You are on page 1of 16

Ecological Economics 45 (2003) 133 /148

www.elsevier.com/locate/ecolecon

ANALYSIS

Determinants of CO2 emissions in a small open economy


Birgit Friedl, Michael Getzner *
Department of Economics, University of Klagenfurt, Universitaetsstrasse 65-67, A-9020 Klagenfurt, Austria

Received 17 June 2002; received in revised form 18 December 2002; accepted 6 January 2003

Abstract

The aim of the paper is to explore the relationship between economic development and carbon dioxide (CO2)
emissions for a small open and industrialized country, Austria. We test whether an Environmental Kuznets Curve
relationship also holds for a single country rather than concentrating on panel or cross-section data for a set of
countries. A cubic (i.e. N-shaped) relationship between GDP and CO2 emissions is found to fit the data most
appropriately for the period 1960 /1999, and a structural break is identified in the mid-seventies due to the oil price
shock. Furthermore, two variables are additionally significant: import shares reflecting the well-known pollution haven
hypothesis, and the share of the tertiary (service) sector of total production (GDP) accounting for structural changes in
the economy. Emission projections derived from this single country specification support the widely held opinion that
significant policy changes are asked for when implementing the Kyoto Protocol in order to bring about a downturn in
future carbon emissions.
# 2003 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.

Keywords: CO2 emissions and economic growth; Environmental Kuznets curve; Stationarity; Cointegration

JEL classification: Q2; O1; C2

1. Introduction for a variety of pollutants, such as nitrogen oxide,


sulfur dioxide, suspended particulate matter, car-
The Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC here- bon monoxide, lead, and for deforestation, biolo-
after) summarizes what has meanwhile become gical oxygen demand and others1. While the EKC
well known as the inverted U-shaped relationship hypothesis has been confirmed */albeit far from
between emissions (environmental pressure) and unanimously */for a set of air pollutants, water,
GDP per capita. The inverse relationship between and land use, the empirical evidence is very
pollution and per capita income has been explored inconclusive in the case of greenhouse gas
(GHG) emissions, in particular CO2 emissions.

* Corresponding author. Tel.: /43-463-2700-4124; fax: /


1
43-463-2700-4191. For critical surveys, see, for instance, Stern et al. (1996),
E-mail address: michael.getzner@uni-klu.ac.at (M. Getzner). Ekins (1997), and Panayotou (2000).

0921-8009/03/$ - see front matter # 2003 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/S0921-8009(03)00008-9
134 B. Friedl, M. Getzner / Ecological Economics 45 (2003) 133 /148

Due to the release of enormous amounts of CO2 in mental recovery (see, for example, Stern et al.,
the combustion of fossil energy, CO2 emissions are 1996). The fact that nations which formerly had or
classified as one of the main driving forces behind currently have low per capita income are experi-
global warming today. Worldwide, greenhouse gas encing increasing pollution while industrialized
emissions are increasing despite common efforts to countries are successful in abating emissions does
implement internationally binding agreements not imply that economic development will solve
such as the Kyoto Protocol, and a turning point environmental problems quasi automatically.
in the positive relationship between CO2 emissions Rather, the EKC might be considered as a
and per capita income has not yet been identified, descriptive statistic on a par with literacy rates or
at least not on a global scale. The question arises health indicators relative to per capita income. The
as to whether the delinking of carbon emissions more promising approach, therefore, seems to be
and income is possible at high levels of income. an investigation of the time-series data of a single
This is the main motivation for testing the EKC country which may be able to account for historic
hypothesis for the case of CO2 emissions in a single experience such as environmental policy, develop-
open and industrialized country. ment of trade relations, and exogenous shocks
From a theoretical point of view, the inverted-U such as the oil crisis (Stern et al., 1996).
relationship is less likely for CO2 emissions than The vast majority of investigations regarding the
for ‘traditional’ air pollutants such as NOx or SO2. existence of an EKC concentrate on cross-section
While these air pollutants have local effects, CO2 and panel data. To the authors’ knowledge, EKC
emissions cause problems on a global scale, and studies for single countries most often address
the social costs of global warming accrue both developing countries (e.g. Patel et al., 1995;
across time and nations. Therefore, free-rider Vincent, 1997). Rare exceptions addressing indus-
behavior might lead to a close relationship be- trialized countries include De Bruyn et al. (1998)
tween carbon emissions and income at all levels of and Moomaw and Unruh (1997). Thus, the
per capita income (Arrow et al., 1995). In line with current study contributes to the discussion on the
this argument, a linear relationship for CO2 implementation of the Kyoto Protocol since the
emissions and GDP per capita was confirmed in EKC relationship found for CO2 could serve as a
early studies (Shafik and Bandyopadhyay, 1992; counterfactual scenario reflecting current develop-
Shafik, 1994). A delinking of growth in carbon ments of emissions in industrialized countries.
emissions from economic growth does, however, As far as Austria is concerned, Schandl et al.
seem possible, if either carbon emissions fall as a (1999, 2000) present an in-depth case study of
by-product of other abatement activities (Holtz- Austrian materials flows. Other time-series inves-
Eakin and Selden, 1995) or institutions such as tigations focusing particularly on Austrian CO2
environmental regulations are improved with in- emissions in comparison to other countries have
creasing per capita income. Thus, an inverted U- been carried out by Dijkgraaf and Vollebergh
shaped function has also been identified (De (1998), Liski and Toppinen (2001) and Panayotou
Bruyn et al., 1998; Heil and Selden, 2001; Holtz- et al. (2000).
Eakin and Selden, 1995; Moomaw and Unruh, The paper is structured as follows. Section 2
1997), followed by N-shaped (cubic) specifications reviews previous efforts to test the EKC for carbon
(e.g. Galeotti and Lanza, 1999). Neither the linear emissions in more detail. Different functional
nor the cubic relationship allows for an optimistic specifications are introduced and their economic
interpretation of economic growth as being bene- implications are explained. Section 3 deals with the
ficial for the environment. Rather, at high levels of Austrian database and a description of the time
income, CO2 emissions are found to increase with path of CO2 emissions, including environmental
income. policy efforts to reduce CO2 emissions. In addi-
One of the major qualifications regarding the tion, the empirical EKC model is described,
existence of an EKC for all types of pollution is stationarity and cointegration tests are reported,
that economic growth is not sufficient for environ- and structural breaks within the time series are
B. Friedl, M. Getzner / Ecological Economics 45 (2003) 133 /148 135

dealt with. The paper closes with a discussion of the former, namely the hypothesis that polluting
the results and conclusions for environmental and industries are displaced to developing countries
economic policy. (sometimes referred to as the ‘pollution haven’
hypothesis), have been presented by Hettige et al.
(1992), Jänicke et al. (1997), Suri and Chapman
2. Lessons from the past (1998) and Cole (2000).
Both critical aspects are dealt with in the present
study for Austria. The data set for CO2 emissions
2.1. The relevant set of data is available from 1960 onwards on an annual basis
and was provided by the Austrian Central Me-
Two of the main points of criticism of the EKC teorology and Geodynamics Institute.3 Three
hypothesis are, first, that the inverted U-shape is additional variables (besides economic growth)
merely a statistical result (a juxtaposition) and not are identified which can be hypothesized to be
a common development path holding for the relevant for a small open economy: (i) the oil price
subsets of industrialized or developing countries shock followed by improvements in energy effi-
since it is derived from cross-section data (see, for ciency and stricter environmental regulations, (ii)
example, Roberts and Grimes, 1997), and second, the structural change in the Austrian economy
that by abstracting from other causalities besides from a strong emphasis on industrial and agrarian
income and emissions the EKC hypothesis does production in the 1950s to an economy dominated
not account properly for crucial historic develop- by the service sector accounting for more than 60%
ments and unique events such as the oil crisis in the of GDP at present, and (iii) the worldwide increase
mid-seventies (e.g. Panayotou, 1997). Therefore, in trade and international policies which have led
investigations of the EKC relationship for one to a specialization in more eco-friendly production
single country could shed some light on the in Austria on the one hand and have raised the
validity of the claim that economic development pressure on environmental policy (EU legislation,
might improve environmental quality.2 Contribu- Kyoto Protocol) on the other.
tions to the existence of EKC relations in time-
series data can be found in De Bruyn et al. (1998) 2.2. The relevant indicator for CO2 emissions
for the Netherlands, the United Kingdom and
Western Germany, in Roberts and Grimes (1997) Before considering different functional forms to
for three groups of countries differing in their explain the environment /income relationship, we
income, and in Moomaw and Unruh (1997) for all make some comments on the correct dependent
countries having experienced a negative relation- variable. Four types of indicators are commonly
ship between emissions and income per capita. employed for different pollutants or sorts of
With respect to the second criticism that im- environmental degradation: (i) emissions per ca-
portant variables are omitted, valuable contribu- pita, (ii) emissions per gross domestic output
tions have been made by Panayotou (1997) and De (pollution intensity) or gross product, (iii) ambient
Bruyn et al. (1998). For Austria, as a small open levels of pollution (concentrations; impacts on a
economy, it follows that the influence of develop- certain area), and (iv) total emissions. In cross-
ments abroad might be of crucial importance, both country studies by far the most frequently used
regarding the possibility of ‘exporting’ emissions, indicator for CO2 is emissions per capita (see Heil
and the influence of foreign and international
environmental policy. Empirical indications of
3
Previous studies by Panayotou et al. (2000) and Liski and
Toppinen (2001) use the data set for the period 1870-current for
2
It is worth noting that per capita income should be 17 OECD countries provided by Marland et al. (1996) of the
interpreted as a proxy for other less easily measurable variables Carbon Dioxide Information Center (CDIAC) in which a
such as economic development, institutions, and environmental correction for the enormous territorial and economic
awareness. adjustments after WWI is missing.
136 B. Friedl, M. Getzner / Ecological Economics 45 (2003) 133 /148

and Selden, 2001; Holtz-Eakin and Selden, 1995; quadratic case, if b1 /0, b2 B/0, and b3 /0,
Liski and Toppinen, 2001; Moomaw and Unruh, emissions exhibit an inverted-U relationship to
1997; Panayotou et al., 2000). per capita income.5 In the cubic case, if b1 /0,
The indicator chosen in the current paper is the b2 B/0, and b3 /0, an N-shaped relationship
annual level of total CO2 emissions, mainly for the between emissions and income can result6. If the
following reasons. First, Kyoto reduction targets coefficients are reversed in their sign (b1 B/0, b2 /
relate to percentage decreases in annual GHG 0, and b3 B/0), a sideways-mirrored S graph can be
emission levels (and not decreases in per capita identified. The functional forms are specified as
emissions or emissions per unit of output). As has logarithms in some studies as well, e.g. Cole et al.
been shown in various studies (e.g. Tisdell, 2001), (1997), Galeotti and Lanza (1999) and Holtz-
total emissions can still increase even when emis- Eakin and Selden (1995).
sions per unit of output decrease. More precisely, The linear relationship between GDP and CO2
the scale effect of economic growth outweighs the emissions was confirmed by Shafik and Bandyo-
composition effect (structural change of the econ- padhyay (1992) and Shafik (1994) in panel studies,
omy) and the technological effect due to higher and by De Bruyn et al. (1998) for four single
productive efficiency (cf. Panayotou, 2000). Sec- countries. The inverted-U pattern was laid out by
ond, for a single country with roughly constant Holtz-Eakin and Selden (1995) in a panel investi-
population across the previous decades (annual gation albeit basically on explanatory grounds
population growth rates of less than one percent), rather than econometric results (for a discussion
dividing total emissions by population merely see Ekins 1997, 811). The inverted-U hypothesis
results in scaling down the numbers.4 Third, since was also confirmed by Heil and Selden (2001) and
one of the main contributors to CO2 emissions is Galeotti and Lanza (1999) for worldwide panel
(freight and private) transport, emissions should data (IEA database). So far, no country-specific
not be related to industrial output. Fourth, con- study has confirmed the existence of an inverted-U
centration levels are suitable for local pollutants relationship. The only indication along these lines
(see, for example, Borghesi, 1999) but not for is the structural change model employed by
global pollutants, which cannot be described in Moomaw and Unruh (1997) who find an in-
local impact levels. verted-V shape with discontinuous rather than
gradual change. Their key result is that the cubic
functional form is caused by data aggregation
2.3. Possible functional forms of EKCs for CO2 across countries. De Bruyn et al. (1998), however,
show theoretically that cross-section inverted-U
As mentioned in Section 1, three specifications relationships for different points in time corre-
for EKCs for CO2 have been described in the spond to single country N-shaped curves if poli-
literature: a linear, a quadratic (inverted U) and a tical adjustments are taken into account.
cubic specification (N-shaped or sideways-mir- A review of these studies does not conclusively
rored S-shaped). One general functional form for reveal which relationship we should expect for the
the level of CO2 emissions, abstracting from other emission /income relationship in a single country.
explanatory variables (e.g. time and country As the evidence is rather diverse for panel data and
specific effects), is: the studies on single countries are rather rare,
CO2t  b0 b1 Yt b2 Yt2 b3 Yt3 (1) additional research is called for.
In the linear case, b1 /0 and b2 /b3 /0. In the
5
For an inverted U to result, the second coefficient has to be
smaller than the first in absolute terms (½b2 ½B/½b1 ½). See Ekins,
4
Modeling the dependent variable in CO2 per capita instead 1997, 807 f.
6
of total CO2 emissions (in million mt) did not lead to any As Ekins (1997) correctly points out, the N shape is
significant changes in the results obtained in the econometric dependent on the relative size of the coefficients. Only if ½b3 ½ B/
estimations (see section Section 3.4). ½b2 ½ B/½b1 ½ does this pattern result.
B. Friedl, M. Getzner / Ecological Economics 45 (2003) 133 /148 137

2.4. Explanatory variables other than income 


3. Estimating a CO2 /EKC for Austria7

In the present study, two further independent


3.1. CO2 emissions and Austria’s commitments to
variables are tested for their significance. The first reducing CO2 emissions
is trade (to test for the pollution haven hypothesis)
and the second is structural change to take the Initial insight into the development of CO2
composition effect into account (see Section 3.2 emissions in Austria can be gained by describing
for an operationalization of both potentially the time series of CO2 emissions for the period
explanatory variables). 1960/1999. Fig. 1 shows CO2 emissions in Aus-
For an industrialized country, exports are likely tria. The starting point for the official statistics for
to be serially correlated with GDP, i.e. if exports CO2 is the year 1960, when CO2 emissions
increase, total emissions will fall only if increased amounted to around 34 million metric tons (mt).
efficiency outweighs the scale effect. On the other Until the early 1970s, CO2 emissions grew rapidly
hand, imports should lead to a reduction in to over 61 million mt in 1973. The oil price shock
emissions if the pollution haven hypothesis holds. did not fail to leave its mark on CO2 emissions.
For the case of a small open economy such Economic growth slowed down, and due to
as Austria, the impact of trade on emissions changes in energy policies, such as rationalizing
should be comparatively greater than for a larger private consumption of fuels by restricting private
economy. Previous results obtained in cross-coun- car use, CO2 emissions dropped to about 57
try studies (e.g. Arrow et al., 1995; Cole et al., 1997 million mt in 1975. Between 1973 and 1975 there
for a discussion see Cavlovic et al., 2000) are is a structural break in CO2 emissions (regarding
mixed. the slope of the time path), as general awareness of
In previous studies, a country’s openness was the growing scarcity of energy resources increased
approximated by different trade measures, such dramatically. (A Chow breakpoint test in a simple
as the ratio of imports (exports) of manufactured autoregressive trend model to test for stationarity
goods to domestic manufactured production, indicated a clear structural break in the year 1974
the sum of imports and exports relative to GDP with a log likelihood ratio of 19.0858 with P B/
(Harbaugh et al., 2000), or export volumes per 0.001; see also Section 3.3.)
capita (Panayotou et al., 2000). In the present Subsequently, CO2 emissions increased slightly
case, the ratio of imports to GDP will be used as until 1981 and then fell during the recession in the
an explanatory variable for the reasons given early 1980s. A rather constant rise in CO2 emis-
above. sions followed, and at the end of the 1980s, the
When testing for structural change, it turned out next peak was reached with CO2 emissions
to be difficult to come up with convincing amounting to around 66 million mt. The recession
statistics. Structural change can be the result of in 1992 and 1993 again reduced CO2 emissions.
changes in the political system (which is appar- Most recently, from 1994 onwards, there has been
ently not the case for Austria in the period covered constant but slow growth currently amounting to
by the current study), the degree of (environmen- around 65 million mt (see also Fig. 2 which
tal) legislation, or increases in energy prices etc. presents a scatter plot of CO2 emissions and
Again, as Austria is a small open economy, the Austrian per capita GDP in constant 1995 prices).
While absolute figures for CO2 emissions are
influence of international markets is not negligible.
important for assessing their implications for the
Over the last 50 years, the service sector has
world’s climate and ecosystems, a comparison with
expanded and the industrial, agricultural and
the growth in GDP is important when considering
resource sectors have been observed to shrink.
Therefore, we test for the influence of the increase
in the service share (value added in the service 7
All data and statistical and econometric results are
sector relative to GDP) on CO2 emissions. available in detail from the authors on request.
138 B. Friedl, M. Getzner / Ecological Economics 45 (2003) 133 /148

Fig. 1. CO2 emissions in Austria 1960 /1999.

the EKC relationship. In this respect, Fig. 3 followed by a short-term reduction after the
presents three indices (base year 1960 /100): recession in 1993, and subsequently by constant
GDP, total CO2 emissions, and CO2 intensity. growth in CO2 emissions.
While real GDP more than tripled by 1999, total As will be argued later, the time series up to the
CO2 emissions doubled in this period. The index of present and the structural models estimating an
‘CO2-intensity of GDP’, expressed as CO2 emis- EKC for CO2 emissions in Austria give no
sions in kilograms per unit of GDP (in Euro 1000), indication that there is any mean-reverting ten-
followed a constant time path until the mid-1970s, dency in the data. Between 1990 and 1999,
and decreased from an index of around 100 to Austrian CO2 emissions grew from 62 to 66
about 55 index points afterwards. However, there million mt. Thus, according to the Kyoto Proto-
was a rather constant decrease between the 1970s col, Austria has to reduce its emissions to around
and the beginning of the 1990s followed by a 53 million mt, corresponding to a reduction of
leveling off in the 1990s. Consequently, the data nearly 20% based on current emissions. What is
suggests a structural break in the mid-1970s. more, if there is no significant policy change
The only significant structural break can be leading to a dramatic structural break such as
attributed to the oil price shock. Changes in the one caused by the oil price shock in the mid
environmental and energy policies such as, for 1970s, CO2 emissions will grow further, at least in
instance, the international Bergen, Strasbourg and a ‘business-as-usual’ scenario.
Toronto agreements in the 1980s and the Kyoto
protocol in the 1990s, and the government’s 3.2. The empirical model
domestic energy policy report in the early 1990s,
had no impact on reducing CO2 emissions. After Based on the theoretical considerations dis-
1990, there was a sharp increase in CO2 emissions, cussed in Section 2, we apply the following
B. Friedl, M. Getzner / Ecological Economics 45 (2003) 133 /148 139

Fig. 2. CO2 emissions and GDP in Austria.

empirical model to test for the EKC hypothesis: Neck and Getzner, 2002). Short-term fluctuations
can be hypothesized to lead to a significantly
CO2t  f (Yt ; ydt ; Tt ; it ; st ; Xt ) (2)
positive coefficient of ydt because an actual GDP
where CO2t are CO2 emissions in year t .8 We above the long-term trend might lead to a short-
hypothesize that these emissions depend on Yt term increase in CO2 emissions (all variables are
denoting GDP at constant 1995 prices per capita, listed and described in Table 1).
either in a linear, quadratic or cubic relationship. While economic determinants may be the reason
Furthermore, we test for short-term fluctuations in for long- and short-term developments in CO2
CO2 emissions by accounting for short-term dis- emissions, the average temperature in year t might,
turbances in economic growth as measured by of course, be influential. For an approximation of
GDP (Yt ). The variable ydt represents the devia- climatic variations, we take a time series of the
tion of Yt from its long-term trend, expressed as a yearly temperature deviation Tt from the long-run
percentage of trend-Yt . Trend-Yt is calculated by temperature average. Climatic conditions opera-
means of a linear autoregressive model. This tionalized by Tt can be hypothesized to exhibit a
specification includes short-term variations of negative coefficient: in years with an above-aver-
GDP and has proven to be the most appropriate age temperature, energy consumption (e.g. for
when analyzing Austrian fiscal and economic heating) is lower, and thus lower CO2 emissions
policy (see, for example, Getzner et al., 2001; can be expected.
In order to test for structural changes in an
8
Austrian and an international economic context,
Note that emissions are estimated in absolute numbers. To
compare the results with other countries, divide emissions by
we test for the influence of two more variables.
the factor of 8/106 (the approximate population of Austria First, the variable it denotes imports as a ratio to
which has remained roughly constant during the last decades). GDP to account for the openness of the Austrian
140 B. Friedl, M. Getzner / Ecological Economics 45 (2003) 133 /148

Fig. 3. Development of GDP and CO2 emissions relative to GDP (index, 1960/100; 1960 /1999).

(see Section 2 above). If this hypothesis proves to


Table 1 be realistic, higher imports should lead to lower
Variables and data used for estimating Environmental Kuznets
Curves for Austria
CO2 emissions. Thus, we test for the hypothesis
that the coefficient for it is significantly negative
Dependent variables (i.e. higher imports reduce domestic CO2 emis-
CO2t CO2 emissions in Austria in year t (in mt)
rt Residuals of the cointegrating regression (CO2t and Yt )
sions).
Second, we explain structural changes in the
Explanatory variables
Yt GDP (constant 1995 prices), per capita (in Euro 1000)
Austrian domestic economy by accounting for the
y dt Deviation of GDP from trend-GDP (% of trend-GDP) significant growth in the tertiary sector (service
Tt Deviation from long-term mean temperature in Austria sector). Variable st denotes the value added
(8C) produced in the service sector as a share of
it Imports, nominal ratio to GDP (%)
st Value added in the service sector (tertiary sector),
GDP. The share of services (st ) grew from 39%
nominal ratio to GDP (%) in 1960 to over 62% in 2000. As services cause
D75 Dummy variable ( /1 for the period 1975 /2000) relatively lower CO2 emissions than industrial
d (xt) First difference of variable xt production, the coefficient of st can be hypothe-
n Number of observations
sized to be significantly negative as a growing
share of value added from the service sector
reduces pollution-intensive industries and thus
economy. This ratio grew from around 21% in Austrian CO2 emissions.
1960 to over 36% in 2000. A popular hypothesis in Finally, we include variables accounting for
the environmental debate is the ‘export’ of envir- other politico-economic determinants of CO2
onmentally harmful production to other countries emissions. For instance, Xt might include a
B. Friedl, M. Getzner / Ecological Economics 45 (2003) 133 /148 141

dummy variable for a change in the slope of the afterwards. Applying a Chow breakpoint test to
regression function, due to the structural break, the estimations for stationarity strongly indicates
from 1974 onwards; Xt might also include vari- that the structural break appears to have taken
ables denoting policy changes such as the signing place in 1974 (for that year, the log likelihood ratio
of international agreements to reduce CO2 emis- amounts to 19.0858 which is highest compared to
sions (e.g. the aforementioned commitments). test statistics for other years and significant at P B/
The methodological approach in this paper is as 0.001). Thus, we explore the characteristics of the
follows: First, we test for stationarity in the time time series of CO2 emissions for the two periods
series of the dependent and independent variables. separately. First, we apply the ADF test to CO2t
Second, we explore whether the main variables for the period from 1957 to 1974. Again the
CO2t and Yt are cointegrated. Based on these estimation strongly implies that the time series is
results, we then test which functional form is most not stationary in levels. The explanatory power of
appropriate to describe the time path of CO2 the model is much higher than the estimation for
emissions in Austria. the whole period. Alongside a drift in the time
series, there is also an indication that the time
3.3. The time series of CO2 emissions: stationarity series is driven by a deterministic trend. For the
and cointegration analysis time series in its first difference, H0 has to be
rejected. Similar results are obtained when testing
3.3.1. Stationarity and structural breaks in the time the stationarity of CO2t for the period after 1974.
path of CO2 emissions The time series is again non-stationary in levels but
In order to test for stationarity in the time series stationary in its first difference. However, the
of the dependent and independent variables, the structural break in the series can also be seen in
most common stationarity test, namely the aug- the differing size of the coefficients for the estima-
mented Dickey/Fuller test (ADF test), was ap- tions for the two periods. While the drift in the
plied. The aim of this procedure is to test for the second period is much larger, the trend is smaller
characteristics of the time series with CO2t as the and only significant at P B/0.1. The mean-revert-
dependent variable and Yt , st , it and Tt as the ing tendency is also stronger in the second period
explanatory variables. compared to the first one. Summing up, the
Without presenting the details of the econo- variable CO2t exhibits an order of integration of
metric estimations, it can be concluded that the I(1); this result is valid both for a joint estimation
hypothesis (H0) of non-stationarity for the time for the whole period as well as for a separate
series of the dependent variable CO2t in levels estimation for the two periods.
cannot be rejected at any reasonable level of Furthermore, we test the variables Yt , st , it and
significance. However, if we apply the ADF test Tt for stationarity. Without going too much into
in order to explore the stationarity of the first detail here, the explanatory variables of the
difference of the time series, we have to reject H0 at empirical model given in Eq. (2) above again
the 1% level of significance. From a qualitative prove to be non-stationary in levels but stationary
viewpoint, we can conclude that the time path of in their first differences (I(1)). One exception is the
CO2 emissions in Austria is not independent of variable Tt which is stationary in levels. This is a
time, i.e. CO2 emissions grew during the relevant result, which we would expect; however, Tt also
period without a significant mean-reverting trend. follows a small but significantly increasing trend
On the contrary, there is some indication that the path, indicating a small but significant increase in
time series includes an upward drift eventually temperatures.
leading to future growth. The results so far indicate that there is econo-
As discussed in Section 3.1, the development of metric evidence for non-stationarity in the time
CO2 emissions in Austria might be characterized series of both the dependent and the explanatory
by a structural break during the mid-1970s with variables. Simply regressing a non-stationary vari-
more rapid growth before 1975 and slower growth able on another non-stationary variable might lead
142 B. Friedl, M. Getzner / Ecological Economics 45 (2003) 133 /148

to spurious results, i.e. a significant relation might column shows the results of the cointegrating
be indicated where, in fact, there is none. However, regression for the period 1960 to 1974. The
if the time series are cointegrated, i.e. if they ‘run hypothesis of no cointegration has to be rejected
parallel’ and the residuals of the cointegrating at the 1% level of significance when we take the
regression are stationary, OLS is again an ade- Durbin /Watson statistic as the main guideline.
quate estimation procedure. Therefore, in the next Testing the residuals for stationarity, as shown in
section we test for cointegration between the two the fourth column of the table, we reject the
main variables, namely CO2t and Yt . hypothesis of a unit root in the residuals at the
5% level of significance. The ADF test statistic is
3.3.2. Cointegration: economic growth and CO2 /2.6715 which is smaller than the critical value of
emissions /1.9699 at the 5% level of significance as the
Testing for cointegration bilaterally is usually inspection of the graphical representation of the
done by means of the so-called cointegrating time series of CO2 emissions shows (Figs. 1 and 2),
regression. The equation to be estimated is simply: CO2 emissions and GDP merely ‘run parallel’ in
CO2t  abYt o t (3) the first period. The adj. R2 for the first period is
Cointegration is then tested in two steps. First, thus very high with a value of 0.9651. This result
the value of the Durbin /Watson statistic resulting can also be interpreted as a further indication of
from the estimation is an indication of cointegra- the strong links between economic growth and
tion. If the Durbin /Watson statistic is signifi- increasing CO2 emissions between 1960 and 19749.
cantly different from zero, H0 of no cointegration The fifth column in Table 2 shows the results of
between the two time series has to be rejected. the cointegrating regression for the second period,
However, this test is commonly not considered to 1975 to 1999. The Durbin/Watson statistic again
be very decisive. Second, the residuals resulting leads to a rejection of H0 at the 1% level of
from estimating equation (Eq. (3)) are tested for significance, and the hypothesis of non-stationar-
stationarity, e.g. with the ADF test. ity of the residuals of the cointegrating regression
Table 2 presents the results of the bilateral can also be rejected (the ADF test statistic is
cointegration test for the time series of CO2t and /2.9192 compared to a critical value of /2.6700
Yt . The cointegrating regression exhibits a signifi- at the 1% level of significance). The coefficient for
cant constant and a significantly positive coeffi- the explanatory variable Yt is much smaller than
cient for Yt with an adj. R2 of about 0.76. With a the one for the first period, indicating that the
Durbin /Watson statistic of 0.2708, H0 has to be links between CO2 emissions and GDP are much
rejected at a rather ‘weak’ level of significance of weaker in the second period.
10%. The second column of the table shows the Based on the results of the cointegrating regres-
more important test for cointegration, i.e. the sion, we can conclude that Austrian CO2 emissions
stationarity test of the residuals of the cointegrat- and GDP are cointegrated, i.e. they ‘run parallel’,
ing regression. Well below the significance level of hence, OLS is an appropriate estimation tool.
1%, H0 of no cointegration has to be rejected (the
However, the differences in the two periods
ADF test statistic amounts to /4.3512 compared
(1960 /1974 and 1975/1999) again become appar-
with a critical value of /2.6280 at the 1% level of
ent. In order to estimate an EKC, we thus have to
significance). The results indicate that there is not
focus on a functional form, which is able to
a unit root in the residuals and that the two
account for the structural break in the time series.
variables are indeed cointegrated.
Table 2 also presents the results of the test for
cointegration in the two separate periods (1954 /
1974; 1975/1999). As discussed above, the two
periods might be different regarding the correla- 9
Moomaw and Unruh (1997) derive a similar result for a
tion between CO2 emissions and GDP. The third subset of OECD countries.
B. Friedl, M. Getzner / Ecological Economics 45 (2003) 133 /148 143

Table 2
Testing for cointegration between GDP and CO2 emissions

Explanatory variables Dependent variable

1960 /1999 1960 /1974 1975 /1999

CO2t d(rt ) CO2t d(rt ) CO2t d(rt )

Constant 28.1188*** /1.7615 47.2344***


(11.0427) (/0.7107) (13.5127)
Yt 1.7572*** 4.5547*** 0.7389***
(11.2095) (19.7301) (3.9723)
rt-1 /1.0607*** /0.9771** /0.6051***
(/4.3512) (/2.6715) (/2.9192)
d (rt-1) 0.0689 0.5385 0.1987
(0.3967) 1.3720 (0.9873)
Adj R2 0.7617 0.4843 0.9651 0.3347 0.3811 0.2634
S.E. of regression 4.5359 2.3156 1.6760 1.5752 2.4980 2.1039
Akaike info criterion 5.9106 4.5712 3.9942 3.8873 4.7455 4.4084
Schwarz criterion 5.9951 4.6592 4.0887 3.9742 4.8430 4.5071
F -statistic 125.6527*** 33.8748*** 389.2776*** 7.0396** 15.7791*** 8.8673***
log likelihood /116.2128 /80.2821 /27.9572 /23.2676 /57.3193 /48.6972
Durbin /Watson statis- 0.2708* 1.2708*** 1.0413***
tic
Breusch /Godfrey LM 0.3463 0.5263 0.5924
test
ADF Test statistic /4.3512*** /2.6715** /2.9192***
Critical 1%-ADF test /2.6280 /2.7760 /2.6700
statistic
Critical 5%-ADF test /1.9504 /1.9699 /1.9566
statistic
N 40 36 15 13 25 25
H0a rejected YES* YES*** YES*** YES*** YES*** YES***

OLS estimation; ***P B/0.01, **P B/0.05, *P B/0.1.


a
H0: No cointegration between CO2t and Yt .

3.4. Structural models: estimating an EKC for function between these two periods by including
Austria the dummy variable D75 which takes the value of
1 for the period 1975/1999. The first column of
After having explored the characteristics of the Table 3 shows the estimation results (excluding the
different time series, we now turn to an empirical variables it and st whose influence we want to test
estimation of the EKC model described above in separately). The coefficient for the variable Yt is
Eq. (2). Model 1 (Table 3) is a simple linear model, highly significant as are the coefficients for ydt and
which takes the structural break in 1974 into Tt which all have the ‘correct’ (theoretically
account. The graph (Fig. 1) shows that for the expected) sign. Accounting for the dummy vari-
first period in particular, a linear model might be able D75 , the estimation shows that the slope in
appropriate while in the second period, GDP as a the second period might be much smaller than in
determinant of CO2 emissions might be weaker. the first one. However, the coefficient for Yt xD75
Thus, we estimate a model, which enables us to is not significant. Estimation of a linear specifica-
differentiate between the slope of the regression tion shows that the dependent variable is mainly
144 B. Friedl, M. Getzner / Ecological Economics 45 (2003) 133 /148

Table 3
Estimation of an Environmental Kuznets Curve for Austrian CO2 emissions

Explanatory variables Carbon Dioxide Emissions 1960 /1999

Model 1 (linear) Model 2 (quadratic) Model 3 (cubic) Model 4 (cubic extended)

Constant 5.5915** 3.6924 /68.6600*** /60.1008***


(2.1197) (0.9070) (/4.1447) (/3.5378)
Yt 0.7596*** 1.6320* 18.7849*** 21.1495***
(3.0664) (1.6935) (4.7834) (4.9449)
Y2t 10  2 /0.0367 /1.0791*** /1.1150***
(/1.1852) (/4.5678) (/4.6573)
Y3t /10  5 0.0211*** 0.0219***
(4.4549) (4.4967)
Yt /D75 /0.1280
(/1.3540)
ydt 0.6283*** 0.7029*** 0.7430*** 0.7052***
(2.7706) (3.1466) (4.1415) (3.5594)
Tt /2.1547*** /2.0328*** /2.3404*** /2.4897***
(/3.5577) (/3.3443) (/4.7529) (/5.0236)
it /0.3090*
(/1.6525)
st /0.3613[*]
(/1.7300)
CO2t1 0.7315*** 0.6385*** 0.2969** 0.2117
(10.3888) (5.9182) (2.5675) (1.5792)
Adj R2 0.9575 0.9570 0.9744 0.9794
S.E. of regression 1.9138 1.9254 1.5444 1.4942
Akaike info criterion 4.2736 4.2856 3.8648 3.8361
Schwarz criterion 4.5269 4.5389 4.1603 4.2161
F -statistic 177.0471*** 174.8480*** 229.7808*** 184.6474***
log likelihood /79.4723 /79.7130 /70.2954 /67.7226
Durbin /Watson stat. 1.9857 1.7325 1.8869 2.0021
n 40 40 40 40

OLS estimation; *** P B/0.01, **P B/0.05, *P B/0.1, [*] P B/0.11.

driven by its own autoregressive term, which is not indicating that these coefficients are stable regard-
very satisfactory for an exploration of the relation- less of the functional form chosen.
ship between CO2 and GDP emissions. As the linear and quadratic model are not
Model 2 (Table 3, column 2) presents a direct satisfactory from an econometric point of view, a
test of the EKC hypothesis, i.e. an inverted U- cubic relation between CO2 and GDP is tested in
shaped relation between CO2 and economic model 3. This functional form suggests an N-
growth (GDP), by assuming a quadratic func- shaped relation, with increasing CO2 emissions at
tional form. The estimation of a quadratic func- the beginning of the period, stabilization (or
tional form is clearly rejected due to the reduction) in CO2 emissions in the middle of the
insignificant coefficient for the quadratic term period, and an increase in emissions at the end.
(Yt )2. The estimation is weaker than the linear The third column in Table 3 presents the results of
model with a coefficient for Yt which is only the cubic functional form. The statistical quality of
significant at the 10% level of significance. Again the estimation is better in terms of the highly
the autoregressive term plays an important role in significant coefficients for the Yt -terms, an in-
explaining the dependent variable. The coefficients creased adj. R2 as well as an improved F-statistic
for the variables ydt and Tt stay roughly the same, and log likelihood. The size and sign of the
B. Friedl, M. Getzner / Ecological Economics 45 (2003) 133 /148 145

coefficients suggest that a functional form mirror- CO2 emissions as the actual and fitted values are
ing an N-shaped relation between CO2 emissions very close (see Fig. 4).
and GDP is appropriate.
Finally, in model 4 two more variables are
included to take account for structural changes 4. Discussion, summary and conclusions
in the Austrian economy. The fourth column of
the table includes an estimation of a cubic form The first insight gained from exploring the time
which also accounts for the import share variable series of Austrian CO2 emissions is that the
it and the service intensity variable st . While the development of CO2 emissions has to be split
size of the other coefficients stays about the same, into two different periods. In the first period,
the two variables additionally exhibit significant before the oil price shock in the mid-1970s, CO2
influence on the dependent variable. The coeffi- emissions followed a strong growth path, reflect-
cient of it is negative and significant at the 10% ing a proportional increase in CO2 emissions with
level of significance indicating that CO2 emissions economic growth. For the second period, from
are indeed ‘exported’ by importing goods. How- 1975 to 1999, growth of CO2 emissions was
ever, this ‘export’ of CO2 emissions is compara- significantly smaller, indicating that the oil price
tively small and only seems to slightly mitigate the shock led to significantly altered energy and
positive effect of GDP on CO2 emissions. One environmental policies. However, for the whole
reason for this surprisingly small impact might be period as well as for the two periods separately, the
that Germany, Austria’s main trading partner, time series of CO2 emissions are non-stationary in
pursues similar environmental objectives to Aus- the sense that they incorporate growth (i.e. their
tria (and, therefore, does not produce very pollu- mean-reverting tendency is too small to result in a
tion-intensive commodities). Likewise, the stationary time series). The structural break in the
mid-1970s is also indicated econometrically by
structural change in the Austrian economy, i.e.
testing for a breakpoint, resulting in 1974 as the
the growth of the service sector, is only weakly
crucial year. Further tests resulted in a rejection of
influential. While the sign of the coefficient of st is
the hypothesis of no cointegration between CO2
negative as expected, the significance level is only
emissions and GDP. Thus, both variables can be
11% which is only a minor indication that CO2
considered to be cointegrated.
emissions are also determined by the structural
A number of functional forms of the relation
change. This can partly be traced back to the fact
between CO2 emissions and GDP were tested. A
that carbon emissions are increasingly caused by
linear functional form including a dummy variable
(public and private) transport, and freight and
for the period after 1974 to account for the
passenger transport are classified as services in the structural break in the mid-1970s was unsatisfac-
national accounts. Therefore, although an increas- tory as was the choice of a quadratic form. The
ing share of the service sector tends to reduce insignificant coefficient for the quadratic term is a
emissions in general, the growing contribution of clear rejection of the hypothesis of an inverted U-
the transport sector works in the opposite direc- shaped EKC for CO2 emissions in Austria. How-
tion. Summing up, both the influence of the ever, a cubic functional form proved to be the
import share and the service intensity are overlaid most appropriate one in terms of econometric
by the main driving forces of GDP growth. But quality. This result suggests that Austrian CO2
still, the estimation of a cubic functional form is emissions are exemplified by an N-shaped relation-
the most appropriate one10 in terms of forecasting ship with GDP; at least, CO2 emissions of the past
can be described most adequately by such a
10 functional form.
We also tried other functional forms such as log-linear
and logarithmic, as well as an error-correction model. However, Two possible explanations can be given for the
none of the results proved to be as good as the cubic functional N-shaped curve. First, it could merely be a
form presented in Table 3. statistical result since CO2 emissions seem to
146 B. Friedl, M. Getzner / Ecological Economics 45 (2003) 133 /148

Fig. 4. Actual and fitted CO2 emissions.

have stabilized or at least have been growing only increases nowadays, the pressure to increase en-
slowly in recent years.11 This would be true if the ergy efficiency and to implement more stringent
sample happens to fall between the two ‘kinks’ environmental policies is gradually falling. This
(more mathematically, the two local extreme second point particularly needs further research.
values) of the N-shaped relationship (which in CO2 emissions do not only depend on economic
our case might be a very flat section). Therefore, a growth but are determined by short-term fluctua-
projection based on the statistically significant N- tions in GDP and by climatic conditions. Further-
shape would lead to an unrealistic result. This more, structural changes in a small open economy
argument must be underlined since in our estima- such as the Austrian one have regularly been
tion the minimum value is well outside current hypothesized to crucially determine CO2 emis-
GDP values (in fact, not only the second ‘kink’ but sions. We find that the growth of the tertiary
also the mathematical turning point lies outside sector (service sector) ceteris paribus reduces CO2
the data set). Second, the N-shape could be the emissions. Imports as an auxiliary measure for
result of a ‘recovery effect’ because the initial ‘exporting’ CO2-emitting industries also reduce
shock of the oil crisis in the mid-1970s might have CO2 emissions. However, the main driving force
been reduced after one decade. In other words, behind CO2 emissions in Austria is economic
since oil prices are not undergoing permanent growth. Structural changes can only weaken the
tendency for growth but cannot contribute suffi-
ciently to a mean-reversion process of CO2 emis-
11
Cole et al. (1997) argue in a similar way for cross-country sions, let alone reduce CO2 emissions in times of
studies on global pollutants, predicting that the second turning
point (implying the upward slope at high income) is outside the
economic growth.
income range reached so far by the countries under This main driving force behind CO2 emissions is
investigation. also highlighted by forecasting CO2 emissions
B. Friedl, M. Getzner / Ecological Economics 45 (2003) 133 /148 147

(based on trend-GDP) for the period of 2000 / tocol, a significant shift in climate policy will have
2010 (see Fig. 4). If we take the cubic functional to take place.
form (upper dotted line) as the appropriate form,
CO2 emissions will grow significantly in the next
few years. However, assuming a linear model Acknowledgements
(lower dotted line), CO2 emissions will increase
less. Both projections clearly show that there is no We would like to thank Heinz Schandl (Depart-
indication from past energy and environmental ment of Social Ecology, IFF, University of Kla-
policies that CO2 emissions will decrease*/a genfurt) and anonymous referees for helpful
policy target to which Austria has committed itself comments on an earlier draft of the paper. Thanks
on numerous occasions. From a methodological are also due to the Austrian Central Meteorology
point of view, the estimated model describes the and Geodynamics Institute for providing data on
time path of the analyzed period most appropri- climate conditions. All errors are, of course, our
ately. But two qualifications should be borne in responsibility.
mind. First, as indicated above, the data set falls
within the flat part of the curve, between the two
turning points. Therefore, the estimated model References
cannot be used for precise quantitative forecasts
for future emissions. Second, the Lucas critique Arrow, K., Bolin, B., Costanza, R., Dasgupta, P., Folke, C.,
(Lucas, 1976) is relevant in the sense that, parti- Holling, C.S., Jansson, B.-O., Levin, S., Mäler, K.-G.,
Perrings, C., Pimentel, D., 1995. Economic growth, carrying
cularly with partial models such as the one capacity and the environment. Science 268, 520 /521.
presented in the current paper, projections of Borghesi, S., 1999. The Environmental Kuznets Curve: a survey
policies and their outcomes based on past trends of the literature. Working Paper 85-99, Fondazione Eni
are problematic. However, we clearly find no Enrico Mattei.
Cavlovic, T.A., Baker, K.H., Berrens, R.P., Gawande, K.,
indication for a reduction in CO2 emissions in
2000. A meta-analysis of environmental Kuznets curve
the future, and at the very least a slight upward studies. Agric. Resource Econ. Rev. 29 (1), 32 /42.
trend. Cole, M.A., 2000. Air pollution and ‘dirty’ industries: how and
The main policy conclusion of this paper is that why does the composition of manufacturing output change
in order to fulfill international agreements to with economic development. Environ. Resource Econ. 17,
reduce CO2 emissions, Austria needs a radically 109 /123.
Cole, M.A., Rayner, A.J., Bates, J.M., 1997. The environmental
revised policy framework to achieve a structural Kuznets curve: an empirical analysis. Environ. Devel. Econ.
break in the time series of CO2 emissions equiva- 2 (4), 401 /416.
lent to the policy changes following the oil price De Bruyn, S.M., van den Bergh, J.C.J.M., Opschoor, J.B.,
shock in the mid-1970s. There is apparently no 1998. Economic growth and emissions: reconsidering the
‘automatism’ in the time series, which would empirical basis of the Environmental Kuznets Curves. Ecol.
Econ. 25 (2), 161 /175.
suggest that CO2 emissions would fall with higher Dijkgraaf, E., Vollebergh, H.R.J., 1998. Environmental Kuz-
GDP. Structural changes like the increasing im- nets revisited. Time-series versus panel estimation: the CO2
portance of the service sector or higher import case, OcfEB Research Memorandum 9806, Erasmus Uni-
quotas do not exhibit sufficient influence to versity Rotterdam.
Ekins, P., 1997. The Kuznets curve for the environment and
stabilize or reduce CO2 emissions. Thus, policy
economic growth: examining the evidence. Environ. Plan-
changes aiming at ‘policy induced price shocks’, ning A 29, 805 /830.
e.g. by means of an ecological tax reform, seem to Galeotti, M., Lanza, A., 1999. Desperately seeking (environ-
be the most appropriate environmental policy mental) Kuznets. Mimeo, International Energy Agency,
instruments to cut CO2 emissions since other Paris.
instruments applied by Austrian environmental Getzner, M., Glatzer, E., Neck, R., 2001. On the sustainability
of Austrian budgetary policies. Empirica 28 (1), 21 /40.
policies in the past have had no clear growth- Harbaugh, W., Levinson, A., Wilson, D., 2000. Re-examining
reversing effects on CO2 emissions. In order to the empirical basis for the environmental Kuznets curve,
fulfill Austria’s obligations under the Kyoto Pro- NBER Working Paper, Cambridge, MA.
148 B. Friedl, M. Getzner / Ecological Economics 45 (2003) 133 /148

Heil, M.T., Selden, T.M., 2001. Carbon Emissions and Patel, S.H., Pickney, T.C., Jaeger, W.K., 1995. Smallholder
economic development: future trajectories based on histor- wood production and population pressure in East Africa:
ical experience. Environ. Dev. Econ. 6 (1), 63 /68. evidence of an Environmental Kuznets Curve. Land Econ.
Hettige, H., Lucas, R.E.B., Wheeler, D., 1992. The toxic 71 (4), 516 /530.
intensity of industrial production: global patterns, trends, Roberts, J.T., Grimes, P.E., 1997. Carbon intensity and
and trade policy. Am. Econ. Rev. 82 (2), 478 /481. economic development 1962 /91: a brief exploration of the
Holtz-Eakin, D., Selden, T.M., 1995. Stoking the fires? CO2 Environmental Kuznets Curve. World Dev. 25 (2), 191 /
emissions and economic growth. J. Public Econ. 57, 85 /101. 198.
Jänicke, M., Binder, M., Mönch, H., 1997. ‘Dirty industries’: Schandl, H., Hüttler, W., Payer, H., 1999. Delinking of
patterns of change in industrial countries. Environ. Re- economic growth and materials turnover. Innovation 12
source Econ. 9, 467 /491. (1), 31 /45.
Liski, M., Toppinen, A., 2001. Stochastic versus Deterministic
Schandl, H., Weisz, H., Petrovic, B., 2000. Materialflussrech-
Trends in Carbon Dioxide Time Series, Working Paper,
nung für Österreich 1960 bis 1997. (Material Flow Analysis
Helsinki School of Economics.
for Austria 1960 /1997) Statistische Nachrichten 55 (2),
Lucas, R., 1976. Econometric policy evaluation: a critique, the
128 /137 (in German).
Phillips Curve and Labor Markets. Carnegie Rochester
Shafik, N., 1994. Economic development and environmental
Conf. 1, 19 /46.
Marland, G., Andres, R.J., Boden, T.A., Johnson, C., Bernkert, quality: an econometric analysis. Oxford Econ. Pap. 46,
A., 1996. Global, Regional, and National CO2 Estimates 757 /773.
from Fossil Fuel Burning, Cement Production, and Gas Shafik, N., Bandyopadhyay, S., 1992. Economic growth and
Flaring: 1751 /1996. Carbon Dioxide Information Center, environmental quality. Background Paper for the 1992
Oak Ridge, TN. World Development Report, The World Bank, Washing-
Moomaw, W.R., Unruh, G.C., 1997. Are Environmental ton, DC.
Kuznets Curves misleading us? The case of CO2 emissions. Stern, D.I., Common, M.S., Barbier, E.B., 1996. Economic
Environ. Dev. Econ. 2 (4), 451 /463. growth and environmental degradation: the Environmental
Neck, R., Getzner, M., 2002. Politico-economic determinants Kuznets Curve and sustainable development. World Dev.
of public debt growth: a case study for Austria. Public 24 (7), 1151 /1160.
Choice 109 (3 /4), 243 /268. Suri, V., Chapman, D., 1998. Economic growth, trade and
Panayotou, T., 1997. Demystifying the Environmental Kuznets energy: implications for the environmental Kuznets curve.
Curve: turning a black box into a policy tool. Environ. Dev. Ecol. Econ. 25 (2), 195 /208.
Econ. 2 (4), 465 /484. Tisdell, C., 2001. Globalisation and sustainability: environ-
Panayotou, T., 2000. Economic growth and the environment. mental Kuznets curve and the WTO. Ecol. Econ. 39, 185 /
CID Working Paper 56, Harvard. 196.
Panayotou, T., Peterson, A., Sachs, J., 2000. Is the Environ- Vincent, J.R., 1997. Testing for Environmental Kuznets Curves
mental Kuznets Curve driven by structural change? What within a developing country. Environ. Dev. Econ. 2 (4),
extended time series may imply for developing countries. 417 /431.
CAER II Discussion Paper 80.

You might also like