You are on page 1of 15

152 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

A Taxonomy of Systems of Corporate


Governance
Jeroen Weimer* 1 and Joost C. Pape
This paper argues that debate on corporate governance in an international context is
hampered by the lack of a coherent framework. A taxonomy of systems of corporate govern-
ance is proposed as a remedy. The taxonomy is based upon eight characteristics: the pre-
vailing concept of the firm, the board system, the salient stakeholders able to exert influence
on managerial decision-making, the importance of stock markets in the national economy,
the presence or absence of an external market for corporate control, the ownership structure,
the extent to which executive compensation is dependent on corporate performance, and the
time horizon of economic relationships. Four types of systems of corporate governance
emerge: the Anglo-Saxon systems, the Germanic systems, the Latin systems and the Japanese
system.

Key words: systems of corporate governance, international, taxonomy.

Introduction of governance research in an international


setting.

E specially since the collapse of the cen-


trally planned economies, academics,
practitioners and policy makers have demon- Terminology, structure and
strated a dramatically increased interest in limitations
systems of corporate governance. The most
familiar outcomes of this interest are the The scope of this paper and its ambitious
reports in which independent committees purpose require specification of the terminol-
assess national governance systems and make ogy used and explication of its limitations.
recommendations to improve their effective- First, a system of corporate governance is
ness. Examples are the Council of Competi- defined as a more-or-less country-specific
tiveness' Report (USA, 1992), the Cadbury framework of legal, institutional and cultural
Report (UK, 1993), the VieÂnot Report (France, factors shaping the patterns of influence that
1996) and the Peters Report (the Netherlands, stakeholders (e.g. managers, employees,
1998). Although the differences between the shareholders, creditors, customers, suppliers
``Anglo-Saxon'' and ``Rhineland'' governance and the government) exert on managerial
systems are now far from unfamiliar, the decision-making. The breadth of this defini-
debate on corporate governance in an inter- tion adheres to the purpose of the paper and
national context is still hampered by the lack allows approaches of governance issues from
of a framework wherein these systems can be different theoretical angles (e.g. economic,
positioned in a methodical manner. As a sociological and psychological). An examin-
result, the purpose of this paper is to develop ation of the merits and drawbacks of different
a taxonomy of systems of corporate govern- theories for increasing our understanding of
* Address for corresondence: ance. Such a taxonomy adheres to the corporate governance is however not con-
Dr ir. J. Weimer, University of increased interest in different governance ducted in this paper. The reason is that these
Twente, Faculty T&M, P.O.
Box 217, 7500 AE Enschede,
systems, the apparent willingness to make theories are primarily concerned with corpor-
The Netherlands. critical self-evaluations and the structuring ate governance at the level of the firm (for an

# Blackwell Publishers Ltd 1999. 108 Cowley Road, Oxford OX4 1JF, UK
Volume 7 Number 2 April 1999 and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA.
THEORY PAPERS 153

extensive overview, see Turnbull, 1997). The control, which serves as a mechanism for
focus of this paper is on corporate governance independent shareholders to influence man-
at the level of countries, that is on systems of agerial decision-making. By contrast, in the
corporate governance. Second, by ``taxon- network-oriented systems oligarchic groups
omy'' is meant an overview of characteristics substantially sway managerial decision-
of systems of corporate governance, wherein making via networks of relatively stable
the appraisal of the characteristics results relationships. The most common forms of
logically in discernible classes of governance networks are cross-shareholdings and inter-
systems. In this respect, ``taxonomy'' is seen to locking directorships. The market-oriented
be synonymous with ``typology'' or ``classifi- systems prevail in the Anglo-Saxon countries.
cation''. Largely based on the identity of oligarchic
Among others, Scott (1985), De Jong (1989), groups, different classes of network-oriented
Moerland (1995a,b) and Weimer (1995) pro- systems can be recognized for Germanic
pose four groups of relatively rich, indus- countries (e.g. Germany, where banks and Four global
trialized countries for which more or less employees are influential), Latin countries governance systems
resembling so-called corporate systems can (e.g. France and Italy, where family control
be identified: (1) Anglo-Saxon countries (the is relatively important), and Japan (where
USA, the UK, Canada and Australia), (2) banks serve as the nucleus of mutually
Germanic countries (Germany, the Nether- related, vertically and horizontally integrated
lands, Switzerland, Sweden, Austria, Den- groups of firms). To a greater or lesser extent,
mark, Norway and Finland), (3) Latin the qualification of all other characteristics
countries (France, Italy, Spain and Belgium) supports the division between these four
and (4) Japan (which is considered an isolate). classes of governance systems, as will be
This division into four groups is used to demonstrated in the course of the paper. In
classify governance systems in this paper. order to further facilitate comparison, the
Based on the aforementioned and a large Gross Domestic Product (GDP) and the GDP
number of other sources containing both per capita are denoted in Table 1 for each
qualitative and quantitative data, at least country.
eight characteristics of systems of corporate The major limitation of the taxonomy is that
governance can be identified. All character- it is descriptive, and solely meant for enabling
istics have legal, institutional and cultural rough comparisons using a common set of
dimensions, although one of these is com- system characteristics. In addition, the classi-
monly prevalent. The inventory of character- fication is not entirely unequivocal. National
istics is seen to cover a major part of the governance systems within one country
governance spectrum, but it is not regarded group might show relevant differences, and
to be exhaustive. The eight characteristics to systems in countries attributed to different
be examined in this paper are: groups might display noteworthy similarities.
Another limitation of the taxonomy is that
a. The prevailing concept of the firm;
emphasis is placed on publicly listed firms.2
b. The board system;
Notwithstanding the relevance of a taxonomy
c. The salient stakeholders able to exert influ-
for other types of companies, this is regarded
ence on managerial decision-making;
unavoidable because many of the data to
d. The importance of stock markets in the
support the classification are solely available
national economy;
for listed firms.
e. The presence or absence of an external
In the remainder of this paper the qualifi-
market for corporate control;
cation of the characteristics of governance
f. The ownership structure;
systems in Table 1 will be explicated for the
g. The extent to which executive compen-
Anglo-Saxon, Germanic and Latin countries,
sation is dependent on corporate perform-
and Japan, respectively. Afterwards, a sum-
ance;
mary and concluding remarks follow.
h. The time horizon of economic relation-
ships.
In Table 1, these characteristics are assayed Anglo-Saxon countries
for the different country groups. At the
highest level of abstraction, this results in a Regarding the Anglo-Saxon countries, only
distinction between ``market-oriented'' and the USA and the UK are dealt with in some-
``network-oriented'' systems of corporate what greater depth because of the relative
governance. This terminology is also used size of their GDPs (see Table 1). In the Anglo-
by Moerland (1995a,b). The paramount Saxon countries one specific stakeholder can
characteristic of the market-oriented systems be identified which can exert a substantial
is an active external market for corporate influence on managerial decision-making: the

# Blackwell Publishers Ltd 1999 Volume 7 Number 2 April 1999


154 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

Table 1. A taxonomy of systems of corporate governance

Market/network-oriented Market-oriented Network-oriented


system of corporate
governance

Country class Anglo-Saxon Germanic Latin Japan

Countries (GDP 19956US$ USA (7,246; 25,512) Germany (2,259; 25,133) France (1,567; 22,944) Japan (4,961; 36,732)
1,000,000,000; GDP per UK (1,107; 17,468) the Netherlands (396; 21,733) Italy (1,119; 17,796)
capita6US$ 1 at current Canada (569; 18,598) Switzerland (287; 36,790) Spain (574; 12,321)
prices and exchange rates). Australia (349; 18,072) Sweden (246; 22,389) Belgium (264; 22,515)
Source: IMF for GDP, Austria (233; 24,670)
OECD for GDP per capita Denmark (175; 28,181)
Norway (147; 28,434)
Finland (126; 19,106)
Concept of the firm Instrumental, shareholder- Institutional Institutional Institutional
oriented
Board system One-tier (executive and Two-tier (executive and Optional (France), in Board of directors; office of
non-executive board) supervisory board) general one-tier representative directors;
office of auditors; de facto
one-tier
Salient stakeholder(s) Shareholders Industrial banks (Germany), Financial holdings, the City banks, other financial
employees, in general government, families, in institutions, employees, in
oligarchic group general oligarchic group general oligarchic group
Importance of stock market High Moderate/high Moderate High
in the national economy
Active external market Yes No No No
for corporate control
Ownership concentration Low Moderate/high High Low/moderate
Performance-dependent High Low Moderate Low
executive compensation
Time horizon of economic Short term Long term Long term Long term
relationships

influence of shareholders is strongly institu- democratic principle of ``one share, one vote''
tionalized in these countries. Roughly put, applies.
the firm is conceived as a combination of A one-tier board of directors further charac-
managerial directors operating for the benefit terizes the Anglo-Saxon countries: executive
of shareholders, or as an instrument for the and supervisory responsibilities of the board
creation of shareholder wealth. In connection are condensed in one legal entity. There are,
hereto, the law strongly protects share- however, executive (``inside'') and non-execu-
holders. In the USA, this protection is tive (``outside'') board members. The latter are
embodied in, among others, the Securities outside experts, who are frequently also execu-
Exchange Act (1934), the Securities Investor tive board members of other firms. From a
Protection Act (1970), the Insider Trading legal point of view, the outside directors are
Sanctions Act (1984) and the Private Securities responsible for the management of the corpor-
Litigation Act (1995).3 Comparable legislation ation. They are expected to exercise the duties
or codes of conduct in the UK comprise the of loyalty, care and good business judgment,
Company Securities Act (1985, revised in and their primary accountability is to share-
1989), the City Code on Takeovers and holders (Lorsch and MacIver, 1989). From a
Mergers and the Financial Services Act practical point of view, the non-executive board
(1986).4 According to Franks and Mayer members advise the inside directors on major
(1990), ``the rationale behind these rules and policy decisions while bearing the interests of
regulations is the promotion of securities shareholders in mind (Bleicher and Paul,
markets. Equal access to information and 1986). Both the executive and non-executive
protection of small investors from exploita- board members are appointed and dismissed
tion by dominant shareholders are regarded by the general assembly of shareholders.
as central to that process'' (p. 209). As a result, In line with the previous observations,
in the Anglo-Saxon countries by-and-large the stock markets play a more important role in

Volume 7 Number 2 April 1999 # Blackwell Publishers Ltd 1999


THEORY PAPERS 155

Anglo-Saxon countries than they do in the capital in comparison to Germanic and Latin
other groups of countries. The Federation of ones (10.0% versus 6.5% and 3.9% respec-
International Stock Exchanges (FIBV) uses tively).
two indicators of this importance: (1) the Probably the best known characteristic of the
market capitalization of domestic companies Anglo-Saxon systems of corporate govern- Anglo-Saxon ±
as a percentage of the GDP and (2) new equity ance is an active external market for corporate takeover corporate
capital raised through public offerings as a control, often referred to as the takeover governance
percentage of the Gross Fixed Capital For- market. The most familiar takeover tech-
mation (GFCF). The values of these indicators niques are mergers, tender offers, proxy fights
are denoted for the countries under consider- and leveraged buy-outs. The takeover process
ation in Table 2. As the table shows, the is seen to act as a discipline on firms, allowing
aggregate market capitalization of companies control to be transferred from inefficient to
in the Anglo-Saxon countries equals 82.1% of efficient management teams and encouraging
their GDPs in 1995. This figure is considerably a convergence of interests between the cor-
smaller for the Germanic and Latin countries: porate management and the shareholders
41.7% and 27.3%, respectively. Measured by (Franks and Mayer, 1990).5 Especially in the
this indicator, stock markets also play an USA and the UK takeovers are regarded as a
important role in Japan's national economy central function of stock markets. Prowse
(83.5%). However, the new capital raised as a (1995) reports that the average annual volume
percentage of the GFCF is much lower in of completed domestic takeovers as a per-
Japan than in the Anglo-Saxon countries centage of total market capitalization over the
(0.5% versus 10.0%). Regarding the Germanic period 1985±1989 equals 41.1% in the USA
and Latin countries, the second indicator and 18.7% in the UK. In the non-Anglo-Saxon
points in the same direction as the first rela- countries much less emphasis is placed on the
tive to the Anglo-Saxon countries. Anglo- role of takeovers through stock markets in
Saxon stock markets are utilized more inten- changing corporate control. For instance, the
sively by domestic companies for raising aforementioned figures are 2.3% and 3.1% for

Table 2. Importance of stock markets in the national economies of Anglo-Saxon, Germanic, and Latin countries, and Japan
(figures6US$ 1,000,000,000)

COUNTRY CLASS Gross Domestic Market Value MVDC as Gross Fixed New Capital Raised NCR as Data based
Country Product Domestic % of GDP Capital Formation (NCR) 1995 % of GFCF on stock
(GDP) 1995 Companies (GFCF) 1995 exchange(s)
(MVDC) 1995

ANGLO-SAXON
United States 7,245.8 5,654.8 78.0% 1,028.2 96.5 9.4% NYSE
United Kingdom 1,106.7 1,346.6 121.7% 163.6 20.3 12.4% London
Canada 568.6 366.3 64.4% 98.4 8.9 9.1% Toronto
Australia 348.8 244.3 70.1% 71.6 10.3 14.4% Australian
Total 9,269.9 7,612.1 82.1% 1,361.8 136.0 10.0% Total
GERMANIC
Germany 2,259.3 577.4 25.6% 401.1 23.0 5.7% Germany
Netherlands 395.6 286.7 72.5% 77.8 11.1 14.3% Amsterdam
Switzerland 287.2 398.1 138.6% 63.0 1.9 3.0% Switzerland
Sweden 245.5 172.6 70.3% 35.7 3.6 10.0% Stockholm
Austria 233.2 32.5 13.9% 57.7 2.1 3.7% Vienna
Denmark 174.7 57.7 33.0% 28.1 2.1 7.3% Copenhagen
Norway 146.5 44.6 30.4% 31.3 1.2 3.8% Oslo
Finland 126.2 44.1 35.0% 19.4 1.4 7.2% Helsinki
Total 3,868.2 1,613.6 41.7% 714.0 46.4 6.5% Total
LATIN
France 1,566.8 500.0 31.9% 281.8 13.8 4.9% Paris
Italy 1,118.7 209.5 18.7% 170.0 9.7 5.7% Italy
Spain 574.3 150.9 26.3% 119.6 N/A N/A Madrid
Belgium 263.5 101.8 38.6% 45.2 0.4 0.8% Brussels
Total 3,523.3 962.2 27.3% 616.6 23.8 3.9% Total
JAPAN
Japan 4,393.8 3,667.3 83.5% 1,385.0 6.8 0.5% Tokyo

Sources: IMF and World Bank for GDP, IMF for GFCF, FIBV for MVDC and NCR

# Blackwell Publishers Ltd 1999 Volume 7 Number 2 April 1999


156 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

Germany and Japan, respectively (Prowse, panies (51.4%). The degree of individual
1995). In the Germanic and Latin countries ownership is much lower in the UK (17.7%),
and Japan different means of swaying man- while the vast majority of the other shares are
agerial decision-making prevail, which will held by financial institutions (61.2%). The
be covered in the next sections. ownership structure in the Anglo-Saxon
Takeovers are termed ``hostile'' when the countries partly explains the existence of an
management of the target firm opposes them active market for corporate control. The wider
(Franks and Mayer, 1990). Perhaps contrary corporations are held, the less mechanisms
to popular belief, hostile takeovers are a shareholders can use effectively to influence
minority of total takeovers in the Anglo- managerial decision-making in a direct man-
Saxon countries. Such takeovers are con- ner (e.g. by the exercise of voting rights at the
sidered an ``option of last resort'' because general assembly, board opposition to man-
they are a relatively expensive means of cor- agement proposals and informal dialogue). In
recting managerial decision-making (Fama, the USA, direct mechanisms of influence can
1980). Prowse (1995) reports that of all at- be utilized even less effectively because of the
tempted takeovers in the period 1985±1989, non-professionalism associated with owner-
17.8% could be termed hostile in the USA and ship by individuals.
37.1% in the UK. In accordance with conven- In the context of corporate governance,
tional wisdom, the frequency of hostile take- executive compensation customarily concerns
overs is much lower in the network-oriented the extent to which executive pay is related to
governance systems (9.6% for the rest of Europe: the performance of the firm. Common forms
Prowse, 1995). In Germany only a handful of of performance-dependent executive com-
completed hostile takeovers have been re- pensation are share-option plans to align the
ported.6 In Japan they have never occurred interests of managers and shareholders, as
(Moerland, 1995a). well as multi-year bonus plans. Abowd and
Systems of corporate governance in the Bognanno (1995) report that particularly in
industrialized nations also differ markedly the USA, this remuneration is an important
with respect to their ownership structures. and still growing part of total managerial
The structure of ownership has two mutually compensation. It accounts for approximately
related dimensions: the concentration of one-third of total compensation for CEOs
ownership and the identity of shareholders. in 1992. Also in the UK and Canada, the
In general, in the Anglo-Saxon countries firms employment of performance-related pay is of
are relatively widely held (low ownership clear and growing importance. Weimer (1995)
concentration). The OECD (1997) estimates supports the notion of relatively high variable
that in the USA and the UK the largest five remuneration in the USA. In a sample of 220
shareholders hold on average 20±25% of the listed firms, top management owned shares
outstanding shares. Ownership concentration in ``their'' firms in 100% of the cases in the
is significantly higher in Japan and Germany, USA, compared to 67% in the Netherlands
and especially in the Latin countries. and 33% in Germany.
The identities of shareholders of listed cor- Finally, the Anglo-Saxon system of corpor-
porations in the five largest countries under ate governance is characterized by relatively
study are summarized in Table 3. As the table short-term economic relationships. Quite un-
shows, especially in the USA individuals own restricted markets for capital, labor, goods
a large portion of the shares of quoted com- and services ensure rapid adjustment to

Table 3. Ownership of common stock in the US, UK, Germany, France and Japan

US UK Germany France Japan


(1994) (1993) (1993) (1994) (1992)

Individuals 51.4% 17.7% 16.6% 19.5% 22.4%


Banks 0.1% 0.6% 14.3% 3.8% 18.9%
Other financial institutions 44.4% 61.2% 14.7% 4% 29.1%
Non-financial corporations 0% 3.1% 38.8% 57.9% 24.9%
Government 0% 1.3% 3.4% 3.7% 0.7%
Foreign 4.2% 16.3% 12.2% 11.1% 4.0%

Source: OECD (1997)

Volume 7 Number 2 April 1999 # Blackwell Publishers Ltd 1999


THEORY PAPERS 157

changing circumstances, thereby disfavoring workers' counsels have rights regarding


long-term and stable relationships (Gelauff working hours, holidays, hirings, and dis-
and Den Broeder, 1996). This phenomenon missals. The other members of the super-
has led some to observe that managers in the visory board are appointed by the general
Anglo-Saxon countries are myopic, focussing assembly of shareholders (Hauptversamm-
on boosting the next quarterly figures while lung). The assembly has the right to elect the
underinvesting in long-term assets such as chairman, who has double voting rights.
research and development or training (e.g. Removal of members of the supervisory
Porter, 1992; Prodhan, 1993). However, ac- board requires the approval of 75% of the
cording to others, there is no concrete shareholders. The influence of independent
evidence to support these claims (e.g. Shleifer shareholders on managerial decision-making
and Vishny, 1997). is limited, however. The ``one share, one vote''
principle pursued in the Anglo-Saxon coun-
tries does not prevail in the Germanic
Germanic countries countries. German companies can issue non-
voting shares up to an amount equal to that of
Regarding the Germanic countries, only all voting shares issued and can limit the
Germany and, to a much lesser extent, the voting power of an individual shareholder
Netherlands are dealt with in somewhat more irrespective of the number of shares held
depth because of the relative size of their (Franks and Mayer, 1990). Dutch, Swiss and
GDPs (see Table 1). The corporation is not, as the firms from the other Germanic countries
in Anglo-Saxon countries, seen as a device also have and utilize the ability to limit the
to create shareholder value. Rather, it is con- power of the shareholders by several protec-
sidered as an autonomous economic entity tive measures.7 Germanic ±
constituting a coalition of various partici- More specifically, large German general autonomous
pants, such as shareholders, corporate man- banks are salient influential stakeholders. economic corporate
agement, employees, suppliers of goods and Apart from their role as suppliers of debt,
services, suppliers of debt and customers, their potential influence has two dimensions:
governance
striving for the continuity of the firm as a equity ownership and supervisory board
whole (Moerland, 1995a). seats. There are almost no restrictions for the
In contrast to the USA and the UK, German banks to hold large blocks of shares
Germany and the Netherlands have a two- of non-financial firms. This is in sharp
tier board system. In Germany, the board contrast to, for instance, the USA, where the
comprises a management board (Vorstand) Glass-Steagall Act (1933) and the Bank Hold-
and a supervisory board (Aufsichtsrat), which ing Company Act (1956) forbid commercial
provides a complete separation between banks to participate in the shareholders'
management and supervision of manage- capital of non-financial corporations on their
ment. From a legal point of view, the super- own account.8 German banks own about 14%
visory board has the duty to monitor the of listed companies (see Table 3). However,
competence of the management board. From the potential influence of banks in their role as
a practical point of view, it gives advice on shareholders is larger than this figure sug-
major policy decisions. The management gests. By legal device called Depotstimmrecht
board is appointed and dismissed by the banks have the right to assemble the voting
supervisory board. For an extensive descrip- rights conferred to them by custody of bearer
tion of the German two-tier board system shares of individual investors who have
the reader is referred to Bleicher and Paul surrendered their proxies. Thus, the 16.6%
(1986), Edwards and Fischer (1994) and of individual ownership in Table 3 can be
Kaplan (1995). attributed partly to banks.9
The composition of the Aufsichtsrat in Regarding the second dimension, Schneider-
Germany reflects that employees and share- Lenne (1994) reports that of the total number
holders are salient stakeholders that can exert of 1,495 supervisory boards of the 100 largest
substantial influence on managerial decision- German firms in 1988, 136 were occupied by
making. This also applies to the Netherlands. representatives of banks, while 729 seats were
German corporations with 2,000 employees or appointed to trade union and other employee
more must occupy half of the supervisory representatives. The remaining seats were
board seats with employee representatives occupied mainly by shareholder representa-
(smaller ones appoint one-third). Trade unions tives other than banks. These figures reflect
are entitled to supervisory board positions. the system of codetermination mentioned
The right of employees to participate in earlier. However, as in the case of ownership,
decision-making is known as ``codetermina- the potential influence of banks in their role as
tion'', which is also reflected in the fact that supervisory board members is larger than the

# Blackwell Publishers Ltd 1999 Volume 7 Number 2 April 1999


158 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

9% of seats might suggest. If the number of the establishment of the current ownership
interlocking board seats is taken into account, structure. The scope of this paper does not
as opposed to the number of seats, it can be allow a balanced perspective on this process.
concluded that banks are strongly involved For historical overviews the reader is referred
in the corporate network.10 In addition, the to Dyson (1986), Schneider-Lenne (1994) and
chairman of the supervisory board is some- Edwards and Fischer (1994).11
times a bank representative (as in the case of The use of performance-related compensa-
Deutsche Bank and Daimler-Benz) and there- tion for executives in the Germanic countries
fore has a casting vote. seems to be rather limited. Although variable
As illustrated in Table 2, stock markets play pay has been becoming more important in
a less important role in the economy of these countries, Abowd and Bognanno (1995)
Germanic countries than they do in Anglo- report hardly any such compensation at all in
Saxon countries, and an active external Germany, the Netherlands and Sweden. In
market for corporate control is almost non- Switzerland performance-related remunera-
existent. Generally, in the Germanic countries tion is not uncommon, but its significance is
influence on managerial decision-making is small in comparison with the Anglo-Saxon
not exerted via the ``invisible hand'' of stock countries.
markets, but via the visible hand of dialogue Germany is one of the countries wherein
between the management board and the stakeholders are persistently seen to employ a
supervisory board around the negotiation long-term time horizon (ICMG, 1995). The
table. The ownership structure in Germanic sizeable and stable shareholdings by non-
countries partly explains the absence of an financial corporations and banks mentioned
active market for corporate control. The more earlier allow for long-term and stable eco-
concentrated companies are held, the more nomic relationships, as does the institution-
mechanisms shareholders can use effectively alized influence of employees (Gelauff and
to influence managerial decision-making in Den Broeder, 1996). In general, also in the
a direct manner, and the less acute is the other Germanic countries the institutional
``option of last resort'' to correct managerial environment favors the establishment of
decision-making by (the threat of) a hostile long-term relationships.
takeover. This applies in particular to
Germany, where companies are very densely
held. The OECD (1997) estimates that the Latin countries
largest five shareholders hold on average 41%
of the outstanding shares. In addition, Prowse Regarding the Latin countries, only France
(1995) reports that in a sample of 310 listed and, to a lesser extent, Italy is dealt with in
non-financial German companies roughly somewhat more depth because of the relative
Latin ± concept one-quarter had a majority shareholder. This size of their GDPs (see Table 1). The concept
between situation is significantly different in the USA of the firm in the Latin countries lies some-
instrumental and and the UK, where the frequency of majority where in between the instrumental, Anglo-
ownership yielded about 10% in comparable Saxon view and the institutional, Germanic
institutional samples. view, but is altogether probably closer to the
The other dimension of ownership struc- latter. In France, companies have the choice
ture, shareholder identity, also helps explain of using either a one-tier or a two-tier board
the absence of a market for corporate control. system. The vast majority of listed companies
The network orientation of the German (98%) have chosen the unitary system,
governance system is reflected in the fact that Peugeot and Paribas being the notable excep-
non-financial corporations own 38.8% of the tions (ICMG, 1995). Shareholders can appoint
shares of listed firms (see Table 3): mutual and dismiss the management board with a
cross-shareholdings between firms are gener- 50% majority of the voting rights. Limited to
ally permitted and commonplace. There is the one-tier system, French corporate law
an implicit agreement that such share- does not distinguish between executive and
holdings are not used to launch unwelcome non-executive directors on the management
takeovers (Franks and Mayer, 1990). German board. De facto at least two third of the board
corporations can take cross-shareholdings can be qualified as non-executives, usually
subject to a limitation of 25% of the voting being representatives of major shareholders.
rights associated with those shareholdings, Accordingly, they are not ``independent'' in
but irrespective of their size. By contrast, in the sense of having no business or other
the Anglo-Saxon countries one-third of cor- relationship with the company. The authority
porate ownership must result in a bid on all of the company president (preÂsident-directeur-
the other shares. Over the course of time, geÂneÂrale) further characterizes the French
German banks have played a pivotal role in board system. He has wide powers in relation

Volume 7 Number 2 April 1999 # Blackwell Publishers Ltd 1999


THEORY PAPERS 159

to the management of the company. His role in the recent past the influence of the French
can be seen as an indication of a significant government found expression in the delay
cultural influence on the French governance and impediment of takeovers that have been
system: the predilection for concentrations of deemed against the national interest (e.g.
power (ICMG, 1995). Victoire, Gallimard, Te le me canique and
Shareholders in the Latin countries are prob- Navigation Mixte). The 19.5% of ownership
ably more influential than in the Germanic by individuals in France in Table 3 can be
countries since shareholder sovereignty is attributed in part to the founding families of
viewed as an important concept, but their corporations (ICMG, 1995). Family control is
influence is not as decisive as in the Anglo- even more important in Italy (e.g. the Agnel-
Saxon countries. One of the fundamental lis; Moerland, 1995a,b).
principles of French corporate law is that As illustrated in Table 2, stock markets play
directors can be removed by the shareholders a much less important role in the economy of
at will. This principle is known as reÂvocabilite Latin countries than they do in the Anglo-
ad nutum (ICMG, 1995). In addition, the Saxon countries. There is no active market for
countervailing influence of employees is less corporate control, but the number of hostile
institutionalized than in the Germanic coun- takeovers is higher than in the Germanic
tries.12 However, in practice the influence on countries (Moerland, 1995b). As in the cases
managerial decision-making that can be ex- of the two previous groups of countries, the
erted by independent shareholders is rela- ownership structure in the Latin countries
tively small (De Jong, 1989). As in the partly explains the minor role the market for
Germanic countries, and in contrast to the corporate control plays. Ownership concen-
Anglo-Saxon countries, the ``one share, one tration is relatively high in France, Italy and
vote'' principle does not apply in general. In Spain. The percentage of shares controlled by
France, up to 25% of shareholders' capital the five largest shareholders average 48% in
can, under certain circumstances, be issued as France and nearly 87% in Italy (OECD, 1997).
non-voting preferred equity. Also, up to 25% In Italy, family or industrial groups hold con-
of capital may be issued as investment trolling interests in virtually all of the 200 listed
certificates that can only be transferred to corporations (Zingales, 1994). In addition, in
holders of other investment certificates France the effectiveness of a market for
(Franks and Mayer, 1990). corporate control is impeded by regulatory
Regarding the influence of shareholders restrictions on the transferability of shares.13
more specifically, the Latin countries are As in Germany, mutual cross-sharehold-
characterized by financial holdings and ings between firms are generally permitted
cross-shareholdings, government control and and commonplace in France. As a result,
family control (De Jong, 1989; Moerland, non-financial corporations own a weighty
1995a,b). As in Germany and Switzerland, portion of the shares of listed firms (57.9%;
bank shareholdings are important especially see Table 3). The French network orientation
in France (banque d'affaires) and Spain. How- is possibly less dominant in this respect when
ever, as in the USA, Italian banks are not compared with Germany, because French
allowed to hold securities on their own companies can take cross-shareholdings only
behalf, and also in Belgium there are legal up to a limit of 10% and also subsidiaries may
requirements preventing banks from taking own up to 10%. In addition, a rather Anglo-
stakes in non-banking corporations. Financial Saxon feature of French corporate law is that
holdings in France come in diverse schemes, concert parties that hold more than one-third
which in effect are similar to cross-share- of a company's capital are required to launch
holdings. One common form is where cor- full takeovers (Franks and Mayer, 1990).
porations and their subsidiaries hold each However, as in Germany, interlocking direc-
other's voting rights reciprocally (systeÁme torships frequently accompany the cross-
autocontroÃle). Another form is where com- shareholdings (Moerland, 1995b) and there
panies place their shares within a limited is an implicit agreement that cross-share-
group of ``friendly'' companies (systeÁme ver- holdings are not used to launch unwelcome
rouillage; De Jong, 1989). In France the entire takeovers (Franks and Mayer, 1990).
banking sector was nationalized in 1981, In the Latin countries in general, perform-
resulting in the government becoming an ance-related executive compensation is not
important shareholder in a variety of corpor- common. The only exception is France, where
ations. As Table 3 shows, the recent wave of percentages of executive remuneration simi-
privatizations (e.g. RhoÃne Poulenc, Elf Aqui- lar to those in the UK and Canada are per-
taine and Renault) has resulted in a now formance-dependent (Abowd and Bognanno,
small fraction of government ownership. 1995). On the whole, however, the Latin
However, as Franks and Mayer (1990) report, countries score low on this characteristic.

# Blackwell Publishers Ltd 1999 Volume 7 Number 2 April 1999


160 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

With respect to the stimuli to sustain long- frequently create an informal substructure of
term economic relationships, there is scant the board of directors. This results in a board
documentation on the Latin countries. In of inside directors and outside members,
view of the reciprocal shareholdings, family which de facto resembles the one-tier board
ownership and government control it seems system in the USA and the UK (Aoki, 1984a;
likely that long-term relationships are encour- Corbett, 1994).17 As in the Anglo-Saxon coun-
aged rather than disfavored by the institu- tries, the board is elected and dismissed by
tional environment. the general assembly of shareholders.
As in Germany, employees and shareholders
are salient stakeholders that can substantially
Japan sway managerial decision-making in Japan.
In this respect, Aoki (1984a) advanced a
Of all the countries examined in this paper, model in which the Japanese firm is presented
Japan ± cultural from a Western point of view the cultural as a coalition of the body of employees and
corporate dimension of the system of corporate govern- the body of shareholders, integrated and
governance ance is probably the most preponderant in mediated by the management acting to strike
Japan. The features of Japanese culture that a balance between the interests of both
probably have the most impact are the sense parties. The influence of employees is related
of ``family'' and the importance of ``achieving strongly to the cultural tradition of familyism.
consensus''. As will be illustrated below, The concept of lifetime employment has
family values pervade all characteristics of become a well-known characteristic of the
the Japanese governance system. That is, the Japanese economy in the Western world, if
cultural tradition of familyism goes far not a myth.18 Employees have a say in a
beyond the scope of the blood ties indicating considerable breadth of corporate affairs,
family control over firms in the Latin coun- such as wage determination, the way in
tries. In addition, relatively little emphasis which work is organized, and the way in
is placed on litigation in Japan (ICMG, 1995). which managerial choices are made that
The Japanese governance system does, how- would affect the lives of the employees (Aoki,
ever, have a number of Anglo-Saxon traits. 1984b). Under the Japanese Commercial
These are basically the result of the US Code, the shareholders are viewed as im-
occupation of 1945 to 1952 (Harrison, 1997). portant stakeholders. However, for cultural
Japan could be said to be the epitome of reasons their role is different from that in
the countries where the institutional concept most Western governance systems (ICMG,
of the firm prevails. This concept finds ex- 1995). As a group, the shareholders in Japan
pression in the large-scale presence of inter- seem to make a long-term commitment to the
corporate networks, the so-called keiretsu. keiretsu in which they participate. In contrast
They comprise almost half of the top 200 to especially the Anglo-Saxon countries, the
Japanese firms.14 The six largest of these ``value'' of the investments of shareholders
industrial groupings are Mitsubishi, Mitsui, seems to be considered as the sum total of a
Sumitomo, Fuyo, Dai-ichi Kangyo, and business relationship with another company,
Sanwa. They involve companies that share of which the stocks' voting rights, dividends
the same names and logos and organize and capital gains are only a part. The
relationships among major financial insti- Japanese shareholders seem to own their
tutions, trading companies and industrial securities for strategic purposes. Among these
producers (Orru et al., 1989). Most of the are the cementing of long-term business ties,
keiretsu are both diversified and vertically the acquisition of new customers and the
integrated.15 Large industrial companies (e.g. warding off of unwelcome outsiders. Shares
Toyota Motors and Hitachi) are in turn are also held for symbolic purposes, in the
positioned at the apex of their own vertically sense that they are considered as a ticket of
linked groupings of smaller affiliated supplier admission to the corporate network (Zielinski
and distribution firms (Aoki, 1989). Some of and Holloway, 1991).
the keiretsu descended from the prewar As in Germany, large Japanese banks are
family-centered holding companies, the so- salient influential stakeholders (other finan-
called zaibatsu (e.g. Iwasaki, Yasuda, Mitsui cial institutions are influential as well). They
and Sumitomo). Others were established after have traditionally had close relations with
the war.16 their customers (Harrison, 1997). The so-called
The Japanese board system is rather com- city banks are the nuclei in the corporate webs
plex. It comprises a board of directors, an of the keiretsu, which is partly historically
office of representative directors and an office determined.19 The modes of influence of city
of auditors, which all have different respon- banks stem from three sources. Of course,
sibilities. However, Japanese companies they supply the other group members with

Volume 7 Number 2 April 1999 # Blackwell Publishers Ltd 1999


THEORY PAPERS 161

debt. As suppliers of debt, the banks have 1 and 5%) and that the number of such ties is
been playing a more important role than, for high, in particular in the keiretsu (Kester,
instance, in Germany. The level of debt 1992). For an elaboration of cross-sharehold-
financing in Japan is high by international ings in Japan the reader is referred to
standards (Corbett, 1994). Second, city banks Masuyama (1994).
are shareholders in members of the keiretsu. Performance-related executive compensa-
The individual equity stakes of Japanese tion is not widespread in Japan (Abowd and
banks in non-financial firms are smaller than Bognanno, 1995). In fact, the issue of manage-
in Germany. Largely as a result of the rial remuneration is of much less interest to
postwar US occupation, direct ownership by stakeholders than in many other countries
Japanese banks in non-financial firms is (ICMG, 1995). In accordance with the prevail-
limited to 5% by the law (Harrison, 1997). ing concept of the firm in Japan and the role
On aggregate, bank shareholdings are some- that shareholders play therein, there seems
what more important in Japan than in to be little necessity to align the interests of
Germany (see Table 3). In Japan both bank managers and shareholders by means of
finance and banks' shareholdings have a very performance-dependent pay.
stable character. For instance, Hoshi et al. Even more so than in the Germanic
(1990) report that the main bank accounted countries, stakeholders in Japan seem to have
for an average of about 22% of the firms' a predilection for long-term and stable eco-
loans in a sample of 125 firms and that it held nomic relationships. The keiretsu and the
about 4% of the firm's equity on average. concept of long-term employment attest most
Third, city banks influence managerial deci- notably to this observation. The institution-
sion-making by transferring their own staff alized ties between stakeholders and the
members as both executive and non-executive preponderant sense of familyism and con-
directors to non-financial firms in the keiretsu.20 sensus open the door to long-term engage-
Generally, banks sending directors to firms ments, while in the Anglo-Saxon countries
are shareholders, even when they are not the such commitments might be inhibited by
main bank (Corbett, 1994). market forces.
In terms of their sizes, stock markets play
an important role in Japan's economy (see
Table 2). Although the postwar US adminis- Summary and concluding remarks
tration has contributed to this phenomenon,
Japan's stock markets are the oldest in Asia This paper started with the observation that
(Harrison, 1997). There is no active market for debate on corporate governance in an inter-
corporate control in Japan, where achieving national setting is impeded by the lack of a
consensus is one of the cultural tenets. Hostile clear framework. Consequently, the establish-
takeovers are considered as a curse (Moer- ment of a taxonomy of systems of corporate
land, 1995a).21 The ownership structure in governance was the objective of this paper.
Japan also encumbers a market for corporate The taxonomy is based upon eight related,
control. In the early sixties, when Japan was yet discernable characteristics: (1) the prevail-
liberalizing its capital markets, a high number ing concept of the firm, (2) the board system,
of managers of the typically large firms (3) the salient stakeholders able to exert
engaged in a ``shareholder stabilization oper- influence on managerial decision-making,
ation'' (Aoki, 1989). As a result, the ownership (4) the importance of stock markets in the
structure in Japan is characterized by rela- national economy, (5) the presence or absence
tively stable cross-shareholdings between of an external market for corporate control,
financial and non-financial companies (see (6) the ownership structure, (7) the extent to
Table 3). Ownership is more widely dispersed which executive compensation is dependent
than in Germany, but the concentration is on corporate performance and (8) the time
not as low as in the USA. The largest five horizon of economic relationships. For com-
shareholders in Japan own a significantly parative purposes, systems of corporate
larger portion of companies than in the USA governance prevailing in the industrial-
and the UK (33% versus 20±25%: OECD, ized countries can be divided roughly into
1997). However, a majority owner is found at ``market-oriented'' systems (Anglo-Saxon
a frequency similar to these countries (8% countries, e.g. the USA and the UK) and
versus 10±11%), while in Germany a majority ``network-oriented'' systems. In turn, net-
owner is found in about 25% of the cases work-oriented systems come in distinguish-
(Prowse, 1995). The explanation for this able forms in the Germanic countries (e.g.
phenomenon is that the cross-shareholdings Germany and the Netherlands), in Latin
in Japan are relatively small on a bilateral countries (e.g. France and Italy), and in Japan.
basis (as a rule of thumb, somewhere between The paramount characteristic of the market-

# Blackwell Publishers Ltd 1999 Volume 7 Number 2 April 1999


162 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

oriented systems is an active external market oriented and network-oriented systems have
for corporate control, which serves as a been surviving over many decades. From an
mechanism for shareholders to influence empirical point of view, there is no evidence
managerial decision-making in an indirect to pinpoint the ``fittest'' system (see also
manner. By contrast, in the network-oriented Mayer, 1997). The second reason concerns
systems oligarchic groups with different the unpredictability of the consequences of
identities substantially sway managerial policy decisions resulting from critical self-
decision-making by more direct modes of evaluations of domestic governance systems.
influence. Especially the limited voting rights As this paper hopefully has shown, each
of independent shareholders, cross-share- characteristic of a governance system is
holdings and interlocking directorships in- inextricably intertwined with others in the
dicate the network orientation. The appraisal matured context of legal, institutional and
of the other characteristics of governance cultural factors. Policy makers might thus
systems is strongly related to this overall fall into the trap of changing one system
difference between a stronger reliance on characteristic (e.g. liberalizing the regulations
either markets or networks of relationships regarding takeovers) and underestimating the
between stakeholders, as was illustrated in countervailing effect this could have on other
the course of the paper. characteristics (e.g. an increase in mutual
In view of the dramatically increased cross-shareholdings). As a result, unbalanced
interest in corporate governance, it can be policy decisions might yield an outcome
observed that changes are taking place in both contradictory to that intended (more closed
the market-oriented and network-oriented corporations as opposed to more open cor-
systems. These developments seem to have porations). The third reason to be cautious
a converging character and are likely to add with foretelling is that we still know so little
some shades of grey to the black-and-white about the current governance systems, as
picture painted in this paper. The level of Moerland (1995b) and Shleifer and Vishny
hostile activity at the market for corporate (1997) also conclude. In this respect, the
control in the Anglo-Saxon countries in ``the taxonomy proposed in this paper might help
roaring eighties'' has been decreasing in the to structure governance research in an inter-
nineties. Diplomacy and persuasion by pen- national setting.
sion funds (e.g. CALPers) and other active Regarding further research, a first rec-
institutional investors have been gradually ommendation is to qualify and quantify each
substituting practices like corporate raiding of the examined characteristics more exten-
and asset stripping. On the other hand, sively per individual country. Second, atten-
regulation by the European Union has been tion should be devoted to the development of
developing in a direction more favorable to a theoretical framework combining insights
independent shareholders. The proposal for from economics, sociology and psychology to
the 13th Directive Company Law on Public improve methodical comparisons of govern-
Bids is quite similar to the UK City Code on ance systems. This could also pave the way to
Takeovers and Mergers. The role of banks in the constructive linkage of the taxonomy to
Germany and Japan is becoming less domi- relevant issues such as (national) economic
nant. In Germany the banks' ownership of development, judicial constraints, and board
blocks of equity in non-financial corporations effectiveness. Third, the current taxonomy
and their large numbers of interlocking board should be protracted with newly industrial-
seats are subject to severe criticism of both ized countries and developing countries.
policy makers and practitioners. The prepon- Furthermore, new characteristics of govern-
derance of Japanese banks is crumbling as a ance systems could be added to the current
result of regulatory changes, massive losses classification.
on outstanding loans, and financial scandals.
In the opposite direction, in the USA a long
period of banking restrictions is likely to Notes
come gradually and partially to an end. Other
developments, such as the globalization of 1. During one of the fruitful discussions at the
competition and the institutionalization of International Research Seminar on Corporate
investments, also seem to imply a growing Governance and Direction held at Henley
convergence of governance systems (Moer- Management College, England, on 11 and 12
June 1997, the need was emphasized for a
land, 1995b).
taxonomy of systems of corporate governance.
It is difficult to predict accurately how The authors are grateful for the stimulating
the different national systems of corporate input of the participants at the seminar, as well
governance will evolve. The first reason for as for the financial support of ABN Amro Bank
this observation is that both the market- to conduct this research.

Volume 7 Number 2 April 1999 # Blackwell Publishers Ltd 1999


THEORY PAPERS 163

2. By far, most corporations are privately held avoid a takeover to act in the interest of the
and remain so during their lifetimes. Only a shareholders, that is, to create wealth for them
tiny fraction of firms have become listed on a by increasing the value of their investments.
stock exchange. On a worldwide scale, at most In line with Manne's (1965) reasoning, Jensen
20,000 firms are publicly held, while many and Ruback (1983) regard the market for
millions of private corporations exist. How- corporate control as a component of the
ever, their economic importance is dispropor- managerial labor market. Jensen and Ruback
tionately high because of their size, scope, and (1983) define the market for corporate control
impact. In addition, the availability of public as ``the arena in which alternative management
data is greater in the case of listed corporations teams compete for the rights to manage
(Moerland, 1995b). corporate resources, with stockholders playing
3. The Securities Exchange Act (``the Act'') im- the relatively passive role of accepting or
poses relatively strict and detailed disclosure rejecting offers from competing management
rules. The Act requires that every officer or teams'' (p. 6). From the Jensen and Ruback
director of a firm with an equity security and perspective, it is not the group of shareholders
every person who is directly or indirectly the that should be regarded as the primary actor
beneficial owner of more than 10% of any class on the takeover market, but rather the compet-
of equity security file a report of his holdings to ing management teams.
the Securities Exchange Commission (SEC) and 6. The only recorded cases of attempted hostile
to the exchange on which the security is listed, domestic acquisitions in Germany are Klages
whereas the disclosure threshold for organiza- takeover of Zellstoff-Waldhof in the mid-
tions is 3%. Special reports must be filed if any sixties (Mayer and Alexander, 1990) and the
change in holdings take place. The Securities attack of Flick Industrieverwaltung on Feld-
Investor Protection Act provides protection muÈhle Nobel in the early eighties (Franks and
against financial loss to shareholders resulting Mayer, 1990).
from brokers or dealers who fail. The Insider 7. Dutch firms can issue non-voting shares,
Trading Sanctions Act provides the possibility preferred shares, and priority shares. The latter
of seeking civil penalties whenever it appears ones are non-tradable, but have statutorily
to the SEC that a person has violated a fixed prerogatives relating to, for instance, the
provision of the Act by dealing in a security nomination of executive board members and
while in possession of material non-public their compensation, the issuance of shares, and
information. Under the ``lead plaintiff'' pro- additions to the reserves. Swiss firms are
vision of the Private Securities Litigation Act, authorized to have bearer shares outstanding
large shareholders can seek to be named with a lower nominal value and a correspond-
controlling parties in class-action shareholders ingly lower voting power than registered
lawsuits. shares. Shareholders that are deemed unwel-
4. The cornerstone of the Company Securities Act come cannot even buy registered shares with-
and a number of regulations governing sub- out the voting rights (Horner, 1988). In
stantial acquisition of shares is that share- addition, Sweden, Norway, and Finland do
holders should be ``fairly'' treated. The not allow foreigners to have more than a
Company Securities Act places limitations on minority of a firm's shares (20 to 40%) and
individuals who are connected with a firm may limit the voting power to an even lower
from dealing in listed securities when they are percentage. Swedish firms might issue A
in possession of price-sensitive information. shares (for inhabitants, carrying one vote) and
The City Code on Takeovers and Mergers lays B shares (for foreigners, with a severely
down general principles of good standards of diminished voting fraction). Danish firms have
commercial behavior to be followed by the one type of shares with enhanced voting
parties involved in a takeover transaction. It power (up to ten times), which are tightly held
also contains detailed rules designed to ensure by family-controlled foundations. The other
that all shareholders of the target firm are type, B-shares, may be held by domestic
treated similarly by an offerer and are given inhabitants and foreigners alike (De Jong,
sufficient information and advice to reach a 1989).
properly informed decision, and that the board 8. The UK had a comparable regulation that was
of directors of the target firm takes no action to modified recently as a result of the design of
frustrate an offer. the EU Banking Law. In addition, until 1994 it
5. The general line of reasoning in the Anglo- was characteristic of US banks that they were
Saxon countries is related to the ``improved not allowed to perform banking activities
management hypothesis'', which was ad- outside their home state, apart from agree-
vanced by Manne (1965): when the incumbent ments made on the federal level. In September
management fails to achieve the performance 1994 the Riegle-Neal Interstate Banking and
that could be expected from them, an incentive Branching Efficiency Act, which allows banks
exists for a takeover of the firm by a manage- more latitude in performing their cross-state
ment team who believes itself to be able to activities, replaced this Interstate Banking
extract relatively more value from it. Accord- regulation. Roe (1990) gives detailed infor-
ing to the improved management hypothesis, mation on the restrictions imposed on the
even if no takeover actually occurs, the mere portfolios of banks and other financial insti-
possibility disciplines managers who want to tutions in the USA.

# Blackwell Publishers Ltd 1999 Volume 7 Number 2 April 1999


164 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

9. In addition, banks can loan their voting rights into related businesses, such as trading (Mit-
to another bank that specializes in a particular subishi Corp.), casualty insurance (Tokyo
industry (Leihstimmrecht). Furthermore, owner- Marine and Fire Insurance), warehousing
ship by banks tends to increase with the size of (Mitsubishi Warehouse), shipbuilding (Mitsu-
the corporation they invest in (Kester, 1992), so bishi Heavy Industries), and banking (Mitsu-
that their ``weighted'' potential influence is bishi Bank).
relatively high. 16. The Kenkyusha's Japanese-English dictionary
10. In a study of Germany's 325 largest industrial (1987, p. 778) translates a keiretsu and its related
and financial firms, Ziegler et al. (1985) found meanings as ``a system; an order of descent;
that banks displayed the greatest number of succession; a series. Serial correlation. The
links where supervisory board members of two systematization of enterprises''. Zaibatsu and
different firms worked with each other on the its related meanings are translated as ``a
Aufsichtsrat of a third firm. Deutsche Bank had financial combine [group, clique]; a big busi-
by far the largest network, affecting 239 firms ness; the plutocracy; the plutocrats; a giant
through these links and links where it had family trust'' (p. 2037). The singular and plural
seats on the board of two or more different forms of both words are the same.
firms. 17. The formal responsibility of the board of
11. In Germany, the process of industrialization directors is to make managerial decisions. The
commenced in the second half of the last office of representative directors is responsible
century, much later than in the USA and the for executing the decisions of the board of
UK. The industrial revolution in the USA and directors. The office of auditors has the task to
the UK was financed by a broad cross-section supervise (or audit) the activities of both the
of private individuals willing and able to make directors and the representative directors. In so
equity investments, paving the way for a far as the function of the office of auditors is
market-oriented governance system with effi- separated formally from the board of directors
cient capital markets and dispersed ownership. and the office of representative directors, the
In particular at the end of both world wars, a Japanese board system resembles the board
comparable source of finance was not available system in Germany and the Netherlands. In
in Germany. Consequently, banks had to relation to the informal substructure Japanese
assume an active role in both granting credit companies frequently create, Corbett (1994)
and injecting equity capital (Schneider-LenneÂ, contends that ``the board is (. . .) hierarchically
1994). In addition, in the course of time some of ranked rather than functionally divided''
the outstanding credits were converted into (p. 320). In addition, she argues that the most
bank-held shares to assist reconstruction striking difference with the Anglo-Saxon board
(Dyson, 1986). These network-oriented devel- system is that most of the executive directors
opments are illustrated by the long list of will have formerly been middle managers who
actions in which German banks have deprived were promoted from the outside.
``predators'' of taking over a target firm 18. In this respect, Aoki (1984b) notes that that it is
through concerted action and instead have more correct to refer to the stable relationship
imposed their own solutions. Examples are the between the firm and its employees as long-
cases of SuÈddeutsche Chemiefaser, AEG, term employment instead of lifetime employ-
KloÈckner & Co., and Nixdorf (De Jong, 1989). ment. In addition, the long-term employment
12. For instance, in France two employee rep- is assured for male employees with a relatively
resentatives may attend board meetings, but high functional position at larger firms, but not
have no voting power. Trade unions do not for the majority of workers.
have to be consulted about a merger, but in 19. Shortly after World War II, the US administra-
firms with more than 50 employees they can tion in Japan dismantled the zaibatsu by selling
attend meetings between employers and em- the shares then held by the families to the
ployees. Workers' counsels are informed about general public. In accordance with the widely
bids but have no power to block them (Franks dispersed ownership in the USA, no individual
and Mayer, 1990). was allowed to acquire more than 1% of any
13. Listed companies may limit this transfer- company in this liquidation operation. In 1947
ability by contract, articles of incorporation the Japanese parliament passed an US-based
or establishment of private companies that Anti-Monopoly Law. As in the USA and in
hold a group of shareholders' capital. Market contrast to Germany, the Japanese banks were
illiquidity is further increased by the regu- kept out of the securities business as part of
lation that shareholders that have held shares this law. However, in the post-war era Japa-
for a specified period may be entitled to double nese firms re-established their old ties through
votes (Franks and Mayer, 1990). what was, in effect, a share buy-back process.
14. The majority of firms listed at the Tokyo Stock The regulatory framework imposed by the US
Exchange are part of a keiretsu. In March 1991 administration turned out to be unable to
they were responsible for 58% of all listed prevent the gradual reformation of corporate
corporations' sales excluding financial institu- grouping. The reformation process was in-
tions, 39% of net income, and 35% of net assets itiated and coordinated by the city banks
(Zielinski and Holloway, 1991). (Aoki, 1989). In 1991, Japanese firms (both
15. For example, the Mitsubishi Company was financial and non-financial) held 70% of all
established in 1870 and gradually expanded outstanding stock, approximately the same

Volume 7 Number 2 April 1999 # Blackwell Publishers Ltd 1999


THEORY PAPERS 165

degree of ownership by individuals in 1949 finance and industry: A comparative analysis of


(Zielinski and Holloway, 1991; see also Table postwar trends in six advanced industrial economies,
3). As a result, the zaibatsu seem to have been Brighton: Wheatsheaf.
revived in another form during the post-war Edwards, J.S.S. and Fischer, K. (1994) ``An over-
period, but instead of families the city banks view of the German financial system'', in: Dims-
now control them. The cultural tradition of dale, N. and Prevezer, M. (eds.), Capital markets
familyism played a significant role in prevent- and corporate governance, Oxford: Clarendon Press.
ing the US administration from establishing Fama, E.F. (1980) ``Agency problems and the
the reforms they had intended. In the words of theory of the firm'', Journal of Political Economy,
a Japanese executive: ``Because one parents are 88, pp. 288±307.
dead, one is not prevented from continuing as FIBV (FeÂdeÂration Internationale des Bourses de Valeurs)
before with one's brothers and sisters. What (1996) Statistics 1995, Paris: FIBV.
could be more natural than the brothers and Franks, J.R. and Mayer, C. (1990) ``Capital markets
sisters of a family helping each other to keep and corporate control: A study of France, Ger-
going as a group?'' (Oriental Economist, 1959, many and the UK'', Economic Policy, pp. 191±231.
cited in Gerlach, 1992, p. 109). Gelauff, G.M.M. and Den Broeder, C. (1996),
20. Several reasons may underlie such transfers. Governance of stakeholder relationships; the German
They include managerial reorganization when and Dutch experience, The Hague: Centraal Plan
the non-financial firm has been performing Bureau.
poorly, the finding of an equivalent status Gerlach, M.L. (1992) ``The Japanese corporate
position when a senior member of the bank network: A blockmodel analysis'', Administrative
staff is passed over for promotion in the bank, Science Quarterly, 1, pp. 105±139.
or the nearing of retirement of a bank staff Harrison, M. (1997) Asia-Pacific securities markets,
member (Corbett, 1994). Hong Kong: FT Financial Publishing Asia
21. Regarding the relation between the keiretsu and Pacific.
the market for corporate control, Nakatani Horner, M.R. (1988) ``The value of the corporate
(1984) contends that ``the primary purpose of voting right: Evidence from Switzerland'', Jour-
group formation seems to be the sharing of nal of Banking and Finance, 12, pp. 69±83.
risks and profits among group members by Hoshi, T., Kashap, A. and Scharfstein, D. (1990)
which stabilization of corporate performance is ``The role of banks in reducing the costs of
enhanced, but it is also important to note that financial distress in Japan'', Journal of Financial
group formation makes it possible for indi- Economics, 27, pp. 67±88.
vidual firms to insulate themselves from the ICMG (International Capital Markets Group)
imperatives of market forces, particularly of (1995) International corporate governance: Who
the capital market'' (p. 245). holds the reins?, London: ICMG.
Jensen, M.C. and Ruback, R.R. (1983) ``The market
for corporate control: The scientific evidence'',
References Journal of Financial Economics, 11, pp. 5±50.
Kaplan, S.N. (1995) ``Corporate governance and
Abowd, J. and Bognanno, M. (1995) ``International incentives in German companies: Evidence from
differences in executive and managerial com- top executive turnover and firm performance'',
pensation'', in: Freeman, R.B. and Katz, L.F. European Financial Management, 1, pp. 23±36.
(eds.), Differences and Changes in Wage Structures, Kester, W.C. (1992) ``Governance, contracting and
Chicago: University of Chicago Press. investment horizons: A look at Japan and
Aoki, M. (1984a) The cooperative game theory of the Germany'', Journal of Applied Corporate Finance,
firm, Oxford: Oxford University Press. 5, pp. 83±98.
Aoki, M. (1984b) ``Aspects of the Japanese firm'', Lorsch, J.W. and MacIver, E. (1989) Pawns or
in: Aoki, M. (ed.), The economic analysis of the potentates: The reality of America's corporate boards,
Japanese firm, Amsterdam: North-Holland. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
Aoki, M. (1989) Information, incentives and bargain- Manne, H. (1965) ``Mergers and the market for
ing in the Japanese economy, Cambridge: Cam- corporate control'', Journal of Political Economy,
bridge University Press. 74, pp. 110±120.
Bleicher, K. and Paul, H. (1986) ``Das Amerika- Masuyama, S. (1994) ``The role of Japanese capital
nische Board-Modell im Vergleich zur deutschen markets: The effect of cross-shareholdings on
Vorstands-/Aufsichtratsverfassung ± Stand und corporate accountability'', in: Dimsdale, N. and
Entwicklungstendenzen'', Die Betriebswirtschaft, Prevezer, M. (eds.), Capital markets and corporate
3, pp. 263±288. governance, Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Corbett, J. (1994) ``An overview of the Japanese Mayer, C. (1997) ``Corporate governance, competi-
financial system'', in: Dimsdale, N. and Prevezer, tion and performance'', Journal of Law and Society,
M. (eds.), Capital markets and corporate governance, 24, pp. 152±176.
Oxford: Clarendon Press. Mayer, C. and Alexander, I. (1990) ``Banks and
De Jong, H.W. (1989) ``The takeover market in securities markets: Corporate financing in
Europe: control structures and the performance Germany and the United Kingdom'', Journal
of large companies compared'', Review of Indus- of the Japanese and International Economies, 4,
trial Organization, 6, pp. 1-18. pp. 450±475.
Dyson, K. (1986) ``The state, banks and industry: Moerland, P.W. (1995a) ``Alternative disciplinary
The West German case'', in: Cox, A. (ed.), State, mechanisms in different corporate systems'',

# Blackwell Publishers Ltd 1999 Volume 7 Number 2 April 1999


166 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization, 26, Schneider-LenneÂ, E. (1994) ``The role of the German
pp. 17±34. capital markets and the universal banks, super-
Moerland, P.W. (1995b) ``Corporate ownership and visory boards, and interlocking directorships'',
control structures: An international comparison'', in: Dimsdale, N. and Prevezer, M. (eds.), Capital
Review of Industrial Organization, 10, pp. 443±464. markets and corporate governance, Oxford: Clar-
Nakatani, I. (1984) ``The economic role of financial endon Press.
corporate grouping'', in: Aoki, M. (ed.), The Scott, J. (1985) Corporations, classes and capitalism,
economic analysis of the Japanese firm, Amsterdam: London: Hutchinson.
North-Holland. Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R.W. (1997) ``A survey
OECD (1997) Economic Surveys: France 1997, Paris: of corporate governance'', Journal of Finance, 2,
OECD. pp. 737±783.
Orru, M., Hamilton, G.G. and Suzuki, M. (1989) Turnbull, S. (1997) ``Corporate governance: Its
``Patterns of inter-firm control in Japanese busi- scope, concerns and theories'', Corporate Govern-
ness'', Organization Studies, 10, pp. 549±574. ance, an International Review, 4, pp. 180±205.
Porter, M.E. (1992) ``Capital disadvantage: Amer- Weimer, J. (1995) Corporate financial goals, Ph.D.
ica's failing capital investment system'', Harvard thesis, Enschede: University of Twente Press.
Business Review, September-October, pp. 65±82. Ziegler, R., Bender, D. and Biehler, H. (1985)
Prodhan, B. (1993) ``Corporate governance and ``Industry and banking in the German corpor-
long-term performance'', International Review of ate network'', in: Stokman, F.N., Ziegler, J. and
Corporate Governance, 4, pp. 172±177. Scott, J. (eds.), Networks of corporate power: A
Prowse, S. (1995) ``Corporate Governance in an comparative analysis of ten countries, Cambridge:
international perspective; a survey of corporate Policy Press.
control mechanisms among large firms in the Zielinski, R. and Holloway, N. (1991) Unequal
US, UK, Japan and Germany'', Financial Markets equities: Power and risk in Japan's stock market,
and Institutions, 1, pp. 1±63. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Roe, M.J. (1990) ``Political and legal restraints on Zingales, L. (1994) ``The value of the voting right: A
ownership and control of public companies'', study of the Milan stock exchange experience'',
Journal of Financial Economics, 27, pp. 7±41. The Review of Financial Studies, 7, pp. 125±148.

Volume 7 Number 2 April 1999 # Blackwell Publishers Ltd 1999

You might also like