You are on page 1of 15

HEALTH ECONOMICS DETERMINANTS OF HEALTH

Health Econ. 13: 885–899 (2004)


Published online 24 February 2004 in Wiley InterScience (www.interscience.wiley.com). DOI:10.1002/hec.881

The wage e¡ects of obesity: a longitudinal study


Charles L. Baum II* and William F. Ford
Economics and Finance Department, Middle Tennessee State University, USA

Summary
We use National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (NLSY) data to examine the effects of obesity on wages by gender.
Sample means indicate that both men and women experience a persistent obesity wage penalty over the first two
decades of their careers. We then control for a standard set of socioeconomic and familial variables but find that
standard covariates do not explain why obese workers experience persistent wage penalties. This suggests that other
variables – including job discrimination, health-related factors and/or obese workers’ behavior patterns – may be the
channels through which obesity adversely affects wages. The study closes with a discussion of the public policy
implications suggested by these findings. Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.

Keywords obesity; wages; discrimination; body mass index

However, economists have given relatively little


Introduction systematic attention to the effects of obesity on
labor market outcomes.
An increasing number of Americans are over- We seek to fill a gap in the literature by
weight and obese, with currently about one in examining the effect of obesity on wages by gender
three overweight and one in five obese [1].a As a using National Longitudinal Study of Youth
result, Americans are now more likely to be obese (NSLY) data. Our raw data suggests that obese
than to smoke cigarettes or use illegal drugs [2]. NLSY respondents persistently earn lower wages
Public health officials in the United States have than their non-obese peers. To determine whether
become increasingly alarmed about the growing obesity causes lower wages, we estimate various
incidence of obesity in part because recent research wage model specifications, including fixed-effects
indicates that societal costs of obesity exceed those models to control for potential unobserved hetero-
of cigarette smoking and alcoholism [3].b One such geneity bias. After controlling for a standard set of
cost is the medical expense that obesity imposes: individual characteristics, we find that an obesity
Sturm estimates that obesity increases inpatient wage penalty persists for both males and females,
and outpatient spending by 36 percent. Further, though this penalty is larger for females. We also
obese individuals are shown to experience social examine various channels through which obesity
penalties in their interpersonal activities and in the may affect wages. To do this, we test whether obese
‘marriage market’ [4,5]. Obesity may also have workers earn lower wages because (i) they are
consequences on economic outcomes such as limited by health constraints, (ii) they are more
earnings and employment. For example, obese economically myopic, (iii) they are more costly for
workers may earn lower wages or be less likely to employers who provide health care, or (iv) they are
find employment due to employer discrimination. discriminated against by customers.

*Correspondence to: Economics and Finance Department, Middle Tennessee State University, Box 27, Murfreesboro, TN 37132,
USA. E-mail: cbaum@mtsu.edu

Received 28 August 2002


Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Accepted 25 September 2003
886 C. L. Baum II and W. F. Ford

The next section of the paper addresses the A number of external behavioral forces in the
conceptual rationales for why obesity might obese worker’s environment may also help to
adversely impact workers’ wages. Literature Re- explain the observed earnings penalty. Employers
view section sets out the empirical methodology. may discriminate in hiring, promoting, compen-
The scope and limitations of the NLSY data set sating, or firing such workers. Further, employers
are discussed in Empirical Methodology section, who provide health insurance may penalize obese
and the results are presented in Data section. The workers with lower wages because they fear that
final section of the paper presents conclusions of these workers’ health care will be more expensive.
the study and some areas of future research If so, then obesity wage penalties would be
interest. concentrated among workers with employer-pro-
vided health insurance. Another possible form of
external discrimination against obese workers is
customer discrimination. Obese workers in occu-
Conceptual issues pations involving direct public contact may
experience a wage penalty though their interaction
Simply demonstrating that obese workers earn less with customers. This would occur if customers
than their non-obese co-workers begs the question were averse to interacting with those who are
of exactly how obesity adversely affects their career obese.
earnings. Since Americans typically gain weight as
they age, it is possible, for example, that the
observed obesity wage penalty may simply be
masking employer discrimination against older Literature review
workers in the labor market. Discrimination
against women and members of minority groups The economics literature has given relatively little
may also account for some of the apparent obesity attention to the effects of obesity on wages [5]. In
wage penalty since, for example, blacks are more fact, only four studies in the literature have used
likely to be obese. The same is true of differences in multivariate regression analysis to examine the
work experience, educational achievement, and effects of obesity on wages in the United States.c
familiar environment factors. Its follows, there- Though they essentially use the same data, their
fore, that any attempt to identify the underlying results differ markedly. Register and Williams [7]
causes of obesity earnings penalties must include use cross-sectional data from the 1982 NLSY to
controls for those standard socioeconomic vari- examine the effect of obesity on wages (in wage
ables. Applying such controls may then help focus level models) by gender. Their results indicate that
the search for other possible explanations, includ- obesity reduces females’ wages by 12 percent but
ing a variety of behavioral factors. has no significant effects for males. Loh [8] also
Two basic types of behavioral factors warrant uses 1982 NLSY data, but he finds that obesity
attention – those internal to the workers and does not significantly affect wage level for males or
external forces impacting them in their work females. When examining wage changes (between
environments. First, consider factors internal to 1982 and 1985), however, Loh finds that obesity
the worker. Obese workers may earn lower wages does have a statistically significant negative effect
because they are less productive due to health for males (of about 5.5 percent) but not for
problems. That is, obesity may limit the kind or females.
amount of work they can perform. Alternatively, Pagan and Davila [9] also estimate cross-section
obese workers may suffer a wage penalty because wage level models using 1989 NLSY data. They
they place a higher premium on present con- find that obesity reduces female wages, with some
sumption. Economically myopic workers, who variation across occupations, but not those of
have higher marginal rates of time preference, males. They argue that males’ greater occupational
may be less concerned about the possible long- mobility offsets potential wage penalties due to
term health effects of obesity and, consequently, obesity. Similarly, Averett and Korenman [5] use
may be more likely to be obese. Further, such 1988 NLSY data to examine the effects of obesity
myopic workers may also be less likely to engage on wages. Their results are mixed: wage level
in training, resulting in a flatter career earnings models indicate that women and, to a lesser extent,
profile. men both suffer obesity wage penalties, but their

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Health Econ. 13: 885–899 (2004)
The Wage E¡ects of Obesity 887

sibling-differenced fixed-effects models indicate no Empirical methodology


significant obesity wage penalties. In particular, in
their wage level models, obese women suffer a 10– We use four approaches to determine the effect of
24 percent wage penalty and men suffer an obesity obesity on wages.e First, we assume that the effect
wage penalty of about 8 percent. of obesity on wages can be estimated from the
The forgoing literature has some shortcomings, following ‘wage level’ model:
and these shortcomings probably account for their
contrasting results. First, the literature uses small lnðWit Þ ¼ bXit þ eit ð1Þ
and unrepresentative samples. For example, the
Loh [8] and Register and Williams [7] studies only where W is the wage rate, X is a vector of
include respondents from the 1982 NLSY wave explanatory variables that includes variables mea-
who were then unusually young – between the suring obesity, and e is the error term for
ages of 17 and 24. As our analysis shows below, observation i in time t. We initially assume e is a
these respondents were less likely to be obese mean-zero, constant-variance random variable
because they were still quite young. (Actually, our that is uncorrelated with the explanatory variables
descriptive statistics show that in 1982 obese in X. Correspondingly, we use ordinary least
NLSY youth earned no less than those who were squares (OLS) regression to estimate the effect of
not obese). Further, in 1982 the careers of NLSY obesity on log wages.
youth had just begun, their wages were highly However, there may be unobserved factors that
variable, and many were still in school. Second, affect wages and that are correlated with the
the estimates found in the literature fail to control explanatory variables in X. Such correlation would
sufficiently for unobserved heterogeneity. Only exist, for example, if unobserved variables such as
Averett and Korenman [5] attempt to control for ability and motivation are correlated with both
unobserved heterogeneity. However, their sibling- obesity and wages. This would be true if those with
differenced fixed effects wage models produce low motivation and/or low ability were more likely
few statistically significant results because of to be obese and earn lower wages. If variables such
small sample sizes. Unobserved heterogeneity as ability and motivation are unobserved, then
could bias the results if the same unmeasured they will be captured by the error term, and the
traits that determine obesity simultaneously affect obesity variable and the error term will be
wages. An additional shortcoming is that the correlated. If these factors are not controlled for,
literature fails to identify the channels through then OLS estimates will be biased. Therefore,
which obesity affects wages.d Thus, though these we add a supplemental set of covariates to our
studies identify the overall effect of obesity on wage models, as discussed below in the data
wages, they can only speculate on the reasons for section, to control more extensively for individual
this effect. background characteristics that might affect
We build upon the existing literature by using wages.
longitudinal NLSY data from the 1981 through In our second approach, we assume that the
1998 waves, which includes older respondents wage model contains an individual fixed compo-
who were more likely to be obese and were nent, ni , which represents individual-specific un-
further along in their careers. This strategy also observed heterogeneity. Thus, the wage equation
results in a much larger sample. Second, we becomes
attempt to control for potential unobserved
heterogeneity bias by including a large number of lnðWit Þ ¼ bXit þ vi þ eit ð2Þ
exogenous background characteristics, by compar-
ing individual-specific wage changes over time, and where W, X, and e are as defined above, and
by comparing wages between siblings and wage ni is an individual-specific factor representing
changes over time between siblings. Additionally, unobserved characteristics. If correlation between
we not only identify the effect of obesity on wages, X and ni exists and if the individual heterogeneity
we also attempt to identify specific mechanisms component (ni ) is unobserved to the researcher,
through which obesity affects wages. This is then estimates will be biased. The fixed-effects
important in order to determine whether obesity technique uses cases where respondents provide
wage penalties are due to discrimination or other at least two wage observations, taking the differ-
factors. ence between wage observations from the same

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Health Econ. 13: 885–899 (2004)
888 C. L. Baum II and W. F. Ford

respondent across time: (from a first-stage model) because the latter


instrumental variable technique relies on assumed
lnðWit Þ  lnðWit1 Þ ¼ bðXit  Xit1 Þ þ ðnit  nit1 Þ
exclusion restrictions and on the assumption
þ ðeit  eit1 Þ ð3Þ that the excluded variables are uncorrelated with
for observation i in time t and t  1. If we assume the unobserved fixed effects.f Our fixed-effects
that the individual-specific unobserved heteroge- estimators will simultaneously control for sample
neity is fixed over time, then nit ¼ nit1 and the selection bias assuming any unobserved factors
unobserved variables drop out. that determine employment are fixed.g Further,
Our third approach allows the unobserved the unobserved variables may vary over time
heterogeneity to change over time but assumes (as may family-specific unobserved heterogeneity
that such heterogeneity at time t is family-specific. at time t between siblings) without inducing bias
That is, the wage model contains a component, nft, if the remaining error differences are unco-
which represents family-specific unobserved het- rrelated with the differenced covariates. However,
erogeneity at time t. Thus, the wage equation if the unobserved variables vary over time
becomes (or family-specific unobserved heterogeneity at
time t differs between siblings) and the error
lnðWit Þ ¼ b Xit þ nft þ eit ð4Þ differences are correlated with the differenced
As before, if correlation between X and nft exists covariates, then the fixed effects estimates will be
and if the family heterogeneity component (nft ) is biased as well.
unmeasurable to the researcher, then estimates will
be biased. To control for this source of bias, the
fixed-effects technique uses cases where the re-
Data
spondent has a sibling, and it takes the difference
between wage observations between siblings from We use National Longitudinal Survey of Youth
the same family at time t: (NLSY) data to examine the effects of obesity on
wages by gender. From 1979 through 1994, the
lnðWit Þ  lnðWjt Þ ¼ bðXit  Xjt Þ þ ðnift  njft Þ NLSY annually interviewed a cohort of 12 686
þ ðeit  ejt Þ ð5Þ respondents (6283 of whom are female) who were
between the ages of 14 and 21 in 1979. After the
for siblings i and j in time t. 1994 survey, the NLSY began interviewing bien-
Our fourth and final approach controls for both nially, and these respondents have since been re-
individual-specific heterogeneity and family-speci- interviewed on that basis. In each survey, the
fic heterogeneity. In this approach, the wage model NLSY collects information on each respondent’s
contains an individual-specific component, ni , that employment status, wages, and personal charac-
is intertemporally fixed, as well as a family fixed teristics.h In addition, questions about weight were
component, nft , which may be variable over time. asked in the 1981, 1982, 1985, 1986, 1987, 1989,
Thus, the wage equation becomes: 1990, 1992, 1993, 1994, 1996, and 1998 surveys.i
lnðWit Þ ¼ bXi þ nit  nft þ eit ð6Þ We use four strategies to identify the effect of
obesity on wages. In each approach, we exclude
To control for these sources of bias, the fixed- person-year observations in which the respondent
effects technique examines individual changes over is less than 18 years old. We also exclude
time and compares these changes with changes for respondents in years during which their education
a sibling over the same period: has yet to be completed. Additionally, respondents
½lnðWit Þ  lnðWit1 Þ  ½lnðWjt Þ  lnðWjt1 Þ who were in the armed forces or self-employed are
excluded. In all four approaches, respondents
¼ ½bðXit  Xit1 Þ þ ðnit  nit1 Þ þ ðnift  nift1 Þ potentially provide multiple observations. There-
þ ðejt  eit1 Þ  ½bðXjt  Xjt1 Þ þ ðnjt  njt1 Þ fore, we control for correlation among observa-
þ ðnift  nift1 Þ þ ðejt  ejt1 Þ ð7Þ tions that come from the same respondent.j
Otherwise, such correlation would lead to under-
for siblings i and j in time t. estimated standard errors and overestimated sig-
We use these various types of fixed-effects nificance levels because observations from the
estimators to control for fixed unobserved vari- same respondent are not independent from one
ables rather than using a predicted value of obesity another.

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Health Econ. 13: 885–899 (2004)
The Wage E¡ects of Obesity 889

Our first approach uses person-year observa- greater than 25 (greater than 24) is above normal
tions to estimate a wage model where the (overweight). Obesity for males and females is
dependant variable is the log real wage (in levels). defined as a BMI of 30 or more [7,9,18]. The
Each year in which a respondent meets the criteria average BMI over all survey years is 25.36, which,
listed above is included as a separate observation. ironically, is above normal.
This approach results in 51 500 person-year Figure 1 shows the average yearly BMI for the
observations that provide the requisite wage and full sample, for males, and for females. In 1981,
weight information, 26 611 of whom are male and the average BMI for the full sample was about
24 889 of whom are female. The average real wage 22.5, with males having a slightly higher average
is $7.33, based on the CPI base year period of BMI. However, the average BMI increases mono-
1982–1984. tonically as the sample ages. By 1989, the average
Our second approach uses a fixed effects BMI for the full sample was 25. After 1990, both
specification where each observation is a compar- males and females had an average BMI that would
ison of two wage observations. Specifically, we be classified as overweight. By 1998, the BMI
compare wages between each survey year that measures averaged between 26 and 27.
provides weight data. This strategy not only Table 1 shows the average wage for 4 BMI
provides some observations from relatively long categories (BMI between 0 and 20, between 20 and
comparison periods during which wages and 25, between 25 and 30, and 30 or more) from the
weight have the potential to change substantially sample of the person-year observations used in the
(between, say, the 1981 and 1998 surveys), but it analysis. Results show that wages are increasing
also provides observations that compare wages with BMI until the BMI reaches 30, at which point
over briefer comparison periods to identify more wages fall slightly. The most populous category is
frequent wage and weight changes (between, say, for those with a BMI of 20–25. Wages are highest
the 1996 and 1998 surveys). This strategy produces for men with BMIs between 25 and 30 ($8.46) and
226 620 wage comparisons (123 064 males and lowest for men with BMIs below 20 and equal to
103 556 females), with the average interval between 30 or more.m Women’s wages are highest in the
wage observations being 10.3 years. 20–25 BMI category ($6.82), and those with BMIs
Our third approach is similar, but the fixed of 25 or more have the lowest wages.
effects specification becomes a comparison of wage In Figure 2, we plot the average yearly wage for
observations between siblings. That is, we compare the full sample, an obese sample, and a non-obese
wages between siblings for each survey year that sample. Results indicate that wages generally
provides weight data. This strategy produces
12 369 wage comparisons (3906 male pairs and
2695 female pairs).k The fourth approach com- Body Mass Index by Year
30
bines the second and third approaches by compar-
ing an individual’s wages over time with a sibling’s
wage over the same period. This strategy produces 25
20 470 wage comparisons (6848 male pairs and
Body Mass Index (BMI)

4553 female pairs).l 20


The NLSY surveys that collect information
about weight identify how much each respondent
weighed in pounds in those surveys. In 1981, 15
respondents (between the ages of 16 and 23)
weighed an average of 145 pounds. However, their 10
average weight increases monotonically with each
successive survey, and in 1998, respondents (then 5
Body Mass Index (BMI)
between the ages of 33 and 40) weighed an average BMI (Males)
of 175 pounds. To measure obesity, we calculate BMI (Females)
each individual’s body mass index (BMI), which is 0
defined as weight in kilograms divided by height in
81

82

85

86

87

89

90

92

93

94

96

98
19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

meters squared. For males (females), a BMI of 20–


Year
25 (19–24) is considered normal, a BMI less than
20 (less than 19) is below normal, and a BMI Figure 1. Body mass index by year

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Health Econ. 13: 885–899 (2004)
890 C. L. Baum II and W. F. Ford

Table 1. Average real wage by weight (BMI), from 1981 to 1998


Full sample Males Females
BMI Wage Number Wage Number Wage Number
0–20 6.57 5055 6.28 1056 6.65 3999
20–25 7.37 23 695 7.88 12 228 6.82 11 467
25–30 7.72 14 967 8.46 9404 6.48 5563
30 or more (obese) 6.97 7783 7.99 3923 5.94 3860
There are 51 500 person-year observations. Based on the consumer price index with a 1982–1984 year base.

Obesity Wage Differentials Obesity Wage Differential by Gender


10 12
9

8 10

6 8
Wage

5
Wage

4 6

3
Wage
2 4
Wage for Obese
1 Wage for Nonobese Obese Male Wage
Nonobese Male Wage
0 2
Obese Female Wage
81

82

85

86

87

89

90

92

93

94

96

98

Nonobese Female Wage


19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

Year 0
Figure 2. Obesity wage differentials by year
81
82
85
86
87
89
90
92
93
94
96
98
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
19
Year
increase over time, and the disparity between the Figure 3. Obesity wage differential by gender and year
obese and non-obese wages increases over time as
well. For example, in 1981 and 1982, the obese and
non-obese wages were virtually identical. How- with age, and BMI tends to increase with age as
ever, between 1985 and 1998, the difference in non- well. Thus, there may appear to be a positive
obese and obese wages increased from 34 cents to correlation between BMI and wages when, in fact,
$1.20. A similar pattern is depicted in Figure 3, this correlation is due to age-related changes. To
which shows average yearly wages for obese and determine the causal effect of weight on wages, we
non-obese workers separately by gender. As use multivariate regression analysis to control for
before, the obesity wage differential increases over other factors that might be correlated with weight
time, but the obesity wage penalty is consistently and wages. Each model that we estimate contains a
larger for women than men. In fact, in 1981 and standard set of explanatory variables that have
1982, obese men earn more than non-obese men. frequently been used in wage models.n
By 1998, however, the obesity wage penalty for Table 2 provides each variable’s sample
men is $1.11 and is more than $1.25 for women. mean and standard deviation measured at the
These simple descriptive statistics suggest that time of the survey. First, we include variables to
wages are lower for those who are obese. However, control for standard socio-economic characteris-
these correlations do not necessarily imply a causal tics. These include controls for race (black and
relationship. For example, wages tend to increase Hispanic dummy variables), age, education,

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Health Econ. 13: 885–899 (2004)
The Wage E¡ects of Obesity 891

Table 2. Descriptive statistics of standard variables


Obese Non-obese
Dependant variable
Wage 7.334 (4.765) 6.974 7.398
Log wage 1.849 (0.517) 1.807 1.857

Explanatory variables
Body mass index (BMI=weight/(height2)) 25.362 (5.012) 34.345 23.763
Black (=1 if black) 0.293 (0.455) 0.381 0.277
Hispanic (=1 if Hispanic) 0.175 (0.380) 0.209 0.169
Age (in years) 29.197 (5.198) 31.320 28.819
Education level (years of schooling completed) 12.910 (2.151) 12.626 12.960
Marital status (=1 if married) 0.486 (0.500) 0.515 0.480
Children (=number of children) 0.929 (1.142) 1.196 0.881
Experience (in weeks/52) 8.553 (2.443) 9.703 8.105
South (=1 if lived in south) 0.400 (0.490) 0.440 0.393
Urban (=1 if lived in an urban area) 0.794 (0.404) 0.756 0.801
Local unemployment rate (percent) 0.029 (0.010) 0.028 0.029
Agriculture industry 0.021 (0.143) 0.022 0.021
Mining industry 0.007 (0.082) 0.004 0.007
Construction industry 0.065 (0.247) 0.052 0.068
Manufacturing industry 0.192 (0.394) 0.178 0.195
Transportation/communications industry 0.061 (0.240) 0.059 0.062
Wholesale/retail trade industry 0.195 (0.396) 0.175 0.198
Finance/insurance/real estate industry 0.063 (0.244) 0.047 0.066
Business/repair services industry 0.068 (0.251) 0.065 0.068
Personal services industry 0.034 (0.180) 0.044 0.032
Entertainment/recreational services industry 0.011 (0.105) 0.009 0.011
Professional work industry 0.183 (0.387) 0.208 0.179
Public administration industry 0.055 (0.227) 0.075 0.051
Sample means with standard deviations in parentheses. The sample size contains 51 500 person-year observations, 7783 of which
are obese and 43 717 of which are not.

marital status, and children. We also control for professionals and the non-obese are most likely
human capital accumulation with a variable to work in wholesale and retail trades.
measuring weeks of work experience and for To limit the potential for unobserved hetero-
residence in the south, residence in an urban area, geneity bias, we also include a set of supplemental
and the local unemployment rate. Finally, we regressors that controls more extensively for
include 12 industry dummy variables to control for background characteristics and the worker’s atti-
wages differences across industries [19] and 12-year tudes. Descriptive statistics for the supplemental
dummy variables to control for intertemporal background characteristics variables are presented
differences.o in Table 3. Table 3 also gives separate means for
Table 2 also gives separate means for the obese and non-obese workers.
portion of the full sample that is obese and non-
obese. Obese workers in our sample are more
likely to be married.p These statistics also indicate Results
that obese workers are more likely to be black or
Hispanic, to be older, to have more children and We examine the effects of obesity on wages
work experience, and to live in the south. The separately for males and females first using wage
obese also tend to be less educated and less likely level models. The results from these models are
to live in an urban area. Obese and non-obese presented in Table 4. Then, we re-examine the
workers also differ in their industry of employ- male and female samples using individual differ-
ment: the obese are most likely to work as ence models, sibling difference models, and

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Health Econ. 13: 885–899 (2004)
892 C. L. Baum II and W. F. Ford

Table 3. Descriptive statistics of supplemental background variables


Full Sample Obese Non-obese
Supplemental background variables
AFQT (residual test score controlling for age) 0.037 (27.246) 4.998 0.933
Native born (=1 if born outside the U.S.) 0.049 (0.215) 0.049 0.049
Foreign language (=1 if foreign language was spoken) 0.209 (0.406) 0.237 0.204
Lived with both parents (at age 14) 0.719 (0.450) 0.698 0.722
Received magazines (at age 14) 0.573 (0.495) 0.501 0.585
Received newspaper (at age 14) 0.769 (0.422) 0.716 0.778
Library card (at age 14) 0.709 (0.454) 0.659 0.717
South (at age 14) 0.378 (0.485) 0.425 0.370
Urban (at age 14) 0.782 (0.413) 0.753 0.787
Mother’s education 10.442 (3.700) 9.897 10.539
Mother’s education missing (=1 if missing) 0.051 (0.220) 0.057 0.050
Mother worked part-time (when worker was 14) 0.209 (0.407) 0.214 0.209
Mother worked full-time (when worker was 14) 0.418 (0.493) 0.383 0.425
Father’s education 9.625 (5.089) 8.714 9.787
Father’s education missing (=1 if missing) 0.140 (0.347) 0.173 0.134
Siblings 3.758 (2.576) 3.891 3.735
Rotter test score (higher scores = less efficacy) 8.731 (2.338) 8.947 8.692
Attitudes about family roles (higher scores = traditional views) 17.346 (3.463) 17.446 17.328
Sample means with standard deviations in parentheses. The sample size contains 51 500 person-year observations, 7783 of which
are obese and 43 717 of which are not.

Table 4. The effect of obesity on wages by gender


Individual Sibling Individual
Individual difference difference sibling
models models models difference models
Males
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5
Obese 0.034*** 0.032*** 0.007** 0.008 0.007
(0.007) (0.007) (0.003) (0.017) (0.011)
Standard covariates Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Supplemental covariates No Yes Yes Yes Yes
R2 0.375 0.399 0.105 0.204 0.039

Females
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5
Obese 0.061*** 0.058*** 0.023*** 0.015 0.048***
(0.007) (0.007) (0.004) (0.020) (0.013)
Standard covariates Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Supplemental covariates No Yes Yes Yes Yes
R2 0.397 0.413 0.096 0.262 0.046
Standard errors are in parentheses. ***p50.01; **p50.05; *p50.10. There are 26 611 males in the wage level model, 123 064 in the
individual difference models, 3906 in the sibling difference models, and 6848 in the individual sibling difference models. There are
24 889 females in the wage level model, 103 556 in the individual difference models, 2695 in the sibling difference models, and 4553 in
the individual sibling difference models. Covariates are differences in the fixed effects models.

individual difference-sibling difference models. these models are presented in Table 5 for males
These results are also presented in Table 4. Finally, and in Table 6 for females. The results of any other
we explore potential explanations for the effects of covariates not reported are available from the
obesity by gender. The obesity-related results from authors.

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Health Econ. 13: 885–899 (2004)
Table 5. Potential explanations for the obesity wage penalty (males)
The Wage E¡ects of Obesity

Levels models Individual difference Sibling difference Individual sibling difference


(Model 2) Model 6 (Model 3) Model 7 (Model 4) Model 8 (Model 5) Model 9
Obese 0.032*** 0.032*** 0.007** 0.007** 0.008 0.007 0.007 0.007
(0.007) (0.007) (0.003) (0.003) (0.017) (0.017) (0.011) (0.011)
Health limitations 0.106*** 0.028*** 0.152*** 0.005
(0.014) (0.005) (0.033) (0.018)

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.


Model 10 Model 11 Model 12 Model 13
Obese 0.035** 0.012* 0.010 0.007
(0.017) (0.007) (0.019) (0.011)
Experience 0.0007*** 0.0009*** 0.0005*** 0.00004
(0.00001) (0.00001) (0.00005) (0.00008)
Obesity*experience 0.0001*** 0.00006*** 0.0002** 0.0001
(0.00002) (0.00001) (0.00009) (0.0001)
Model 14 Model 15 Model 16 Model 17
Obese 0.058*** 0.015*** 0.012 0.008
(0.013) (0.003) (0.017) (0.011)
Employer insurance 0.205*** 0.123*** 0.169*** 0.080***
(0.006) (0.002) (0.014) (0.007)
Obesity*employer insurance 0.028* 0.047*** 0.019 0.023
(0.015) (0.006) (0.032) (0.017)
Model 18 Model 19 Model 20 Model 21
Obese 0.028*** 0.006** 0.011 0.007
(0.007) (0.003) (0.017) (0.011)
Customer occupation 0.074*** 0.051*** 0.087*** 0.010
(0.007) (0.003) (0.015) (0.009)
Obesity*occupation 0.018 0.006 0.057* 0.063***
(0.018) (0.008) (0.032) (0.022)
Standard errors are in parentheses. ***p50.01; **p50.05; *p50.10. Number of observations are as in other models.
893

Health Econ. 13: 885–899 (2004)


894

Table 6. Potential explanations for the obesity wage penalty (females)


Levels models Individual difference Sibling difference Individual sibling difference
(Model 2) Model 6 (Model 3) Model 7 (Model 4) Model 8 (Model 5) Model 9
Obese 0.058*** 0.056*** 0.023*** 0.022*** 0.015 0.015 0.048*** 0.049***
(0.007) (0.007) (0.004) (0.003) (0.020) (0.020) (0.0013) (0.013)
Health limitations 0.073*** 0.018*** 0.014 0.014
(0.011) (0.004) (0.035) (0.017)
Model 10 Model 11 Model 12 Model 13

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.


Obese 0.011 0.009 0.021 0.049***
(0.014) (0.007) (0.021) (0.013)
Experience 0.0007*** 0.0008*** 0.0006*** 0.0002***
(0.00001) (0.00001) (0.00005) (0.00007)
Obesity*experience 0.0001*** 0.0001*** 0.0001 0.0004***
(0.00002) (0.00002) (0.00009) (0.0001)
Model 14 Model 15 Model 16 Model 17
Obese 0.026** 0.023*** 0.014 0.046***
(0.011) (0.004) (0.020) (0.013)
Employer insurance 0.201*** 0.115*** 0.218*** 0.063***
(0.006) (0.002) (0.016) (0.009)
Obesity*employer insurance 0.048*** 0.027*** 0.053 0.021
(0.014) (0.007) (0.034) (0.019)
Model 18 Model 19 Model 20 Model 21
Obese 0.063*** 0.023*** 0.016 0.049***
(0.008) (0.004) (0.020) (0.013)
Customer occupation 0.077*** 0.033*** 0.037** 0.018**
(0.006) (0.002) (0.018) (0.009)
Obesity*occupation 0.017 0.0006 0.005 0.002
(0.015) (0.008) (0.034) (0.021)
Standard errors are in parentheses. ***p50.01; **p50.05; *p50.10. Number of observations are as in other models.

Health Econ. 13: 885–899 (2004)


C. L. Baum II and W. F. Ford
The Wage E¡ects of Obesity 895

To determine the causal effect of obesity on nificantly decreases wages by 4.8 percent in model
wages, we estimate a model including the standard 5, which again suggests there is an obesity wage
covariates that are typically included in wage penalty.
models. Model 1’s results show that wages are It is not clear from these results why models for
significantly lower (at the 1 percent level) for those males that use siblings (models 4 and 5) differ from
with BMIs of 30 or more. In particular, wages for models that do not (models 2 and 3). Perhaps
obese males are 3.4 percent lower than for non- differences occur due to family-specific unobserved
obese males, and this penalty for obese females is heterogeneity bias that is eliminated in the sibling
6.1 percent.q Consequently, these results provide models. Another potential explanation why results
evidence that obese workers receive a wage penalty differ when controlling for family-specific unob-
with this penalty being almost twice as large for served heterogeneity is that the subsample of
females. siblings is unrepresentative. However, comparing
Because the log wage models potentially suffer sample means from the full sample with those
from bias due to unobserved heterogeneity, we from the sibling subsample (results not shown)
next re-estimate model 1 (as model 2) including the does not indicate any notable differences. Another
supplemental set of background variables outlined potential explanation is that the sibling models in
above to further control for individual differences. fact produce similar coefficients that are simply
The results are similar to those reported: BMIs of estimated imprecisely because siblings constitute a
30 or more continue to decrease wages signifi- reduced sample. Note that the sibling coefficient
cantly in model 2. Further, the magnitudes of these estimates (models 4 and 5) for males are negative
effects are left much the same. For example, and are of about the same magnitude as in
obesity lowers male wages by 3.2 percent and individual difference model 3. These models differ
female wages by 5.8 percent. Since adding an not in their coefficients but in the size of their
extensive list of supplemental variables does not standard errors. The standard errors might be
substantively change the results, this provides larger in the sibling models because they use
support that our estimates are not biased. samples that are substantially smaller than the
As noted before, however, the log wage models samples used in the levels models and individual
may still suffer from unobserved heterogeneity difference models.
bias. To control for intertemporally fixed sources We also re-estimate the models by gender using
of heterogeneity bias, we next estimate fixed effects various alternative specifications of obesity (results
models that examine individual changes over time. not shown). For example, in one specification, we
In model 3, the obesity variable equals 1 if the include a continuous measure of BMI instead of
respondent becomes obese, 1 if the respondent is the obesity dummy variable. However, the results
no longer obese, and 0 if there is no change in are generally statistically insignificant. We later
obesity. Model 3 provides further evidence that found this to be due to a non-linear effect of BMI
obesity lowers wages: becoming obese significantly on wages. When we re-estimate the models
lowers wages for males and females. However, separately identifying different categories of BMIs
these penalties are again larger for females, (BMI between 0 and 20, between 20 and 25,
reducing their wages by 2.3 percent compared to between 25 and 30, and 30 or more), those with
0.7 percent for males. BMIs between 0 and 20 and those with BMIs of 30
In model 4, we control for potential unobserved or more both experience a wage penalty, with
heterogeneity bias by estimating sibling difference wages being highest for those with average (or
models. The sibling difference models examine somewhat above average) BMIs. We also estimate
obesity and wage differences between siblings. models identifying the effects of merely being
Sibling differences in obesity do not have statisti- overweight on wages (results not shown). Results
cally significant effects. In model 5, we examine indicate that being overweight but not obese has
individual-specific obesity and wage differences no significant effects on male wages. However, our
over time and compare these differences with a models that separately examine females find that
sibling in ‘individual difference-sibling difference’ being overweight significantly decreases their
models. The individual difference-sibling difference wages.
results are similar to the sibling difference model Next, we look at four possible explanations for
(model 4) for males, both being statistically why obese workers might receive lower wages: (i)
insignificant. However, for females, obesity sig- obese workers are less productive due to health

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Health Econ. 13: 885–899 (2004)
896 C. L. Baum II and W. F. Ford

limitations, (ii) obese workers are more economic- and less likely to engage in training, then this
ally myopic and consequently less likely to invest interaction term will be negative, indicating a
in training, (iii) employers who provide health flatter earnings profile [10]. Models 10–13 examine
insurance are unwilling to pay as much to obese this hypothesis. These models generally show that
workers because their health care may be more experience has a positive and statistically signifi-
expensive, and (iv) customers may discriminate cant effect on wages as expected. Further, in
against obese workers. We estimate models to test models 10–12 for males and models 10 and 11
each of these possible explanations, and the results for females, the obesity–experience interaction
from these models are presented in Table 5 for term is negative and statistically significant. In
males and Table 6 for females. For comparison some cases, the obesity dummy variable is not
purposes, we re-report the obesity results from statistically significant (models 12 and 13 for males
wage level model 2, individual difference model 3, and models 10–12 for females) and in other cases,
sibling difference model 4, and individual sibling the obesity variable actually is significant and
difference model 5 in Tables 5 and 6. These positive (models 10 and 11 for males). This
estimates reappear with their original model suggests that obesity wage penalties essentially
numbers. disappear when controlling for different rates of
Our first hypothesis is that obese workers earn return on experience, and it certainly provides
lower wages because they are less productive. One evidence that obese workers have flatter earnings
reason why obese workers might be less productive profiles. One likely explanation for this is that
is that they are more likely to have health obese workers invest less in training. This would
problems that limit their work. To test the validity explain why obese workers with no experience do
of this hypothesis, we include a ‘health limitations’ not suffer a wage penalty (relative to non-obese
dummy variable that equals 1 if the respondent workers with no experience) but obese workers
reports that they have any health problems limit- with a substantial amount of experience earn
ing the kind or amount of work they can do. If the significantly less than their non-obese and equally
obesity wage penalty is due to health limitations, experienced counterparts. However, another ex-
then the obesity coefficient will become statistically planation is discrimination in training opportu-
insignificant when we control for health limitations nities. The negative obesity-experience interaction
[10]. However, coefficient results from models 6–9 term may reflect that those who are obese do not
are virtually unchanged for both males and have an equal opportunity to train due to
females. While health limitations significantly prejudice. This result also suggests that obesity
reduce wages for males in models 6–8 and females wage penalties may differ with age. To test this, we
in models 6 and 7, obesity wage penalties remain re-estimate the models interacting obesity with age
the same, indicating that obesity affects wages instead of experience (results not shown). The
independently of health limitations. Alternatively, results are essentially the same, with older obese
it is possible that health limitations among obese workers receiving a larger wage penalty. Perhaps
workers affect employment (their ability to work) age is substantively measuring experience. Con-
rather than wages. versely, this may be due to a change in the impact
Second, we suspect that obese workers may of obesity with age.
suffer wage penalties because they are more Third, we hypothesize that employers who
economically myopic. That is, they are less provide health insurance penalize obese workers
concerned about the future, placing a higher in the form of lower wages because they fear it will
premium on present consumption. If respondents be more costly to provide such workers with health
who are more myopic are also more likely to be care. To test this hypothesis, we create a dummy
obese (less likely to be concerned about the variable that equals 1 if the respondent works for
possible long-term health effects of obesity) and an employer who provides health insurance. Then,
less likely to engage in training (less likely to invest we estimate models that include both the employ-
in human capital), then obese workers will have a er-provided insurance variable and its interaction
flatter earnings profile.r This occurs because those with the obesity variable. If there is veracity to this
who invest less in training have less future earnings hypothesis, then the ‘obesity – employer insurance’
potential. To test this, we estimate a model that interaction term will be negative and significant,
interacts the obesity variable with the experience indicating that obese respondents who work for
variable. If obese respondents are more myopic employers providing health insurance are pena-

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Health Econ. 13: 885–899 (2004)
The Wage E¡ects of Obesity 897

lized to a greater extent than obese respondents penalties are equivalent across occupations, then
who are responsible for providing their own health this interaction term will have an insignificant
insurance [10]. That is, obesity wage penalties will effect. Models 18–20 indicate that workers in
be concentrated among workers with employer- customer-oriented occupations do earn less but
provided health insurance. Models 14–17 show do not experience a larger obesity wage penalty.
that wages are higher for both males and females (The one exception is sibling difference model 20
with employer-provided health insurance. Though for males, where obese males in customer-oriented
economic theory suggests that wages are decreas- occupations do earn significantly less.) That is,
ing in fringe benefits, it is difficult in practice to only one of the obesity–occupation interaction
estimate this holding all else constant. For example, terms is significantly negative. This suggests that
fringe benefits may at least partially proxy for obesity wage penalties are the same across
worker value where valuable workers receive occupations. Of course, this may be the result of
enhanced fringe benefits (and higher wages). If us imperfectly identifying those occupations where
so, and if a worker’s value is not completely interpersonal interactions with customers are
controlled, then wages and fringe benefits may important.
appear to be positively related. The obesity –
employer-provided health insurance interaction
term is negative in the wage level model (model
14) for females, but it is positive and statistically Discussion and conclusions
significant in the wage level model for males and
the individual difference models for males and Where statistically significant, our results suggest
females (model 15). The latter two models suggest that obese workers suffer a wage penalty in the
the opposite of what we predict: they suggest that range of 0.7–6.3 percent. This result is robust in
obese respondents with employer-provided health the wage level models regardless of what combina-
insurance receive less of a wage penalty than tion of explanatory variables are included, as well
obese workers without such fringe benefits. This is as in the individual difference models. However,
a surprising result, but perhaps it indicates that the sibling difference and individual sibling differ-
the type of employer who provides such fringe ence models do not consistently provide significant
benefits is less likely to discriminate against obese evidence of an obesity wage penalty. The results in
workers. Another explanation is that our test does the wage level and individual difference models
not measure what we intend. Regardless, our may be different than those in the sibling models
models as specified provide little support for this because they inadequately control for family-
hypothesis. specific sources of unobserved heterogeneity. Or,
Our final hypothesis is that obese workers as noted before, differences may be due to the
may earn less because they are discriminated sibling sample being unrepresentative of the full
against by customers. That is, customers may sample (though descriptive statistics do not
prefer not to interact with obese individuals. If so, indicate any notable differences in sample char-
then obese workers may suffer a greater wage acteristics) or to the reduced sibling sample size
penalty in customer-oriented service and sales (where the standard errors for the sibling models
occupations. However, obese workers who are are estimated less precisely though their coefficients
not in contact with customers will not suffer such a are of about the same magnitude as those from
wage penalty. Conversely, if obesity wage penalties other models).
are due to employer discrimination, then such Our results also provide evidence that obese
wage penalties will be the same across occupa- females suffer more of a wage penalty than obese
tions. To test this, we identify each worker’s males. Negative obesity coefficients in the female
occupation and classify each as a customer-related wage models are always larger in absolute value
occupation or not.s Then, we interact the customer and are more likely to be statistically significant.
occupation variable with the obesity variable. If For example, in wage level model 2, the male
the obesity wage penalty is due to customer obesity wage penalty is 3.2 percent while the
discrimination, then the obesity wage penalty will female obesity wage penalty is 5.8 percent; in
be larger in occupations that deal with consumers. individual difference model 3, the male obesity
That is, the obesity – customer occupation wage penalty is 0.7 percent while the female
interaction term will be negative. If obesity wage obesity wage penalty is 2.3 percent.

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Health Econ. 13: 885–899 (2004)
898 C. L. Baum II and W. F. Ford

We also have examined some possible channels d. Averett and Korenman [5] do examine the hypoth-
through which obesity affects wages. The wage esis that obesity affects wages through health
level and individual difference models (and the limitations. They also include occupational dummy
sibling difference models for males) indicate that variables to control for occupational sergregation.
However, it is not clear whether obsesity wage
obese workers have flatter earnings profiles. We
penalities differ across occupations because Averett
suspect that this may be due to myopia, where and Korenman do not interact these variables with
those who are less far-sighted are also more likely obesity.
to be obese and less likely to engage in training. e. Our empirical approach, which uses fixed effects
However, discrimination in training opportunities models, is similar to that used by Levine et al. [10]
and obesity wage penalties that vary with age who examine wage penalties for cigarette smokers.
are also potential explanations. Our results pro- Conversely, our approach differs from that of
vide virtually no evidence that obesity affects Kaestner [11], Register and Williams [12], Gill and
wages via health limitations or customer discrimi- Michaels [13], and Berger and Leigh [14] who use a
nation. Further, our evidence actually hints that method proposed by Oaxaca [15] and used by many
others (for example, Blau and Ferber [16]).
obese workers with employer-provided health Following Oaxaca [15], Kaestner [11], Gill and
insurance receive less of a wage penalty than their Michaels [13], and Register and Williams [12]
obese counterparts without such fringe benefits. examine the effect of drug use on wages and Berger
Of course, tests of these explanations are only and Leigh [14] examine the effect of alcohol on
effective to the extent that they adequately evaluate wages, using predicted values of potentially en-
the hypotheses for which they are intended. dogenous variables. We choose to follow Levine
hese tests are crude, and they may not identify et al., rather than Oaxaca, because the latter’s
the effects that we intend. For example, our method would require us to find variables that
tests do not completely control for a worker’s affect obesity but are orthogonal to wages. It is not
productivity, and obesity may affect wages via clear what identification variables would be
sufficiently powerful to predict obesity, which is
reduced productivity in ways other than health why Levine et al. choose to use fixed effects
limitations. models.
Additionally, we offer no tests for employer f. The fixed effects estimators are instrumental vari-
discrimination. Residual wage differences are often able estimators as well – it is the assumed
attributed to employer discrimination, and we exogeneity of the differences that lead to the fixed
certainly find that obesity wage penalties do not effects estimators being unbiased and consistent
differ across occupations. Thus, our findings suggest g. Those who explicitly control for sample selection
that such discrimination may be present in our bias typically find that the estimates are left
unexplained residual after controlling for other virtually unchanged [6,11].
plausible explanatory variables. Further research is h. All wages (and other dollar measures) from the
NLSY are adjusted appropriately using the Con-
needed to search for evidence of systematic sumer Price Index from the US Census Bureau with
discrimination against obese workers. An expand- a 1982–1984 base.
ing catalog of lawsuits alleging that it exists adds i. See the Center for Human Resource Research’s
further urgency to pursuing that line of inquiry. NSLY79 1996 Users’ Guide [17] for more details on
the NLSY sample.
j. This is done using the ‘cluster’ command in
STATA. This command relaxes the assumption of
Notes error independence between observations from the
same person, instead defining an error structure
a. Overweight for males is defined as having a Body where only errors between observations with
Mass Index (BMI) of 25–30 (24–30 for females) and different person ids are independent.
obese is defined as having a BMI of 30 or more, k. The other 5768 pairs contain a male and female (a
where BMI is calculated as weight in kilograms brother and sister).
divided by height in meters squared. l. The other 9069 pairs contain a male and female (a
b. See also Philipson [2]. brother and sister).
c. Harper [6] examines the obesity wage penalty with m. Actually, wages are lowest for men with BMIs
British data, finding that obesity only lowers the between 0 and 20 ($6.28).
wages of women. However, Harper’s results are n. Note that time-invariant variables are not included
difficult to interpret because they simultaneously in the individual fixed effects model because no such
hold physical appearance constant. change occurs between wage observations; for

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Health Econ. 13: 885–899 (2004)
The Wage E¡ects of Obesity 899

similar reasons, family-constant variables are not overweight in adolescence and young adulthood.
included in the sibling fixed effects models. New Engl J Med 1993; 329: 1008–1012.
o. The industries identified by the dummy variables 5. Averett S, Korenman S. The economic reality of the
include: agriculture; mining; construction; manu- beauty myth. J Hum Res 1996; 31: 304–330.
facturing; transportation and communication; 6. Harper B. Beauty, stature, and the labour market.
wholesale and retail trade; finance, insurance, and Oxford Bull Econ Statist 2000; 62: 771–800.
real estate; business and repair services; personal 7. Register CA, Williams DR. Wage effects of
services; entertainment and recreational services; obesity among young workers. Soc Sci Q 1990; 71:
professional work; and public administration. The 130–141.
year dummy variables correspond to the 12 NLSY 8. Loh ES. The economic effects of physical appear-
surveys with weight information. ance. Soc Sci Q 1993; 74: 420–438.
p. Register and Williams [12] and Harper [6] also 9. Pagan JA, Davila A. Obesity, occupational attain-
report higher rates of obesity among those who are ment, and earnings. Soc Sci Q 1997; 78: 756–770.
married. Conversely, Gortmaker et al. [4] finds that 10. Levine PB, Gustafson TA, Velenchik AD. More bad
those who are overweight (in the 95th BMI news for smokers? The effects of cigarette smoking
percentile) are less likely to be married. on wages. Ind Lab Relat Rev 1997; 50: 493–509.
q. Since log wages are the dependent variable, percent 11. Kaestner R. The effect of illicit drug use on the
changes can be obtained from eb1. wages of young adults. J Lab Econ 1991; 9: 381–412.
r. Similarly, Becker and Murphy [20] argue that those 12. Register CA, Williams DR. Labor market effects of
with higher rates of time preference are more likely marijuana and cocaine use among young men. Ind
to engage in illegal drug use and to have flatter Lab Relat Rev 1992; 45: 435–448.
earnings profiles. 13. Gill AM, Michaels RJ. Does drug use lower wages?
s. We admit that selecting those occupations where Ind Lab Relat Rev 1992; 45: 419–434.
customer preferences affect productivity is subjec- 14. Berger MC, Leigh JP. The effect of alcohol use on
tive. Unfortunately, the NLSY does not ask wages. Appl Econ 1988; 20: 1343–1351.
respondents the extent to which their job involves 15. Oaxaca R. Male-female wage differentials in urban
interpersonal interactions with customers. markets. Int Econ Rev 1973; 14: 694–709.
16. Blau FD, Ferber M. Discrimination: empirical
evidence from the United States. Am Econ Rev
1987; 77: 316–320.
References 17. Center for Human Resource Research. NSLY79
1996 Users’ Guide. The Ohio State University:
1. Rundle RA. Obesity tops smoking for medical costs. Columbus, OH, 1996.
Wall Street J 2003; March 12: B7. 18. Metropolitan Life Insurance Company of New
2. Philipson T. The world-wide growth in obesity: an York. The Statistical Bulletin of the Metropolitan
economic research agenda. Health Econ 2001; 10: 1–7. Life Insurance Company 1983; 64: 2–9.
3. Sturm R. The effects of obesity, smoking, and 19. England P. The failure of human capital theory to
drinking on medical problems and costs. Health explain occupational sex segregation. J Hum Res
Affairs 2002; 21: 245–253. 1982; 17: 358–370.
4. Gortmaker SL, Must A, Perrin JM, Sobol AM, 20. Becker G, Murphy K. A theory of rational
Dietz WH. Social and economic consequences of addiction. J Polit Econ 1988; 96: 675–700.

Copyright # 2004 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Health Econ. 13: 885–899 (2004)

You might also like