You are on page 1of 16

A Test for Moral Hazard in the Labor Market: Contractual Arrangements, Effort, and

Health
Author(s): Andrew D. Foster and Mark R. Rosenzweig
Source: The Review of Economics and Statistics , May, 1994, Vol. 76, No. 2 (May, 1994),
pp. 213-227
Published by: The MIT Press

Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/2109876

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

The MIT Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
Review of Economics and Statistics

This content downloaded from


103.21.125.80 on Wed, 03 May 2023 10:13:50 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
The Review of Economics and Statistics
VOL. LXXVI MAY 1994 NUMBER 2

CONFERENCE ANNOUNCEMENT

The National Science Foundation and the Review of Economics and Statistics are planning a
conference on the effects of educational quality on achievement and earnings. Authors are invited
to submit paper abstracts for the conference, which will aim to address key conflicting results in
existing work on the subject and to conduct new research on the critical issues remaining. Shared
data sets among participants will be a feature of the conference. The conference will be held in
Fall 1994 or Spring 1995 and a special issue of the Review is planned subsequently. Abstracts
should be submitted to Robert Moffitt, c/o the Review offices, by August 31, 1994.

A TEST FOR MORAL HAZARD IN THE LABOR MARKET:


CONTRACTUAL ARRANGEMENTS, EFFORT, AND HEALTH

Andrew D. Foster and Mark R. Rosenzweig*

Abstract-Moral hazard plays a central role in many models justify the superiority of family labor over hired
depicting contractual relationships involving worker effort.
labor paid on a time basis, and hence the relative
We show how time-series information on worker health, con-
sumption and work time can be used to measure the effort cost advantage of small-scale farms. Despite the
effects of payment schemes. Estimates from longitudinal data theoretical importance of moral hazard and the
describing farming rural households indicate that time-wage
distinction between worker time and worker ef-
payment schemes and share-tenancy contracts reduce effort
compared to piece-rate payment schemes and on-farm em- fort, however, there is little direct empirical evi-
ployment. The evidence also indicates, consistent with moral dence on worker shirking. The reason for this is
hazard, that the same workers consume more calories under a
clear, the hypothesized feature of these models
piece-rate payment scheme or in on-farm employment than
when employed for time wages. that deters workers from supplying full effort, the
lack of observability by the employer of worker
M /[ORAL hazard plays a central role in many effort, also represents a barrier to the empirical
models depicting contractual relationships verification of the importance of moral hazard,
or payment schemes involving the supply of namely the unobservability to the researcher of
worker effort, particularly in the context of low- worker performance.
income countries. Among the most prominent of While there have been credible studies of the
these are sharecropping, efficiency wages, and disincentive effects of input use associated with
permanent worker contracts (e.g., Stiglitz, 1982; share tenancy (Bell, 1977; Shaban, 1985), this
Eswaran and Kotwal, 1985a and 1985b). The exis- evidence is based on the withholding of readily
tence of moral hazard also has been used to measured inputs such as fertilizer, seeds and
worker time. There is no evidence on the with-
holding of worker effort, given worker labor time,
Received for publication June 20, 1992. Revision accepted
for publication March 22, 1994. due to the lack of full incentives. In this paper,
* University of Pennsylvania. we show how time-series information on worker
This research was supported in part by NICHD Grant No.
health and the inputs to worker health can be
HD-28687. We are grateful to two referees for helpful com-
ments. used to measure the effort effects of different

Copyright C) 1994 [ 213 1

This content downloaded from


103.21.125.80 on Wed, 03 May 2023 10:13:50 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
214 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

labor payment schemes. In particular, we make evidence also indicates that calorie intake is re-
use of the biological balance equation in which warded when workers work for piece-rates but
calorie intake and energy expenditure determine not when workers work for time wages and that
weight (body mass) change. The basic idea is that the same worker consumes 23% (16%) more
the loss of worker body mass, for given calorie calories per day when employed under a piece-
intake, should vary directly with the degree to rate payment scheme (on-farm employment) than
which the worker appropriates his/her contribu- when employed for time wages, also consistent
tion to output if there is moral hazard. Similarly, with the energy expenditure implications of moral
calorie intake, which can be directly measured hazard.
but is not necessarily information known by the
employer, may also be positively related to worker I. Theory
effort incentives. A study of these relationships
A. Worker Effort
between payment schemes, calorie intake and
health may also help illuminate the conflicting The hypothesis of moral hazard applied to the
results from studies of the effects of calories labor market is that the amount of an input
and/or health status on worker wages and contri- supplied by a worker to a task will depend posi-
butions to output (e.g., Strauss (1986), Behrman tively on the extent to which that input is re-
and Deolalikar (1989), Deolalikar (1988) and warded. This will in turn depend on the degree to
Schultz (1992)). which the employer can monitor or observe the
In section I we set out a simple model in which input. Worker effort is one example of an imper-
individuals work in different activities that dif- fectly perceived input from the perspective of the
ferently reward worker effort and in which worker employer whose supply, for given work time, will
health is affected by effort and food intake. The depend positively on the degree to which it is
model is used to show how the relationship be- rewarded.' Another is the consumption of the
tween reward schemes and unmeasured effort worker, which may also influence productivity.
can be inferred from health and calorie informa- While it is possible for the researcher to measure
tion and to derive the relationship between calo- directly worker consumption to evaluate the ef-
rie intake and worker incentives. In section II fects of moral hazard, at some expense, worker
we describe the data used. These data, from effort is not likely to be easily observed by either
Bukidnon, Philippines, provide longitudinal body employers or researchers.
mass, individual calorie intake and wage informa- The key feature of the analysis that follows is
tion on workers who work for time wages, on that worker effort, although unobservable, di-
their own plots of land, under share tenancy and rectly influences the health of a worker, which
for piece-rate wages in a setting in which these has measurable components, net of caloric in-
different reward schemes are offered for the same take, time spent working, and illness. In particu-
agricultural tasks. We also discuss estimation is- lar, it is assumed that there is a health production
sues and specification of the tests for moral haz- function:
ard derived from the model. The empirical re-
Hit =h( Hit- cit, zit S fit)(l
sults are reported in section III. The estimates
indicate that time-wage payment schemes as well
where Hit is a measure of the body size of
as share-tenancy are associated with moral haz-
individual i at time t, Cit is nutrient intake, zit iS
ard. In particular, workers evidently supply more
illness in that interval, and fit is total effort
expended between periods t - 1 and t, where
effort under a piece-rate payment scheme or in
the total amount of effort expended can be writ-
own-farm work compared to time-wage employ-
ten
ment as reflected in the fact that they deplete
their body mass by approximately 10% more, net fit = Ejtljt (2)
of calorie consumption, when working under a j E=_

piece-rate scheme or on their own plots of land


compared to working as time-wage workers and 1 Note the distinction betwe
amount of work done (e.g., the number of bushels of corn that
13% more than when working under share ten- are picked), and effort, which may be thought of as the
ancy or when outside of the labor force. The amount of energy expended per day.

This content downloaded from


103.21.125.80 on Wed, 03 May 2023 10:13:50 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
MORAL HAZARD IN THE LABOR MARKET 215

where j indexes the different reward schemes of and p,3,8 denote the Lagrange multipliers at time
the activities undertaken by individual i, lIit is the t associated with the health production function
number of days spent doing activity j, and ejit is(1) and the budget constraint (4), respectively,
the effort expended per day under payment and assuming for simplicity that workers have
scheme J. positive employment in all schemes3 the first or-
Because effort is not directly observable, esti- der conditions are:
mation of equation (1) requires that we derive an
expression for the effort that each individual will
expend as a function of observable (to the re- uct + At E wjcliit) -Pt)IthcLh = 0 (6)
searcher) characteristics of the worker as well as
Uf tljit + At(Wjej t)ljit + Iithf,tliit = 0 (7)
the payment scheme. It is assumed that payment
schemes can be characterized by a function Ufi ekit + AtWk -thftekit ? (8)
wjit =wj( Hit -1, cit, ejit ) (3) UHIt + At+1 H ( t+l jit+l
jeJ

where wjit is the daily earnings of individual


+ ?t -i At+lhHit8 = 0 (9)
under contract j. The extent to which effort is
At-At_1(1 + r)f3 = 0. (10)
rewarded is determined by Wje = 9wl/de. Be-
cause effective work is fully rewarded in piece-rate Equations (7) and (8) may be solved to obtain an
work or in self-cultivation, it is expected that for effort supply function by payment regime. In par-
a given level of health and consumption wie will ticular, these two equations imply that effort in
be higher under these schemes than in share- sector k will be chosen to equate the marginal
cropping and time-wage employment. and average products of effort in that regime
Effort by payment scheme, labor allocation, (Wke = wk/ek). Because daily earnings in a given
and calorie consumption are determined as a regime depend only on effort, consumption and
solution to a dynamic optimization problem. For health, this latter equation implies that the maxi-
simplicity, we assume that individuals may borrow mizing choice of effort under scheme k can be
and lend as much as they want at a fixed interest written as a function of health and calories alone.
rate r so that net assets in period t + 1 are Since the marginal products of effort in the dif-
ferent regimes must also be equal (an implication
Ait+1 = (1 + r)Ait + Ew1J. -PL ci. of
(4)
equation (7)), the effort under regimes other
jfEJ
than k may also be written as a function of effort
Each individual has a felicity function that is under regime k, consumption and health and
increasing in body size and consumption and de- thus on consumption and health alone, that is,
creasing in total effort expenditure U(Hit, Cit, fit)
and he/she chooses consumption, effort, and days
ejit = ej( Hit -1, cit). *(11)
worked in order to maximize discounted utility: Moreover, if effort is rewarded more under
T scheme j than under some scheme j' (i.e., Wie >
max E f3sU(His,cis,fis) (5) Wj,e) and the wage is concave in effort over the
c1s, e,lsX ljls s = O relevant range, effort in regime j must exceed
that in j'.
subject to equations (1)-(4) and the health pro-
Substituting equation (11) into (1) and taking a
duction function. We assume that there is at least
linear approximation around H*, c*, and l* gives
one payment scheme, indexed by k, for which
labor demand is perfectly elastic.2 Letting A t3t Hit= ao + allHHitl + azzit
+ accit + E aIjljit + UHit
2Although labor supply in self-cultivation and share-crop- jeJ
ping may be constrained, workers are likely to have consider-
able liberty with regard to their choice of the number of days
spent in off-farm employment. If an individual's labor supply 3 The requirement that there is positive employment in all
were to be constrained in all work regimes then the optimal schemes is made primarily for notational convenience. As
effort expended will in general depend on the marginal utility long as the individual chooses positive employment in scheme
of income and thus estimation of the modified health produc- k, the analysis is unchanged except for the fact that the effort
tion function (equation (11) below) would be substantially functions will only be defined for those schemes in which
more complicated. labor activity is positive.

This content downloaded from


103.21.125.80 on Wed, 03 May 2023 10:13:50 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
216 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

where In order to use the above model to obtain a


tractable empirical test of whether calorie alloca-
alj = hf.,ej tions are a function of the incentive schemes of
work activities, it is therefore necessary to make
aH= hHit-1 + E dH IJit (12) an important simplifying assumption: the single-
period utility function is assumed to depend only
and on body size Hi, and consumption cit. Thus,
de. energy expenditure only leads to a decrease in
utility to the extent that it lowers body size. This
ac =hclt + L dc iJ*t
jedCJ it assumption allows us to combine equations (6)
and (8) to obtain
Of particular interest are the coefficients on the
aij terms, which provide measures of the effort Ucit= Apt7kit (13)
expended in task j. Given an a priori ranking of
where
n payment schemes by the degree to which they
reward effort, from lowest to highest, the test of
moral hazard is that a1l < a12 ... < ain < 0. 7rkit Pt h ~~ ' E wjcitljit (14)
ekit hfit jE.J

B. Calorie Consumption and k indexes the payment regime in which labor


The above analysis indicates that to identify demand is assumed to be elastic. The interpreta-
the presence of moral hazard with respect to tion of equations (13) and (14) is that the marginal
work effort based on changes in worker health utility of calorie consumption in any particular
requires measurement of the calorie intake of the period must equal the marginal utility of wealth
worker among other worker characteristics. Infor- in that period times a shadow price that reflects
mation on this variable also permits another test the net cost of increasing calorie consumption
of the role of moral hazard. If caloric intake is and work in payment regime k in such a way as
also not readily known by employers but is associ- to keep health unchanged. Equation (13) for two
ated with worker productivity, either because it different periods may then be combined with

directly augments the amount of effective work equation (10) to obtain a Euler equation
done by an individual (as suggested by the wage Ucit 7rkit
equation (2)) or because workers who expend 8i (1 + r) vkt(15)
greater effort are likely to consume more in order ucit + 1 7rkit + 1

to maintain their health, then the allocation of In order to derive an estimable form for equa-
consumption across periods may also be related tion (15) it is helpful to further simplify the wage
to payment schemes due to moral hazard. In and health technologies as follows:
particular, in periods when individuals are work-
ing primarily in piece-rate activities one should
U(cit, Hit) = 1l CtYCH[yH
expect to observe elevated levels of consumption.
On the other hand, in periods when individuals
h(Hit_ 1, cit, fit) = h(Hit- 1, Ocit -fit)
are primarily working for time wages we should
expect to see low levels of consumption. wj( Hit_ 1, cit, ejit) = mj( Hit 1) nj(6cjcit + ejit
A standard approach to the analysis of the (16)
intertemporal allocation of consumption is to de-
We also assume that sector k is the time-wage
rive Euler equations for consumption from a dy-
sector and that calories are not rewarded in that
namic stochastic model. Unfortunately, imple-
mentation of this approach is greatly complicated sector (i.e., 8ck = 0), and thus that ekit does not
vary across individuals or over time.4 Thus a
by the fact that body size at a given point in time
log-linear approximation to equation (15) in cit,
depends on previous body size. As a result, calo-
rie allocations in one period will depend on fu- Pto Wkit, and 1jit around c*, p , wk, and 17,
ture as well as present labor-market returns to 4 Evidence that calories are not rewarded in the time-wage
nutrition. sector is presented below.

This content downloaded from


103.21.125.80 on Wed, 03 May 2023 10:13:50 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
MORAL HAZARD IN THE LABOR MARKET 217

respectively, yields holds in Bukidon in northern Mindanao, Philip-


1 pines where, as is typical of agriculture in the
Alnci t-ln(I3(1 + r)) Philippines, individuals work not only on their
YC
own or rented (shared-in) plots of land but in the
YH1
+ -A In Hit --A In pt labor market under both piece-rate and time-wage
YC YC payment schemes.7 These households, whose
principal crops are corn, rice and sugar cane,
1Wk* (0 + were
E interviewed
SCj1j*) in four rounds at four month

+- W 7*e8 ) A lnWki
intervals in 1984-85 as part of an International
Food Policy Research Institute study by Bouis
1 W* and Haddad (1990). In addition to detailed infor-
*k E 6 cj A lit (17)
YC kek ijeJ mation in each round on wages received, days

The key implication of equation (17) is that the worked, payment method, and activity type (e.g.,
harvesting, planting, weeding), there is informa-
parameter estimates associated with the labor
tion for each household member on weight, height
supplied to each of the different reward schemes
and calorie intake based on the 24-hour recall
reflect differences in the return to calories icS
method.
Thus in periods when an individual allocates more
Table 1 provides descriptive statistics for the
work to payment schemes for which the returns
sample adults, aged 18 through 59, that we use
to calories are higher he/she will also, ceteris
paribus, consume a greater amount of calories. for analysis. Five types of contractual work ar-
This result is the dynamic analogue to the result rangements corresponding a priori to differing

in the static intrahousehold allocation model of effort incentives can be distinguished in the data
-piece-rate wages, under which workers receive
Pitt et al. (1990), although that model did not
all of the returns from their work; on-farm work,
distinguish work activities by their effort incen-
where about half of workers receive a full share
tives.
of their work and about half are working under a
II. Data share tenancy contract from which they typically
receive about 50% of the returns from their ef-
The above framework suggests that to test for
fort; agricultural time-wages, which are poten-
the existence and importance of moral hazard
tially subject to the most severe moral hazard,
associated with contractual arrangements, in the
and non-agricultural wages, which are also paid
absence of direct measures of worker effort, it is
on a time basis. As can be seen, a substantial
necessary to have longitudinal information on
number of sample individuals worked under
health, calorie intakes, and activities, differenti-
piece-rate and time-wage payment schemes; in-
ated by incentives regimes, for individual work-
deed, of adult workers in the sample households
ers. The data used in this analysis are from a
who contribute at least two observations to the
stratified6 random panel of 448 farming house-
labor market data (i.e., at the very least they
performed the same job in two different rounds
SNote that the fact that the marginal product of effort is
equated across the different schemes implies that wj,/8j, will or different jobs in the same or different rounds),
also be equated across schemes given the specification for 70.7%wj of men and 67.7% of women worked both
in equation (16).
6 The sampling frame for the survey stratified barrios (vil-
for piece-rate and time wages. Men evidently
lages) into three classifications-those in which households spend more time in the wage labor market, but
were mostly engaged in corn production, those in which are substantially more likely to work for time
households were mostly engaged in sugar cane production,
wages than for piece-rates compared to women.
and those barrios in which both corn and sugar were pro-
duced. These strata were formed on the basis of the distance
of the barrios from a sugar cane mill. Within these strata,
households and barrios were selected on a random basis. 7Although we focus on the distinction between piece-rate
Despite the stratification, the information on primary occupa-and time-wage earnings, there is some heterogeneity in the
tions provided by respondents indicates that 63% of the heads form of payment within each type of work. Piece-rates include
of households in the sample were engaged in corn production, cash payments on a unit basis as well as in-kind payments that
8% were engaged in rice production, and only 6% were are a share of the harvest. It should also be noted that the
engaged in sugar production, as either landowners, tenants or appropriate unit to be used in the piece-rate payment for
laborers (Bouis, 1984). plowing or weeding may, for example, be the plot of land.

This content downloaded from


103.21.125.80 on Wed, 03 May 2023 10:13:50 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
218 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

TABLE 1.-DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS

Men Women
(N= 458) (N= 494)

Mean Std. Dev Mean Std. Dev.

Fraction of people working


during study period in:
Piece-rate 0.423 0.495 0.240 0.428
Time-wage 0.581 0.494 0.194 0.396
On-farm 0.530 0.500 0.367 0.482
Non-agric. 0.366 0.482 0.251 0.434
Fraction of total days
worked in:
Piece-rate 0.052 0.156 0.014 0.065
Time-wage 0.125 0.260 0.020 0.091
On-farm 0.128 0.260 0.042 0.151
Non-agric. 0.157 0.331 0.126 0.313
Calories 2609.6 990.2 2160.0 861.5
Body-mass index (kg/meter2) 20.17 1.963 20.64 2.815
Illness (fraction days) 0.033 0.144 0.045 0.175
Height (cm) 160.7 6.163 150.1 5.491
Education (years completed) 5.903 5.104 6.581 6.760
Land owned (hectares) 2.253 3.830 1.953 3.458

This is due in part to the fact that piece-rates are ing to a survey round using as determinants the
predominantly paid in harvesting, a labor-inten- fraction of total days in that period spent by the
sive activity that employs a higher proportion of worker in each of the five contractual regimes,
women compared to other activities, although calories consumed in the survey day, the fraction
piece rates are also paid in other activities-for of days that the individual reported that he or she
example, 23% of all plowing days are paid ac- was ill in the round (based on a two-week refer-
cording to piece rates.8 ence period), sex, age and previous-period BMI.
As in other data sets from low-income coun- We also include in the specification dummy vari-
tries reporting individual calorie consumption ables for the ten municipios, which will capture
(e.g., Pitt et al., 1990), men consume significantly differences across households in the local health
more calories on average than do women, a dif- infrastructure and environment (e.g., water qual-
ferential that may in part be explained by the ity, sanitation).
greater labor-force activity of men. Women also To estimate the health production function, it
report that they are ill more often than do the is necessary to take into account the possibility
men. We use a measure of health that is sensitive that activities, differentiated by contractual terms,
to short-run consumption and work activity, the and thus by effort expended, and calories are
body mass index (BMI), weight divided by height allocated according to unmeasured health-related
squared. This measure, as can be seen in table 1, endowments, as found in Pitt et al. (1990). More-
is approximately the same on average for men over, illness is not likely to be orthogonal to
and women, with men being on average 7% taller unobserved healthiness, nor is the initial-period
than women. BMI, and calories consumed in the 24-hour recall
We estimate the health or BMI production period measure with error the average consump-
function over the four-month period correspond- tion of calories over the round, which is approxi-
mately three months. Accordingly, both to take
into account the measurement error in the calo-
rie variable and the endogeneity of the activity
and health variables, we estimate the health
8 Within tasks, payment form appears to be related to the
(BMI) production function using two-stage least-
size of the farm operated by the employer due to evident scale
economies in hiring supervisors of piece-rate workers (Foster
squares, where we employ variables reflecting
and Rosenzweig, 1992). household budget constraints-household wealth

This content downloaded from


103.21.125.80 on Wed, 03 May 2023 10:13:50 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
MORAL HAZARD IN THE LABOR MARKET 219

and area-specific prices-as instruments, includ- body mass and that participation in non-agricult-
ing the land owned by the household, the age and ural work actually increases BMI net of calorie
sex composition of the household (which affects consumption compared to the left out non-labor-
the allocation of household resources to each force activity! Indeed, the results are sensible
individual in the household), the height of the only when two-stage least squares, which is pre-
individual, the price of corn (the principal com- ferred statistically, is used, as reported in the
modity for which there is price information for subsequent columns. In all specifications esti-
each area and round), and round and municipio mated by the two-stage procedure, increases in
dummy variables, which reflect locale-specific la- calories, net of activities, increase BMI and ill-
bor market conditions and consumption prices.9 ness depletes BMI. Moreover, in column 2, where
To make use of as much of the sample infor- we replicate the OLS specification, the ordering
mation as possible, we use all observations on of the deleterious effects of work on BMI con-
individuals in which there is adjacent-period in- forms to the a priori ranking of the potential
formation on BMI, as well as information on the moral hazard entailed by the different work ar-
other variables. For most individuals, therefore, rangements, with piece-rate work depleting BMI
we have three observations (one round is lost by substantially more than the next most effort-
because of the use of lagged-BMI in the specifi- intensive payment scheme, on-farm work (some
cation), although some rounds are missing for of which is on a share basis), and with time-wage
some individuals, mainly due to lack of informa- agricultural or non-agricultural work not dimin-
tion on BMI for consecutive periods or on calorie ishing BMI more than the reference non-labor-
consumption. The total number of observations force activity.
from which the production function could be In column 3, we report the estimates obtained
estimated is 2274. To take into account the non- when we decompose the self-cultivation activity
independence of the observations, we employed into share-tenancy and own-cultivation by adding
an ARl-error scheme. We report the estimated a variable that is self-cultivation multiplied by the
error correlations, which differ by specification, share of the farmer's total cultivated land that is
below. farmed under share tenancy. If share tenancy
reduces effort, then the coefficient on this vari-
III. Estimates able should be positive. The estimates confirm
this, and indicate that the negative effect on body
A. Determinants of BMI. mass of self-cultivation on own or fixed-rent land
Table 2 reports the estimates of the BMI pro- is no different from that of piece-rate wage work
duction function (equation (12)).1o The first col- (F(1, 2255) = 1.63), while work effort is evidently
umn of the table reports the OLS-AR1 estimates substantially less in time-wage activities and un-
in which we do not distinguish between self- der share tenancy cultivation compared to either
cultivation on own land or cultivation under share piece-rate or own cultivation. The significantly
tenancy. These estimates, which are rejected by higher effort observed under piece-rate compared
the Hausman-Wu test, indicate that, net of calo- to self-cultivation observed in the second-column
rie consumption, time-wage work depletes body estimates is evidently due to the high proportion
fat no less than do self-cultivation and wage work of cultivators in the sample working as share
under piece-rates. The OLS estimates also indi- tenants and the reduced incentives of that con-
cate that calories do not significantly augment tractual form.
In the fourth column we test whether the sig-
nificantly greater negative effect of work on BMI
9 The instrumental-variables method will result in consistent
estimates as long as the measurement errors in calorie con- elicited by a piece-rate regime or in self-cultiva-
sumption are random. tion compared to time-wage work is due to dif-
10 We omit from the table all of the municipio dummy
ferences in the type of work activity. For example,
variable coefficients. In all specifications, the set of municipio
variables is statistically significant. We also tested whether or 59.0% of the days spent in harvest work by paid
not the set of production function coefficients differed by sex. laborers were paid under a piece-rate scheme,
The (preferred) two-stage estimates indicated that we could
while only 14.6% of paid labor days in weeding
not reject the hypothesis that the health production function
is the same for both men and women (F(17,2238) = 0.67). were compensated under a piece-rate regime. If

This content downloaded from


103.21.125.80 on Wed, 03 May 2023 10:13:50 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
220 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

TABLE 2.-LEAST SQUARES AND Two-STAGE LEAST SQUARES ESTIMATES


WITH AR1 ERRORS OF BODY-MASS INDEX (BMI) PRODUCTION FUNCTION'

OLS TSLS

1 2 3 4 5

Piece-rate workb -0.175 - 3.36 - 3.33 -4.49 -4.78d


(0.95)c (2.48) (2.47) (2.36) (2.52)
On-farm workb - 0.206 -1.28 -1.57 -2.00 - 1.90d
(1.33) (2.86) (3.08) (3.22) (2.57)
On farm work x 1.12 0.900 1.49d
fraction (1.17) (0.88) (1.00)
sharecroppedb
Time-wage workb - 0.155 - 0.0682 - 0.464 - 1.04 - 0.150d
(1.29) (0.10) (0.60) (1.13) (0.10)
Non-agric. workb 0.144 - 0.382 - 0.406 - 0.249 -0.622d
(2.19) (1.40) (1.50) (0.83) (1.35)
Calories (x 10-3)b 0.0112 0.146 0.135 0.151 0.0613d
(0.44) (1.39) (1.29) (1.30) (0.39)
Illness - 0.0327 -0.149 -0.144 -0.116 -0.108
(3.64) (2.50) (2.42) (1.76) (1.62)
Lagged BMIb 0.912 0.948 0.948 0.936 0.820e
(11.4) (44.5) (44.7) (39.1) (10.3)
Harvesting b -0.175
(0.48)
Harvest sugarb 1.78
(0.89)
Weedingb 0.878
(1.22)
Male -0.0527 0.0742 0.111 0.134 0.121
(1.13) (0.84) (1.18) (1.39) (0.84)
Hausman test:
F-test (7,2249) (8,2247) (11,2241) (14,2235)
3.67 3.41 2.73 4.72
P-value 0.0006 0.0007 0.0017 0.0001
a All specifications also include nine municipio dummy variables.
b Endogenous variable. Instruments include education, height, age, age squared, land, household composition
(age, sex groups), round and municipio dummy variables, and interactions of these variables with land. Work by
contractual arrangement and by task and illness measured as fraction of days in the previous four-month period.
c Absolute value of t-ratios in parentheses.
d Estimates of work activity, calorie and BMI effects and their t-ratios computed at the sample mean estimate of
BMI from specification in which all of these variables are interacted with lagged BMI.
e Estimate of lagged BMI effect and its t-ratio computed at the sample means of the work activity and calorie
variables.

harvesting is a more energy-intensive activity agricultural


than task variables are not jointly statisti-
weeding or other activities, then the differences cally significant (F(3,2252) = 0.69).
observed in BMI depletion by contractual terms All of the specifications reported in columns
may merely reflect differences in the energy- one through four assume that BMI depletion
intensity of work tasks. Variables reflecting the reflects energy expenditures equally for all indi-
proportion of days in the round (whether as a viduals. The nutrition literature (e.g., Sukhatme
wage laborer or self-employed) spent by the indi- 1977) suggests, however, that exertion rates, for
vidual in harvesting, in weeding and in harvestinggiven activities, and basal metabolic rates depend
inversely on weight. This implies that those indi-
sugar, alleged to be a particularly onerous activity
(Immink and Viteri, 1981), are thus added to the viduals with greater initial BMI will draw down
specification in column three. Although harvest their BMI more in any given activity than will
work is evidently a more energy-intensive activity,those with initially lower BMI, and the effect of
the results are essentially unchanged when the calories on BMI will also be less for those with
variables that also classify work activities by agri-initially greater BMI. Indeed, as might be the
cultural task are added to the specification; in- case if more rapid growth in one period resulted
deed, the joint F-test indicates that the three in less efficient growth in a subsequent period,

This content downloaded from


103.21.125.80 on Wed, 03 May 2023 10:13:50 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
MORAL HAZARD IN THE LABOR MARKET 221

the estimates of the intrapersonal cross-period ancy are statistically different (F(1,2249) = 3.09
correlations in residuals from all of the linear and 4.54, respectively). Work paid under share
specifications are negative and statistically signif- tenancy, moreover, essentially depletes BMI no
icant, although not large (-0.10). To the extent differently than non-participation in the labor
that BMI sorts people among activities differen- force net of calorie intake."
tiated by payment schemes, as implied by our
results reported below, not taking into account B. Payment Method and the Return to Calories
potential interactions between BMI and activities
The production function estimates indicate that
in estimating the effects of the payment schemes
there is substantial moral hazard associated with
on BMI depletion could result in misleading in-
time-wage employment relative to piece-rate and
ferences.
own-employment payment schemes with respect
In the last column of table 2 we report esti-
to worker effort, as reflected in differential
mates from a specification of the produc-
scheme-specific rates of BMI depletion. The fact
tion function in which all of the (endogenous)
that effort is not directly observable precludes the
payment-scheme variables and calories are inter-
direct estimation of the wage equation (2). How-
acted with the lagged BMI variable. In this speci-
ever, it is possible to estimate directly whether
fication all but one of the six estimated interac-
calories, which are also unlikely to be well-
tion coefficients were negative, consistent with
observed by employers, are differentially re-
the hypothesis of homeostatic metabolism, and
warded according to payment scheme. Because
the set of interaction terms is jointly statistically
effort under payment regime j may be written as
significant (F(6,2249) = 3.48). We report in the
a function of caloric intake and health alone, we
last column of table 2 the estimated effects of the
may substitute equation (11) into equation (2) to
payment schemes and of calories implied by the
obtain a wage equation that depends only on
interactive specification at the sample mean level
health and calories:
of BMI; the reported BMI effect is that at the
sample mean values for the work activities and
wjit =w(i_,c, j(Hit_l, COt)
calories. Although the estimated error-correla-
tion is positive (0.096) for this specification, sug- = wj*(Hit_1, Cit). (18)
gesting that the negative autocorrelation obtained
from the linear specifications arose from the In order to assess whether calories and health
omission of the interactions between initial are differentially rewarded under piece and
body-mass and the efficiency of calorie consump- time-rate wages we estimate equation (18) by
tion and expenditure, the mean effects of the relating the difference between a worker's piece-
payment schemes are not very different from rate and time wages within the same survey round
those obtained from the linear (instrumented) to his/her calorie consumption, BMI, height, sex,
specifications. In particular, consistent with the schooling, and age.12 The coefficients of this spec-
existence of moral hazard in time-wage work and ification are thus the difference between the
in share tenancy, the estimates indicate that, net piece-rate wage and time-wage coefficients in in-
of calorie consumption, for a worker with the dividual wage equations. If calories are not known
sample mean BMI employment under a piece-rate by employers then we would expect a positive
payment scheme or self-cultivating entirely on coefficient on calories. Coefficients on other vari-
owned land over the survey period would dimin- ables will depend on the extent to which, on the
ish BMI by 23% and 9%, respectively, relative to one hand, these variables are associated with
the omitted activity, non-labor force time, while higher effort given caloric intake in piece-rate
BMI would only be reduced (relatively) by 1% if work, in which case they will be positive, and on
all work time was devoted to time-wage work.
11 Of course, the left out activity includes in some cases
The difference between the depletion of BMI household production. The results do not therefore imply that
under the piece-rate and self-employment "leisure" and work under time wages are equally onerous to
schemes is not statistically different (F(1,2249) = workers.
12 The price of corn may also affect wage rates if employers
2.18), while that between piece-rate work and use price as a signal of caloric intake, and is included in the
either time-wage work or work under share ten- empirical specifications of (18).

This content downloaded from


103.21.125.80 on Wed, 03 May 2023 10:13:50 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
222 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

the other hand they are used by employers using In the second column of table 3 we report
a time-wage payment scheme as a signal of caloric estimates obtained from a specification which also
intake (in which case they will be negative). A includes controls for crop and task. Controlling
likely candidate for the latter would seem to be for the within-round differences in tasks does not
BMI which is responsive to recent nutritional affect the inferences about the effects of incen-
intake (as is evident in table 2). tives, although the precision of the differential
An advantage of the within-round estimation calorie effect is reduced. However, differences in
procedure is that the existence of any worker tasks also do not appear to significantly affect the
characteristics that are not measured in the data differential in piece-rate and time wages, net of
but which are observed by employers, correlated worker characteristics and the difference in pay-
with the measured worker characteristics, and ment regimes, and so are just adding random
have equal effects on piece-rates and time-wages noise to the specification and reducing estimation
will not bias the estimates of the differential wage efficiency.
effects of the measured characteristics. Because The estimates of the differential effects of calo-
calorie consumption and BMI may depend on rie consumption on wage earnings under the two
wages, however, two-stage least-squares is again payment schemes are based on a sample of work-
used. The instruments are land owned by the ers who were employed under both schemes in a
household and round dummy variables. The sam- single four-month period. Although almost half
ple consists of all individuals who worked under (47.1% based on all four rounds) of all wage
both types of wage-payment regimes within a earners in a period worked under both regimes, it
single round, with one random round selected for is not likely that this is a random sample of all
each worker among those with more than two workers, particularly because only 28% of all
rounds in which he or she had worked for the two sample individuals work for wages at all in a
wage types. round. Indeed, it would be expected, for example,
The weighted (by the number .of days in wage that workers with unobserved (by employers) pro-
activities) within-round, two-stage least-squares ductivity-enhancing characteristics that are not
estimates are reported in the first column of table rewarded under a time-wage regime would tend
3.13 The estimates indicate, consistent with the to specialize in either self-cultivation or piece-rate
differential incentives associated with piece-rate work, while those with low levels of skills would
and time-wage payment schemes and with the seek time-wage employment.16 Selection also may
difficulty of monitoring calorie consumption and apply to the group of workers under both pay-
effort, that calories are significantly more re- ment methods; such workers are likely to be
warded when workers are paid on a piece-rate those for whom differentials in rewards across
basis than when they receive time-wages, while wage payment regimes are minimized. If calories
observable BMI, which may be used by employers do increase piece-rate wages more than they do
as a signal for calorie consumption, is significantly time wages and workers are heterogeneous in
more rewarded under time wages than under a characteristics that affect their payment-method
piece-rate regime.14"5 reward differentials, the estimated effects of in-
creased calorie consumption on the difference in
earnings under piece-rate and time wage schemes

13 The specification also includes municipio dummy vari-may be underestimated if such selection is not
ables. taken into account. This is because among work-
14 These results may explain the finding in Behrman and ers with high levels of calorie consumption, only
Deolalikar (1989), based on Indian data, that calories were
significantly more rewarded in the labor market during the
"peak" season while the opposite was true for weight-for-
height because in that setting piece-rate wages are almost
exclusively paid for harvest (peak-period) operations. example, if the returns to additional effort in terms of effec-
15The positive coefficients on height, male and schooling
tive work accomplished are higher for taller individuals than
level should not be interpreted in the same way as that on these individuals will exhibit higher wages in piece-rate than
caloric intake, because there is no reason to believe that in time-wage employment.
employers will have difficulty in measuring these variables. 16 In Foster and Rosenzweig (1993), evidence is presented
Instead, as indicated above, these coefficients likely reflect the based on these data that a large component of worker skills is
fact that in equation (18) effort has been solved out. For not known by employers and that adverse selection is present:

This content downloaded from


103.21.125.80 on Wed, 03 May 2023 10:13:50 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
MORAL HAZARD IN THE LABOR MARKET 223

TABLE 3.-WEIGHTED Two-STAGE LEAST SQUARES ESTIMATES: WITHIN-ROUND


DIFFERENTIAL EFFECTS OF CALORIC CONSUMPTION AND BODY SIZE ON PIECE-RATE

MINUS TIME WAGES

Add Task and Selectivity- Selectivity-


Basic Sugar Harvesting Correction: Correction:
Variable Specificationa Controls Probit Multinomial Logit

Calories (X 10-3)b 0.311 0.215 0.317 0.347


(2.40)c (1.66) (2.55) (2.66)
BMIb -19.9 - 22.9 - 19.1 -17.2
(1.80) (2.28) (1.61) (1.36)
Height 1.38 1.56 1.33 1.24
(1.68) (1.82) (1.55) (1.42)
Male 0.477 0.361 0.483 0.506
(3.14) (2.18) (3.19) (3.28)
Schooling 0.0492 0.0294 0.0510 0.0554
(1.80) (1.05) (1.85) (1.98)
Age - .00392 .0332 - .00830 - .0232
(0.06) (0.52) (0.11) (0.29)
Age squared 0.104 - 0.441 0.168 0.393
(X 10-3) (0.10) (0.48) (0.16) (0.34)
Corn price - 0.0638 - 0.0279 - 0.0680 - 0.0719
(0.66) (0.30) (0.69) (0.73)
A (X 10-4) -0.101 -0.415
(0.24) (0.58)
Test statistic, task 1.23 1.18 1.14
variables + sugar
harvesting F(4,170)
Number of
observations 191 191 191 191

'All specifications include municipio dummy v


b Endogenous variable: Instruments include
and land interacted with round variables.
cAbsolute values of asymptotic t-ratios in parentheses.

those who were penalized least under a time-wage categories, as in a multinomial probit model, is
regime would work for both piece-rate and time extremely computationally burdensome. Instead,
wages. we estimate as a second model, the multinomial-
To assess if sample selection importantly af- logit selectivity model of Lee (1983), which
fects the estimates presented in columns one and provides estimates characterizing the complete
two, we estimated two selectivity models. First, choice-set, although it assumes independent er-
we estimated the standard two-stage probit selec- rors, and use those estimates to correct the sec-
tion model (Heckman (1979)) in which we esti- ond-stage equation for the selectivity, if any, of
mated in the first stage probit equations for each being in any one of the alternative sample cate-
of the four survey rounds determining the proba- gories.
bility that a worker earned both piece-rate and The last two columns of table 3 report the
time wages in that round. In principle, it is desir- estimates of the differenced wage equations cor-
able to estimate a model that incorporates the rected for the selectivity of the sample using the
complete choice set of workers, of which working probit and multinomial selectivity models, respec-
under both payment regimes is one of four alter- tively. The first-stage probit and the multinomial
natives, the others being working for piece-rate logit estimates are presented in appendix tables
wages only, for time wages only, and not partici- Al and A2. Both selectivity models yield similar
pating in the wage labor market. From such a results. The signs of the coefficients of the A-terms
model, the probability of being in the category in in each column, which indicate the correlation
which payment forms are used can be computed between the residuals of the selection equation
for each worker and this can be used to correct and the wage difference equation, are, as ex-
for the selection of the sample. To estimate this pected, negative, suggesting that individuals more
model and allow for error correlations across likely to work under both payment regimes also

This content downloaded from


103.21.125.80 on Wed, 03 May 2023 10:13:50 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
224 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

TABLE 4.-FIXED-EFFECTS ESTIMATES OF LINEAR APPROXIMATION


To EULER EQUATION

Piece-rate work 0.225 0.225


(2.24)a (2.24)
On-farm work 0.158 0.161
(1.61) (0.98)
On-farm work x - 0.00386
fraction sharecropped (0.02)
Time-wage work 0.0456 0.0457
(0.58) (0.58)
Non-agric. work 0.00515 0.00513
(0.07) (0.07)
Log BMI -0.151 -0.151
(0.40) (0.40)
Illness -0.190 -0.190
(1.97) (1.96)
Log wage -
0.0276 - 0.0276
(0.64) (0.63)
Log corn price - 0.423 - 0.423
(5.31) (5.30)
Hypotheses
Piece-rate and on-farm coeffs. F(1,588) 0.27 F(1,587) 0.13
equal p-value 0.606 p-value 0.723
Piece-rate and non-agric. coeffs. F(1,588) 4.82 F(1,587) 4.82
equal p-value 0.029 p-value 0.029
Piece-rate and time-wage coeffs. F(1,588) 4.23 F(1,587) 4.22
equal p-value 0.040 p-value 0.040
Hausman testb F(7,581) 0.32 F(8,579) 0.28
p-value 0.945 p-value 0.973
All coefficients zero F(8,588) 5.68 F(9,587) 5.04
p-value 0.000 p-value 0.000
a Absolute values of t-ratios in parentheses.
bJoint test for endogeneity of all variables other than corn price. Instr
dummy variables interacted with land, age, sex, education and height.

experience a smaller premium for piece-rate tertemporal allocation of the log of calories for
wages relative to time-wages. And, the estimated individuals working in the wage labor market to
differential effect of calorie consumption on their work activities classified by payment regime,
piece-rate wages is greater when selectivity is their (log) BMI, illness, their (log) wage rate in
taken into account than when it is not. However, piece-rate work and the log of the price of corn,
the A coefficient estimated under either model is the dominant consumption good.'7 Consistent
not statistically significant, suggesting, conditional with the unobservability of calorie allocations to
on the selectivity models approximating the true the employer and with the existence of moral
model relatively well, that sample selectivity is hazard with respect to calories, the estimates
not important, given the specification of the wage indicate that piece-rate work evokes a signifi-
differential equation. cantly greater calorie allocation compared to
time-wage and non-agricultural work but no more
so than on-farm work.18
C. Payment Method and the Allocation
of Calories
17 We estimated the Euler equation on a sample of wage
If, as is evident in table 3, calorie consumption workers because it is necessary to include the period-specific
is not well-observed by employers, then we should value of time as a regressor, and this is not available for
individuals who are employed exclusively in own-farm activi-
expect that a worker's calorie consumption, like
ties. Because the Euler equation is estimated using fixed-
worker effort or energy expenditure, is withheld effects, sample selectivity should not be a problem as long as
when working for time-wages compared to piece the determinants of the probability of wage employment are
not different across periods.
rates or self-employment. Table 4 reports esti-
18 The Hausman-Wu test does not reject the orthogonality
mates of equation (17), which relates the in- of the regressors to the error term.

This content downloaded from


103.21.125.80 on Wed, 03 May 2023 10:13:50 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
MORAL HAZARD IN THE LABOR MARKET 225

The estimates in column one indicate that The estimates, based on longitudinal data from
workers devoting all of their work time to piece- the Philippines, indicate that contractual terms
rate activities are allocated 23% more calories significantly affect worker performance, with
per day on average over the reference period worker effort, as reflected by both calorie expen-
compared to a situation in which they devoted all diture and intake, inversely related to the degree
of their time to the non-labor-market activity, to which the worker has a claim on his or her
workers devoting all of their time to on-farm contribution to output. In particular, workers evi-
work are allocated 16% more calories while dently supply more effort under a piece-rate pay-
workers employed exclusively under a time-wage ment scheme or in self-cultivation on own land
payment scheme receive only an insignificant 5% compared to time-wage employment as reflected
greater allocation compared to being engaged in in the fact that they deplete their body mass by
the non-labor-force activity. In the second col- 10% more, net of calorie consumption, when
umn we again differentiate cultivation by whether working under a piece-rate scheme compared to
it is performed under a share tenancy contract. working as time-wage workers and 13% more
The addition of the share tenancy variable in- than share tenants or those outside of the labor
creases the own-cultivation calorie effect so that force. The evidence also indicates that calorie
it is even closer in magnitude to that for piece- intake is rewarded when workers work for piece-
rates (the difference is not statistically significant),
rates but not when workers work for time wages
and suggests, as expected, that share tenancy and that the same worker consumes 23% (16%)
reduces the calorie allocation, although the effect more calories per day when employed under a
is not statistically significant. These results, con- piece-rate payment scheme (on-farm employ-
sistent with the a priori ranking of worker incen- ment) than when employed for time wages, also
tives associated with the payment regimes with consistent with the energy expenditure implica-
respect to calorie intake, thus conform to the tions of moral hazard.
findings from the production function estimates These results not only provide some empirical
with regard to effort, as measured by BMI deple- foundation for the vast theoretical literature that
tion.19 focusses on the central problem of effort elicita-
tion, but suggests that existing empirical evidence
on moral hazard, based on directly observed in-
V. Conclusion put use, such as labor time, fertilizer, etc., under-
In this paper we have established a method for states the extent of moral hazard. The findings
testing for the existence of moral hazard in labor also provide evidence that enterprises that rely
markets using information on worker health, on wage labor, to the extent that such labor
calorie consumption and type of payment regime. cannot be paid on a piece-rate basis,20 or that
engage in operations on a share contract basis
will be inefficient relative to operations that rely
on family labor utilized on own resources. Finally,
the finding that calorie consumption augments
19 We performed two other tests of the Euler-equation productivity and negatively responds to the price
specification. First, we tested whether calorie allocation rules of the staple food crop implies that the seasonal
differed between men and women. The test statistic based on
the Chow test, in which the sample was split intar subsamples
pattern of food price variation in part augments
containing men and women exclusively, was not statistically productivity. This is because, typically, food prices
significant (F(9,576) = 1.32). We also tested whether there are lowest in the peak (harvest) work periods.
were significant differences in the costs of transferring re-
sources across periods among households. Individuals' in-
Thus, stabilization schemes may reduce total out-
tertemporal strategies of storing calories in the form of food put in such contexts, to the extent that workers
stocks or in the body, through augmenting BMI, may depend work under payment schemes that reward effort.
importantly on direct storage costs and rates of interest. To
assess the importance of heterogeneity in these costs, which
may vary by season and by wealth, we added round dummy
variables and interaction terms involving land size (to proxy
household wealth) and the round variables to the specifica- 20 For a discussion of the conditions that determine the
tion. However, the set of coefficients associated with these feasibility of piece-rate work in the context of agriculture, see
terms was also not statistically significant (F(6,582) = 0.60). Roumasset and Uy (1980) and Foster and Rosenzweig (1992). -

This content downloaded from


103.21.125.80 on Wed, 03 May 2023 10:13:50 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
226 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

REFERENCES Econometrica 47 (Jan. 1979), 153-162.

Bell, Clive, "Alternative Theories of Sharecropping: Some Immink, M., and V. Viteri, "Energy Intake and Productivity
Tests Using Evidence from Northeast India," Journal of Guatemalan Sugarcane Cutters: An Empirical Test
of Development Studies 13 (1977), 317-346. of the Efficiency Wages Hypothesis, Parts I and II,"
Behrman, Jere R., and Anil B. Deolalikar, "Agricultural Journal of Development Economics 92 (1981), 251-287.
Wages in India: The Role of Health, Nutrition, and Lee, Lung-Fei, "Generalized Econometric Models with Selec-
Seasonality," in David E. Sahn (ed.), Seasonal Variabil- tivity," Econometrica 51 (Mar. 1983), 507-512.
ity in Third World Agriculture (Baltimore: Johns Hop- Pitt, Mark M., Mark R. Rosenzweig, and M. N. Hassan,
kins, 1989), 107-117. "Productivity, Health and Inequality in the Intrahouse-
Bouis, Howarth, "Progress Report on Philippine Cash Crop- hold Distribution of Food in Low-income Countries,"
ping Project," The International Food Policy Research American Economic Review 80 (5) (1990), 1139-1156.
Institute, Sept. 1984, mimeo. Roumasset, James, and Marilou Uy, "Piece Rates, Time
Bouis, Howarth E., and Lawrence J. Haddad, Agricultural Rates, and Teams: Explaining Patterns in the Employ-
Commercialization, Nutrition, and the Rural Poor: A ment Relation," Journal of Economic Behavior and
Study of Philippine Farm Households (Boulder: Lynne Organization 1 (1980), 343-360.
Rienner Publishers, 1990). Schultz, T. Paul, "Measurement of Returns to Adult Health:
Deolalikar, Anil B., "Nutrition and Labor Productivity in Morbidity Effects on Wage Rates in Cote D'Ivoire and
Agriculture: Estimates for Rural South India," this Ghana," mimeo (1992).
REVIEW 70 (3) (1988), 406-413. Shaban, Radwan A. "Testing between Competing Models of
Eswaran, Mukesh, and Ashok Kotwal, "A Theory of Two-tier Sharecropping," Journal of Political Economy 95 (5)
(1987), 893-920.
Labor Markets in Agrarian Economies," American
Economic Review 75 (2) (1985a), 162-177. Stiglitz, Joseph E., "Alternative Theories of Wage Determina-
tion and Unemployment: The Efficiency Wage Model,"
, "A Theory of Contractual Structure in Agriculture,"
in Mark Gersovitz, Carlos Diaz-Alejandro, Gustav
American Economic Review 75 (3) (1985b), 352-367.
Ranis, and Mark R. Rosenzweig (eds.), The Theory and
Foster, Andrew D., and Mark R. Rosenzweig, "Unequal Pay Experience of Economic Development (London: George
for Unequal Work: Asymmetric Information, Sex Dis- Allen and Unwin, 1982),
crimination, and the Efficiency of Casual Labor Mar- Strauss, John, "Does Better Nutrition Raise Farm Productiv-
kets," manuscript, University of Pennsylvania (1992). ity?" Journal of Political Economy 94 (2) (1986),
, "Information, Learning and Wage Rates in Low- 297-320.
Income Rural Areas," Journal of Human Resources 28 Sukhatme, P. V., "Malnutrition and Poverty," Ninth Lal
(4) (1993), 759-790. Bhaduri Shastri Memorial Lecture, Indian Agricultural
Heckman, James J., "Sample Bias as a Specification Error," Research Institute, New Delhi, 1977.

TABLE Al.-MULTINOMIAL LOGIT ESTIMATES: DETERMINANTS OF THE LOG-ODDS


OF RECEIVING ONLY A PIECE-RATE WAGE, ONLY A TIME WAGE
OR BOTH TYPES OF PAYMENTS IN A ROUND RELATIVE TO NEITHER

Variablea Piece-Rate Only Time Wage Only Both Wages

Schooling -0.219 -0.135 -0.167


(8.87)b (5.72) (9.02)
Age 0.421 0.306 0.200
(7.23) (5.74) (5.82)
Age squared - 0.00661 - 0.00454 - 0.00294
(7.47) (5.73) (5.92)
Height -
0.0194 - 0.0107 - 0.0248
(1.80) (1.01) (2.96)
Land owned - 0.410 - 0.289 0.241
(8.48) (8.25) (10.43)
Corn Price - 0.490 0.115 -0.279
(2.16) (0.51) (1.62)
Male 2.26 1.27 2.34
(12.0) (7.39) (15.8)
N 4896
x2(57) 1785.9
a Specification also includes three
bAbsolute value of asymptotic t-r

This content downloaded from


103.21.125.80 on Wed, 03 May 2023 10:13:50 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
MORAL HAZARD IN THE LABOR MARKET 227

TABLE A2.-PROBIT ESTIMATES, BY ROUND: DETERMINANTS OF RECEIVING BOTH

PIECE-RATE AND TIME WAGE RATES IN ROUND

Round

Variablea 1 2 3 4

Schooling - 0.106 - 0.0908 - 0.0614 - 0.0876


(3.75)b (3.70) (2.34) (3.68)
Age 0.189 0.122 0.117 0.310
(2.87) (2.57) (2.18) (4.85)
Age squared - 0.00303 -0.00210 -0.00177 - 0.00474
(3.01) (2.97) (2.24) (4.87)
Height -0.00955 -0.0199 -0.00912 0.00650
(0.80) (1.84) (0.76) (0.63)
Land owned -0.142 -0.174 -0.150 -0.167
(3.27) (4.58) (3.16) (4.15)
Cornprice 0.189 0.196 -0.267 -0.590
(0.41) (0.54) (0.81) (3.50)
Male 0.871 0.147 0.636 0.561
(4.36) (7.40) (3.27) (3.29)
N 1224 1224 1152 1224
X2(16) 149.0 246.5 91.3 206.4

a Specification also includes nine munic


bAbsolute value of asymptotic t-ratio in parentheses.

This content downloaded from


103.21.125.80 on Wed, 03 May 2023 10:13:50 +00:00
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like