the 265
national government rarely used the parliamentary channel to sanction the violation of
the agreements in practice (Houlberg 2018).
National government policy changed dramatically in the wake of the financial crisis
and the historically large municipal budget overruns in 2009. In 2011, the national
parliament implemented a sanction regime on the municipalities, later integrated in
the so-called ‘Budget Law’ (Houlberg 2018; Suenson et al. 2016). The sanction regime
implies that economie sanctions are enforced by law if the municipalities (and regions)
are not keeping the economie agreements in both the approved budgets and the final
accounts. Possible sanctions will be implemented by cuts of up to DKK 3 billion in gen-
eral grants. In addition, the law stipulates that if the budgets are overrun, the sanctions
will be directed by 60 per cent on the individual violating municipalities and 40 per cent
collectively on all municipalities. So far, no actual sanctions have been practised; the
threat of sanctions combined with an increased crisis consciousness seems to have been
successful (Houlberg 2018; Suenson et al. 2016).
Budget overruns typically characterized the municipalities and regions at large prior
to the sanction regime, whereas budget undenuns seems to be a permanent feature after
the implementation of the sanction regime in 2011 (Houlberg 2018). Figure 10.1 illustrates
this as the grey pillars are lower than the dark pillars since 2011, and the budgets of the figure 10.1 Municipal service expenditures, 2007-2019 (2019 price and task level).
Source: LGDK
municipalities at large have been underrun by DKK 1-6 billion each year. As a by-product
of the increased focus on keeping the budget, the economie policies of municipalities
have partly moved away from performance management in favour of expenditure exact functional and financial interface between regions and municipalities continues
control (Sorensen and Foged 2015), and the political influence on agenda-setting and to be challenging and disputed. Though the agreements between the national govern­
decision-making in the municipal councils has been redistributed from the council- ment and the LGDK and the DR are, in principle, two separate pillars of the budget
lors not on the Finance Committee towards members of the Finance Committee cooperation system, the agreements are chronologically synchronous, and in practice,
(Houlberg et al. 2018). connected and interwoven.
A similar pattern such as in Figure 10.1 applies for the regions, albeit the level of the A tax stop has been a core element of national tax policies since 2001, and unchanged
agreed expenditures in general has been increasing as a reflection of the high policy pri- tax levels for municipalities and regions at large have correspondingly been an integral
oritization of healthcare in Parliament. In addition to expenditure limitations, the eco­ part of the yearly agreements. From 2007, the regions have no right to levy taxes, and
nomie agreements at regional level since 2002 have included a demand for 2 per cent accordingly, this element is no longer part of the regional agreements but continues to
yearly hospital efficiency gains. Within the same level of expenditures, the hospital has, in be a core element of the municipal agreements. However, less and less municipalities are
other words, had to produce 2 per cent more activities each year. Otherwise, activity- actually changing their tax rates (Blom-Hansen et al. 2012:129). The system thus loses
based state grants are not released to regions not fulfilling the demanded efficiency gains. flexibility as municipalities are only allowed to raise taxes if other municipalities simi-
From 2003 to 2015, the hospitals on average increased efficiency as demanded larly lower the taxes, and municipalities that have the economie possibilities and the
(Hojgaard et al. 2018: 172) but not without feedback consequences for the budget political ambitions to lower taxes may refrain from doing so as they fear they will not
cooperation system. According to the DR, the continuous efficiency demand implies be allowed to raise taxes again if the economie situation worsens. Put in other words, the
that hospitals are not always delivering the best possible service to citizens and that the local income taxation right, which has traditionally been considered a cornerstone
hospital staff is too busy. In the agreements for the regions for 2018 and 2019, the of Danish local self-government, is losing its vitality and mainly exists on paper (Blom-
efficiency demand has been suspended. In addition, a significant share of the efficiency Hansen et al. 2012:129).
gains has been realized by switching activities towards ambulant/outpatient treatment, Besides a tighter economie steering regime in central-local relations, a setting of
and the LGDK have accused the DR of having realized efficiency gains by shifting costs tighter norms and the centralization by the national level has occurred since the mid-
to the municipalities as the costs of patiënt rehabilitation is a regional responsibility, 1990S. Central regulation of the municipalities is increasingly a regulation of the admin-

whereas the costs of rehabilitation of citizens is a municipal responsibility. Thus, the istrative processes in the municipalities, i. e. process regulation (Andersen 2010). Process
150 KURT HOULBERG AND NIELS EJERSBO MUNICIPALITIES AND REGIONS 151

regulation refers, inter alia, to regulation on user involvement, requirements to produce Table 10.2. Gross Current and Capital Expenditures of Municipalities and
plans of actions, visitation and requirements on applying specific methods, follow-up Regions (2019 Budget)
actions, free choke, and applying standards of quality. Within specific sector areas such
Municipalities DKK billions Percent Regions DKK billions Percent
as health and basic education, the national government has interfered more, and more
emphasis is put on the results achieved within these areas (Andersen 2010). Municipalities Urban and environmental affairs 17.9 4.0 Healthcare 130.9 93.3
and regions document their achievements through benchmarking and the publication
Public Utilities 9.7 2.1 Social affairs 4.3 3.0
of waiting lists or exam results. This process is supplemented by national legislation
Traffic and infrastructure 15.2 3.4 Regional 3.4 2.4
introducing free choice in various public service areas (Andersen 2010).
development
In addition, the impact of EU policies affects the discretion of local government in
Education and culture 79.4 17.5 Administration v'; 1.7 1.2
Denmark (Andersen 2010). As a supra-national unit, the EU primarily affects the national
level of government. However, given the position of municipalities in the Danish public Healthcare 31.8 7.0
sector, the EU also has consequences for the discretion of local government, particularly in Social affairs and employment 253.0 55.8
areas such as the environment, outsourcing and call for tenders, regional development, Administration 46.1 10.2
and the labour market. The municipalities are either boundby EU regulation in these areas Total 453.1 100.0 Total 140.3 100.0
or responsible for administering EU regulation. In sum, the steady decentralization of Hereof:
tasks has, on the one hand, increased the discretion of the municipalities for the past 20.3 4.5 7.9 5.6
Capital expenditures (gross)
decades. On the other hand, this decentralization has subsequently been accompanied
Service expenditures (net current) 251.8 55.6
by process regulation that restricts the discretion of the municipalities. The ‘national
Social benefits and employment 80.9 17.9
mood’ may also have changed in the sense that less emphasis is put on local diversity
(net current)
(Andersen 2010). However, as pointed out below, considerable diversity still exists.
Co-financing of regional healthcare 22.5 5.0
(net current)
Fiscal Autonomy Regarding Source: Statisties Denmark.
Expenditures and Revenues

far the most important task of the regions. Hospitals account for the majority of the
Changes in central regulation through the implementation of major reforms and changes
health expenditures, but primary healthcare by general practitioners and the like is also
in spending regimes may influence the level of expenditures and revenues and the vari-
included. National regulations and standards delimit the regional autonomy substan-
ation in these between local entities. Evaluations of the economie effects of the 2007
tially, basically leaving the regional councils with fairly little discretion only for priori-
reform show that the amalgamated municipalities—compared to the non-amalgamated
tizing and organizing within the hospital sector.
ones—improved their fiscal management capacity and realized economies of scale with
At municipal level, the most important task category is social affairs and employ-
regard to the costs of administration and road maintenance (Hansen et al. 2014; Blom-
ment. This includes a number of policy areas like daycare, eldercare, specialized services
Hansen et al. 2014; Blom-Hansen et al. 2016). Conversely, expenditures for children and
for children, youth, and adults with special needs, social benefits, and employment
young people with social/behavioural problems and for labour market activities increased
activities for the unemployed, as well as education accounts for a substantial part of the
relatively, and no economies of scale with regard to total expenditures were realized
budget. In contrast to the regions, the municipalities are entitled to a high level of local
(Blom-Hansen et al. 2016). Below, we take a closer look at the variation and develop­
decision-making autonomy with respect to allocating resources according to local
ment in expenditures and revenues after the reform and the new spending regime.
needs and preferences. Within the framework of national legislation and the yearly eco­
nomie agreement between the government and the LGDK, the municipal councils have
Expenditures the autonomy to decide the allocation of resources across policy areas and have a large
degree of discretion in setting the Standard and quality of services (Andersen 2010). This
Table 10.2 shows the distribution of municipal and regional expenditures by main func- discretion is reflected in the substantial differences in the levels of expenditure among
tional categories. In line with the task portfolios set by the 2007 reform, healthcare is by the municipalities, cf. Table 10.3.
152 KURT HOULBERG AND NIELS EJERSBO MUNICIPALITIES AND REGIONS 153

Table 10.3. Variations in Selected Municipal Expenditure and Taxation Revenues


Levels (2019 Budget)
Municipal and regional expenditures are financed by different income sources. The
Mean Minimum Maximum Standard Coëfficiënt
regions are not allowed to levy taxes, so state grants are by far the most important rev-
deviation of variation
enue source. General grants account for 75 per cent of the revenue and are distributed to
Expenditures (DKK) the individual regions according to demographic and socioeconomic criteria. Besides
Daycare per 0-5-year-old 70,974 53,566 89,719 6,488 0.091 these activity-independent grants, the regions are financed by activity-based co-financing
from municipalities for citizens’ treatment at hospitals and general practitioners and
Schools per 6-16-year-old 80,118 69,257 109,902 8,566 0.107
until 2018 by activity-dependent grants from the state (depending on an assessment of
Eldercare per 65+-year-old 39,711 25,078 58,906 5,846 0.147
the 2 per cent efficiency demands).
Children and youth with special 10,827 5,614 25,919 3,740 0.345 At the municipal level, taxes are the main source of revenue (Blom-Hansen and
needs per 0-22-year-old
Heeager 2011). Taxes account for nearly two thirds of the revenue of the municipalities at
Adults with special needs per 9,457 6,508 16,478 1,715 0.181
large (see Table 10.4). The most important tax source is local income tax. In addition,
18-64-year-old
municipalities levy land taxes and corporate taxes, but these generate far less revenue.
Culture per inhabitant 1,770 894 3,089 445 0.252
The second most important revenue source is grants from central government in the
Road maintenance per inhabitant 1,140 404 2,801 387 0.340 form of a general block grant and conditional grants for expenditures, mainly for income
Administration per inhabitant 6,502 4,685 14,760 1,443 0.222 transfers to recipients of unemployment benefits, social benefits, sickness benefits, etc.
Selected tax rates Moreover, municipalities levy fees and user charges within the utility area and the social
Income tax rate (%) 25.3 22.5 27.8 1.0 0.039 area. Finally, borrowing is generally forbidden, but exemptions are granted for a
Land tax rate, farm buildings (°/oo) 6.8 1.2 7.2 1.0 0.151 number of capita! goods specified by central government regulation (Blom-Hansen and
Heeager 2011).
Land tax rate, other buildings (°/oo) 26.2 16.0 34.0 4.7 0.179
The figures in Table 10.4, however, represent the average revenue profile, and consid­
Source: Statistics Denmark. erable variation exists across municipalities due to variations in local fiscal environ­
ments and local policies. In some municipalities, general grants account for 35 per cent
of the revenue, whereas in other municipalities, general grants account for minus 30 per
The differences in expenditures at municipal level do not necessarily indicate similar cent of the revenue. These differences reflect the importance of the equalization scheme
differences in the quality of service. They may reflect differences in expenditure needs which aims at evening out the differences in the economie situation within the munici­
and municipal wealth, and for most policy areas, 50-80 per cent of the inter-municipal palities and giving the municipalities approximately the same financial basis on which
variations may be explained by differences in fiscal environment (Houlberg et al. 2018), to solve their tasks (Ministry for Economie Affairs and the Interior 2014).
indicating that the municipalities are adapting policies to local needs and preferences.
However, the difference between the municipalities with the highest and lowest expend­
itures within a number of sector areas is considerable. Though national regulation through Table 10.4. Municipal Revenue Sources (2019 Budget)
the budget cooperation system has been strengthened and has become more detailed, DKK Billion Percent
considerable variation in the levels of expenditure across the municipalities remains
and reflects the autonomy and discretion entitled at municipal level. Taxes 291.2 64.3
Furthermore, some delegation of functions and financial responsibility from the General grants and equalization 79.1 17.5
Conditional grants 24.0 5.3
municipal level to the service-producing institutions has been implemented in most
Fees and user charges 61.4 13.5
municipalities since the early 1990S (Andersen 2010). We find a decentralized system Net borrowing -1.4 -0.3
not just between the state and the municipalities but also within the municipalities. Other -1.1 -0.2
Though many municipalities seem to have restricted the access of transferring budgets Total 453.1 100.0
from one budget year to another in the wake of the Budget Law, the managers at schools,
daycare centres, and eldercare centres still have a large degree of discretion with regard Source: Statistics Denmark. 'Other' includes the sale of capita! assets,
net interest payment, and use of liquid assets.
to finance and organization.
154 KURT HOULBERG AND NIELS EJERSBO MUNICIPALITIES AND REGIONS 155

The equalization scheme is complex and includes a set of special subsidies and Third, not all municipalities have the sufficiënt professional and economie capacity for
equalization schemes. The main clements are a national equalization scheme covering all handling the more complex social and educational tasks transferred to municipalities in
municipalities and an additional capita! equalization scheme for the municipalities in the 2007. Increased horizontal coordination may thus be needed, and/or the quality of the
capita! area. Based on a number of indicators for demographic and economie expenditure services will come under pressure or vary across municipalities. A number of institu-
needs, 61 per cent of the inter-municipal differences in expenditure needs relative tional arrangements have been established in order to remedy this. Among these are
to local tax bases are equalized in the national equalization scheme, and an additional niandatory agreements between the municipalities and the regions in each area involving
27 per cent in the capita! equalization scheme. The level of equalization in the national multiple actors with potentially conflicting interests (Blom-Hansen and Heeager 2011)
scheme was increased as part of the 2007 reform, and the new tasks were transferred to and a state agency supervising and overseeing the municipalities’ ability to handle spe­
the municipalities. Combined with the subsequent redistribution of conditional grants cialized social and educational tasks. Such institutional arrangements are complex
and less flexibility in the economie agreements to adjust taxes, this has turned general arenas for coordination and may reduce democratie accountability as it becomes less
grants and equalization into an important and viable part of municipal revenues. transparent for voters whom to blame electorally if unsatisfied with the service delivered.
Fourth, the increased decentralization and the development in state-local relations
since the turn of the century has challenged the budget cooperation system between the
national government and local government associations. The regions rely solely on state
Challenges and Opportunities grants and thus have strong incentives to join forces with interest organizations in the
healthcare area and pressure central government for increased funding in the annual
negotiations between the government and the DR (Blom-Hansen and Heeager 2011). At
The continuingly high level of decentralization turns local governments into important
municipal level, a tax stop has been an integral part of the annual economie agreements
arenas for local democracy as well as important implementing agencies of the welfare state.
between the government and the LGDK since 2001 and has contributed to reducing the
Danish municipalities and regions thus enjoy a delicate balance between self-government
system’s flexibility. Although the tax stop applies to the municipalities at large, the number
and central control (Blom-Hansen and Heeager 2011), and developments, reforms, and
of individual municipalities lowering tax rates have been reduced significantly after the
increased decentralization have accentuated a number of challenging clements.
tax stop, and the flexibility of the budget cooperation system reduced equally as tax
First, in the political rhetoric, the reshuffling of functions in the 2007 structural
reduction in one municipality is a prerequisite for an increase in another municipality.
reform was intended to eliminate ‘functional overlaps’ and ambiguous vertical
This de facto freezing of tax rates rocks a core element of local self-government: the
responsibilities between the three tiers of government. However, the reform has
independent taxation right (Blom-Hansen et al. 2012:129). Since 2001, the LGDK’s role
invoked new forms of challenges regarding the functional and financial interface
as coördinator has become increasingly important to ensure that the sum of the indi­
between municipalities and regions, especially with regard to specialized social tasks
vidual municipal decisions stays within the expenditure limits both in the budgets and
and health (Blom-Hansen and Heeager 2011). One example is retraining and rehabilita-
in the final accounts. Though the expenditure limits apply to the municipalities at large,
tion of patients after hospital admission. The regions are responsible for the hospitals
in years of zero-growth, municipalities wishing to increase service expenditures cannot
and for financing patient-related rehabilitation, whereas the municipalities are responsible
do so if other municipalities are not reducing their expenditures equally. In this collect-
for financing citizen-related rehabilitation. Increased use of outpatient/ambulant treatment
ive action dilemma, municipalities are reluctant to lower taxes or reduce expenditures
at the hospitals means that patients are increasingly discharged from hospitals right
as they are not sure they will be able to increase it again at a later stage if needs are
after treatment and staying in their homes in the period of rehabilitation. Consequently,
increasing and/or political preferences for higher service levels gain ground. Thus, the
municipalities and regions are continuously discussing the financial interface between
flexibility of the system to adjust taxes and service levels to local needs and preferences is
patient-related rehabilitation and citizen-related rehabilitation—and thus who is
under continuous pressure.
responsible for financing a specific rehabilitation activity.
Fifth, the sanction regime allows no transferals of unused budgets from one year’s
Second, the regions created by the 2007 reform are hybrid and crippled political insti-
ceiling to another year’s ceiling. Consequently, unused budgets end up in the municipal
tutions in the sense that they are basically single-purpose entities responsible for only
purse, and the liquid assets of the municipalities have now reached a historie height of
hospitals, are not allowed to set up standing committees apart from the executive
DKK 50 billion. Another by-product is an increased tendency of expenditure-burning’
committees, and have no independent taxation rights (Blom-Hansen and Heeager 2011).
towards the end of the budget year (Bask et al. 2016).
In addition, citizens have no strong affective attachment to the regions, and their single-
Sixth, in line with the increased economie importance of the equalization scheme, the
purpose status is likely to further decrease voter interest and democratie legitimacy.
content of the scheme is increasingly being politicized both at national and local level.
Thus, the future of the regions appears uncertain (Blom-Hansen and Heeager 2011).
An increasing number of municipalities or groups of municipalities are questioning the
156 KURT HOULBERG AND NIELS EJERSBO MUNICIPALITIES AND REGIONS 157

level of equalization and/or the criteria of the equalization scheme, the relative weights coordination and national supervision challenging local democratie accountability,
of the criteria, or the measurement of the individual criteria and are calling for a more ‘just’ reduced flexibility to adjust taxes and service levels to local needs and preferences, pres-
equalization scheme. However, the scheme is a zero-sum game, and what one group of sure on the institutional framework for coordination of the local governments economie
municipalities argue to be more ‘just’, other municipalities argue to be the opposite. As activities with overall national policies, and increasing politicization of the equalization
stakeholders often evaluate loses higher than gains (Kahneman and Tversky 1979), any scheme. Nevertheless, the local government system continues to demonstrate a high level
national reform of the equalization scheme is likely to produce more local opponents of viability and capability for adapting to changing conditions and externalities.
than proponents.
Despite these challenges, the local government System has demonstrated an impres-
References
sive level of adaptability to changing conditions and externalities. Besides the adaption
of policies to a strengthened national sanction regime, the municipalities at large have,
Andersen, Vibeke N. (2010). ‘Changes in central-local relations. Denmark’, in
for instance, reorganized eldercare to focus more on rehabilitation in the light of an Michael J. Goldsmith and Edward C. Page, eds, Changing Government Relations in Europe:
ageing population and have focused services for children and young people with social/ Erom Localism to Intergovernmentalism. London: Routledge, 47-66.
behavioural problems more on preventive and less intervening activities. Beek, Thomas A., Mikkel M. Q. Andersen, and Steffen K. J. Krahn (2016). Sanktionslovgivningen
og kommunernes okonorniske styring. Copenhagen: KORA.
Bffikgaard, Martin (2009). ‘Organizational change in local governments: The impact of the
CONCLUSION Danish local government reform’, World Political Science Review 5/1, article 6.
Baekgaard, Martin (2011). ‘The impact of formal organizational structure on politico-
administrative interaction: Evidence from a natural experiment’, Public Administration,
89/3:1063-80.
The Danish local government system is one of the most decentralized systems in
Baldersheim, Harald, and Lawrence E. Rosé (2010). Territorial Choke: The Politics of
Western democracies. The system has been through major changes over the past years.
Boundaries and Borders. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
In 2007, a local government reform was implemented, changing the local government Blom-Hansen, Jens (1999). ‘Avoiding the ‘joint-decision trap’: Lessons from intergovernmen-
structure and the division of tasks among state, local, and regional government. Later, a tal relations in Scandinavia’, European Journal of Political Research, 35/1:35-67
new national spending regime put tougher limitations on the spending of local govern- Blom-Hansen, Jens (2002). Den fjerde statsmagt. Kommunernes Landsforening i Dansk
ments, backed up by law-enforced economie sanctions if the municipalities (and regions) Politik. Magtudredningen. Aarhus: Aarhus University Press.
at large do not keep spending within the expenditure limits. The question raised was: Blom-Hansen, Jens, and Anne Heeager (2011). ‘Denmark: Between local democracy and
what are the consequences of a major structural reform followed by a national spending implementing agency of the welfare state’, in John Loughlin, Frank Hendriks, and Anders
regime for a highly decentralized local government system? The main answer is that Lidström, eds, The Oxford Handbook of Local and Regional Democracy in Europe. Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 221-41.
Danish local governments experience an increased level of decentralization of tasks but
Blom-Hansen, Jens, Kurt Houlberg, and Soren Serritzlew (2014). ‘Size, democracy, and the
also witness an increasing central regulation, reducing the autonomy of local govern­
economie costs of running the political system’, American Journal of Political Science, 58/4:
ment to adjust taxes and service levels to local needs and preferences. Though the local 790-803.
government system experiences less autonomy, there continues to be variation in local Blom-Hansen, Jens, Kurt Houlberg, Soren Serritzlew, and DaniëlTreisman (2016). ‘Jurisdiction
government taxes and expenditures. However, as the flexibility of the system to adjust size and local government policy expenditure: Assessing the effect of municipal amalgama-
taxes and service has been reduced, the variations between municipalities is increas- tion’, American Political Science Review, 110/4: 812-31.
ingly a reflection of past rather than present choices and preferences. In addition, local Blom-Hansen, Jens, Marius Ibsen, Thorkil Juul, and Poul Erik Mouritzen (2012). Fra sogn til
government revenues become more dependent on general grants and the functioning of velfcerdsproducent. kommunestyret gennem fire artier. Odense: University Press of Southern
the equalization scheme. Denmark.
Christensen, Jorgen G„ Peter M. Christiansen, and Marius Ibsen (2017). Politik ogForvaltning,
Summing up, increasing decentralization seems to be accompanied by decreasing
Copenhagen: Hans Reitzels Forlag.
autonomy. The Danish local government system can still be characterized as highly
Ejersbo, Niels (1998). ‘Kommunale strukturer - et studie i lokal variation’, Politica, 30/3: 285-97.
decentralized, but it faces significant challenges in maintaining the delicate balance Elklit, Jorgen, and Ulrik Kjser (2007). ‘The decreasing number of candidates at Danish local
between local self-government and implementing agency of the state. Besides an uncer- elections - Local democracy in crisis?’, Local Government Studies, 33/2:195-213.
tain future for the hybrid and crippled political institutions at regional level and insuffi­ Hansen, Kasper M. (2020). ‘Electoral turnout. Strong social norms of voting’, in Peter
ciënt professional and economie capacity at municipal level for handling the most M. Christiansen, Jorgen Elklit, and Peter Nedergaard, eds, The Oxford Handbook of Danish
complex decentralized tasks, the challenges also include issues like complex arenas for Politics. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 76-87.
158 KURT HOULBERG AND NIELS EJERSBO MUNICIPALITIES AND REGIONS 159

Hansen, Morten B„ Jens T. Pedersen, and Emil Thylin (2010). ‘Regeneration og strukturel pedersen, Niels Jorgen M., and Maja F. Frandsen (2017). ‘Decentralisation at sectoral level:
forandring i de danske kommuners lederskab 1980-2008. Dokumentation af en undersogelse Developing the role of local governments on labour market oriented social benefits’, in
baseret pa kommunale arboger’, Kommunalpolitiske Studier, nr. 27. Junghun Kim and Niels J. M. Pedersen, eds, Decentralisation ofEducation, Health and Social
Hansen, Sune W., and Ulf Hjelmar (2015). ‘Nar kommuner bliver storre: De korte og mere Protection: Issues and Challenges. The Copenhagen Workshop 2015. Copenhagen: The
langsigtede konsekvenser for lokaldemokratiet’, Politica, 47/3: 464-84. Korea Institute of Public Finance and the Danish Ministry for Economie Affairs and the
Hansen, Sune W., Kurt Houlberg, and Lene H. Pedersen (2014). ‘Do municipal mergers Interior, 79-109-
improve fiscal outcomes?’ Scandinavian Political Studies, 37/2:196-214. Rodden, Jonathan (2004). ‘Comparative federalism and decentralization: On meaning and
Houlberg, Kurt (2018). ‘Lokale styringsvilkars betydning for kommunernes okonomiske measurement’, Comparative Politics, 36/4: 481-500.
styring - fungerer sanktionslovgivningen som brandtaeppe eller ilttelt?’ Politica, 50/1: Serritzlew, Soren, and Jens Blom-Hansen (2014). ‘Budgetlaegning i kommuner og regioner’, in
45-64. Peter M. Christiansen, ed., Budgetlcegning og offentlige udgifter. and ed. Copenhagen: Hans
Houlberg, Kurt, Sune W. Voigt, and Lene H. Pedersen (2018). ‘How is political influence Reitzel, 170-201.
redistributed in times of fiscal austerity?’, Scandinavian Political Studies, 41/1: 98-119. Sorensen, Eva M., and Soren K. Foged (2015). ‘Mal- og resultatstyring i kommunerne efter
Hojgaard, Betina, Jakob Kjellberg, and Mickael Bech (2018). Den statslige styring afdet regionale krisen’, Okonomi & Politik, 88/1: 46-56.
sundhedsomrdde. Analyse af centrale instrumenter. Copenhagen: VIVE. Suenson, Emil L, Peter Nedergaard, and Peter M. Christiansen (2016). ‘Why lash yourself to
Ivanyna, Maksym, and Anwar Shah (2014). ‘How close is your government to its people? the mast? The case of the Danish “Budget Law” ’, Public Budgeting and Finance, 36/1:3-21-
Worldwide indicators on localization and decentralization’, Economics, 8/3:1.
Juul, Thorkil, and Henrik Kyvsgaard (2004). Kommunens budget—udgifter og finansiering.
Frederiksberg: Danmarks Forvaltningshojskoles Forlag.
Kahneman, Daniël, and Amos Tversky (1979). ‘Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under
risk’, Econometrica, 47I2: 263-92.
Kjaer, Ulrik (2020). ‘Local elections. Localized voting within a nationalized party system, in
Peter M. Christiansen, Jorgen Elklit, and Peter Nedergaard, eds, The Oxford Handbook of
Danish Politics. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 382-99.
Kjaer, Ulrik, Ulf Hjelmar, and Asmus L. Olsen (2010). ‘Municipal amalgamations and the
democratie functioning of local councils. The case of the Danish 2007 structural reform’,
Local Government Studies, 36/4: 569-85.
Kjaer, Ulrik, and Poul Erik Mouritzen (2003) (eds). Kommunestorrelse og lokalt demokrati.
Odense: University Press of Southern Denmark.
Ladner, Andreas, Nicolas Keuffer, and Harald Baldersheim (2016). ‘Measuring local autonomy
in 39 countries (1990-2014)’, Regional & Federal Studies, 26/3: 321-57.
Lassen, David D., and Soren Serritzlew (2011). ‘Jurisdiction size and local democracy: Evidence
on internal political efficacy from large-scale municipal reform’, American Political Science
Review, 105/2: 238-58.
Ministry for Economie Affairs and the Interior (2014). Municipalities and Regions—Tasks and
Financing 2014. Copenhagen: Ministry of Economie Affairs and the Interior.
Ministry of Interior and Health (2005). The Local Government Reform—In Brief, Copenhagen:
Ministry of Interior and Health.
Mortensen, Peter B. (2014). ‘Udviklingen i de offentlige udgifter’, in Peter M. Christiansen, ed„
Budgetlaegning og offentlige udgifter. 2nd ed. Copenhagen: Hans Reitzel, 66-91.
Mouritzen, Poul Erik (2010). ‘The Danish revolution in local government: How and why?’, in
Harald Baldersheim and Lawrence E. Rosé, eds, Territorial Choke: The Politics ofBoundaries
and Borders. Houndmills: Palgrave, 21-41.
Mouritzen, Poul Erik, and James H. Svara (2002). Leadership at the Apex. Pittsburgh, PA:
University of Pittsburgh Press.
Olsen, Asmus L. (2010). ‘Kommunalreformens konsekvenser: kommunalpolitikernes rolle,
borgernes lokaldemokratiske opfattelse og den administrative organisering’, Tidsskriftet
Politik, 13/3:38-47.

You might also like