You are on page 1of 13

J Bus Ethics (2014) 124:173–184

DOI 10.1007/s10551-013-1862-4

The Curious Case of Corporate Tax Avoidance:


Is it Socially Irresponsible?
Grahame R. Dowling

Received: 6 February 2013 / Accepted: 2 August 2013 / Published online: 17 August 2013
Ó Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht 2013

Abstract In contrast to many aspects of the social after the global financial crisis many commentators called
responsibility of business, CSR scholarship has been lar- for more social responsibility to be delivered by Corporate
gely silent on the issue of the payment of corporate tax. America. While movements like Occupy Wall Street had a
This is curious because such tax payments are often con- somewhat confused message about the reforms they wan-
sidered a fundamental and easily measured example of a ted, they made it clear that the current financial system did
company’s citizenship behavior. However, because the not work for large sections of society. The overriding
payment of corporate tax can often be legally avoided, this sentiment was that many large corporations had let down
activity represents a boundary condition for CSR. If the law the government and major parts of the societies in which
and CSR suggest that a company should pay its fair share they operate.
of tax, yet many successful companies actively avoid this At the heart of this feeling is a debate about the nature of
social obligation, should they be considered socially irre- the social responsibility of business. While most people
sponsible. This paper explores the issue of tax avoidance believe that companies should sell products and services
and the implications it has for any credible definition and that people want, provide employment, make returns to
measure of CSR. It also highlights an aspect of corporate shareholders, and operate within the law, there is dis-
practice that is deliberately hidden from public view. agreement about whether this range of activities should be
voluntarily expanded (Kemper and Martin 2010). Not-
Keywords Tax avoidance  Law  CSR  Business withstanding these disagreements, most descriptions of
ethics CSR and codes of good business conduct include the
requirement that corporations should abide by the laws of
the land in which they operate (e.g., Carroll 1979; Paine
Introduction et al. 2005). Some even suggest that companies exceed
their minimal legal requirements (Davis 1973; McWilliams
As the twenty-first century gathers pace the clamor for and Siegel 2001). But what does this boundary condition
business enterprises to be socially responsible shows no really mean for the CSR activities of a corporation? Does it
sign of abating. In fact, a sophisticated corporate social mean that abiding by the letter of the law is not enough?
responsibility (CSR) industry has developed to research, Must a company be seen to abide by some fuzzy notion of
report about, offer advice, and sanction this endeavor. And the spirit of the law? For example, should it pay more tax
than it is required to? This paper explores this distinction
with respect to the payment of federal corporate income
tax.
Interest in the relationship between the tax paying
behavior of companies and CSR comes from two obser-
G. R. Dowling (&)
vations. The first was made by Christensen and Murphy
Marketing Discipline Group, University of Technology, Sydney,
Broadway, Ultimo, NSW 2007, Australia (2004) who note that most of the CSR industry has con-
e-mail: Grahame.Dowling@uts.edu.au sistently avoided the issue of the role of these payments in

123
174 G. R. Dowling

the fulfillment of a company’s social responsibility. Also, minimization1) or illegal (termed tax evasion). Hereafter I
in other scholarly literatures such as accounting, econom- use the single term tax avoidance because this is what the
ics, tax practice, and public policy (see for example, Bra- authors of the cases reported below are focusing on.
ithwaite 2003; Erle et al. 2004; Schön 2008), corporate tax Another motivation for this paper is that the widespread
paying behavior is seldom linked directly to CSR. It has practice of tax avoidance sits uncomfortably with much of
only been in recent years that this topic has come to public the moral rhetoric in many corporate codes of conduct and
prominence because of some parliamentary inquiries in the pronouncements by advocates of social responsibility. What
UK and the US and investigative journalism in both is curious about this situation is that most of the web sites of
countries. Its global importance was signaled by being the companies noted below proudly proclaim their social
included on the agendas of the G8 and G20 conferences in responsibility yet they have been found to actively avoid
2013. paying corporate tax. While they presumably see no
The second observation is that the lack of discussion hypocrisy in this behavior, even The Economist newspaper
about the nexus between the payment of corporate tax and has recently labeled the practice of massive tax avoidance as
the socially responsible practices of companies exposes a ‘‘inexcusable’’ (Charlemagne 2013). In contrast, the com-
weakness in many definitions and measures of CSR. From panies and their professional tax advisers that actively avoid
this perspective tax payments can be considered a clear tax see this activity as part of the financial responsibility of
measure of the direct financial contribution a company the company (Erle et al. 2004). And as noted below, some
makes to an elected government. Because there are few well-respected US companies are winning handsome
other such monetary measures of CSR available, it is financial rewards from their expertise in avoiding tax.
curious that so few scholars and advocates of CSR have In the next section I present evidence as to the state of
examined these transfer payments. While this is not an easy tax avoidance by major US companies. Following this I
task, scrutiny of corporate tax practices raises some focus on the relationship between tax payments and so-
uncomfortable questions about the integrity of many defi- called socially responsible corporate behavior.
nitions of CSR.
To frame the issues discussed here I pose the following
question. ‘‘If a company does not pay corporate tax on its The Corporate Tax Game2
profits, should it be regarded as socially irresponsible?’’ As
noted below, the significance of this question emerges Nearly all discussion of CSR suggests that companies
because most of the money ‘‘lost’’ from tax avoidance is a should abide by the law. Within the CSR context this
direct financial transfer from society to the company’s requirement can be interpreted in at least three ways. These
shareholders. It is unclear how much of this money ulti- range across a spectrum of independence between the
mately enters the government’s revenue through the taxa- notion of ‘‘abiding by the spirit of the law’’ and ‘‘abiding
tion of these individuals. And because tax avoidance is a by the letter of the law.’’ The chosen interpretation will
legal activity, it exposes the ambiguity of what is meant by help to consider whether companies that avoid tax are
the simple statement that companies should ‘‘abide by the socially irresponsible. Consider the following options:
law.’’ Here, we need to be clear about the distinction
(A) There is a popular and political understanding of the
between what is meant by abiding by the letter of the law
spirit of the law. Thus, if legislation stipulates that
and the spirit of the law. This situation poses a challenge to
companies are required to pay tax on their accounting
a crucial aspect of modern thinking about CSR and gov-
profits, then all profitable companies are expected to
ernment fiscal and social policy (e.g., Carroll 1991, 1999;
pay such tax. The spirit of the law is that companies
Palazzo and Richter 2005).
owe a financial return to the State. The letter of the
The question of the social irresponsibility of business
law stipulates what are considered to be accounting
stands regardless of the difficulty in estimating the tax
profits and the rate of tax payable on such profits.
liability of corporations (Hanlon 2003). This difficulty
(B) The letter of the law is contained in a statute and
arises because the combined complexity of financial
various regulations. These are then interpreted by an
reporting and tax law provides ample scope for tax plan-
ning arrangements that often result in multinational cor-
1
porations paying ‘‘only as much tax as the choose,’’ as one Tax minimization is defined as looking for ways to minimize the
European Union diplomat put it (Charlemagne 2013). Such tax bill in relation to transactions usually undertaken, whereas tax
avoidance is defined as transactions entered into solely for the
arrangements are often contested by the tax authorities and
purpose of generating a tax benefit (Bowler 2009, Para. 2.5).
have recently raised the ire of some social commentators. 2
I use the word ‘‘game’’ for two reasons. First, tax specialists often
The question also stands regardless of whether the non- refer to their activities as ‘‘gaming the system.’’ Second, some
payment of tax is legal (termed tax avoidance and tax theories of tax evasion are couched in terms of game theory.

123
174 G. R. Dowling

the fulfillment of a company’s social responsibility. Also, minimization1) or illegal (termed tax evasion). Hereafter I
in other scholarly literatures such as accounting, econom- use the single term tax avoidance because this is what the
ics, tax practice, and public policy (see for example, Bra- authors of the cases reported below are focusing on.
ithwaite 2003; Erle et al. 2004; Schön 2008), corporate tax Another motivation for this paper is that the widespread
paying behavior is seldom linked directly to CSR. It has practice of tax avoidance sits uncomfortably with much of
only been in recent years that this topic has come to public the moral rhetoric in many corporate codes of conduct and
prominence because of some parliamentary inquiries in the pronouncements by advocates of social responsibility. What
UK and the US and investigative journalism in both is curious about this situation is that most of the web sites of
countries. Its global importance was signaled by being the companies noted below proudly proclaim their social
included on the agendas of the G8 and G20 conferences in responsibility yet they have been found to actively avoid
2013. paying corporate tax. While they presumably see no
The second observation is that the lack of discussion hypocrisy in this behavior, even The Economist newspaper
about the nexus between the payment of corporate tax and has recently labeled the practice of massive tax avoidance as
the socially responsible practices of companies exposes a ‘‘inexcusable’’ (Charlemagne 2013). In contrast, the com-
weakness in many definitions and measures of CSR. From panies and their professional tax advisers that actively avoid
this perspective tax payments can be considered a clear tax see this activity as part of the financial responsibility of
measure of the direct financial contribution a company the company (Erle et al. 2004). And as noted below, some
makes to an elected government. Because there are few well-respected US companies are winning handsome
other such monetary measures of CSR available, it is financial rewards from their expertise in avoiding tax.
curious that so few scholars and advocates of CSR have In the next section I present evidence as to the state of
examined these transfer payments. While this is not an easy tax avoidance by major US companies. Following this I
task, scrutiny of corporate tax practices raises some focus on the relationship between tax payments and so-
uncomfortable questions about the integrity of many defi- called socially responsible corporate behavior.
nitions of CSR.
To frame the issues discussed here I pose the following
question. ‘‘If a company does not pay corporate tax on its The Corporate Tax Game2
profits, should it be regarded as socially irresponsible?’’ As
noted below, the significance of this question emerges Nearly all discussion of CSR suggests that companies
because most of the money ‘‘lost’’ from tax avoidance is a should abide by the law. Within the CSR context this
direct financial transfer from society to the company’s requirement can be interpreted in at least three ways. These
shareholders. It is unclear how much of this money ulti- range across a spectrum of independence between the
mately enters the government’s revenue through the taxa- notion of ‘‘abiding by the spirit of the law’’ and ‘‘abiding
tion of these individuals. And because tax avoidance is a by the letter of the law.’’ The chosen interpretation will
legal activity, it exposes the ambiguity of what is meant by help to consider whether companies that avoid tax are
the simple statement that companies should ‘‘abide by the socially irresponsible. Consider the following options:
law.’’ Here, we need to be clear about the distinction
(A) There is a popular and political understanding of the
between what is meant by abiding by the letter of the law
spirit of the law. Thus, if legislation stipulates that
and the spirit of the law. This situation poses a challenge to
companies are required to pay tax on their accounting
a crucial aspect of modern thinking about CSR and gov-
profits, then all profitable companies are expected to
ernment fiscal and social policy (e.g., Carroll 1991, 1999;
pay such tax. The spirit of the law is that companies
Palazzo and Richter 2005).
owe a financial return to the State. The letter of the
The question of the social irresponsibility of business
law stipulates what are considered to be accounting
stands regardless of the difficulty in estimating the tax
profits and the rate of tax payable on such profits.
liability of corporations (Hanlon 2003). This difficulty
(B) The letter of the law is contained in a statute and
arises because the combined complexity of financial
various regulations. These are then interpreted by an
reporting and tax law provides ample scope for tax plan-
ning arrangements that often result in multinational cor-
1
porations paying ‘‘only as much tax as the choose,’’ as one Tax minimization is defined as looking for ways to minimize the
European Union diplomat put it (Charlemagne 2013). Such tax bill in relation to transactions usually undertaken, whereas tax
avoidance is defined as transactions entered into solely for the
arrangements are often contested by the tax authorities and
purpose of generating a tax benefit (Bowler 2009, Para. 2.5).
have recently raised the ire of some social commentators. 2
I use the word ‘‘game’’ for two reasons. First, tax specialists often
The question also stands regardless of whether the non- refer to their activities as ‘‘gaming the system.’’ Second, some
payment of tax is legal (termed tax avoidance and tax theories of tax evasion are couched in terms of game theory.

123
The Curious Case of Corporate Tax Avoidance 175

agency such as the IRS in the US. This agency this leads to illegal tax evasion. In most cases it leads to
divines the spirit of the law (i.e., its intention) from legal tax avoidance. What is a fair share of tax is defined by
its preamble, explanatory memoranda, and the set of the probability of being apprehended and the penalties for
principles used to design the legislation. In the case avoidance or evasion. In essence, Interpretation C is legal
of corporate tax practice these are written for the and game theoretic by nature.
entities that are charged with administering and Commentary in the popular press suggests that many
complying with the law. It is a mistake to confound citizens and politicians consider that Interpretation A
this ‘‘spirit’’ with one based on contemporary popular should prevail. Here companies (and people) should pay
or political sentiment. their fair share of tax so that these payments can help fund
(C) There is no spirit of the law independent of the the provision of public goods (schools, defense, health
language of the law. Both the spirit and intent are care, etc.) and welfare. This position can be justified from
bound together in the words used in the legislation. an ethical standpoint (McGee 2006; Preuss 2012). It is also
When there are ambiguities in the language they will finding its way into various voluntary Codes of Corporate
be resolved by construing the plain meaning of the Conduct. For example, after reviewing a variety of these
words in the context of the law and by court written by people who represent business and others who
decisions. represent different sectors of society, Paine et al. (2005)
found general agreement for the principle that companies
Interpretation A can be grounded in social norm theory
should pay tax. From all the codes surveyed the authors
which would suggest that tax avoidance is not considered
then formed an overarching ‘‘codex’’—a set of governing
to be right and just from a general public point of view
principles to guide business conduct. Included in their
because it imposes costs on society (e.g., Elster 1989). It
citizenship principle is the statement that companies should
also captures the principle of ‘‘giving back.’’ Companies
‘‘adhere to the letter and spirit of tax laws and make timely
have an obligation to structure their affairs in such a way as
payments of tax liabilities.’’
not to avoid paying a ‘‘fair share’’ of tax on their profits to
Interpretations B and C involve what is called ‘‘rules
the State. This behavior is guided by the ethics and moral
lawyering’’ or ‘‘creative compliance’’ (Freedman 2010).
compass of the company and implemented through its
This involves exploiting the complexity, technicalities, and
corporate governance principles. Here a fair share of tax is
loopholes in the law, which in the case of the UK and US
defined by the statutory rate of tax at the time on a rea-
tax codes is considerable. Legal tax avoidance may also
sonable estimate of the company’s profits, that is, its tax
involve what accountants politely call ‘‘creative tax
base. What is considered to be ‘‘fair’’ may be conditioned
accounting’’ or ‘‘earnings management.’’ Here they exer-
by the tax regime imposed on individuals and small busi-
cise their discretion over the accounting numbers without
nesses that have little room to legally avoid tax. What this
violating generally accepted accounting principles. The
means in practice is that because most individuals can not
aim is to reduce to a minimum the company’s tax base.
avoid tax many think that large companies should not be
A quote by a tax partner at one of the UK’s larger
allowed to do this. In essence, Interpretation A is social by
accountancy firms sums up the essential nature of the game
nature.
of tax avoidance.
Interpretation B captures the principle of ‘‘negotiated
settlement.’’ Here, the company and the designated No matter what legislation is in place, the accountants
administrative authority come to a series of agreements as and lawyers will find a way around it. Rules are rules,
to what constitutes a fair tax burden. Settlements are on a but rules are meant to be broken. (Finch 2004)
case-by-case basis and the settlement process is of a private
Tax avoidance is most prevalent among multinational
nature. Both these conditions have been the source of
companies because their multiple locations allow them to
disquiet with tax specialists, legal experts, and social
organize their affairs to realize profits in countries with the
commentators. In essence, Interpretation B is political and
most favorable tax regimes. Bowler (2009) notes that tax
expedient by nature.
avoidance occurs to the degree that it does because of the
Interpretation C captures the principle of ‘‘taking from.’’
complexity of the current tax legislation and administration
Here, the State is perceived to be extracting economic rents
within a country and across the countries in which multi-
from wealth producing corporate entities. Proponents of
national companies operate. The key issue here is whether
this interpretation sometimes hark back to medieval times
the payment of tax should occur in the country where value
when Monarchs and Churches extracted taxes from their
is created or the profit is actually earned or in the jurisdiction
subjects to fund their nefarious activities. From this per-
that has the lowest tax rate. Social responsibility suggests the
spective tax avoidance is seen as a legitimate contest with
former while financial responsibility suggests the latter.
the authorities by any means available. In extreme cases

123
176 G. R. Dowling

Corporations that actively practice tax avoidance sub- billion. Also, the US Congressional Research Service
scribe to a view that different country tax rates are a form (Keightley 2013) published a report showing evidence of
of healthy competition among countries to attract multi- massive tax avoidance by US companies through the use of
national corporations. They also argue that tax is an tax havens. Because even the tax authorities have trouble
expense to be minimized. This is a fiduciary responsibility calculating the revenue lost to tax avoidance these numbers
to shareholders. Here, ‘‘fair share’’ means using all must be regarded as speculative. Notwithstanding this
allowable deductions to minimize the tax base by actively uncertainty there is widespread agreement in the business
organizing the company’s affairs to receive the maximum and financial press that this amount is substantial. For
deductions offered in various jurisdictions. This view of tax example, the Guardian and the Financial Times newspapers
liability runs counter to the view that tax should be paid in the UK have run a series of articles and blogs on this
primarily where value is created or where transactions issue, the overwhelming tone of which is negative. Thus
occur. Under this interpretation a US multinational com- the public policy issue is that tax avoidance undermines the
pany should pay tax in the US as a return to the State for tax base of the US and other countries where it is widely
the use and protection of its securities laws. The same practiced. To further characterize the nature of this prob-
company should pay tax in the countries in which it lem the following information is informative.
operates as recompense for the use of their public services.
However in practice, many US companies artificially Who Does not Pay Tax?
realize their profits overseas and then leave them there to
avoid paying tax in the US (Gongloff 2012). Most contemporary tax avoidance schemes are derived
from Stigliz’s (1985) basic principles of tax avoidance,
The Cost of Tax Avoidance namely, the postponement of taxes, and tax arbitrage across
different types of income and tax entities. For many
By any estimate the corporate tax codes of many large modern multinational companies, these principles motivate
industrialized countries like the UK and US are extremely them to create what Kleinbard (2011) calls ‘‘stateless
complex. Adding to this is the complexity of cross-country income.’’ This is the movement of taxable income within a
taxation agreements. Then there is the complexity of multinational group from high-tax to low-tax countries
modern accounting practice. Finally there is the private without shifting the location of externally supplied capital
nature of company negotiations with the tax authorities. In or productive activities. In effect, profit is subject to tax in
combination, all these factors make it almost impossible a jurisdiction that is not directly related to where transac-
for a member of the general public to understand whether tions occur, value is created or where the company is
or not a company pays its fair share of tax. domiciled.
Within this regime there are five types of costs and Some common practices for tax avoidance are offshore
inefficiencies created when companies vigorously practice tax sheltering, accounting manipulation, and legal obfus-
tax avoidance. One is that as tax authorities try to counter cation. Offshore tax sheltering (aka profit laundering, tax
clever tax avoidance practices new regulations and opin- arbitrage, and the use of tax havens) is the practice of using
ions get added to the tax code. While the aim of these is to artificial transactions to shift revenue to low-tax countries
produce more certainty, the result is a more convoluted tax while recognizing expenses in high-tax countries. For
system. This leads to the next issue, namely, that as cor- example, eBay uses Luxembourg as a tax haven for its UK
porate compliance costs grow so do the administration operations (Moulds 2012). Accounting manipulation
costs of the authorities. For example, the IRS has perma- involves practices like transfer pricing, charging royalties,
nent offices in two Hewlett-Packard facilities and has been making administrative payments, and using revolving
continually auditing H–P since 1962 (Gongloff 2012). short-term loans between head office and subsidiaries to
The legalized nature of tax avoidance encourages the minimize profits. For example, on similar sales revenues in
formation of two industries that are designed to exploit the the UK for 2010–2011, Costa paid an effective tax rate of
system. One is composed of lobbyists. The other is com- 30.5 % while Starbucks rate was 0 % (Ebrahimi 2012).
posed of tax specialists who are often located inside large Legal obfuscation is the practice of overwhelming the
corporations and accounting firms. For example, Sikka authorities with complicated paperwork. For example, the
(2004) reports that in 1 year Enron paid $88 million in fees 2009–2010 tax return of General Electric (GE) was 57,000
to its tax advisers to avoid paying $2 billion in US taxes. (electronic) pages in length (McCormack 2011).
The fifth cost is lost government revenue. Kocieniewski One question is whether the companies cited above are
(2011b) and Sikka (2003) estimate that tax avoidance costs the exception or the rule? A report produced by McIntyre
the US federal government between $50 and $170 billion et al. (2011) suggests that gross tax avoidance by US
annually. Clausing (2011) reports estimates of $57–$90 companies is widespread. For example, they identified 78

123
The Curious Case of Corporate Tax Avoidance 177

profitable companies that paid zero federal income tax or during 2008–2010 14 had a 3-year average effective tax
less in at least 1 year during the period 2008–2010. This rate just above the statutory corporate rate of 35 %. In total
report stimulated the interest of a number of investigative 25 % had an effective tax rate of more than 30 %; 35 %
journalists. In 2011–2012 high-profile companies like had a rate of between 17.5 and 30 %; and 40 % had a rate
Amazon, Apple, Bank of America, Boeing, Cadbury, of \17.5 %. In the top group were companies like Best
Chevron, eBay, Exxon Mobil, Google, IKEA, Microsoft, Buy, Harley-Davidson, Hershey, Home Depot, Humana,
News Corporation, Hewlett-Packard, and Starbucks have Radio Shack, Sealed Air, St Jude Medical, and Walmart.
all received bad publicity about their tax practices. How- It is interesting to contrast GE’s record of tax payments
ever, GE has been signaled out as the Poster Child of US with those of the so-called ‘‘vice company’’ Altria Group,
tax avoidance practice. previously known as Philip Morris. The company’s 2010
In a pivotal article published in The New York Times, Responsibility Report notes that Altria paid excise tax
David Kocieniewski (2011a) highlights the skill with payments on the production for sale of cigarettes of $32.7
which GE plays the tax avoidance game.3 Based on a billion; a further $10.2 billion in other charges, and $1.4
review of GE’s statutory company filings he reports that billion of federal income tax (McIntyre et al. 2011).
during 2009–2010 GE made world-wide profits of $14.2 Depending on how the calculations are made this amount
billion of which $5.1 billion was made in the US. After of corporate tax represents an effective tax rate of 26.2 %
submitting its 57,000 page tax return the company paid no (McIntyre et al. 2011) or 31.7 % (Altria corporate website)
tax in the US. It also made a claim for a potential reduction in 2010. Few US companies make such a huge financial
of its future tax liability of $3.2 billion. While Kocie- contribution to government revenue. These figures, and
niewski’s interpretation of these figures was not indepen- similar ones in the past, suggest that the government relies
dently verified, GE did not provide any other estimates to heavily on direct corporate and ‘‘social’’ taxes from Altria
counter them. Group and the other vice companies.
As subsequent news commentary about this episode
revealed (e.g., Helman 2011), GE achieved this position
through a wide variety of legal tax avoidance schemes. In Tax Payments and Social Reputation
the business community GE’s tax department, which
employed 975 people at that time, gained a reputation for The recent publicity about the tax practices of many large
being ‘‘the world’s best tax law firm’’ (Kocieniewski corporations raises the interesting question of whether
2011a). Inside GE the tax department is the company’s best these practices might affect the social reputations of the
performing profit center. During this period GE also paid companies exposed. Many CSR advocates would suggest
$41.8 million for lobbying and political campaign contri- that it does or should. However, public relations people
butions (Anderson et al. 2011). might suggest that it will depend on what people know and
Because large, well-respected companies are role mod- what they value. For example, for smokers Altria’s social
els in the economy and society, and because the amounts of reputation might be considered to be good. For people who
money involved in tax avoidance are not trivial, this issue are indifferent to smoking the tax payments of Altria might
speaks to the heart of modern notions of CSR. And the offset some of the negative health effects of its products.
sanctity of CSR is not helped by academic studies like the For non-smokers, no amount of financial restitution might
one done by Prior et al. (2008) which found that companies offset the health effects caused by tobacco. Similar com-
that engage in accounting practices to lower their tax base ments would apply to other vice companies. In the case of
were also more likely to use CSR activities to deflect the GE many business people seem to agree with its behavior.
attention and potential criticism of non-shareholders from Also, many business academics would not consider that it
these accounting activities. Together, the results of these is socially unacceptable to legally minimize corporate tax.
and other similar investigations have surprised many pol- The perspective here is that this is an issue of financial not
iticians and members of the general public. social responsibility. In effect, these two responsibilities
are deemed to be separate and should be neither con-
Who Does Pay Tax? founded nor confused.
Reputation scholars believe that reputations are groun-
As one would expect most US companies do pay tax on ded in what people know about an organization (Dowling
their profits. For example, McIntyre et al.’s (2011) study and Gardberg 2012). The tax issue here is informative. I
found that of the 280 major US companies they studied would venture to say that the tax payments of most big
companies are not widely known. The reasoning here is
3
In April, 2012 he was awarded a Pulitzer Prize for this explanatory that because companies tend to report their tax obligations
journalism. in obscure ways in their annual reports, as Hanlon (2003)

123
178 G. R. Dowling

illustrates it takes a tax expert to figure out what tax has 2003, p. 369). It scores a company across seven different
been, and is likely to be paid in any tax year. Also, while social screens, each of which is composed of multiple
many companies claim that they are transparent in their items where the company’s ‘‘strengths’’ and ‘‘concerns’’
values, Paine et al. (2005) found that most corporate codes in the area offset each other to form an overall score.
of conduct rarely discuss tax obligations. Researchers often combine these sub-scores (sum or
Many companies like GE have done a good job of average) to provide an overall score of social perfor-
deflecting attention away from some potentially negative mance. In effect, CSP is measured here in a compensatory
aspects of their social reputations by promoting other manner.
aspects of it. For example, GE has launched a major pro- What is noteworthy about these and most other measures
gram called ‘‘ecomagination’’—described as ‘‘a commit- of CSR is that they are silent about the issues raised in this
ment to imagine and build innovative solutions to today’s paper. Neither the measures nor their underlying definitions
environmental challenges while driving economic growth’’ articulate which interpretation (A, B, or C) of abiding by the
(GE website. Accessed 2 July 2013). This program has law is operable, and whether or not the company is expected
been well publicized. It might now help to deflect attention to pay a fair share of tax on its profits. They are also silent
from the recent negative publicity about its tax affairs. about the decision calculus used by people to form an overall
evaluation of social responsibility (Yani-de-Soriano et al.
2012). For these reasons I suggest that much of the scholarly
Definitions and Measures of CSR and public rhetoric about CSR conceptualizes it in terms of a
number of broad ranging citizenship behaviors but measures
An important research question linked to how people form these with some notable omissions.
their social reputation of a company is how should CSR be To extend the examination of whether tax avoidance is
defined and measured? Devinney (2009) notes the confusion socially irresponsible I pursue four lines of inquiry, some
in the scholarly literature about exactly what is meant by of which are outside the traditional domain of CSR
CSR and its offspring corporate social performance (CSP). scholarship. The first focuses on the ethics and morals of
Notwithstanding this confusion a key issue is whether tax avoidance. The two terms are considered as synony-
scholars, companies, and members of the general public mous in the corporate context. This line of inquiry turns out
consider the payment of corporate tax as a fundamental to be unhelpful. The next is socio-economic in nature. Here
aspect of CSR. And if so, how would each group assess the I outline many of the common arguments for and against
importance of this activity in relation to other aspects of tax avoidance. This exposes some of the fundamental
CSR? One way to assess these questions is to examine how contradictions about the social and financial roles of paying
CSR is actually measured. Two commonly used measures corporate tax. The third is political in nature. It focuses on
are illustrative. One assumes that people will not make trade- tax avoidance as a political issue and a technical issue of
offs across elements of CSR while the other assumes they do. corporate law. The last line of inquiry is principles based.
Given that both are used to assess the CSR profile of com- Here the set of principles of a modern tax system is used to
panies and predict the responses of the same types of people highlight how the social responsibility or not of tax
to these companies both are unlikely to be valid. avoidance hinges on which principles one adheres to.
Consider the case of social investment funds. To be
included in such a fund the company must be perceived as
socially responsible. Thus, in order to avoid including a The Morality of Tax Avoidance
company that is not socially responsible many fund man-
agers employ a non-compensatory approach that screens The problem with assessing the tax paying behaviors of
out companies with clear socially undesirable attributes companies through the lens of ethics and morality is that it
from their social investment funds. For example, if a relies on a definition of CSR and the establishment of a set
company makes products or is involved in activities that of moral principles against which to judge this definition.
harm people it is excluded. A variation on this approach is As noted earlier, the definitional landscape of CSR is a
to include or exclude companies from a fund based on a morass. I would suggest that the landscape of moral rea-
single surrogate indicator of corporate responsibility. For soning is even more complex. Thus, it should not be a
example, a company might be automatically included if it surprise to discover that an analysis of the ethics of tax
engages in philanthropy or automatically excluded if it is avoidance illustrates how a persuasive case can be made
involved in an environmental disaster. for or against this behavior, either from religious scriptures
Now consider the measure of CSP developed by KLD or from the ethical theories of political philosophers
Research & Analytics. This measure has become ‘‘the de (McGee 2006). However, what is somewhat surprising is
facto research standard’’ in scholarly research (Waddock the strength of the arguments that can be mounted for the

123
The Curious Case of Corporate Tax Avoidance 179

case that tax is legalized theft by a government and the case where corporate citizenship is most tangible and most
that it is the rightful appropriation of funds to run an important. He aggressively supports the view that paying
elected government. This state of affairs suggests that there tax is a prime social responsibility of the modern corpo-
is likely to be little agreement between the moral advocates ration. His view is supported by others (e.g., Avi-Yonah
and opponents of tax avoidance. 2008; Devinney 2009; Klinger et al. 2011; Lanis and
Another perspective on tax morality is to consider Richardson 2012; Paine et al. 2005; Preuss 2012; Sikka
whether or not the two issues should be related. This line of 2011). The tax legislation in some countries like Australia
argument suggests that some people will consider the also supports this view. It provides for the authorities to
payment of corporate tax as a moral issue (it is the right determine if schemes or arrangements that are used are
thing to do) while others will see it as amoral (they are substantive (i.e., they create business value) or whether
unaware of, or indifferent to, or they separate it from right they are merely of a form to artificially lower the tax base
or wrong), and still others will see it as immoral (they are (Gilders et al. 2004). This type of provision is known as a
actively opposed to paying tax). This perspective suggests general anti-avoidance rule. It authorizes the tax authorities
that people who disapprove of tax avoidance think that this and the courts to vault substance over form.
is a moral issue because paying tax is the right thing to do While the case against tax avoidance is based on various
and because to do otherwise shifts the burden of tax from combinations of the following ideas Devinney (2009) notes
companies to others. In contrast, many tax specialists and that although they sound noble, they are often difficult to
multinational companies that practice tax avoidance sug- operationalize.
gest that it is amoral. There is no morality in tax and no
1. If a company is viewed as an entity of the State with
immorality in tax avoidance. However, for those compa-
certain privileges granted by the State (the ‘‘artificial
nies that practice illegal tax evasion this might be consid-
entity view’’ of the firm) then paying corporate tax is
ered as immoral if one accepts the premise that the laws of
one way of fulfilling its obligations to the State (Avi-
the land reflect the social norms of society.
Yonah 2008).
Scanning the literature suggests that CSR advocates are
2. If companies avoid paying tax then the State may not
trying to use the basic moral principles of justice (and thus
have enough money to fulfill even its exclusive social
fairness) and beneficence (helping yourself and others) to
obligations (such as defense and the judiciary).
frame many business issues. Tax avoidance fits neatly into
3. A company can not be deemed to practice an ethical
this genre. Recently this group has been aided and abetted
approach to doing business if it does not pay tax, and is
by the media who have reported corporate tax practice and
not transparent about its tax practices.
provided a platform to publicize the moral stance of some
4. The non-payment of corporate tax shifts the tax burden
groups about tax avoidance. If tax avoidance can be effec-
to other less mobile and often less well off tax payers.
tively framed as immoral it may motivate governments to
Thus, it promotes social inequality and undermines
restrict the various avenues available to its practitioners.
public confidence in the tax law.
Within the business community there is resistance to
5. Tax avoidance demands complexity and obfuscation to
framing corporate tax and its avoidance as a moral issue.
avoid detection. Such non-transparent behavior can
For example, Will Morris the director of global tax policy
easily hide managerial opportunism.
at GE and head of the Business and Industry Advisory
6. The tax havens and accounting schemes used by
Committee lobby group recently framed the issue as one of
companies to avoid tax are also used for corrupt
‘‘cross-border trade and investment.’’ Chas Roy-Chowdh-
practices such as money laundering, hiding corruptly
ury, head of taxation at the Association of Chartered Cer-
obtained assets, and evading sanction.
tified Accountants framed tax as ‘‘another cost to the
business’’ and tax management as a part of competition Opponents of tax avoidance suggest that these argu-
(Bergin 2013). These are amoral perspectives. The tug of ments provide a compelling case for government policy to
war between framing tax avoidance as a moral or amoral stop these practices. Yet so far this has not eventuated. It is
issue may ultimately be determined by the revenue difficult to overturn an entrenched business practice and as
requirements of various governments. outlined next there are some persuasive arguments in favor
of tax avoidance.

The Case Against Tax Avoidance: Social


Irresponsibility The Case for Tax Avoidance: Financial Responsibility

Christensen (Christensen and Murphy 2004; Christensen Explanations and arguments that have been advanced for
2011) argues that the payment of corporate tax is the area tax avoidance are:

123
180 G. R. Dowling

1. As the various cases noted above testify, it is hugely potential damage to the company’s social reputation,
profitable. And for big companies it is easy to do. For financial payments to advisers, internal administrative
example, there is a vigorous industry of tax advisers costs, and penalties for violations (Erle et al. 2004).
who promote numerous schemes to avoid tax. Also, However, there is a subtle problem with the logic of this
because many other companies engage in this practice view. It is revealed by accounting convention in the Profit
any company that does not trades at a financial & Loss statement reported in the annual report (Christen-
discount to its peers. Finally, when executive managers sen 2011). Here a company’s tax liability is shown after net
are paid in share options or are encouraged to own profit as a distribution to government just like the main
shares in the corporation they have a personal incen- distributions to shareholders (dividends) and the company
tive to maximize after-tax profits. For example, Lanis (retained earnings). Thus, the financial accounts treat tax as
and Richardson (2011) have found a positive relation- a social distribution, not a cost.
ship between the share ownership of board members The next section explores further the issue of tax
and the tax aggressiveness of their companies. avoidance as a political (public law) issue. I then develop
2. The payment of tax reduces the company’s wealth some principles against which tax avoidance can be judged.
generating activities and thus its ability to deliver some
of its basic corporate social responsibilities. For
example, it may employ fewer people and have less
Tax Avoidance as a Political Issue
money to invest in research and development.
3. There is a widespread social aversion to paying any
Governments have the right to levy taxes. And for a host of
form of tax. This is evidenced by the fact that few
political and economic reasons most countries tax compa-
people pay more tax than they are required to even
nies as well as labor and expenditure. Once this decision
though this is an option on the personal income tax
has been made there is a political imperative for companies
returns of some countries. These attitudes are consis-
to pay a ‘‘fair share’’ of tax, both in appearance and sub-
tent with the hypothesis that the emotion of paying a
stance. The evidence of tax avoidance presented earlier
tax is negative while the emotion of giving a similar
directly challenges the US and UK governments’ compe-
amount is positive (e.g., Kahneman and Tversky
tence in claiming such a quantum of revenue and regulating
1979). Thus, the payment of tax is not viewed as
this mandated aspect of corporate behavior. This in turn
socially responsible in the way that other CSR
has prompted some politicians and social commentators to
activities are. There is mixed empirical evidence about
proclaim immoral behavior on the part of the offending
this view (e.g., Davis et al. 2012; Lanis and Richardson
companies. As noted earlier, the irony here is that this is a
2011; Watson 2011).
problem largely of a government’s own making. It is hard
4. If a company is viewed as an aggregate of its
to find any politician, tax expert, or business person that
individual members (the ‘‘aggregate’’ or ‘‘nexus of
disagrees with the proposition that the current tax systems
contracts’’ view of the firm) then unless paying tax and
of the US and the UK are far too complex for their own
other forms of CSR contributes directly to the
good.
economic viability of the company they are an
The complex jurisprudence (legislation, administration,
illegitimate attempt by managers to defraud share-
and compliance) of taxation reflects a mosaic of the poli-
holders (Avi-Yonah 2008). This view of the firm was
cies and ideologies of successive governments designed to
made famous by Friedman (1970). It has since
build up the State and promote the public good. In this
received favor amongst many economic and corporate
context the anti-tax avoidance provisions embedded in this
governance academics.
system support revenue capture and reinforce these various
5. The level of tax avoidance is a signal to government
governments’ visions of society. Thus, tax law fits firmly
not to abuse its monopoly tax raising power. Also, the
within the realm of politics. And tax avoidance is a direct
various statutory rates of tax are signals by countries of
challenge to the host government of companies that prac-
their desire to host multinational companies.
tice this art form. Governments however have to be careful
In the scholarly literature, it is the nexus of contracts how they respond to this challenge because in international
view of the firm that provides most corporate governance markets where companies can move freely, two responses
support for tax avoidance. Here tax is assumed to be an are evident. One is that companies organize their activities
expense, albeit one that is governed by a complex set of so that realized losses occur in high-tax countries and
laws and regulations that provide ample opportunity to profits in low-tax countries. The other is that foreign gov-
exploit. Thus, tax avoidance becomes a simple cost–benefit ernments poach the tax paying companies of another
calculation. The benefits are financial. The costs are country. This is the political economy context that fosters

123
The Curious Case of Corporate Tax Avoidance 181

the use of many forms of tax avoidance and the estab- point is chosen frames much of the discussion of tax
lishment of tax havens. avoidance. For example, if the statutory rate is thought to
The issue highlighted by the existence of international be fair and/or the minimum payable then any effective tax
tax avoidance schemes is that of ‘‘tax sovereignty,’’ rate less than this may be considered by some people as a
namely, the ability of a government to use its tax law to loss to society. Kahneman (2011, Chap. 28) suggests that
regulate companies and get them to help fund its social most members of society think that the exploitation of
objectives. Snape (2007) suggests that tax sovereignty market power (say by a large company) that imposes a loss
ultimately rests on the credibility of the government to set on others (by shifting the tax burden to other groups) will
appropriate rules for corporate taxation, administer the tax be judged to be morally unacceptable.
system fairly and efficiently, and to spend revenues wisely. As noted earlier, in practice few large US companies
Often there is disagreement between the State and Corpo- pay at or above the current statutory rate of tax. This state
rate America (Australia, Britain, Canada, etc.) about all the of affairs has arisen because of the active role of the tax
elements of this trinity. It might well be that the level of tax authorities. Through their negotiations with large compa-
avoidance is a measure of the level of trust and confidence nies, the use of litigation or the threat thereof, and the use
in the tax system and the government. In a low-trust of no-fault penalties, they effectively determine whether a
environment it encourages the governors of corporations to company’s tax payments are fair. In a very complicated
frame tax avoidance as a legal activity that is controlled in environment this might be an efficient system. However, it
contestable fashion, that is, Interpretations B and C earlier. leaves the tax authorities open to being accused of setting
This framing discounts the social and political conse- an inappropriate standard and/or abusing their power.
quences of tax avoidance. While companies can seek a direct remedy through the
The current tax environment presents politicians, tax courts for any such lapse, society can not.
authorities, and companies with a political dilemma. While As the proceeding discussion illustrates the question of
companies and the authorities would be better off using a the social irresponsibility or otherwise of significant tax
low-cost, relationship style of engagement, neither side can avoidance is difficult to answer. This occurs because there
really trust the other not to shirk on their responsibilities. are conflicting points of view and it is problematic that all
However, it is unclear whether either the fear of financial the necessary information is readily available to politicians,
penalty from the tax authorities and reputation damage social commentators and many lay people. To try to bring
from this exposure or the internal motivation to be seen as a more structure to this debate I will outline a set of tax
respectful member of society is sufficient to produce an principles that speak to the broad notion of tax avoidance.
outcome where companies are seen to pay their fair share Such principles can be used to help antagonists recognize
of tax (Schön 2008). And when politicians enter the tax common ground and the fundamental aspects of their
debate, ideology tends to focus attention on the relative disagreement.
burden of taxes among all tax paying entities (called ver-
tical equity) and the distribution from these taxes across
sectors of society. What joins these two party-political A Principles-Based View of Tax Avoidance
issues is the question of ‘‘What is a company’s ‘fair share’
of tax?’’ The fact is that tax avoidance is a well-established practice
One part of the answer to this question focuses on how among most large corporations. To explore whether it
the tax base of a company is calculated. The calculation of might be considered as socially irresponsible I examine
profit is governed by generally accepted accounting prin- some tax design principles that underpin many modern tax
ciples and other specific abatements, incentives, and systems. These are also related to contemporary ideas
deductions noted in the tax regulations of the time. This is about CSR. From a legal standpoint these principles are the
an opaque world that few people other than accountants intuitive parliamentary intention of a State’s tax legislation
and tax experts understand. As such, it is largely ignored in as understood by someone familiar with the context of
debates about fairness and compliance. Rather these business taxation. They are statements about the intended
debates tend to focus on what is more visible, namely, the outcomes of the legislation. Their aim is to guide taxpay-
government’s statutory rate of tax. ers, governments, tax authorities and CSR scholars and
In any socio-political debate about the social responsi- practitioners.
bility of tax avoidance the statutory rate of tax plays a Within a legal context these principles are not meant to
special role. It becomes a mental reference point against introduce any moral element into tax law (Freedman 2010),
which actual tax payments are evaluated. This reference however, in the context of CSR avoiding any moral eval-
point can be considered as fair and equitable or the mini- uation is almost impossible to achieve. Their interpretation
mum or maximum that should be paid. Which reference also provides an interesting window into the tension

123
182 G. R. Dowling

between Interpretations A, B, and C of the letter and the effectively pay the amount of tax it chooses. This choice
spirit of the tax law. They are described in Table 1. focuses attention on the issue of whether corporate tax is
The origin of the principles-based approach to examin- largely at the discretion of the company or whether it is a
ing and designing tax systems is credited to Smith (1776). State responsibility to collect what it deems to be its ‘‘fair
His ‘‘cannons of taxation’’ for an ideal tax system were share.’’ In the latter case it puts responsibly back on the
fourfold, namely, proportionality (i.e., people should con- State to redesign its corporate tax system to make it more
tribute in proportion to their respective abilities), certainty efficient and effective. In the former case it requires many
(tax payments should not be arbitrary), convenience of large companies to state if corporate tax is a prime deliv-
payment, and efficiency (economy in collection). Alley and erable of their CSR.
Bentley (2005) note that the number of times these prin- The ten principles also highlight the issue of how they
ciples are referred to by tax scholars suggests that they are might be combined to provide a framework to guide the tax
still relevant today. They have also been expanded to paying behavior of companies. Also, should they be used
accommodate the contemporary political environment. For by the tax authorities? Should some be given more
example, the tax system should not diminish economic importance than others? If so, does this depend on the
efficiency; it should be transparent and easy to understand; current circumstances of the company, the economy, or the
it should be fair in its procedures, and it should promote country? In the field of scholarship the issue is if and how
economic welfare by dealing with externalities which arise they might be used to redefine CSR and develop better
when people or organizations do not take account of the measures of the construct. More research is needed to
effects of their actions on others (Mirrlees 2011). explore these issues.
Principles 1–6 and 10 have a positive social responsi- What seems evident at this stage is that the value laden
bility theme; number 9 is counter to these, while principles nature of the principles will trigger some interesting dis-
7 and 8 focus on efficiency. The tension between principle cussion about tax avoidance. What is also interesting is
9 and the pro-social principles hinges on whether a mul- whether the recent public scrutiny by the fourth estate will
tinational company should exercise its current option to have any meaningful affect on the tax avoidance practices

Table 1 Common tax principles


Principle Explanation/policy outcome Relationship to CSR

1. Revenue adequacy It is a fundamental prerogative of the State to raise Because companies rely on these services, they
revenue through taxation to fund public services should pay tax to support their provision
2. Jurisdiction Parliament has decreed that companies pay tax on Thus, paying corporate tax is not contestable
their profits
3. Ability-to-pay Companies are taxed on their profit This social contribution will not put the survival of
the company at risk
4. Sovereignty A company earns taxable income where it creates Company tax should be shared among the countries
and captures value and where it is domiciled in which it relies on public services and
institutions to support its operations
5. Vertical equity While most of the overall tax burden falls on labor Every profitable company should pay its ‘fair share’
and consumers, some should fall on companies of tax
earning resource rents
6. Horizontal equity Companies earning the same amount of profit should When some companies choose to practice tax
pay the same amount of tax avoidance they pose an unfair burden on other tax
payers
7. Certainty The tax system should provide a degree of revenue Uncertainty undermines the revenue contribution
certainty for government and cost certainty for from business to government
business planning
8. Simplicity and The tax system should be as simple and transparent Complexity increases administrative and
transparency as possible compliance costs, and fosters avoidance
9. Tax avoidance Every company is entitled to order its affairs so that There is no obligation to forsake legal opportunities
it minimizes the amount of tax paid under the laws to minimize tax irrespective of the social return
of the land such tax might provide to the State
10. Tax evasion No company is entitled to deliberately violate the Breaking the law is prima facie evidence of poor
tax laws and regulations corporate citizenship
Primary Sources European Commission, Directorate—General Taxation and Customs Union, General Tax Principles (2004), Australian
Government Treasury—Principles for Business Tax Reform (2012), Alley and Bentley (2005), Mirrlees (2011), Duhigg and Kocieniewski (2012)

123
The Curious Case of Corporate Tax Avoidance 183

of companies or the behavior of the tax authorities. To date form of civil disobedience. An alternative perspective is
there is some tentative evidence that negative publicity that tax avoidance is a form of anti-democratic behavior.
surrounding corporate social behavior such as tax avoid-
ance may result in reputation damage and a change in the
behavior of the companies involved (e.g., Bednar et al.
2013). References

Alley, C., & Bentley, D. (2005). A remodeling of Adam Smith’s tax


design principles. http://epublications.bond.edu.au/law_pubs/45.
Conclusions Anderson, S., Collins, C., Klinger, S., & Pizzigati, S. (2011, August
31). The massive CEO rewards for tax dodging. The Institute for
Devinney (2009) suggests that companies will never be Policy Studies. Washington, DC.
Avi-Yonah, R. S. (2008). Corporate social responsibility and strategic
truly socially responsible by even the narrowest definitions tax behavior. In W. Schön (Ed.), Tax and corporate governance
of CSR. The reason is that they have many tradeoffs to (pp. 183–198). Berlin: Springer-Verlag. http://law.bepress.com/
make and these will never be Pareto optimal in the social umichlwps-olin/art65.
domain. Tax avoidance is one such trade off. The thesis of Bednar, M. K., Boivie, S., & Prince, N. R. (2013). Burr under the
saddle: How media coverage influences strategic change.
this paper is that by examining tradeoffs like this it is Organizational Science, 24(3), 910–925.
possible to test some of the foundational assumptions and Bergin, T. (2013). How big tech stays offline on tax. Reuters (23
boundary conditions of CSR. Here, the assumption is that July); Chicago Tribune (23 July); The Age (24 July).
all companies should abide by the law, and the boundary Bowler, T. (2009, February). Countering tax avoidance in the UK:
Which way forward? Institute for Fiscal Studies. Discussion
condition is where CSR theorists and practitioners would Paper No. 7.
draw the line between the ‘‘spirit’’ and the ‘‘letter’’ of the Braithwaite, V. (Ed.). (2003). Taxing democracy: Understanding tax
tax law. avoidance and evasion. Ashgate: Aldershot.
One reason why tax avoidance has not been on the main Carroll, A. B. (1979). A three-dimensional conceptual model of
corporate social performance. Academy of Management Review,
agenda of CSR scholars is that it is a background issue in 4(4), 497–505.
stakeholder theory which is one of the primary theories Carroll, A. B. (1991). The pyramid of corporate social responsibility:
underpinning this field of scholarship. For example, most Towards the moral management of organizational stakeholders.
advocates of stakeholder theory suggest that the three most Business Horizons, 34(4), 39–48.
Carroll, A. B. (1999). Corporate social responsibility: Evolution of
important groups are employees, customers, and investors. definitional construct. Business and Society, 38(3), 268–295.
Across these three groups tax avoidance has a positive Charlemagne. (2013). The flying taxman. The Economist, 407(8832),
outcome because there is more money available to support 51.
low prices, pay employees more, and make the company Christensen, J. (2011). The looting continues: Tax havens and
corruption. Critical Perspectives on International Business, 7(2),
more profitable. 177–196.
However, when the number of important stakeholders is Christensen, J., & Murphy, R. (2004). The social irresponsibility of
expanded to six groups, competitors, suppliers, and the corporate tax avoidance. Development, 7(3), 37–44.
public are generally added to the list (Paine et al. 2005). Clausing, K. A. (2011, March 28). The revenue effects of multi-
national firm income shifting. Tax Notes, 1580–1586.
Now the general public’s interest must be considered Davis, K. (1973). The case for and against business assumption of
against that of the other groups. However, even this per- social responsibilities. Academy of Management Journal, 16(2),
spective seems too narrow. What the various bailouts that 312–322.
occurred as a result of the global financial crisis demon- Davis, A. K., Guenther, D. A., Krull, L. K., & Williams, B. M. (2012).
Taxes and corporate accountability reporting: Is paying taxes
strated is that government is also a primary stakeholder of viewed as socially responsible? Working paper. Eugene, OR:
Corporate-America, etc. Hence, if scholars are prepared to Lundquist College of Business, University of Oregon.
shift the State from the background to the foreground in the Devinney, T. M. (2009). Is the socially responsible corporation a
stakeholder—CSR debate then issues like tax avoidance myth? The good, the bad, and the ugly of corporate social
responsibility. Academy of Management Perspectives, 23(2),
will attract more scrutiny. 44–56.
The aim of this paper is not to resolve the issue of the Dowling, G. R., & Gardberg, N. A. (2012). Keeping score: The
social responsibility of tax avoidance but to start a debate challenges of measuring corporate reputation. In M. L. Barnett &
in the mainstream business ethics literature about the fun- T. G. Pollock (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of corporate
reputations (pp. 34–68). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
damental assumptions and boundary conditions of CSR. Duhigg, C., & Kocieniewski, D. (2012, April 28). How Apple
For example, do advocates of CSR really want companies sidesteps billions in taxes. The New York Times.
to blindly adhere to government policy? Or is there a Ebrahimi, H. (2012, October 19). Starbucks faces further criticism
legitimate role for companies to challenge the social over its tax practices. Telegraph.
Elster, J. (1989). Social norms and economic theory. Journal of
agenda of elected governments? From this perspective Economic Perspectives, 3(4), 99–117.
personal and corporate tax avoidance can be framed as a

123
184 G. R. Dowling

Erle, B., Hickey, L. G., Doherty, R. H., & Flexman, B. P. (2004). Tax McGee, R. W. (2006). Three views on the ethics of tax evasion.
in the boardroom. London: KPMG International. Journal of Business Ethics, 67(1), 15–35.
Finch, J. (2004, March 18). Be fair plea as tax loopholes targeted. The McIntyre, R. S., Gardner, M., Wilkins, R. J., & Phillips, R. (2011).
Guardian. Corporate tax payers & corporate tax dodgers 2008–10.
Freedman, J. (2010). Improving (not perfecting) tax legislation: Rules Washington, D.C.: Citizens for Tax Justice & the Institute on
and principles revisited. British Tax Review, 6, 717–736. Taxation and Economic Policy.
Friedman, M. (1970, September 13). The social responsibility of McWilliams, A., & Siegel, D. (2001). Corporate social responsibility:
business is to increase its profits. New York Times Magazine, A theory of the firm perspective. Academy of Management
32–33. Review, 26(1), 117–127.
Gilders, F., Taylor, J., Richardson, G., & Walpole, M. (2004). Mirrlees, J. (2011). Tax by design: The Mirrlees review (pp. 21–45).
Understanding taxation law: An interactive approach. Sydney: Oxford: Oxford University Press.
LexisNexis Butterworths. Moulds, J. (2012, October 21). Anger grows over large companies’
Gongloff, M. (2012, September 20). Apple, Google, Microsoft avoid tax bills as attention turns to eBay and Ikea. The Guardian.
taxes by keeping billions in profits offshore: Senate report. Huff Paine, L., Deshpandé, R., Margolis, J. D., & Bettcher, E. (2005). Up
Post Business. to code: Does your company’s conduct meet world-class
Hanlon, M. (2003). What can we infer about a firm’s taxable income standards? Harvard Business Review, 83(12), 122–133.
from its financial statements? National Tax Journal, 56(4), Palazzo, G., & Richter, U. (2005). CSR business as usual? The case of
831–863. the tobacco industry. Journal of Business Ethics, 61(4), 387–401.
Helman, C. (2011, April 13). What the top US companies pay in Preuss, L. (2012). Responsibility in paradise? The adoption of CSR
taxes. Forbs.com. tools by companies domiciled in tax havens. Journal of Business
Kahneman, D. (2011). Thinking fast and slow. London: Penguin. Ethics, 110(1), 1–14.
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of Prior, D., Surroca, J., & Tribó, J. A. (2008). Are socially responsible
decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–291. managers really ethical? Exploring the relationship between
Keightley, M. P. (2013, January 18). An analysis of where American earnings management and corporate social responsibility. Cor-
companies report profits: Indications of profit shifting. Congres- porate Governance, 16(3), 160–177.
sional Research Service, 7-5700. Schön, W. (Ed.). (2008). Tax and corporate governance. Berlin:
Kemper, A., & Martin, R. L. (2010). After the fall: The global Springer-Verlag.
financial crisis as a test of corporate social responsibility Sikka, P. (2003, November 17). A taxing account of corporate social
theories. European Management Review, 7(4), 229–239. responsibility. The Guardian.
KLD Research & analytics, Inc. KLD Ratings Data. http://datalib.library. Sikka, P. (2004, February 6). Nobody is called to account. The
ualberta.ca/data/KLDRatings/Ratings%20Criteria%20Description_ Guardian.
All%20Years.pdf. Accessed 13 August 2013. Sikka, P. (2011). Smoke and mirrors: Corporate social responsibility
Kleinbard, E. D. (2011). Stateless income. Florida Tax Review, 11(9), and tax avoidance. Accounting Forum, 34(3–4), 153–168.
699–773. Smith, A. (1776). An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth
Klinger, S., Anderson, S., Collins, C., Cavanagh, J., & Pizzigati, S. of nations. London: Methuen and Co. (Ed. E. Cannan, 1904).
(2011, October 3). America loses: Corporations that take tax Snape, J. (2007). Corporate tax reform—politics and public law.
holidays slash jobs. The Institute for Policy Studies. Washington, British Tax Review, 4, 374–404.
DC. Stiglitz, J. E. (1985). The general theory of tax avoidance. National
Kocieniewski, D. (2011a, March 24). GE’s strategies let it avoid taxes Tax Journal, 38(3), 325–338.
altogether. The New York Times. Waddock, S. A. (2003). Myths and realities of social investing.
Kocieniewski, D. (2011b, May 2). U.S. business has high tax rates but Organization & Environment, 16(3), 369–380.
pays less. The New York Times. Watson, L. (2011). Corporate social responsibility and tax aggres-
Lanis, R., & Richardson, G. (2011). The effect of board of director siveness: An examination of unrecognized tax benefits. Working
composition on corporate tax aggressiveness. Journal of paper. University Park, PA: The Pennsylvania State University.
Accounting and Public Policy, 30(1), 50–70. Yani-de-Soriano, M., Javed, U., & Yousafzai, S. (2012). Can an
Lanis, R., & Richardson, G. (2012). Corporate social responsibility industry be socially responsible if its products harm consumers?
and tax aggressiveness: An empirical analysis. Journal of The case of online gambling. Journal of Business Ethics, 110(4),
Accounting and Public Policy, 31(1), 86–108. 481–497.
McCormack, J. (2011, November 17). GE filed 57,000-page tax
return, paid no taxes on $14 billion in profits. The Weekly
Standard.

123

You might also like