You are on page 1of 11

Energy Policy 62 (2013) 1392–1402

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Energy Policy
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/enpol

The Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC) theory—Part A:


Concept, causes and the CO2 emissions case
Dimitra Kaika, Efthimios Zervas n
School of Science and Technology, Hellenic Open University, Riga Feraiou 167, 26 222 Patra, Greece

H I G H L I G H T S

 The evolution to the EKC-concept and the EKC-speculation is presented.


 The possible factors—other than income—that may lead to an EKC-relationship are analyzed.
 The EKC literature is quite large, and results are at best mixed. No clear conclusion can be drawn.
 The relationship between income and CO2 emissions comes up to be positive due to energy consumption.

art ic l e i nf o a b s t r a c t

Article history: The main purpose of this study is to capture the main features of the Environmental Kuznets Curve
Received 20 February 2012 (EKC)-concept. According to the EKC-theory, the process of economic growth is expected eventually to
Accepted 29 July 2013 limit the environmental degradation created in the early stages of development. The EKC concept leads
Available online 05 September 2013
many researchers from the early 1990s to assume that each economy should focus on its growth, and any
Keywords: environmental problems will be eventually eliminated by the process of economic growth. Several
EKC literature studies attempt to test empirically the EKC-hypothesis using data on many countries and examining
CO2 emissions various types of environmental degradation, while other studies examine the underlying factors that
Economic growth may drive such a relationship. This article reviews the evolution of the EKC-concept and the possible
causes of an EKC-pattern, like the distribution of income, the international trade (pollution haven
hypothesis), structural changes, technical progress and improvements in energy efficiency, institutions
and governance and consumer preferences. As CO2 emissions are a pollutant with global effects, several
studies deal with the possible EKC-pattern for CO2 emissions and these studies are discussed separately.
The various critiques on the EKC-concept are reviewed in the second article of this work.
& 2013 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction Such facts hint that it is the limited ability of nature to act as a
sink of human wastes and not the finite source of resources in
Classical economics consider land, labor and capital as the nature that may restrict the growth process (Brock and Taylor,
primary factors of production. Land is the physical capital (envir- 2004). Environmental deterioration is a by-product of economic
onment) which provides the indispensable natural resources that activity and many authors attempt to study the possible relation-
allow every economic activity to take place. However, the exhaust- ship between environmental degradation (pollution) and eco-
ibility of the natural resources gives rise to concerns about its nomic growth (income). This is called the PIR (pollution–income
possible effect on the productive capabilities (Tahvonen, 2000). relationship) literature (Lieb, 2003). According to this literature,
The oil crises in the 1970s, signaled that the world would run out the relationship between pollution and income may take several
of oil and, consequently, of energy (Tahvonen, 2000) leading to a forms of which the most widely supported is the Environmental
slowdown of productivity (Stern, 2004a). Moreover, scientific Kuznets Curve (cited hereafter EKC). The EKC is tested empirically
researches point out the negative effects of economic growth on on various pollutants. The EKC literature shifts the main issue from
the environment such as the over-accumulation of greenhouse the exhaustion of natural resources and environmental degrada-
gases, the upsetting of air pollution and the significant increase in tion to issues concerning the necessity of economic growth to
the generation of wastes. overcome environmental deterioration and pollution.
The first part of this work focuses on studies dealing with the
EKC-concept. Undoubtedly, the EKC-literature including empirical
studies is very large. Therefore, the current review is not exhaus-
n
Corresponding author. Tel.: +30 2610 367 566. tive. Rather, the focus of interest is to capture the main features of
E-mail address: zervas@eap.gr (E. Zervas). the EKC-subject. This article consists of two parts. The first part is

0301-4215/$ - see front matter & 2013 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2013.07.131
D. Kaika, E. Zervas / Energy Policy 62 (2013) 1392–1402 1393

organized as follows. Initially, we briefly discuss the debate about development aims at a certain level of consumption or welfare
the exhaustion of natural resources, environmental degradation per capita that has to be maintained for future generations. It
and economic growth from the early 1970s onwards. Next, we includes three constituent parts, the environmental sustainability,
describe the general concept of the EKC-theory. Then, insights into the economic sustainability and the sociopolitical sustainability
the EKC-concept follows, as many studies focus on specific factors, (Ekins, 1993).
other than income, that may drive the relationship between Contrary, for economists, pollution remains an outcome of
pollution and income. Finally, we present empirical EKC-studies market failures despite the fact that there have been considerable
dealing with the specific link between economic growth and CO2 reconsiderations in economic growth models. For instance, eco-
emissions since CO2 emissions is a special case of environmental nomic growth models until the mid 1980s, consider technological
degradation with global effects. change as an exogenous variable in the economic system (Stern,
As soon as the first empirical studies on the EKC concept 2004a). After the mid-1980s, some economic theories start to
appeared, the first critiques evolved. These critiques are reviewed place technological development as an endogenous variable in the
in the second part of the current study and are necessary to system (endogenous growth models). Despite this evolution, these
capture the entire EKC-speculation (Kaika and Zervas, 2013). new models do not consider the finiteness of natural resources
(Tahvonen, 2000). As Stern (2004a) notes, there is still an inbuilt
bias in mainstream production and growth theory to downplay the
2. The transition from the “Limits to Growth” in 1970s, to the role of resources in the economy, though there is nothing inherent in
EKC-literature in 1990s economics that restricts the potential role of resources in the
economy. What is more, given the publication of new empirical
Historically, there are opposing views in economic theory that evidence in the early 1990s, the main idea in economics turns out
deal with issues related to the natural resource scarcity (Klassen to be “too poor to be green” (Beckerman, 1992). That is to say, less
and Opschoor, 1991; Ekins, 1993; Tahvonen, 2000). Over the last developed countries lack the resources for environmental protec-
decades, there has been a transition from issues concerning the tion and the economic growth can solve environmental problems
depletion of natural resources into current issues concerning (Tahvonen, 2000; Stern, 2004a). The “World Development Report”
either the sustainability of economic growth or the necessity of in 1992 concludes that some environmental problems are exacer-
economic growth to overcome environmental degradation. bated by the growth of economic activity and are associated with the
In 1972, the report of the Club of Rome “The Limits to Growth” lack of economic development (Ekins, 1993). The Report proposes to
concludes that economic growth has significant environmental accelerate equitable income growth in order to achieve higher world
impacts and the future world will collapse because world economy output and a better environmental protection (Ekins, 1993). This
will reach its physical limits in terms of nonrenewable resources, proposal lays the foundation of the so-called Environmental
agricultural production and excessive pollution (Tahvonen, 2000). Kuznets Curve (EKC) literature, which appears in the early 1990s.
A year after the publication of the report of the Club of Rome, the The EKC-literature is studied in the following sections.
first oil crisis occurs, leading to a general sense that the world is
entering a future of increasing scarcity of energy and of natural
resources (Tahvonen, 2000). This leads to concerns about the
exhaustibility of natural resources that question the possibility of 3. The pollution–income relationship (PIR) and the
attaining a positive consumption level forever. This concern lays Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC) theory
the foundations of sustainability. Two conflicting views appear at
the time. On one side, economists argue that through substitution The basic philosophy of the EKC-theory is reflected in Beck-
and technical progress, consumption can be sustained even if erman's view about the effect of economic growth on environ-
production depends on depleting natural resources (Klassen and mental degradation: there is «clear evidence that, although
Opschoor, 1991). In their view, sustainability is assumed a priori to economic growth usually leads to environmental deterioration in
be technically feasible due to substitution (Klassen and Opschoor, the early stages of the process, in the end, the best and probably the
1991) and the main concern for them is to investigate the only-way to attain a decent environment in most countries is to
institutional arrangements that will lead to sustainability (Stern, become rich» (Beckerman, 1992:482).
2004a). On the other side, environmental economists argue that According to the EKC-hypothesis, further economic growth can
substitution possibilities are restricted by physical laws even if improve environmental degradation after an economy has reached
technological change is continuous (Klassen and Opschoor, 1991; an adequate level of economic growth. In the early stages of
Tahvonen, 2000). Moreover, the environment, either as a produc- economic growth, when primary production dominates, there is
tion factor or as a consumer good or as a waste sink, can restrict an abundance of natural resource stock and a limited generation of
the process of economic growth (Klassen and Opschoor, 1991). wastes because of limited economic activity. In the course of
Some years later, it became clear that future world would not development and through industrialization, there occurs a sig-
collapse at least due to depleting natural resources (Tahvonen, nificant depletion of natural resources and wastes accumulate.
2000). Through new discoveries and technological change, the During this phase, there is a positive relationship between income
nonrenewable resources have been saved from exhaustion or economic growth (per capita) and environmental degradation
(Tahvonen, 2000). However, for environmental economists this is (per capita). With further economic growth, services, improved
not the case with respect to pollution. In line with this, the concept technology and information diffusion limit the material basis of an
of “sustainable development” replaces the concept of “Limits to economy and result in reduced environmental degradation
growth” in the early 1970s. Sustainability of the economic growth (Panayotou, 2003).
process and welfare comes up as an evolution from the first UN An EKC-curve has the form shown in Fig. 1. The relationship
Conference on the Environment in Stockholm (1972), followed by between environmental degradation (per capita) and income (per
the Brundtland report in 1987, which laid the groundwork for capita) is plotted as an inverted U and is similar to the original
the Earth Summit in Brazil in 1992 (Ekins, 1993). Sustainability curve proposed by Simon Kuznets (Kuznets, 1955) concerning the
is referring to the development process which meets the needs relationship between income inequality and economic growth.
of the present without compromising the ability of future genera- The turning point in Fig. 1 represents the level of income (per
tions to meet their own needs. Sustainability of economic capita) beyond which environmental degradation can be de-linked
1394 D. Kaika, E. Zervas / Energy Policy 62 (2013) 1392–1402

vii. If β1 o0, β2 4 0 and β3 4 0, then an inverted N-shaped rela-


tionship exists.

Only the (iv) case indicates an EKC-relationship. Therefore, the


EKC is a specific form of the PIR. If the (iv) case holds, then the
turning point is calculated as (Dinda, 2004):
β1
xn ¼ 
2β2
or xn ¼ expððβ1 =2β2 ÞÞ, in the logarithmic version.
The model (1) is a reduced-form equation. This implies that
Eq. (1) is the solution of a structural system of (unknown)
equations that form the final relationship between environmental
degradation and income. Using a reduced-form model allows us to
measure directly the impact of income on environmental degrada-
tion. However, a disadvantage of using it is that we do not know
the underlying structural functions of the (economic) system that
lead to this relationship (Grossman and Krueger, 1995).
Most empirical studies estimate the model using time series-
Fig. 1. An Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC). cross sectional data (TSCS) or panel data (Shafic and
Bandyopadhyay, 1992; Suri and Chapman, 1998; Dinda et al.,
from the process of economic growth. For higher income levels, 2000; Richmond and Kauffmann, 2006). The combination of data
economic growth improves the quality of environment. from many countries i for certain years or periods t1 increases the
In Fig. 1, the dependent variable on the vertical axis is an sample. Only few empirical studies estimate the model using time-
indicator of environmental degradation. Indicators of environmental series data due to the lack of available data over a long time-period
degradation can be emissions of a specific air pollutant, concentra- (De Bruyn et al., 1998; Asafu-Adjaye, 2000; Egli, 2002).
tion of a particular pollutant in a local level or an alternative form of The first empirical studies on the EKC-relationship appear
environmental degradation like deforestation. The most common independently in the early 1990s (Shafic and Bandyopadhyay,
forms of pollution that are studied in empirical EKC-estimations are 1992; Grossman and Krueger, 1995; Selden and Song, 1994). These
air pollution, water pollution, and land or soil pollution. The empirical studies make use of data on various pollutants that
independent variable on axis x in Fig. 1, is income or alternatively become available due to the Global Environmental Monitoring
economic growth (per capita) which is calculated by dividing the System (GEMS), the OECD environmental data compendium and
Gross Domestic Product (GDP) with the population of the economy. the estimates of CO2 emissions from the Oak Ridge National
Empirical studies test the EKC-hypothesis using the following Laboratory (ORNL) (Dinda, 2004).
general reduced-form model (Dinda, 2004):
yit ¼ ai þ β1 xit þ β2 x2it þ β3 x3it þ β4 zit 4. Possible causes of an EKC
þeit ; i ¼ 1; ::::; N countries; t ¼ 1; ::::; T years ð1Þ
Shafic and Bandyopadhyay (1992), Grossman and Krueger
In Eq. (1), y is the depended variable of environmental
(1995) and Selden and Song (1994) estimate that income has the
degradation, x is the independent variable of income, z reflects
most consistently significant effect on most indicators of environ-
other variables that may affect y, α is the constant term, and βi are
mental quality, as many environmental indicators deteriorate
the estimated coefficients of the κ explanatory variables. The e
initially when income rise but tend to improve as countries
represents the error term. Depending on the study, the model
become richer. Their empirical findings imply that it is possible
(1) varies. For instance, the cubic term of x is included in studies
for a country to “grow out of” its environmental problems,
that try to examine an N-shaped rather than an inverted U
although this process is not automatic. These studies lay the
relationship between environmental degradation and income.
groundwork for intensive work on the EKC-hypothesis both on
Many studies work on a (natural) logarithmic transformation of
theoretical and empirical basis. The main issue for the subsequent
(1) using ln(x) and ln(y) instead of x and y in order to avoid zero or
researchers is to find other than income possible driving forces
negative indicators (Stern, 2004b). In any case, the final choice of
that may lead to an EKC-relationship. The following subsections
the functional form is done on the model that best fits the
review the major driving forces, other than income, of an EKC-
available data and has the higher explanatory power inside the
pattern. This allows us to deepen our understanding of the EKC-
data range (Lieb, 2003).
concept.
In general, the estimation of the model tests the significance of
the coefficients βi. The following cases may occur (Dinda, 2004):
4.1. Equity of income distribution
i. If β1 ¼ β2 ¼ β3 ¼ 0 then there is no relationship between x and
y. The original Kuznets curve deals with issues related to the
ii. If β1 4 0 and β2 ¼ β3 ¼ 0, then a monotonic increasing or linear effect of economic growth on the distribution of income (Kuznets,
relationship exists between x and y. 1955). Similarly, many researchers examine whether the equity of
iii. If β1 o 0 and β2 ¼ β3 ¼ 0, then a monotonic decreasing rela- income distribution is the underlying factor beyond income in an
tionship between x and y exists. EKC-pattern (Torras and Boyce, 1998; Magnani, 2000; Bimonte,
iv. If β1 4 0, β2 o0 and β3 ¼ 0, then an inverted U relationship 2002). The basic thought is that the economic growth process can
(EKC) exists. lead to a more equitable income distribution that improves the
v. If β1 o 0, β2 4 0 and β3 ¼ 0, then a U-shaped relationship exists.
vi. If β1 4 0, β2 o 0 and β3 4 0, then there exists an N-shaped 1
TSCS look like panel data but differ because TSCS refer to relatively long T and
relationship. short N, while panel data include observations for many N and short T.
D. Kaika, E. Zervas / Energy Policy 62 (2013) 1392–1402 1395

relative position of the median agent (citizen). As a result, public income independent explanatory variables to estimate CO2 emis-
awareness of environmental degradation rises and suitable envir- sions. Results show that the inclusion of trade variables raises
onmental regulations are imposed on the economy. substantially the turning point of an EKC. Industrializing countries
The crucial question is whether economic growth leads to a increase the consumption of energy required for the production of
more equitable income distribution or increases income inequal- goods that are exported to industrialized countries and reversely,
ity. According to Torras and Boyce (1998) pollution is abated or industrialized countries lower their energy requirements due to
generated depending on the gap of power between those (agents) imports of manufactured goods from the industrializing countries.
who bear the burden of pollution against those (agents) who It is possible however that the overall result of the PHH on the
benefit from pollution. However, the power of each part is a reduction of pollution is small (Grossman and Krueger, 1995).
function of income distribution. That is to say, if income inequality Considering ten air and water pollutants and four developed-
worsens when income rises, then the environment will keep developing trade-partners, Cole (2004) concludes that there is
deteriorating, and vice versa, because those who suffer from little evidence that pollution havens exist. In an extended Cole's
pollution will not be in (economic) position to impose environ- model by Kearsley and Riddel (2010), authors again do not find
mental regulations on those who benefit from pollution. There- sufficient evidence that the PHH is a strong explanation of a
fore, the demand for environmental protection is determined by possible EKC-pattern. Trade possibly contributes to increased
the improved participation of the people who bear the burden of emissions at a decreasing rate as income rises, but only over
pollution that results from a more equitable income distribution, certain periods of time (Panayotou et al., 2000). Or, pollution
better information access and education (Bimonte, 2002). havens may have a transient effect on environmental degradation
Empirical estimations confirm a significant effect of income (Aldy, 2005) similar to the effect of low-wage havens on the
equality on pollution abatement in certain countries or regions. pattern of comparative advantage (Mani and Wheeler, 1998).
Magnani (2000) uses data on OECD countries from 1980 to 1991 Statistical evidence indicates significant differences in traded
and results indicate that income equality raises expenditure on goods between developing and developed countries. For instance,
research for environmental protection. Therefore, the downward highly polluting industries are typical of the poorest states in USA,
slope of an EKC may emerge in high-income countries if and only if, while high-income states are oriented towards services and high-tech
economic growth does not lead to a “large” increase in income industries (Stern, 1998). Therefore, the trade-specialization between
inequality (Magnani, 2000:442). A similar conclusion is reached by these states may explain the variations in their emissions (Stern,
Bimonte (2002) who uses a sample of countries being at the last 1998). Usually, the industrialization process in developing countries is
stage of economic development. According to the author, the based upon polluting industries and at the same time, developing
participation of the agents in the growth process depends on countries account for a steadily increasing proportion in world output in
income inequality, information access and education and acts as a many of the most highly polluting industries (Perrings and Ansuategi,
shifter translating the EKC upward or downward (Bimonte, 2000). Moreover, the net emissions transfers from developing to
2002:152). This can explain why some economies that are at the developed countries have increased from 0.4 Gt of CO2 emissions in
same level of economic growth have different levels of environ- 1990 to 1.6 Gt of CO2 emissions in 2008 which implies that the
mental degradation (Bimonte, 2002). With respect to CO2 emis- transfer of emissions through international trade often exceeds the
sions and their relationship with inter-country income inequality, reduction of emissions at a single developed-country level (Peters
Coondoo and Dinda (2008) estimate an EKC-pattern in European et al., 2011). Concerning the effect of the cost of pollution abatement
countries. According to Cantore and Padillia (2010) there is a due to imposed environmental regulations on exports and imports,
robust correlation between income inequality and emissions Levinson and Taylor (2004) estimate that an 1% increase in the cost of
distribution and, possibly, the differences in GDP per capita pollution abatement in USA is associated with a 0.2% and 0.4%
between rich and poor regions are significant determinants of increase in net imports (or decrease in USA' net exports) from Mexico
emission distribution among countries. and Canada respectively (Levinson and Taylor, 2004).
A major limitation in examining the effect of income distribu- Contrary, in Kahn's study (2003), the trends in international trade
tion on environmental degradation is that there are few, or poor in in USA during the period 1958–1994 show no evidence that “dirty”
quality data that measure income inequality (Torras and Boyce, (pollution-intensive) trade has increased with the exception of the
1998). This makes hard to examine whether people's perception of African nation's exports to the USA which are considered as energy-
environmental degradation is significantly affected by their rela- intensive rather than pollution-intensive. In a similar study, the
tive position on the income distribution. Southern Africa Customs Union (SACU) may serve as a pollution
haven for USA and UK over time but there is a general shift of
4.2. International trade and the pollution haven hypothesis manufacturing from the latter to the former, which does not include
only the pollution-intensive industries (Nahman and Antrobus, 2005).
Many authors support that an EKC-pattern may appear as a result According to another study, USA have not substituted domestic
of international trade (Suri and Chapman, 1998; Cole, 2004; Kearsley pollution-intensive production for imports over the 1978–1994 per-
and Riddel, 2010). The main argument is that trade openness helps iod. Rather, value-added in the domestic manufacturing industry
the expansion of an economy through increased production of increases as a result of a rise in the number of less-polluting industries
(pollution-intensive) goods to support its exports. Yet, higher produc- and a reduction in tariff-barriers which eventually result in a
tion creates pollution. When income and environmental degradation compositional change in favor of dirtier industries in the USA
rise substantially, more severe environmental regulations are imposed (Ederington et al., 2004). In the European Union case, evidence
on the economy which results in a shift of its domestic production of provide mixed results: imports of energy-intensive goods from poorer
pollution-intensive goods to other, usually low-income countries that countries seem to increase when more stringent environmental
have less strict environmental legislation. This way, the exports of standards are applied in the EU, but this is not the case with respect
goods in a developed country generate the upward slope of its EKC, to toxic-intensive imports (Cave and Blomquist, 2008).
while, consequently, its imports of goods from developing countries
generate the downward slope of its EKC. This is reported the 4.3. Structural change and technical progress
“pollution haven hypothesis” (PHH) (Dinda, 2004).
Suri and Chapman (1998) use a model that includes ratios of Many authors support that two fundamental driving forces
imports, exports and total manufacturing in GDP as additional to of an EKC-pattern are structural changes and technical progress
1396 D. Kaika, E. Zervas / Energy Policy 62 (2013) 1392–1402

(Shafic and Bandyopadhyay, 1992; De Bruyn et al., 1998; Dinda 4.3.1. The effect of structural changes and technical progress in EKC-
et al., 2000; Hettige et al., 2000). Structural changes may include studies
the transition of the production process from the pollution- Advances in technology over time seem to be the major cause
intensive industry to the information-based service sector, which of improved environmental quality (Shafic and Bandyopadhyay,
is considered as less-polluting (Panayotou, 2003), or/and any other 1992). De Bruyn et al. (1998) use proper indicators reflecting
qualitative reformation of the economic structure. Technical pro- changes in the composition and technology and examine their
gress includes any improvement in the production techniques, effect on various indicators of emissions. The authors conclude
which result in less use of inputs or/and the adoption of less that emissions may have declined over time probably due to
polluting technologies in the production process of goods. technological and structural changes and not due to economic
At early stages of development, pollution is generated as a growth. Observed changes in pollution levels over time or across
result of increasing production and extraction of natural resources. region can be attributed to shifts in production techniques and to
This is called the scale effect of production on environment. sectoral-output composition with respect to SPM and SO2 (Dinda
Recalling Fig. 1, on the revised Fig. 2, the scale effect generates et al., 2000). Concerning industrial water pollution, Hettige et al.
the upward trend of an EKC when production shifts from primary (2000) use as explanatory variables the share of industry in total
production to industrial production. At this phase, economic output, the share of polluting sectors in industrial output and ‘the
development gives the opportunity of investing in information- end-of-pipe’ pollution intensities per unit of output in the pollut-
based industry and services as well as improving production ing sectors. According to their results, the share of industry in total
techniques or adopting cleaner technology. These are the called output alone follows an EKC-pattern.
the composition and technique effect respectively. Both effects can It is possible however, that structural and technological changes
overcome the scale effect and generate the downward trend of an may have a transient effect on pollution abatement (Pasche, 2002).
EKC curve (Dinda, 2004). Grossman and Krueger (1995) already point out that improvements
The composition effect is associated with shifts in production- in indicators of urban air quality may result from technological
patterns from the more material and energy-intensive manufac- innovation but this outcome reflects specific technological, political
turing sector towards the (assumingly) more environmentally- and economic conditions of the time under examination. In a similar
friendly services sector. Pollution is initially generated as the notion, an EKC-curve may reflect in the short-run the cycle of
composition of production shifts from light industry (agriculture diffusion-externality generation- innovation of each new technol-
or textile) to heavy industry (minerals, chemical, machinery etc.) ogy. In the long-run, a nonlinear EKC envelops a series of EKCs
but, subsequently, shifts towards information-based industries corresponding to different and subsequent technologies (Dinda,
and services which are less polluting (Panayotou, 2003). 2010).
The technique effect reflects improvements in technology that
allow the use of less inputs per unit of output or the adoption of
cleaner technologies that substitute the old and dirtier technolo-
gies in the production of goods. The development of cleaner 4.3.2. Energy intensity
techniques is encouraged by investments in environmental R&D Many studies emphasize the significant effect of technology
for which, a sufficient level of economic growth is required and structural changes on CO2 emissions over time (Lindmark,
(Neumayer, 1998). 2002; Kander, 2005; Lantz and Feng, 2006; Tol et al., 2009). The
It should be mentioned that both structural changes (composi- key factor for this outcome is the evolution of energy intensity
tion effect) and technical progress (technique effect) focus on the over time and particularly the shifts in energy mix and in
economic activity of production rather than that of consumption. conversion efficiency. Energy intensity emerged as a crucial matter
Moreover, the scale effect may depend on business-cycle fluctua- after the oil crises in the 1970s that gave rise to a general concern
tions while the composition and technique effect may operate about energy conservation. As a result, the structure of the oil-
more gradually (Bouvier, 2004). In addition, some authors indicate depended economies had to be transformed with the adoption of
that the market mechanisms, based upon the cost-criterion new techniques that would lower the energy-intensity per unit of
determine eventually whether a new technology, not necessarily output or/and the reinforcement of the service sector that is based
being the cleanest one, will be adopted (Smulders et al., 2010). on a lighter productive structure (Lindmark, 2002; Kander, 2005;
Tol et al., 2009).
When dealing with energy, most EKC-empirical studies indi-
cate a rather positive relationship among CO2 emissions, energy
and economic growth (Richmond and Kauffmann, 2006; Luzzati
and Orsini, 2009). This is attributed to the fact that energy
accompanies economic growth (Humphrey and Stanislaw, 1979;
Hamilton and Turton, 2002; Ang, 2007, 2008; Marrero, 2010)
while energy is based (mostly) on fossil fuels that are the
primary source of human-related CO2 emissions. However, redu-
cing energy consumption with the aim of reducing CO2 emissions
can have negative effects on economic growth (Chontanawat et al.,
2008).
The evolution of energy intensity depends on various factors
such as energy prices and energy mix (Asafu-Adjaye, 2000).
A large part of EKC-studies deals with these issues. For instance,
Agras and Chapman (1997, 1999) estimate energy prices as a
significant factor affecting both CO2 emissions and energy con-
sumption despite the fact that no EKC-pattern arises. The authors
place emphasis on the oil shocks in the 1970's that led to shifts in
the energy mix. Moomaw and Unruh (1997) draw a similar
Fig. 2. Scale, composition and technique effect on EKC. conclusion in 16 OECD countries.
D. Kaika, E. Zervas / Energy Policy 62 (2013) 1392–1402 1397

Stern (2004a) estimates that energy intensity per unit of output pattern (McConnell, 1997; Roca, 2003). The main question is how
has declined over time, but this is due, to a large extent, to a shift the consumer's preferences with respect to environmental quality
from the direct use of fossil fuels to the use of higher quality fuels shift when their income changes. That is to say, changes in income
and especially electricity. Such changes in fuel-mix are associated alter the elasticity of demand for environmental quality η which is
with technological innovations (Stern, 2004a; Turner and Hanley, defined as (Pearce, 2003):
2011). However, changes in energy intensity are not common in all ðΔEÞ% θE Y
countries. Hamilton and Turton (2002) estimate that the large fall η¼ ¼ ð2Þ
ðΔYÞ% θY E
in the energy intensity of OECD economies over 1982–1997 has been
driven primarily by falling energy intensities in the services and In Eq. (2), E is the quantity of environmental good demanded
industry sectors of the USA and the services sector of the EU, but these and Y is income. Therefore, the income elasticity of demand for
have been offset somewhat by rising energy intensity of services in environmental quality η is the change in the demanded quantity of
Japan (Hamilton and Turton, 2002:70). environmental
quality with respect to a change in income. If
η 4 1, then E is a luxury good and, if η o 1, E is a normal good.

4.4. Institutional framework and governance Most authors accept that η 4 1 treating clean environment and
preservation as “luxury” goods (Dinda, 2004). However, it is
A government's willingness to impose environmental regula- difficult to measure the quantity of environmental good
tions is cited as a crucial factor affecting environmental degrada- demanded. An alternative way is to measure the income elasticity
tion (Panayotou, 1997; Bhattarai and Hammig, 2001). The main of the Willingness to Pay (WTP), which accounts the change in the
speculation is that when an economy grows, its government is willingness to pay for some environmental quality in response to a
expected to respond properly to public awareness on environ- change in income. Most studies show that, while the income
mental degradation and to countervail market failures by impos- elasticity of demand on environmental quality is marginally over
ing suitable regulations that prevent further pollution from unit, the income elasticity of willingness to pay is less than unit
increasing. In view of this, the growth of an economy is an (Pearce, 2003).
essential condition to overcome pollution but it is not an adequate Kander and Lindmark (2004) estimate that environment in
condition alone: whether environmental quality improvements (or Sweden is appreciated at a higher value after the 1970s, which
reduced degradation) will materialize or not, when, and how, leads to deliberate action to prevent further pollution and as a
depends critically on government policies, social institutions and result, pollutants decrease. However, with respect to Italian house-
the completeness and functioning of markets (Panayotou, 1997). In hold's consumption expenditures, results indicate that the income
practice, however, it is difficult to accurately assess the effective- elasticity of the willingness to pay is close to unity for all income
ness or ineffectiveness of a country's governance or, in general, of groups implying that becoming richer does not necessarily leads to
its political institutions that would allow for a better estimation of cleaner environments (Martini and Tiezzi, 2010).
their impact on environmental degradation (Panayotou, 1997). Examining the microeconomic implications of consumer pre-
Some studies already estimate an EKC-pattern in some devel- ferences on the environment is a difficult and complicated task.
oped countries which are characterized by better governance, For instance, suitable preferences can always lead to an EKC-
stronger political institutions, better socioeconomic conditions pattern, but there is no guarantee that such suitable preferences
and greater investment in education (Dutt, 2009). Considering exist (Plassmann and Khanna, 2006). If consumers do not exercise
tropical deforestation, Bhattarai and Hammig (2001) estimate that enough environmental effort as they get richer, then, even the
institutional factors are more significant for the deforestation most sophisticated and effective abatement technologies cannot
process than income or other macroeconomic conditions. How- prevent pollution from increasing. Furthermore, it is difficult to
ever, the institutional development is a time-consuming process predict the effect of a shift in consumers' preferences, because
but stronger regulation is one of the keys to reduce pollution such shift may depend on various spatial and time conditions
(Dasgupta et al., 2002). Economic growth provides the necessary (Plassmann and Khanna, 2006). For example, inhabitants of a city
tools to enforce environmental activities and public authorities may not need concern themselves with the negative health effects
have the legal mandate to collect information on pollution that of a waste treatment installation located in a sparsely populated
allow local communities to set higher environmental standards area, or across a great distance, or generally, when the cost of
(Dasgupta et al., 2002). pollution can be transferred to a remote future. In such cases, the
Nevertheless, as a rule, the governments are elected for a inhabitants have few incentives to alter their consumption pat-
limited period. This fact may deter a government, due to the terns, unless they sincerely worry about the effects of environ-
potential political cost, from imposing environmental regulations mental degradation to others (Roca, 2003; Khanna and Plassmann,
that would protect the environment from market failures that 2004).
generate long-term externalities (pollution) (Ansuategi and On the whole, different preferences shape different consump-
Escapa, 2002). In addition, when the political system is highly tion-patterns, which, in turn, need different abatement policies,
corrupted or less effective, then the agent's willingness to improve while the recognition of an environmental problem takes a long
environmental quality will not be noticed by their governments time (Kander and Lindmark, 2004; Cantore, 2010). Even when
because corruption affects the economic growth process (Leitao, such a problem is realized, the undertaken actions depend on the
2010). Similarly, if governmental institutions are weaker, less utility of the agents, their relative economic position and their
effective and/or more corrupted, then a possible EKC-curve may spatial ability to separate themselves from the source of pollution
peak at higher income levels, well above the social optimal income (Roca, 2003). Above all, the income–pollution issue is a macro-
level (Lopez and Mitra, 2000). In poor countries, however, economic subject and any microeconomic foundations of this
improved governance and/or policy reform are sufficient condi- relationship, although helpful and meaningful, are hard to be
tions to reverse this outcome (Dasgupta et al., 2006). analyzed in a sufficient way (McConnell, 1997).

4.5. Consumers' preferences 5. EKC for CO2 emissions

Some EKC studies focus on the microeconomic implications of Empirical EKC-studies analyze various indicators of environ-
consumer preferences as a partial explanation of an inverted-U mental degradation such as air quality indicators (SO2, SPM, NOX,
1398 D. Kaika, E. Zervas / Energy Policy 62 (2013) 1392–1402

Table 1
EKC studies on CO2 emissions.

Authors (year) Sample Results (income) Other significant parameters/notes

Shafic and Bandyopadhyay  149 countries ↗


(1992)  1960–1990
 Panel data

Holtz-Eakin and Selden  130 countries ↗ Forecasts: ↗


(1995)  1951–1986
 Panel data

Roberts and Grimes (1997)  Low-medium-high income countries \ rich countries Social-political factors
 1962–1991 ↗ low/medium income countries PHH

Carson et al. (1997)  US states \


 1990
 Cross-sectional data

Lim (1997)  South Korea ↗


 1980s onwards
 Time series

Moomaw and Unruh  16 industrial OECD countries N Oil price shocks


(1997)  1950–1992
 Panel data

Schmalensee et al. (1998)  141 countries \ Forecasts: ↗


 1950–1990
 Panel data

De Bruyn et al. (1998)  Netherlands, W.Germany, UK, USA ↗ Population


 1960–1993 intervals Technology
 Time series Structural changes

Galeotti and Lanza (1999)  110 countries \ Population/forecasts: ↗


 1970–1996
 Panel data

Agras and Chapman  34 countries ↗ Energy prices (oil shocks)


(1999)  Various years
 Panel data

Borghesi (2000)  126 countries ↗ Income inequality


 1988–1995
 Panel data

Perrings and Ansuategi  114 countries ↗ Share of agriculture in GDP (negatively)


(2000)  1990
 Panel data

Panayotou et al. (2000)  17 developed countries \ panel data Over time, different driving force of EKC
 1870–1994 \ US, UK with time series
 Panel data and time series

Azomahou and van Phu  100 countries ↗


(2001)  1960–1996
 Panel data

Dijkgraaf and Vollebergh  24 OECD countries \ panel data Rejection of homogeneity using panel data
(2001)  1960–1997 \ time series: 5 countries
 Panel data and Time series

Egli (2002)  Germany No conclusion


 1966–1998
 Time series
D. Kaika, E. Zervas / Energy Policy 62 (2013) 1392–1402 1399

Table 1 (continued )

Authors (year) Sample Results (income) Other significant parameters/notes

Lindmark (2002)  Sweden \ Technological and structural changes (nuclear


 1870–1997 power)
 Time series

Pauli (2003)  29 OECD countries No common EKC:


 1970–1998 \ 12 countries
 Panel data ↗ 2 countries
↘ 7 countries
No conclusion: 8 countries

Friedl and Getzner (2003)  Austria N PHH


 1960–1999 Share of tertiary sector in GDP
 Time series

Cole (2004)  21 countries \ PHH


 1980–1997
 Panel data

Aldy (2005)  USA states \ In few states Emissions-intensive trade


 1960–1999 ↗ (consumption model) Climate conditions
 Panel data Historic coal endowments

Azomahou et al. (2006)  100 countries ↗


 1960–1996
 Panel data

Richmond and Kaufmann  36 countries ↗ Fuel mix/limited support of a turning point in


(2006)  1973–1997 OECD countries
 Panel data

Lantz and Feng (2006)  Canada (five regions) No significant relationship \ population
 1970–2000 [ technology
 Panel data

Kunnas and Myllyntaous  Finland ↗


(2007)  1800–2003
 Time series

Coondoo and Dinda (2008)  88 countries \ only for Europe Inter-country income inequality
 1960–1990 ↗ for whole
 Panel data

Lee et al. (2009)  89 countries N for the whole panel PHH


 1960–2000 \ in middle income, American and
 Panel data European countries

Aslanidis and Iranzo  1971–1997 ↗


(2009)  77 Non-OECD countries
 Panel data

Dutt (2009)  1960–2002 ↗ 1960–1980 Governance


 124 countries \ 1984–2002 Political institutions
 Panel data Socioeconomic conditions
Education

Halicioglu (2009)  Turkey ↗ Energy consumption


 Time series Foreign trade
 1960–2005

Jalil and Mahmud (2009)  China \ Energy consumption


 1971–2005
 Time series
1400 D. Kaika, E. Zervas / Energy Policy 62 (2013) 1392–1402

Table 1 (continued )

Authors (year) Sample Results (income) Other significant parameters/notes

Narayan and Narayan  43 developing countries \ in 15 countries (time series)


(2010)  1980–2004 \ in Middle Eastern and South Asia panels
 Panel data and Time series

Acararci and Ozturk (2010)  19 Europe countries \ in 2 countries Energy consumption


 1960–2005
 Time series

Iwata et al. (2011)  28 countries (17 OECD, 11 non-OECD ↗ Nuclear power


countries)
 1960–2003
 Panel data

Jaunky (2011)  36 high-income countries \ in 5 countries


 1980–2005 ↗ for whole panel
 Panel data

CO, lead, VOC and CO2), water quality indicators (pathogens, heavy significance of these causes may explain adequately or partially a
metals, water oxygen regime) and various other environmental possible EKC-pattern.
indicators such as access to safe drinking water, municipal solid In fact, the EKC literature is quite large, and results are at best
wastes, deforestation etc (Dinda, 2004). The collection and mea- mixed. A large part of studies that deal with CO2 emissions,
sure of the relevant data calls into question their reliability and indicate that the process of economic growth is not reducing such
comparability (Lieb, 2003). emissions over time, thought that CO2 emissions are related with
As part of current issues concerning climate change and the economic growth through energy consumption.
over accumulation of greenhouse gases, many studies examine the
relationship between CO2 emissions, the most prominent green-
house gas, and economic growth. Whether economic growth can References
have a positive impact on CO2 emissions is a matter for debate.
Results seem at best mixed but in most cases, CO2 emissions tend Acaravci, A., Ozturk, I., 2010. On the relationship between energy consumption, CO2
to rise monotonically as income grows. That is to say, no EKC- emissions and economic growth in Europe. Energy 35, 5412–5420.
Agras, J., Chapman, D., 1997. Is there an Environmental Kuznets Curve for energy?
pattern arises with respect to CO2 emissions. An explanation for An econometric analysis. Working paper 97-07.
this is the fact that CO2 emissions are related with energy use Agras, J., Chapman, D., 1999. A dynamic approach to the Environmental Kuznets
which is essential for economic growth. In addition, CO2 emissions Curve hypothesis. Ecological Economics 28, 267–277.
Aldy, J.E., 2005. An Environmental Kuznets Curve analysis of U.S. state-level carbon
do not have local and recognizable effects on the environment dioxide emissions. The Journal of Environment Development 14, 48–72.
(Arrow et al., 1995; Ansuategi and Escapa, 2002). Ang, J.B., 2007. CO2 emissions, energy consumption, and output in France. Energy
Table 1 summarizes some EKC-studies that deal with CO2 Policy 35, 4772–4778.
Ang, J.B., 2008. Economic development, pollutant emissions and energy consump-
emissions. Depending on the analysis used (cross-country or tion in Malaysia. Journal of Policy Modeling 30, 271–278.
time-series) and on the period under examination there seems Ansuategi, A., Escapa, M., 2002. Economic growth and greenhouse gas emissions.
to be conflicting results. Even studies that examine the EKC- Ecological Economics 40, 23–37.
Arrow, K., Bolin, B., Costanza, R., Dasgupta, P., Folke, C., Holling, C.S., Jansson, B-O.,
hypothesis both on individual country-level and on group
Levin, S., Maler, K-G., Perrings, C., Pimentel, D., 1995. Economic growth,
country-level provide contradicting outcomes. carrying capacity, and the environment. Ecological Economics 15, 91–95.
Asafu-Adjaye, J., 2000. The relationship between energy consumption, energy
prices and economic growth: time series evidence from Asian developing
countries. Energy Economics 22, 615–625.
6. Conclusions Aslanidis, N., Iranzo, S., 2009. Environment and development: is there a Kuznets
curve for CO2 emissions? Applied Economics 41, 803–810.
The EKC concept shifts the main subject from the exhaustion of Azomahou, T., Van Phu, N., 2001. Economic growth and CO2 emissions: a nonpara-
metric approach. Available from: 〈http:/www.beta-umr7522.fr/productions/
natural resources to issues related with the necessity of economic publications/2001/2001-01.pdf〉.
growth to overcome environmental problems. According to the Azomahou, T., Laisney, F., Van Phu, N., 2006. Economic development and CO2
EKC-hypothesis, further economic growth is expected to overcome emissions: a nonparametric panel approach. Journal of Public Economics 90,
1347–1363.
the environmental degradation occurred in earlier phases of Beckerman, W., 1992. Economic growth and the environment: whose growth?
development and suggests that the relationship between income Whose environment?. World Development 20, 481–496.
(economic growth) and environmental degradation takes the form Bhattarai, M., Hammig, M., 2001. Institutions and the Environmental Kuznets Curve
for deforestation: a cross-country analysis for Latin America, Africa and Asia.
of an inverted U. World Development 29 (6), 995–1010.
Many studies attempt to test this hypothesis using various Bimonte, S., 2002. Information access, income distribution, and the Environmental
indicators of environmental degradation, while a large part of Kuznets Curve. Ecological Economics 41, 145–156.
Borghesi, S., 2000. Income Inequality and the Environmental Kuznets Curve.
studies attempts to examine the significance of other than income
Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei, Milan, Italy. (Nota di Lavoro 83.2000).
factors that may lead to an EKC-pattern. Such factors are the Bouvier, R.A., 2004. Air Pollution and Per Capita Income: a Disaggregation of the
international trade (pollution haven hypothesis), the equity of Effects of Scale, Sectoral Composition, and Technological Change. Political
income distribution, the structural changes, technical progress Economy Research Institute, Working Paper Series, 84.
Brock, W.A., Taylor, M.S., 2004. Economic Growth and the Environment: a Review of
and improvements in energy efficiency, the institutional frame- Theory and Empirics. NBER Working Paper Series, w.p. 10854. Available from:
work and governance and, finally, consumers' preferences. The 〈http:/www.nber.org/papers/w10854〉.
D. Kaika, E. Zervas / Energy Policy 62 (2013) 1392–1402 1401

Cantore, N., 2010. Social preferences and Environmental Kuznets Curve in climate Kunnas, J., Myllyntaus, T., 2007. The Environmental Kuznets Curve hypothesis and
change integrated assessment modelling. International Journal of Global air pollution in Finland. Scandinavian Economic History Review 55 (2),
Environmental Issues 10 (½), 123–142. 101–127.
Cantore, N., Padilla, E., 2010. Equality and CO2 emissions distribution in climate Kuznets, S., 1955. Economic growth and income inequality. American Economic
change integrated assessment modelling. Energy 35, 298–313. Review 45, 1–28.
Carson, R.T., Jeon, Y., McCubbin, D.R., 1997. The relationship between air pollution Lantz, V., Feng, Q., 2006. Assessing income, population, and technology impacts on
emissions and income: US Data. Environment and Development Economics 2, CO2 emissions in Canada: Where’s the EKC? Ecological Economics 57, 229–238.
433–450. Lee, C-C., Chiu, Y-B., Sun, C-H., 2009. Does one size fit all? A reexamination of the
Cave, L.A., Blomquist, G.C., 2008. Environmental policy in the European Union: fostering Environmental Kuznets Curve using the dynamic panel data approach. Review
the development of pollution havens? Ecological Economics 65, 253–261. of Agricultural Economics 31 (4), 751–778.
Chontanawat, J., Hunt, L.C., Pierse, R., 2008. Does energy consumption cause Leitao, A., 2010. Corruption and the Environmental Kuznets Curve: empirical
economic growth? Evidence from a systematic study of over 100 countries. evidence for sulphur. Ecological Economics 69, 2191–2201.
Journal of Policy Modeling 30, 209–220. Levinson, A., Taylor, M.S., 2004. Unmasking the Pollution Haven Effect. NBER
Cole, M.A., 2004. Trade, the pollution haven hypothesis and the Environmental Working Paper Series, working paper 10629.
Kuznets Curve: examining the linkages. Ecological Economics 48, 71–81. Lieb, C.M., 2003. The Environmental Kuznets Curve – a Survey of the Empirical
Coondoo, D., Dinda, S., 2008. Carbon dioxide emissions and income: a temporal evidence and of Possible Causes. University of Heidelberg – Department of
analysis of cross-country distributional patterns. Ecological Economics 65, Economics, Discussion Paper Series, no 391.
375–385. Lim, J., 1997. Economic Growth and Environment: Some Empirical Evidences from
Dasgupta, S., Laplante, B., Wang, H., Wheeler, D., 2002. Confronting the Environ- South Korea. Seoul Journal of Economics 10 (3), 273–292.
mental Kuznets Curve. Journal of Economic Perspectives 16 (1), 147–168. Lindmark, M., 2002. An EKC-pattern in historical perspective: carbon dioxide
(Winter). emissions, technology, fuel prices and growth in Sweden 1870–1997. Ecological
Dasgupta, S., Hamilton, K., Pandey, K.D., Wheeler, D., 2006. Environment during Economics 42, 333–347.
growth: accounting for governance and vulnerability. World Development 34 Lopez, R., Mitra, S., 2000. Corruption, pollution, and the Kuznets environment
(9), 1597–1611. curve. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 40, 137–150.
De Bruyn, S.M., van den Bergh, J.C.J.M., Opschoor, J.B., 1998. Economic growth and Luzzati, T., Orsini, M., 2009. Investigating the energy-Environmental Kuznets Curve.
emissions: reconsidering the empirical basis of Environmental Kuznets Curves. Energy 34, 291–300.
Ecological Economics 25, 161–175. Magnani, E., 2000. The Environmental Kuznets Curve, environmental protection
Dijkgraaf, E.,Vollebergh, H.R.J., 2001. A Note on Testing for Environmental Kuznets policy and income distribution. Ecological Economics 32, 431–443.
Curves with Panel Data. Available from: 〈http:/www.feem.it/web/activ/_activ. Mani, M., Wheeler, D., 1998. In search of pollution havens? Dirty industry in the
html〉. world economy. 1960–1995. Journal of Environment and Development 7 (3),
Dinda, S., Coondoo, D., Pal, M., 2000. Air quality and economic growth: an empirical 215–247.
study. Ecological Economics 34, 409–423. Marrero, G.A., 2010. Greenhouse gases emissions, growth and the energy mix in
Dinda, S., 2004. Environmental Kuznets Curve hypothesis: a survey. Ecological Europe. Energy Economics 32, 1356–1363.
Economics 49, 431–455. Martini, C., Tiezzi, S., 2010. Is the Environment a Luxury? An Empirical Investigation
Dinda, S., 2010. Environmental Kuznets Curve: an Envelope of Technological using Revealed Preferences and Household Production. Available from: 〈http:/
Progress. MPRA archive, paper no 28092. Available at: 〈http:/mpra.ub.uni-m www.econ-pol.unisi.it/quaderni/599.pdf〉.
uenchen.de/28092〉. McConnell, K.E., 1997. Income and the demand for environmental quality. Envir-
Dutt, K., 2009. Governance, institutions and the environment-income relationship: onment and Development Economics 2, 383–399.
a cross-country study. Environment, Development and Sustainability 11, Moomaw, W.R., Unruh, G.C., 1997. Are Environmental Kuznets Curves misleading
705–723. us? The case of CO2 emissions. Environment and Development Economics 2,
Ederington, J., Levinson, A., Minier, J., 2004. Trade Liberalization and Pollution 451–463.
Havens. Nber Working Paper Series, Working Paper 10585. Available from: Nahman, A., Antrobus, G., 2005. Trade and the Environmental Kuznets Curve: is
〈www.nber.org/papers/w10585〉. Southern Africa a pollution haven? South African Journal of Economics 73 (4),
Egli, H., 2002. Are Cross-Country Studies of the Environmental Kuznets Curve 803–814.
Misleading? New Evidence from Time Series Data for Germany. Fondazione Eni Narayan, P-K., Narayan, S., 2010. Carbon dioxide emissions and economic growth:
Enrico Mattei, Milan, Italy. (Nota di Lavoro 25.2002). panel data evidence from developing countries. Energy Policy 38, 661–666.
Ekins, P., 1993. ‘Limits to Growth’ and ‘Sustainable Development’: grappling with Neumayer, E., 1998. Is economic growth the environment's best friend? Zeitschrift
ecological realities. Ecological Economics 8, 269–288. für Umweltpolitik und Umweltrecht (Journal of Environmental Law and Policy)
Friedl, B., Getzner, M., 2003. Determinants of CO2 emissions in a small open 2/98, 161–176.
economy. Ecological Economics 45, 133–148. Panayotou, T., 1997. Demystifying the Environmental Kuznets Curve: turning a
Galeotti, M., Lanza, A., 1999. Richer and cleaner? A study on carbon dioxide black box into a policy tool. Environment and Development Economics 2,
emissions in developing countries. Energy Policy 27, 565–573. 465–484.
Grossman, G.M., Krueger, A.B., 1995. Economic growth and the environment. The Panayotou, T., Peterson, A., Sachs, J., 2000, August. Is the Environmental Kuznets
Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (2), 353–377. Curve driven by Structural Change? What Extended Time Series May Imply for
Halicioglu, F., 2009. An econometric study of CO2 emissions, energy consumption, Developing Countries? CAER II Discussion Paper no. 80.
income and foreign trade in Turkey. Energy Policy 37, 1156–1164. Panayotou, T., 2003. Economic Growth and the Environment 2003. Economic
Hamilton, C., Turton, H., 2002. Determinants of emissions growth in OECD Survey of Europe: UNECE, vol. no. 2; . ([chapter 2]).
countries. Energy Policy 30, 63–71. Pasche, M., 2002. Technical progress, structural change and the Environmental
Hettige, H., Mani, M., Wheeler, D., 2000. Industrial pollution in economic develop- Kuznets Curve. Ecological Economics 42, 381–389.
ment: the Environmental Kuznets Curve revisited. Journal of Development Pauli, F., 2003, December. Environmental Kuznet Curve Investigation Using a
Economics 62, 445–476. Varying Coefficient AR-Model. EEE Working Papers Series no.12.
Holtz-Eakin, D., Selden, T.M., 1995. Stoking the fires? CO2 emissions and economic Pearce, D., 2003, March. Conceptual Framework for Analysing the Distributive
growth. Journal of Public Economics 57, 85–101. Impacts of Environmental Policies. Prepared for the OECD Environment
Humphrey, W., Stanislaw, J., 1979. Economic Growth and Energy Consumption in Directorate Workshop on the Distribution of Benefits and Costs of Environ-
the UK, 1700–1975. Energy Policy 7, 29–43. mental Policies, Paris.
Iwata, H., Okada, K., Samreth, S., 2011. A note on the Environmental Kuznets Curve Perrings, C., Ansuategi, A., 2000. Sustainability, growth and development. Journal of
for CO2: a pooled mean group approach. Applied Energy 88, 1986–1996. Economic Studies 27 (1/2), 19–54.
Jalil, A., Mahmud, S.F., 2009. Environment Kuznets curve for CO2 emissions: a Peters, G.P., Minx, J.C., Weber, C.L., Edenhofer, O., 2011, 25April. Growth in Emission
cointegration analysis for China. Energy Policy 37, 5167–5172. Transfers via International Trade from 1990 to 2008. doi: 10.1073/
Jaunky, V.C., 2011. The CO2 emissions-income nexus: evidence from rich countries. pnas.1006388108 PNAS.
Energy Policy 39, 1228–1240. Plassmann, F., Khanna, N., 2006. Preferences, Technology, and the Environment:
Kahn, M.E., 2003. The geography of US pollution intensive trade: evidence from Understanding the Environmental Kuznets Curve Hypothesis. Economics
1958 to 1994. Regional Science and Urban Economics 33, 383–400. Department Working Paper 0313.
Kaika, D., Zervas, E., 2013. The Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC) theory. Part B: critical Richmond, A.K., Kaufmann, R.K., 2006. Is there a turning point in the relationship
issues. Energy Policy. (http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2013.07.130, this issue). between income and energy use and/or carbon emissions? Ecological Econom-
Kander, A., Lindmark, M., 2004. Energy consumption, pollutant emissions and ics 56, 176–189.
growth in the long run: Sweden through 200 years. European Review of Roberts, J.T., Grimes, R., 1997. Carbon intensity and economic development 1962–
Economic History 8, 297–335. 91: a brief exploration of the Environmental Kuznets Curve. World Develop-
Kander, A., 2005. Baumol's disease and dematerialization of the economy. Ecolo- ment 25 (2), 191–198.
gical Economics 55, 119–130. Roca, J., 2003. Do individual preferences explain the Environmental Kuznets Curve?
Kearsley, A., Riddel, M., 2010. A further inquiry into the pollution haven hypothesis Ecological Economics 45, 3–10.
and the Environmental Kuznets Curve. Ecological Economics 69, 905–919. Schmalensee, R., Stoker, T.M., Judson, R.A., 1998. World carbon dioxide emissions:
Khanna, N., Plassmann, F., 2004. The demand for environmental quality and the 1950–2050. The Review of Economics and Statistics 80, 15–27.
Environmental Kuznets Curve hypothesis. Ecological Economics 51, 225–236. Selden, T., Song, D., 1994. Environmental quality and development: is there a
Klassen, G.A.J., Opschoor, J.B., 1991. Economics of sustainability or the sustainability Kuznets curve for air pollution emissions? Journal of Environmental Economics
of economics: different paradigms. Ecological Economics 4, 93–115. and Management 27 (2), 147–162.
1402 D. Kaika, E. Zervas / Energy Policy 62 (2013) 1392–1402

Shafic, N., Bandyopadhyay, S., 1992. Economic Growth and Environmental Quality. Suri, V., Chapman, D., 1998. Economic growth, trade and energy: implications for
Time-series and Cross Country Evidence. Policy Research Working Paper no. the Environmental Kuznets Curve. Ecological Economics 25, 195–208.
904, World Development Report 1992, The World Bank. Tahvonen, O., 2000. Economic Sustainability and Scarcity of Natural Resources: A
Smulders, S., Bretschger, L., Egli, H., 2010. Economic Growth and the Diffusion of brief historical review. Resources for the Future. Available from: 〈www.rff.org〉.
Clean Technologies: Explaining Environmental Kuznets Curves. Environ Tol, R.S.J, Pacala, S.W., Socolow, R.H., 2009. Understanding long-term energy use
Resource Econ. doi: 10.1007/s10640-010-9425-y. and carbon dioxide emissions in the USA. Journal of Policy Modeling 31,
Stern, D.I., 1998. Progress on the Environmental Kuznets Curve? Environment and 425–445.
Development Economics 3, 173–196. Torras, M., Boyce, J.K., 1998. Income, inequality, and pollution: a reassessment of the
Stern, D.I., 2004a. Energy and economic growth. In: Cleveland, CJ (Ed.), Encyclope- environmental Kuznets Curve. Ecological Economics 25, 147–160.
dia of Energy. Academic Press, San Diego CA, pp. 35–51. Turner, K., Hanley, N., 2011. Energy efficiency, rebound effects and the Environ-
Stern, D.I., 2004b. The rise and fall of the Environmental Kuznets Curve. World mental Kuznets Curve. Energy Economics 33, 709–720.
Development 32 (8), 1419–1439.

You might also like