You are on page 1of 10

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/348759752

Cotton sector reforms in Central Asia

Chapter · January 2021

CITATION READS

1 167

3 authors:

Nodir Djanibekov Suray Charyyeva


Leibniz Institute of Agricultural Development in Transition Economies Leibniz Institute of Agricultural Development in Transition Economies
82 PUBLICATIONS   957 CITATIONS    3 PUBLICATIONS   1 CITATION   

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

Golib Sanaev
Kangwon National University
12 PUBLICATIONS   14 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Innovation in Governance View project

AGRIWANET – Agricultural Restructuring, Water Scarcity and the Adaptation to Climate Change in Central Asia: A Five-Country Study View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Nodir Djanibekov on 26 January 2021.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Nodir Djanibekov, Suray Charyyeva, Golib Sanaev

Cotton sector­
reforms in
Central Asia
   Cotton as ‘ White Gold ’  economy, one could even speak of a ‘ cotton ’ economy.
Cotton, the White Gold of Central Asian (CA5) countries,  —  The cotton sector in CA5 countries (five countries
once represented a pillar of agricultural ­transformation, of Central Asia) can be grouped into two models based
rural employment, and the spread of new technolo- on the level of state intervention. In the early 1990s, cot-
gies. The continued expansion of cotton in the ­1960–80s ton became a critical source of export revenues for Uz-
caused the massive expansion of irrigated areas in this bekistan, Turkmenistan, and Tajikistan to finance their
dry region. Cotton production was concentrated in col- industrial development. In Kazakhstan and Kyrgyzstan,
lective farms linked to parastatal gins. During the So- where dependence on this crop was less pronounced,
viet Union cotton became the most strategic crop in the governments aligned the changes in the cotton sec-
Central Asia receiving priority in the allocation of in- tor to the general economy-wide reforms. In Uzbekistan
puts and resources by planning authorities. The min- and Turkmenistan, where cotton occupied over half of
istries controlled cotton supply chains, including in- the sown area, sectoral reforms had been careful and
put and machinery supply, and issued production plans. slow. Despite its importance, cotton cultivation in Cen-
Producer prices were fixed throughout the year, and tral Asia, which in the 1980s accounted for over 10 % of
the movement of seed cotton outside of designat- the global cotton area, has shrunk considerably Table 1
ed growing areas was prohibited. In many parts of So- This paper aims to focus on the most relevant aspects of
viet Central Asia, cotton played a vital role in the entire the cotton sector reforms in the CA5 countries since the

46 Cotton sector reforms in Central Asia  —  Nodir Djanibekov, Suray Charyyeva, Golib Sanaev
Table 1 — Harvested area of cotton in Central Asia
Difference
Total harvested area, 1000 ha
between 2018 and 1991
Country
Average
1991 2000 2010 2018 1000 ha %
1981–1990
Kazakhstan 127 116 152 134 133 16 14
Kyrgyzstan 37 26 34 26 23 −3 −10
Tajikistan 311 298 239 162 180 −118 −40
Turkmenistan 584 602 575 550 546 −56 −9
Uzbekistan 1,964 1,720 1,445 1,343 1,071 −649 −38
Total CA5 3,023 2,762 2,443 2,216 1,953 −809 −29
World 32,767 34,845 31,634 31,801 32,979 −1,866 −5
Source: FAOSTAT (2019) for 1992–2017 values; various statistical yearbooks for 1981–1991 and 2018

fall of the Soviet Union to summarise the major lessons to the world market price (POMFRET and CHRISTENSEN 2008).
that can be learned for the next wave of sectoral trans- Competition between private ginneries for cotton output
formation. in both countries has become bottom line for producers’
 ­Competitive cotton supply chains in access to higher prices and ensured that even small indi-
Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan and Tajikistan  vidual farmers benefited from private chain coordination
In Kazakhstan and Kyrgyzstan, the cotton sector reforms (SADLER 2006, PETRICK et al. 2017). As the competition between
started already in 1990s and were linked to the land re- ginneries in Kazakhstan and Kyrgyzstan increased, so did
form when the land of collective farms was distributed the ‘side-selling ’ of harvested cotton by farmers (PETRICK et
to individual farmers. ­Table 2 The economic liberalisation al. 2017). To prevent side selling and to control cotton prices,
of the cotton sector led to reduced state intervention the ginneries arranged a monopsony to which the gov-
and entry of private investors into the ginning and trad- ernments reacted later with re-integrated coordination
ing sectors. Contract farming became common, and gin- of cotton supply chains. — Unlike Kazakhstan and
neries could directly provide inputs to farmers on credit Kyrgyzstan, the cotton sector reforms in Tajikistan were
(SADLER 2006). The calculation of producer prices was linked made only after pressure came from international organ-

47
Table 2 — Overview of cotton sector reforms

Implementation of Ownership
Major cotton producer Cotton pricing
cotton contracts of cotton gins

Kazakhstan Individual farms Contract farming is Related to world market Private with domestic
of ø =10 ha, ­common. Weak bargain- price, varies over time. and foreign investments.
in Turkistan province, ing power of farmers.
60 % is machinery-­ ­Various contract types
harvested (2018). can be negotiated.

Kyrgyzstan Individual farms Contract farming is com- Related to world market Private with domestic
of ø =1,2 ha, mon. Weak bargaining price, varies over time. and foreign investment.
in Jalalabad and power of farmers.
Osh provinces (2017).

Tajikistan Individual farms Weak bargaining power Related to world market Private with domestic
of ø =3,8 ha, of farmers. The contracts price, varies over time. and foreign investment.
in Sughd and Khatlon are imposed by gins.
provinces (2017).

Turkmenistan Peasant associations State association via Issued by the govern- Gins are owned by the
of ø =2500 ha, peasant associations. ment, fixed for the entire state association.
in all ­provinces year.
except Balkan (2017).

Uzbekistan Individual cot- Set either through Issued by the govern- Gins are partly owned
ton-specialized farms ­ arastatal gins or clus-
p ment as ‘guaranteed ’ by the state and private
of ø =75 ha, ters according to farm price, fixed for the entire domestic and foreign
in all provinces, locations. New clusters year. investors.
55 % of cotton area in with direct farming.
clusters (2019).

Note: ø stands for average farm size

48 Cotton sector reforms in Central Asia  —  Nodir Djanibekov, Suray Charyyeva, Golib Sanaev
1— The price for
seed cotton in
Kazakhstan, 1200
Uzbekistan, and current USD/ton
isations and donors (VAN ATTA 2009). By the early 2000s, 1000
Cotlook A Index
almost all ginneries in Tajikistan were privatized. Yet, in World
800
contrast to Kazakhstan and Kyrgyzstan, state interven-
tion into the sector has remained as the land reform led 600
Kazakhstan
only to nominal farm individualization (HOFMAN 2018). Pri-
400
vate gins received local monopsony rights for the pur-
chase of cotton in a particular region. Continued control 200
Uzbekistan
of cotton producers’ decision-making by powerful inter- 0
est groups culminated into the Cotton Debt Crisis in Tajik- 8 0 2 4 6 8 0 2 4 6 8
199 200 200 200 200 200 201 201 201 201 201
istan (HOFMAN 2018). As in Kazakhstan and Kyrgyzstan, the
bargaining position of Tajik cotton growers is weak.
   Monopolised supply chains in value crops. Potential income increasing added value was
Uzbekistan and Turkmenistan  therefore not possible. — Acutely aware of pertain-
Uzbekistan and Turkmenistan, the largest cotton produc- ing inefficiencies in this sector, the Uzbek government in-
ers in Central Asia, took a different path after 1990. Un- itiated reforms in 2017 by converting supply chains into
til recently, the cotton sector reforms in Uzbekistan were vertically-integrated textile companies called cotton-
of a much-restricted scope, in Turkmenistan the stand- textile clusters. The new model legitimized the monop-
still was more extreme. In both countries, the cotton sony of textile companies to govern the distribution of in-
sector remained among the least reformed sectors puts and machinery services to farmers within their ter-
in the post-socialist era. It strongly resembles a blend ritories, cotton procurement, processing, and exports.
of Soviet-style central planning of production, state land Where land was transferred to ‘ cotton clusters ’ a direct
allocation and procurement prices, as well as a sectoral farming was introduced. The previous farmers were then
monopoly of parastatal ginneries, input suppliers and hired to operate the cotton fields of cotton clusters. Com-
cotton exporters. Cotton farmers were taxed via low petition between ginneries is not permitted and farmers
government-stipulated procurement prices and control are still bound to clusters. The prescribed specialisation
over the currency market (POMFRET 2008). The persistence of cotton clusters restrains farmers’ freedom to choose
of state control over the cotton sector has caused ma- crops and marketing channels. The formation of clusters
jor economy-wide distortions and loss of efficiency in in- has neither eliminated the production quota nor state
puts and outputs markets, ginning and textile sectors, as control over cotton prices. — In Turkmenistan, state
well as underutilized export capacity in textiles and high- control over the cotton sector is strong with its produc-

49
2a
— 3.5
World Ton/hectare
and average tion in large peasant associations strictly reg-
Uzbekistan,
CA5 cotton ulated under the state production mandates, 2.5 Turkmenistan
yields centralised price setting, production norms
2.0
and monopolised marketing and input chan- Kazakhstan,
1.5
nels (POMFRET 2008). Private entry in textile sector World
Kyrgyzstan,
1.0 Tajikistan
has been allowed to some extent. In practice, the val-
ue chains remain strongly regulated and monopolised, 0.5
although reforms have been discussed for several years. 0
In Turkmenistan and, since recently much less in Uzbek- 0 2 4 6 8 0 2 4 6 8 0 2 4 6 8 0 2 4 6 8
198 198 198 198 198 199 199 199 199 199 200 200 200 200 200 201 201 201 201 201
istan, forced labour mobilisation for cotton picking has
been an issue in relations with the international commu- sonistic power, consequently, reducing farmers’ share
nity and has led to a loss of reputation for the countries. in the cotton value chain. Subsequent policies intend-
The progress made recently have been recognised by in- ed to rectify the situation contributed to the sector’s de-
ternational organisations such as the International La- cline in Kazakhstan (PETRICK et al. 2017). The drop in world
bour Organization (ILO) and of the EU. cotton price after the 2011 price spike contributed to
   Outcomes of cotton sector reforms  further downward spiralling of producer prices in 2012–
While comparing seed cotton prices in Kazakhstan and 16. Despite the cotton price increase since 2017, cotton
Uzbekistan, Figure 1 shows that the government of Uz- prices in Uzbekistan are stipulated through administra-
bekistan has been taxing cotton producers by purchas- tive measures as ‘ guaranteed ’ prices. — The cotton
ing at prices below world market value. As the exam- sector throughout Central Asia is currently in decline.
ple of Kazakhstan shows, by eliminating taxation and Not only cotton cultivation area, but also cotton yields
allowing privately owned gins, the cotton reforms im- have significantly declined in every Central Asian coun-
proved producer prices (SADLER 2006). The price difference try compared to the level in the early 1980s. Figure 2a
between the two countries resulted in large amounts For Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, and Tajikistan one can no-
of Uzbek seed cotton being smuggled to Kazakhstan tice the recovery of cotton yields as farmers moved cot-
(and to Kyrgyzstan) and offered to local ginneries for ton cultivation to more suitable land. Tajikistan expe-
cash purchase without the provision of crop finance rienced the steepest decline in yields compared to the
(SADLER 2006). In early 2000, as side selling became com- 1980s. In general, the cotton sector in Uzbekistan per-
mon practice among farmers in Kazakhstan, the gin- formed better than in other Central Asian republics, ex-
neries formed a procurement cartel to impose monop- cept Kyrgyzstan, where the cotton-producing farms have

50 Cotton sector reforms in Central Asia  —  Nodir Djanibekov, Suray Charyyeva, Golib Sanaev
2b
200 —
How did
   Recent reforms in the Uzbek cotton total cotton
World
150 sector  production
125 The new waves of expected reforms in the develop?
cotton production in 1992=100 100 cotton sector of Uzbekistan are among the
Uzbekistan, Turkmenistan 75 central aspects of the government’s recent Agri-
Food Development Strategy for 2020–30. In March
Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, 25 2020, the government liberalized the cotton market and
Tajikistan
0 abolished the state regulation of cotton production and
198 198 198 198 198 199 199 199 199 199 200 200 200 200 200 201 201 201 201 201
0 2 4 6 8 0 2 4 6 8 0 2 4 6 8 0 2 4 6 8 price. The aim is to establish a competitive cotton supply
chain with private ginneries and textile companies, with
been the smallest in Central Asia. In fact, Kyrgyzstan is producer prices determined by the market, based on
the only Central Asian country where cotton yields have world market prices. It is expected that price liberalisa-
improved since 1991. — When measured in relative tion will stimulate farm incomes and sector performance,
changes in total cotton output, the monopolised sec- since the state purchase prices set below market price
tors performed better than the reformed ones. ­Figure 2b do not provide an incentive for production. A significant
At first, the cotton sector reform was a success story in role in this process is placed on the cotton-textile clusters,
the three ‘reform countries’ Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, and which are expected to bring substantial efficiency gains
Tajikistan with the cotton cultivation area expanding to the sector by improving processing efficiency, offer-
rapidly as competition between the ginneries to secure ing farmers better access to inputs, investing in new ma-
volumes of seed cotton drove producer prices up. The chinery and textile equipment. Particularly, the clusters
cotton sector growth in Kazakhstan and Kyrgyzstan out- should adopt cotton combines and raise payments for
performed other crops and livestock production. This cotton pickers. The clusters should explore foreign mar-
short period of resurgence illustrates the importance of kets for textile products and increase export revenues.
competition between ginneries for sectoral growth. Al-    Important lessons 
though the cotton sector in Turkmenistan and Uzbeki- The outcomes of cotton sector reforms in Kazakhstan, Kyr-
stan shrank in the 1990s, it stabilised later on. Along with gyzstan, and Tajikistan equally show that, without more
the recent decentralization efforts in Uzbekistan, the cot- pronounced land reform, freedom to farm and select
ton area has been further reduced by a decree, contribut- marketing outlets, none of them can be set as a reference
ing to the production decline of about 1 million tons of for Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan. However, they pro-
seed cotton between 2016 and 2018. vide several valuable lessons to consider for the sector’s

51
52 Cotton sector reforms in Central Asia  —  Nodir Djanibekov, Suray Charyyeva, Golib Sanaev
long-term sustainable growth. — Price liberalisation    Bibliography 
and entry of private investors in the ginning sector had — Hofman, I. (2018): Soft budgets and elastic debt: farm
a positive effect on the sector’s performance. Cotton pro- ­liabilities in the agrarian political economy of post-Soviet
duction in the market-based competitive model expand- ­Tajikistan. Journal of Peasant Studies, 45 (7), 1360–1381.
ed after private investors were allowed and higher pro- — Petrick, M.; Oshakbayev, D.; Taitukova, R.; Djanibekov, N.
ducer prices were offered. This has not been the case for (2017): The Return of the Regulator: Kazakhstan’s Cotton Sec-
state-regulated monopolistic systems in Turkmenistan tor Reforms since Independence. Central Asian Survey, 36 (4),
and Uzbekistan. Second, under liberalised prices, cotton 430–452.
is economically competitive with other high-value crops. — Pomfret, R. (2008): Tajikistan, Turkmenistan, and Uzbek-
­Cotton production will not vanish after the state quo- istan. In Anderson, K.; Swinnen, J. F. M. (Hrsg.), Distortions
ta abolishment nor under the ‘ laissez-faire ’ approach. to ­Agricultural Incentives in Europe’s Transition Economies.
In fact, sectoral development strongly depends on pric- ­Washington, DC.: The World Bank, 297–338.
es received by cotton growers. Third, an export-oriented — Pomfret, R.; Christensen, G. (2008): The Kyrgyz Republic.
cotton value chain with free competition between gin- In Anderson, K.; Swinnen, J. F. M. (Hrsg.), Distortions to Agricul-
neries can benefit small producers. — The cotton tural Incentives in Europe’s Transition Economies. Washington,
sector reforms, however, did not strengthen the power DC.: The World Bank, 265–295.
of newly established individual farms. Cotton produc- — Sadler, M. (2006): Vertical Coordination in the Cotton Sup-
ers lack strong organisations through which they will ei- ply Chains in Central Asia. In Swinnen, J. F. M. (Hrsg.), The Dy-
ther contract or own the ginning sector. Weak capacity namics of Vertical Coordination in Agrifood Chains in Eastern
to organise alternative marketing channels puts produc- Europe and Central Asia. Case Studies, Washington, DC: World
ers under the control of more powerful ginneries. The Bank, 73–114.
impropriety of farmers’ decision-making autonomy and — Shend, J. Y. (1993): Agricultural statistics of the former USSR
low producer prices have already damaged the Tajik cot- republics and the Baltic States. USDA Economic Research Ser-
ton sector. Increased access to credit, the introduction of vice. Statistical Bulletin 863.
private input suppliers, freedom to select marketing out- — Van Atta, D. (2009): ‘ White Gold ’ or Fool’s Gold?, Problems
lets supplemented with a strong organisation represent- of Post-Communism, 56 (2), 17–35.
ing cotton growers’ interests will be the key to the sector’s
growth.

53
 Sources and credits 
p. 46 Cotton pickers, Fergana Valley, Uzbekistan © robertharding /Alamy
Stock Foto
Figure 1 The price for seed cotton in Kazakhstan, Uzbekistan and Cotlook A
Index, current USD/ton © Own Presentation. Source: O ­ fficial statistical data.
Note: For Uzbekistan, average exchange rates from September to July in the
parallel currency market were used to convert to annual prices in USD. ‘ World ’
price for seed cotton was calculated by dividing the Cotlook A Index by 3.
Figure 2 a) Worldwide and average cotton yields in Central Asia, t/ha  b)
Development of total cotton production, 1992 =100 © Own Presentation.
­Sources: Shend (1993) for 1980–91 for CA5, FAOSTAT (2019) for 1992–2017 for
CA5 and ‘ World ’
p. 52 Uzbekistan farmers inspect a cotton combine for field deployment,
2019 © Golib Sanaev

54 Cotton sector reforms in Central Asia  —  Nodir Djanibekov, Suray Charyyeva, Golib Sanaev

View publication stats

You might also like