You are on page 1of 7

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/327463409

Barter

Article · September 2018


DOI: 10.1002/9781118924396.wbiea1648

CITATIONS READS

0 476

1 author:

Hugo Valenzuela-Garcia
Autonomous University of Barcelona
122 PUBLICATIONS   363 CITATIONS   

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Proyecto Nueva Economía 20+20. Empresas de Humanidades View project

Personal Network Analysis View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Hugo Valenzuela-Garcia on 23 October 2021.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Trim Size: 170mm x 244mm k Callan wbiea1648.tex V1 - 04/05/2017 7:30 P.M. Page 1

Barter Barter, commodity exchange, and gift


giving
HUGO VALENZUELA GARCÍA
Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona, Spain Barter has been widely reported in all five
continents in an extensive range of societies
throughout history, from hunter-gatherers to
postsocialist states. However, a pure model of
Barter is the direct exchange of goods or ser-
barter exists only in theory (Chapman 1980).
vices for each other without an intervening
Indeed, an apparently simple barter transaction
medium of exchange, although money can occa-
(i.e., two parties exchanging goods taken to be
sionally become the object of exchange. The
equivalent) entails multiple possibilities concern-
transaction, either simultaneous or delayed, ing the timing of the exchange (simultaneous or
can occur between free individual partners or delayed), the partners (neighbors or foreigners),
within a group as well as between groups, either the relationship between them (fairness or hos-
according to agreed rates of exchange or by tility), the type of items exchanged (foodstuff,
bargaining. luxury goods, labor), and the wider socioe-
While barter touches upon fundamental conomic context in which the exchange takes
economic questions on human nature that go place (economic crisis, international diplomacy,
back at least to Aristotle (e.g., private property, everyday provisioning).
equivalence, justice, value, transaction costs), Conventionally, economic anthropology dis-
it did not initially attract particular anthropo- tinguishes between gift exchange (ideological,
logical interest. In fact, since both Bronisław ceremonial, equal, and socially embedded) and
Malinowski’s study of trade systems in the Tro- commodity exchange (practical, material, free of
briand Islands and Marcel Mauss’s theoretical any social connotation) (Gregory 1982). Barter
k work on the gift appeared in the 1920s, attention thus has been considered a type of commodity k
to gift exchange overshadowed the relevance of exchange involving the transfer of “alienable
this type of exchange. For a long time, barter objects” of which, in contrast to gift giving,
has been considered as a simple bilateral trans- the quantitative value is more important than
action, as socially neutral or even “negative,” the qualitative. Most economists alike gener-
in comparison to the “positive” features of reci- ally assume that in barter, as in commercial
procity and the exchanges embedded in kinship exchanges, the emphasis placed on the item being
relations. exchanged will typically lead the parties involved
It was not until the 1980s that anthropologists to try to get as much as they can out of the deal.
started to pay more attention to barter and its In fact, when common products are bartered,
context, revealing a wide array of situations in exchange ratios naturally tend to market equilib-
which it was practiced along with other exchange rium (in terms of supply and demand), given the
possibility of a degree of bargaining to settle the
arrangements of goods and services, such as
final ratio (Humphrey 1985).
gift exchange, commodity exchange, formalized
Barter, however, embodies further complexi-
trade, credit, or truck systems. From then on
ties that go beyond simple commodity exchanges.
the old analytical distinction between gifts and
The rate of exchange can vary because of sev-
commodities became blurred, to the extent that
eral factors, such as the geographical distance
some current anthropologists suggest that barter between the points of origin of the goods con-
transactions should be considered a third cate- cerned, the availability or nature of the goods
gory of exchange, deserving of study in their own (perishable goods, like fish, will lose their value
right.

The International Encyclopedia of Anthropology. Edited by Hilary Callan.


© 2018 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Published 2018 by John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

k
Trim Size: 170mm x 244mm k Callan wbiea1648.tex V1 - 04/05/2017 7:30 P.M. Page 2

2 BA RTER

if not exchanged in good time), or the acces- Mundurucú of the Amazon River basin described
sibility of potential exchange partners. When by Burkhalter and Murphy (1989, 114).
the number of potential partners is small, the According to ethnographic data, exchange
ideal deal will tend to a zero-sum game in which calculation depends on how much people trust
an increased benefit for one partner represents each other, and when some bargaining takes
a decrease in benefit for the other. So in these place it is rarely competitive or hostile. Among
exchanges a concept of value may apparently the Guisu of Uganda there was no fixed rate of
be lacking, as reported by Steinen and Schütze exchange for articles, each particular transaction
(1894, 390) in the case of the Bakairi people of being arranged to the mutual satisfaction of the
Mato Grosso. Nevertheless, more often than not, two parties involved (La Fontaine 1959, 20). For
the rate of exchange is approximated through Hawaiian people, “no bargain was considered
guesswork, being “more or less notional, almost binding till the articles were actually exchanged,
ideological” (Humphrey 1985, 60). Some groups and the respective owners expressed themselves
fix the rate of exchange according to that used the satisfied” (Ellis 1917, 319). Similar reports from
previous year, while others restrict exchanges to around the world indicate that haggling and
things of the same value and exactly equivalent arguing are not intrinsic to barter: if the rate
to one another. When the goods exchanged tend offered by one’s partner is not satisfactory, one
to be of equivalent value, barter may hint at a can always start a new exchange relation with
sense of moral commitment between trading someone offering a more reasonable exchange
partners, which closely resembles that established rate. A classic example of such nonviolent prac-
by the gift exchange (Heady 2005, 269). In this tice, even where no moral relationship between
the partners exists, is “silent trade” or “depot
respect, Lindholm reports a type of barter termed
trade,” where goods are exchanged without direct
adal-badal (give-and-take) among Pashtun males
contact between the partakers. Herodotus docu-
consisting of an exchange that is like for like:
mented this practice as early as the fifth century
k a radio for a radio, sunglasses for sunglasses, a
bce among the Carthaginians, yet it was widely
k
watch for a watch (1982, 116).
used by merchants from Asia to Africa when
While reciprocity and gift giving are the
traders could not speak each other’s language,
norm inside the community, direct barter as an
right up to the beginning of the twentieth cen-
expression of autonomy is more common with
tury. The Garo from India and Bangladesh, until
outsiders. Within a community, delayed barter recently, exchanged cotton with foreign traders
can work only in a relationship of knowledge and in silent barter for pigs, cattle, goats, tobacco,
trust because it implies credits and debts. Families and metallic tools. Usually one party leaves the
of the Lhomi (Tibet) bartered rice for salt only traded goods in a customary spot and gives a
with other families known to them, habitually signal to the counterpart using smoke, a gong,
with delay or debt (Humphrey 1985). In contrast or a drum. The other group proceeds to leave a
to local exchange, barter with strangers has often second set of articles and retreats. If both agree
been associated with haggling, “chicanery,” and and are satisfied, the transaction concludes.
even “theft.” Actually, the French word bareter Available ethnographic cases show that barter
means to deceive, lie, foist, cheat, or beguile. and gift giving coexist in a symbiotic manner. In
However, even in the case of potential hostility fact, goods usually circulate within regimes of
between foreigners, barter may accomplish some value that differ in space and time. For instance, a
functions beyond its purely material goal. The man can raise a calf, then give it to his friend, who
famous kula exchange of gifts (shell ornaments) in turn can barter it for three pounds of rice with
described by Malinowski was usually accompa- a shopkeeper, who decides to sell it to another
nied by a secondary barter trade in utilitarian man, who finally eats it in a religious feast. Fur-
items (foodstuff, raw materials, manufactures) ther, the exchange of specific types of goods and
named gimwali. In other cases, barter can con- services can occasionally operate within different
vey messages about a mutual relationship and a spheres of exchange. For example, the Tiv of Nige-
sense of honor, fairness, trust, and equality and ria (Bohannan and Bohannan 1968) had three
can strengthen social ties, as in the case of the spheres of exchange: subsistence (i.e., food such

k
Trim Size: 170mm x 244mm k Callan wbiea1648.tex V1 - 04/05/2017 7:30 P.M. Page 3

BA RTER 3

as yams, grains, vegetables, and small livestock would be willing to hold to swap for something
and some tools), wealth (i.e., brass rods, cattle, else in future exchanges: salt, shells, ox hides,
and slaves) and prestige goods (marriageable and so on. The restrictions of barter were lifted
females). In this context subsistence goods were as soon as sellers began to accept these money
the most likely to be exchanged, and conversions tokens regularly, knowing that they could be
from one sphere to another were discouraged for exchanged at any time. With time such money
their moral and social implications. The Kapauku tokens became money as we now know it.
of western New Guinea (now Irian Jaya) actually Nonetheless, as many anthropologists have
shared four spheres of barter: pointed out, there is virtually no evidence that
this is how money really came into existence. As
In the first, pork may be exchanged for growing Humphrey puts it, no “example of barter econ-
crops, land, salt, steel axes, or infrequently, for omy, pure and simple, has ever been described,
bows or net carrying-bags. In the second sphere, let alone the emergence from it of money; all
woti shells, bows, and net carrying-bags may be available ethnography suggest that never has
bartered for growing crops, and very occasionally been such a thing” (1985, 48). Actually, in real life
for pork. The third sphere includes human labor we do not usually experience transaction costs
spent on agricultural tasks, which may be recom- in exactly the same way that economists describe
pensed by a reduction of the bride price, through them: few people with a surplus of three chick-
free lease of land, or by growing crops. The fourth ens who want beans would be likely to spend
sphere of exchange allows artifacts (except canoes their time looking for someone else somewhere
and planks) to be mutually exchangeable. (Pospisil
who is willing at that moment to swap their
1963, 341)
beans for exactly three chickens. In the course of
To understand whether a particular barter history, there have been very few marketplaces
exchange is more commodity-like or more where people are documented as having regularly
swapped goods directly without any reference
k gift-like, anthropologists observe both the dual
to a money of account nor to whole economies
k
aspect of the exchange (its economic and social
operating through barter alone.
side) and the nature of the relationship between
Even though barter is frequently considered an
the partners (Heady 2005, 272).
economic residue (i.e., what the real market can-
not or will not pick up) or as underreported due
to its sporadic nature, the evidence does not sup-
The myth of “money follows barter” port the assertion that nonmonetary economies
would have previously been barter economies.
Barter, most economists mistakenly assert, is Ethnographic data indeed presents robust coun-
regarded as the origin of all exchange, the “prim- terarguments against the evolutionary narrative,
itive” form of commerce par excellence, based as one usually finds barter side by side with gift
on an elementary division of labor and the lack exchange, cash exchanges, and trade, rather than
of money. That argument can be found in Adam one form following the other in a diachronic
Smith (who refers to man’s “propensity to barter, sequence. In other cases, barter can be a more
truck and exchange one thing for another”) efficient, direct, and fair type of exchange when
and it recurs in later schools of economics in one individual owns a surplus of A and needs
attempts to substantiate the idea of the economic B, and another owns a surplus of B and wants
man (Polanyi 1957, 43). As the argument goes, A, particularly when the transaction absorbs
in an imagined and primordial context, people long-distance transport services and involves
produced what they needed for themselves and more than one transaction. This is the reason for
the surplus was swapped between individuals for its popularity in rural communities specialized in
other goods they required. But the difficulties a particular product. Further, sometimes barter
derived from the exchange itself (e.g., searching can be better understood as a postmonetary
for a partner, establishing a fair rate of exchange) phenomenon of economies that are or have been
forced the emergence of some kind of measure decoupled from monetary markets. For instance,
of value, that is, money tokens that most people the Lhomi of the Tibetan border, before the

k
Trim Size: 170mm x 244mm k Callan wbiea1648.tex V1 - 04/05/2017 7:30 P.M. Page 4

4 BA RTER

Chinese invasion in the 1970s, engaged in three the exchange between the Soviet Union and the
kinds of barter: intervillage direct exchange of underdeveloped world (Rogers 2014, 140). Today,
subsistence items; regular large-scale barter of swapping all kinds of things is increasingly com-
agricultural products for Tibetan livestock and mon on a global scale through the internet, and
other products (butter, dried meats, clothes, etc.); corporate barter is a growing industry. In New
and long-distance trade of salt exchanged with York, so-called barter clubs came into being in the
the nomads in Tibet for rice (Humphrey 1985). mid-1960s and today constitute a network of an
They were wealthier in earlier times and their use estimated 450,000 companies (retailers, services,
of money was historically intermittent in favor and manufacturers). In these cases, barter is a
of barter. After World War I in Germany and the payment option for businesses where money is
Great Depression in the United States, barter sys- not used. Similar associations can be found in
tems expanded because of the scarcity of money Australia, Canada, and New Zealand. In some
and goods to meet the population’s basic needs. urban contexts, barter can be quite formalized
In a similar vein, during the communist era the (taxed, registered, audited, etc.) and there are
Russian blat system allowed people with control a growing number of guides and textbooks on
over particular scarce goods to provide access to “how to get almost anything without money.” On
their acquaintances, hoping that the beneficiary a larger scale, barter has long been a strategy of
would later give them access to something else international trade between nations, not only of
they needed in return. Multilateral barter systems hydrocarbons but also of many other goods, espe-
developed in postcommunist European countries cially in Eastern Europe under socialism where
and during Argentina’s corralito, and the prolif- it mitigated the structural problems economies
eration of LETS (local exchange trading system) faced
was widely reported in southern Europe during The marginalists (neoclassicals), in particular,
the financial crisis that began in 2008. deduced that barter was abandoned in favor of
These examples show that barter allows trade money because of its high transaction costs (e.g.,
k to continue in times of monetary scarcity or when searching for partners, setting up a double coinci-
k
a national currency collapses (as a result of war, dence of wants, postponing a desired transaction,
economic crisis, deflation, etc.). Barter not only wasting time on bargaining) and the problem of
makes payment unnecessary but creates a distinct the meeting of wants (i.e., the difficulty of finding
circuit of goods. For this reason, in contexts of a partner with exchange preferences that meet
extreme poverty, it can be also a strategy to resist one’s own). Common arguments of economists
selling labor and land (Humphrey 1985, 52) or to for the efficiency of money over barter are as fol-
elude monetary taxes, thereby acting as a moral lows: (1) it limits the number of price quotations
economy of the poor. In this sense, this type of necessary (i.e., all items can be quoted in money);
exchange opens up economic opportunities for (2) it enables buying to be separated from selling,
other actors that otherwise would have fewer thus permitting trade to take place without the
socioeconomic opportunities, notably women in so-called double concurrence of barter; and (3) it
many West African societies. avoids the possible drawbacks of delayed barter
Yet barter is not only a phenomenon of when information about the buyer is absent.
“communitarian,” local, rural, or crisis-stricken However, in barter the distinction between
modern societies but a socioeconomic strategy money and nonmonetary goods is not always
occasionally found in more “healthy” contempo- clear cut either. A particular example of such
rary economies and in wider geopolitical contexts complexity is posed by the current discussion
as well. In the mid-twentieth century, most Euro- concerning petrobarter, or the exchange of oil
pean currencies were inconvertible and relied, for goods and services on a wide scale without
instead, on bilateral clearing agreements that reference to monetary currency. Oil exchanges
swapped goods for goods and only periodically can indeed be a powerful way of capitalist accu-
sought to reconcile central bank accounts in mulation encompassing “countertrade and offset
monetary terms. During the 1970s and 1980s, trade, in which corporations and states swap
60 percent of trade within Eastern Europe at goods with little or no monetary calculation,
the time was based on barter, as was much of and currency clearing, in which states transact

k
Trim Size: 170mm x 244mm k Callan wbiea1648.tex V1 - 04/05/2017 7:30 P.M. Page 5

BA RTER 5

goods for goods over an agreed period of time, Ellis, William. 1917. Narrative of a Tour through Hawaii,
only periodically reconciling their central bank or Owhyhee: With Remarks on the History, Traditions,
accounts in monetary terms” (Rogers 2014, 133; Manners, Customs, and Language of the Inhabitants of
emphasis original). the Sandwich Islands. Honolulu: Hawaiian Gazette.
Gregory, Chris A. 1982. Gift and Commodities. London:
Academic Press.
Heady, Patrick. 2005. “Barter.” In A Handbook of Eco-
Conclusions nomic Anthropology, edited by James G. Carrier,
262–74. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
In summary, albeit barter was initially dis- Humphrey, Caroline. 1985. “Barter and Economic Dis-
regarded in favor of the social and moral integration.” Man (n.s.) 20 (1): 48–72.
complexities of the gift, it cannot be consid- Humphrey, Caroline, and Stephen Hugh-Jones, eds.
1992. Barter, Exchange, and Value: An Anthropolog-
ered merely as an inefficient alternative to market
ical Value. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
exchange or as an inherent phenomenon of La Fontaine, J. S. 1959. The Gisu of Uganda. London:
so-called primitive economies. Barter practice International African Institute.
takes place in very diverse contexts and situations Lindholm, Charles. 1982. Generosity and Jealousy: The
and, beyond a simple economic institution, it Swat Pukhtun of Northern Pakistan. New York:
should be analyzed as a mode of exchange with Columbia University Press.
its own social characteristics and its own moral Orlove, S. Benjamin, James M. Acheson, John Clammer,
space. Beyond its apparently pragmatic goal—the Thomas Crumop, Stephen Gudeman, David Guil-
provision of goods and services—barter may let, Olivia Harris, and Henry J. Rutz. 1986. “Barter
embody other social, political, and moral func- and Cas Sale on Lake Titicaca: A Test of Competing
Approaches [and Comments and Replies].” Current
tions (equality, fairness, political alliances, etc.),
Anthropology 27 (2): 85–106.
depending on the partners involved and the wider
Polanyi, Karl. 1957. The Great Transformation. Boston:
socioeconomic context in which the exchange Beacon Press.
k takes place. Pospisil, Leopold J. 1963. Kapauku Papuan Economy. k
New Haven: Department of Anthropology, Yale Uni-
wbiea1327 SEE ALSO: <DRAFT: Polanyi, Karl>; Blat; versity.
wbiea1370 Kula; Mauss, Marcel (1872–1950); Commodity; Rogers, Douglas. 2014. “Petrobarter: Oil, Inequality,
wbiea1446
wbiea1541 Gift; Sharing; Money; Trade, Long-Distance; and the Political Imagination in and after the Cold
wbiea1542
Malinowski, Bronisław (1884–1942); Economic War.” Current Anthropology 55 (2): 131–53.
wbiea1650
Anthropology; Credit and Debt Stapleton, Constance, and Phyllis C. Richman. 1978.
wbiea1681
wbiea2004 Barter: How to Get Almost Anything without Money.
wbiea2164 New York: Scribner.
wbiea2194
wbiea2247
Steinen, Karl von den, and Frieda Schütze. 1894.
REFERENCES AND FURTHER READING Among the Primitive Peoples of Central Brazil: A
Travel Account and the Results of the Second Xingu
Bohannan, Paul and Laura Bohannan. 1968. Tiv Econ- Expedition 1887–1888. Berlin: D. Reimer (Hoefer &
omy. Evanston, IL: Northwestern University Press. Vohsen).
Burkhalter, S. Brian, and Robert Francis Murphy.
1989. “Tappers and Sappers: Rubber, Gold and
Money among the Mundurucú.” American Ethnolo-
gist 16 (1): 100–116.
Chapman, Anne. 1980. “Barter as a Universal Mode of
Exchange.” L’homme 20 (3): 33–83.

k
Trim Size: 170mm x 244mm k Callan wbiea1648.tex V1 - 04/05/2017 7:30 P.M. Page 6

Please note that the abstract and keywords will not be included in the printed book, but are required
for the online presentation of this book which will be published on Wiley’s own online publishing
platform.
If the abstract and keywords are not present below, please take this opportunity to add them now.
The abstract should be a short paragraph of between 50 and 150 words in length and there should
be at least 3 keywords.

ABSTRACT
Barter is usually defined as the dyadic exchange of goods and services of similar kind with-
out the intervention of money. Initially regarded as a simple bilateral transaction (equivalent
to commodity exchange), it did not attract particular anthropological attention. However, a
model of pure barter exists only in theory. The available ethnographic data show a wide array
of barter modalities and functions conveying, beyond its pragmatic goal, social, political, and
moral functions. When it takes place within the same community, barter is frequently found in
coexistence with gift exchange, trade, or commodity exchange. While economists commonly
regard barter as the origin of all exchange—eventually leading to the creation of money—the
historical sequence could actually work in the opposite direction. Actually, barter is widely
used not only in the past and traditional societies but also in contemporary societies where, to
k a certain extent, it can be considered a postmonetary phenomenon. k

KEYWORDS
cross-cultural research; economic anthropology; ethnography; exchange; money; value

View publication stats

You might also like