You are on page 1of 13

Blockchain Adoption among Multi-Stakeholders

under Government Subsidy: From the Technology


Diffusion Perspective
Shishu Ding 1; Hao Hu 2; Lei Dai 3; and Wen Wang 4
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by Natl Inst. Of Cons. Mgmt & Rsrch (nicmar) on 04/09/23. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

Abstract: Despite the well-documented benefits and encouraging policy environment for blockchain technology (BT), its extensive
adoption in the construction industry is still unsolved. The interorganizational diffusion of BT is not explored in existing studies, requiring
a comprehensive investigation for better government policymaking. Thus, from the technology diffusion perspective, this paper proposes an
evolutionary game-based system dynamics (EG-SD) model to describe the complicated relationships between government and construction
enterprises in the process of BT adoption. Through theoretical analysis, the main stakeholders, influencing factors, and diffusion channels in
the process of BT adoption are identified. Further, a simulation collecting data from China’s construction industry is conducted to evaluate the
diffusion performance under different scenarios. This study contributes to the body of knowledge by providing a quantitative perspective for
understanding BT adoption behaviors among construction enterprises and revealing the diffusion mechanism of BT from a multilevel
perspective. Also, this paper for the first time combines evolutionary game theory with system dynamics into explaining BT adoption,
providing practical implications to both government and construction enterprises on policymaking and promoting BT adoption practices.
DOI: 10.1061/JCEMD4.COENG-12637. © 2023 American Society of Civil Engineers.
Author keywords: Blockchain technology (BT); Technology diffusion; Government subsidy; Evolutionary game (EG) theory; System
dynamics (SD).

Introduction and Literature Review and uncertainty in construction management (Xu et al. 2022). It
has been regarded as a breakthrough innovation which reforms mu-
With the increasing pressure from the decline in labor and resources, tual trust among different participants in the construction industry.
the last decades witnessed a great transformation in the construc- Consequently, considering the disruptive benefits of BT, coun-
tion industry from labor-intensive to digital and automatic (Dou tries worldwide have proposed specific programs to embrace its
et al. 2020). Blockchain technology (BT), as an emerging technol- adoption. In 2016, the UK took the lead in issuing the white paper
ogy holding the promise of transparent, traceable, and reliable in- “Distributed Ledger Technology: Beyond Blockchain,” raising the
formation management (Yoon and Pishdad-Bozorgi 2022), has research and development of BT into the national strategic level
been viewed as an important booster for this global transformation. (GOS 2016). The Industry and Technology Minister in Turkey
In the last few years, BT has been widely implemented in various issued “Turkey’s 2023 Industry and Technology Strategy,” target-
fields of construction management such as information integration
ing the year 2023 by when a national platform will be established to
(Yang et al. 2020), quality management (Lee et al. 2021), and gov-
apply BT into the public administration and infrastructure manage-
ernmental supervision (Lu et al. 2021). The decentralized nature of
ment (ITMMV 2019). In 2021, the State Council of China issued
BT prevents issues such as information asymmetry, falsification,
the “National Standardization Development Outline” which clearly
and tampering, making it a desirable method to mitigate risks
proposes to strengthen the research on standards of BT, applying it
to improve quality governance (SCPRC 2021). Since then, local
1
Ph.D. Candidate, School of Naval Architecture, Ocean and Civil governments in China have launched numerous incentive policies
Engineering, Shanghai Jiao Tong Univ., Shanghai 201100, People’s Repub- and set up relevant supporting funds for promoting BT adoption.
lic of China. ORCID: https://orcid.org/0000-0001-6328-423X. Email: However, despite the well-documented benefits of BT and the
dss514324152@sjtu.edu.cn
2 encouraging policy environment, the adoption process of BT in the
Professor, School of Naval Architecture, Ocean and Civil Engineering,
Shanghai Jiao Tong Univ., Shanghai 201100, People’s Republic of China
construction industry is much slower than expected. In general,
(corresponding author). ORCID: https://orcid.org/0000-0002-1103-0243. incorporating BT into the construction industry is a lasting process
Email: hhu@sjtu.edu.cn through which BT is adopted and developed among various stake-
3 holders. Given the characteristics of BT, its adoption is a techno-
Associate Professor, School of Naval Architecture, Ocean and Civil
Engineering, Shanghai Jiao Tong Univ., Shanghai 201100, People’s Repub- logy diffusion phenomenon, which is defined as “the process by
lic of China. Email: dailei1989@sjtu.edu.cn which an innovation is communicated through certain channels
4
Ph.D. Candidate, School of Naval Architecture, Ocean and Civil over time among the members of a social system”(Rogers 1983).
Engineering, Shanghai Jiao Tong Univ., Shanghai 201100, People’s Repub- Technology diffusion has been a hot research topic in many fields
lic of China. Email: wangwen2018@sjtu.edu.cn
such as diffusion of green technology (Tian et al. 2014) and manu-
Note. This manuscript was submitted on April 29, 2022; approved on
September 8, 2022; published online on February 16, 2023. Discussion facturing mode (Wang et al. 2020a). In the construction industry,
period open until July 16, 2023; separate discussions must be submitted diffusion of information technologies such as building information
for individual papers. This paper is part of the Journal of Construction modeling (BIM) (Yuan and Yang 2020) and computer aided design
Engineering and Management, © ASCE, ISSN 0733-9364. (Kale and Ardit 2005) has also gained much attention.

© ASCE 04023016-1 J. Constr. Eng. Manage.

J. Constr. Eng. Manage., 2023, 149(5): 04023016


To comprehend BT diffusion, it is important to investigate how industry. Khan et al. (2021) identified ten critical factors influen-
the innovation (BT) is adopted and developed through what chan- cing BT adoption through a systematic literature survey. Kar and
nels among which members. Existing studies have investigated BT Navin (2021) reviewed both academic literature and industrial prac-
diffusion to some extent, mainly focusing on the identification of tices to understand the actual levels of BT adoption. Vu et al. (2021)
influencing factors such as opportunities, challenges, barriers, and conducted a literature review to identify the drivers, barriers, and
drivers (Clohessy and Acton 2019; Teisserenc and Sepasgozar implementation stages of BT. In those studies, BT diffusion was
2021; Wang et al. 2019). However, in those studies, BT diffusion mainly discussed based on qualitative descriptions. While in
was explained from a static and qualitative perspective, ignoring the practice, despite these claimed factors, the main motivation for
changing and dynamic nature of technology diffusion. In practice, enterprises adopting emerging technologies is the visible economic
BT, as an emerging innovation, is mainly adopted among construc- benefits from government subsidies, cost savings, and additional
tion firms through the motivation of the economic benefits brought profits (Cao et al. 2015).
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by Natl Inst. Of Cons. Mgmt & Rsrch (nicmar) on 04/09/23. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

by BT implementation, including reduction in costs, additional To author’s knowledge, there has been no research quantita-
profits, and government subsidy (Cao et al. 2015). Among those tively studying the BT diffusion from the economic perspective
benefits, government subsidy plays the dominant role since the which may be owing to the short time of BT development and
additional profits brought by BT implementation are relatively low in adoption in the construction industry. Nevertheless, many prior
the early stage of development. Under this circumstance, qualitative studies have explored the technology diffusion phenomenon across
descriptions of BT diffusion in existing studies without real-world different fields. Owing to cooperative and competitive characteris-
data support failed to provide practical guidelines on policymaking. tics of technology diffusion phenomenon, game theory has been
Many prior studies have applied game theory in investigating widely applied to find a balance of interests between different par-
the technology diffusion phenomenon across different fields ties (Eissa et al. 2021). In recent years, more and more studies have
(Cheng et al. 2020; Jia et al. 2021; Yuan and Yang 2020). These applied game theory into technology diffusion field with the rapid
studies have provided the groundwork for quantitative analysis of development of simulation methods (Yuan and Yang 2020). Espe-
BT diffusion while they mainly considered the interactions between cially, evolutionary game theory (EGT) has been widely used.
limited participants. Literature indicates that BT diffusion is a Compared with classical statistic game theories, it takes the limited
complex process, involving multiple stakeholders such as local rationality of organizations into consideration and helps to explain
governments, project owners, general contractors, and subcontrac- behavioral relations between those parties in a more practical and
tors, whose decisions would be pivotal in influencing technology realistic way (Lv et al. 2021). By combing game theory and
adoption (Yuan and Yang 2020). This paper argues that it is impor- dynamic evolution process analysis, it has been proven to be more
tant to take more stakeholders into consideration when analyzing suitable for investigating long-term dynamic game processes
BT diffusion to provide more practical implications on policy- (Cheng et al. 2020). By proposing a tripartite game model using
making. Meanwhile, literature reveals that besides government prospect theory and EGT, Jia et al. (2021) discussed the diffusion
subsidy, market competition is also an important factor affecting of BIM among various stakeholders in public-private-partnership
technology adoption significantly (Zhu and Weyant 2003) which (PPP) projects. Liu (2020) constructed an evolutionary game model
existing studies ignored. Those research gaps result in the ineffi- to explore diffusion of BIM between government and developers in
ciency of incentive policies provided by the governments, which the construction industry. A numerical simulation was conducted to
will further limit the BT adoption in the construction industry. analyze the decision-making development under different scenar-
Regarding these insufficiencies, this paper aims to investigate ios. Zhang et al. (2019) studied how the low-carbon policies pro-
how is BT diffused among various stakeholders in the construction mote diffusion of related technologies among alliance-based firms
industry under government subsidy. The primary objective of this in China based on EGT and complex networks. All those studies
paper is to describe the complicated relationships of BT adoption have proven the effectiveness of EGT for exploring technology dif-
among multiple stakeholders to deepen their understandings of how fusion across multiple industries.
to enhance BT adoption. Specifically, this paper proposes an Those aforementioned studies have provided the theoretical
EG-SD model to identify the relevant factors influencing stake- foundations for investigating BT diffusion in construction industry
holders’ decisions on BT adoption, and quantitatively analyze while they mainly focus on interactions between limited parties,
how different stakeholders’ decisions influence with each other. generally government and general contractors. The literature indi-
This research contributes to the body of knowledge by providing cates that BT diffusion is a complex process, involving multiple
a quantitative perspective for understanding BT adoption behaviors stakeholders such as local governments, project owners, general
among construction enterprises and revealing the diffusion mecha- contractors, and subcontractors, whose decisions would be pivotal
nism of BT from a multilevel perspective. Also, through the quan- in influencing technology adoption (Yuan and Yang 2020). Mean-
titative analysis, this paper will provide practical implications to both while, the literature reveals that besides government subsidy, mar-
government and construction enterprises on how to promote BT ket competition is also an important factor affecting technology
adoption in a more efficient way. adoption significantly (Zhu and Weyant 2003). Thus, not only sub-
The remainder of this study is organized as follows: The next sidizing & subsidized relations between government and contrac-
section reviewed the current works of BT diffusion in the construc- tors should be considered, but also cooperative & competitive
tion industry. Further, an analyzing model was proposed to describe relations between different contractors. However, the latter has
the diffusion process comprehensively, followed by a numerical rarely been explored in extant studies. Meanwhile, the analysis
simulation of diffusion performance under different scenarios. of BT diffusion based on EGT is relatively complicated, consisting
Based on simulation results, both theoretical and practical implica- of multiple participants and evolution phases (Guo et al. 2018).
tions were concluded. Finally, conclusions, limitations, and future System dynamics (SD), as a structural modelling technique capable
research were discussed. of understanding, simulating, and analyzing complex systems
In recent years, upon practical needs, increasing studies have (Peña-Mora et al. 2008), has proven to be effective in performing
been conducted on BT adoption and diffusion. For instance, Wang stable analysis and identifying equilibrium solutions in simulating
et al. (2017) investigated the technical, business-related, and the evolutionary game process (Liu et al. 2015). For instance, Tian
human-related challenges of BT adoption in the construction et al. (2014) applied SD to simulate the evolutionary game model of

© ASCE 04023016-2 J. Constr. Eng. Manage.

J. Constr. Eng. Manage., 2023, 149(5): 04023016


green supply chain diffusion in the Chinese manufacturing industry excessive financial burdens for local governments. Recently, some
under government subsidy. studies have claimed that dynamic subsidy may balance the diffu-
To sum up, despite the importance of BT diffusion, it has rarely sion performance and fiscal expenditure (Ji et al. 2019). However, it
been studied in extant studies owing to the complexity of interor- requires exploration in other fields for further validation. Thus, in
ganizational relationships and difficulty in data collection. This this paper, scenarios of LG aimed to investigate the efficiency of
paper’s literature study showed that limited studies have identified static and dynamic subsidies on diffusion performance to analyze
influencing factors of BT diffusion while no study quantitatively which is preferable. Also, within the project perspective, methods
explains the dynamic interactions among stakeholders. When of supply chain collaboration such as revenue-sharing (Zhang and
reviewing the literature on technology diffusion, it was discovered Ma 2020) cost-sharing (Wang et al. 2020a), and penalty for default
that most studies centered on the contacts between government and (Zhang and Ma 2020) have attracted much attention in existing
general contractors but ignored the inter-organizational interactions studies of technology diffusion. Specifically, scenarios of GCE
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by Natl Inst. Of Cons. Mgmt & Rsrch (nicmar) on 04/09/23. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

among different contractors, failing to provide comprehensive aim to discuss the effects of those collaborative measures on dif-
implications on BT diffusion and policy-making. The macrome- fusion performance.
chanism and microfeatures of the interorganizational diffusion of Then, the EG-SD model was proposed. In the EG part, some
BT are not clearly revealed, requiring further exploration. important hypotheses were made according to characteristics of
Therefore, this study combines EGT with SD and constructs a EGT, technology diffusion in construction industry, and BT imple-
comprehensive model to analyze the complicated relationships mentation. The EG model aimed to illustrate the interorganizational
between government and construction enterprises. The proposed interactions from the economic perspective. Also, it served as the
EG-SD model illustrates the holistic evolution process from the input of the simulation in the SD model. Further, the SD model was
external to the internal, revealing both macromechanism and micro- constructed to reveal the diffusion mechanism comprehensively.
characteristics among various stakeholders. The complicated relationship among tripartite stakeholders was
revealed, including evolution between different groups in GCEs and
SEs; competition and cooperation between GCEs and SEs, and
Development of the EG-SD Model subsidy from LG toward GCEs. Meanwhile, relevant factors influ-
encing BT diffusion and their causal relations were also identified.
Some factors have positive effects on BT diffusion while others
Analytical Framework have negative. Finally, based on inputs from the EG model and data
To better understand this study, the structure of the proposed model collected from literature and industry references, a numerical sim-
is presented in Fig. 1. In short, this study analyzed BT diffusion ulation was conducted. Diffusion performance under each scenario
under different scenarios among local government (LG), general was evaluated by conducting a sensitivity analysis regarding impor-
contractor enterprises (GCEs), and subcontractor enterprises (SEs). tant variables. Based on the discussion of simulation results, both
Through modeling, simulating, and discussing, both practical and practical implications on policymaking and theoretical implications
theoretical implications were concluded. on technology diffusion were concluded.
First, multiple scenarios for analyzing BT diffusion were iden-
tified. In general, subsidy from the government has been indicated
Evolutionary Game Model
as a critical factor for promoting technology adoption in the con-
struction industry (Eadie et al. 2013). Static subsidies, on the other To comprehend the model for better analysis, some assumptions are
hand, have been criticized for their low promotion efficiency and made as follows:

Scenarios Evolutionary Game-based System Dynamics Model Implications

Main stakeholders
LG Practical
Limited rationality & Invariable population
Static subsidy Subsidy
Hypothesis Individual interest maximization
policymaking
Dynamic subsidy Payoff-based conditional probability
Collaborative
Dynamic changing rate
measures

Compete
GCEs GCEs GCEs
(Develop BT) Evolve (Not Develop) Theoretical
Adoption degree

Reward Subsidy Diffusion mechanism


Revenue sharing
Government Compete of BT
Penalty
Cost-sharing
Prototype model of
Compete
Penalty for default SEs (Not Apply) BT diffusion
SEs (Apply BT)
Evolve

Fig. 1. Structure of the evolutionary game-based system dynamics model.

© ASCE 04023016-3 J. Constr. Eng. Manage.

J. Constr. Eng. Manage., 2023, 149(5): 04023016


Assumption 1: In this model, the LG, GCEs, and SEs are Macrodiffusion Module
selected as the main stakeholders in the construction industry.
In this module, the diffusion mechanism of BT among GCEs is
SEs refer to all other participants such as manufacturer and
modeled, with two level variables (GD and GN), one rate variable
supervisor.
(DR1 ), and other variables included. Those links represent the
Assumption 2: In this model, the total number of GCEs and SEs
causal associations between variables where links with + mean that
are assumed to be invariable. Within every time period, each GCE
the increase of variable A (end of the arrow) will lead to the in-
or SE will stick to a certain strategy. In the condition of market com-
crease of variable B (head of the arrow) while − mean the decrease
petition, they are assumed to seek maximization of their interests.
of B. Further, the implementation of BT is a lasting process and
Assumption 3: Adoption of BT, as a market activity, is to maxi-
GCEs take different time owing to the difference in scale, resource,
mize its economic benefits. Thus, the behaviors of the GCEs and
and culture. Thus, in this model, the implementation time is
SEs are determined by their payoffs (Chen et al. 2017). Suppose
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by Natl Inst. Of Cons. Mgmt & Rsrch (nicmar) on 04/09/23. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

assumed to be a normally distributed variable. Based on some prac-


that each GCE or SE randomly samples an agent from the corre-
tical policies launched in China, the maximization of implementa-
sponding population with equal probability, observes the respec-
tion time is set to be 2 years, and average to be 1 year. The main
tive strategy, and compares its payoff with the sampled one.
equations are presented as follows:
In the condition of market competition, they are assumed to seek
maximization of their interests. The average expected payoff (U) of DR1 ¼ GT × TR1 ð4Þ
GCEs for choosing the “develop” strategy is U GAD , and U GAN for
“not develop”. Further adjustment parameters are supplemented to TR1 ¼ DELAY FIXED
introduce randomness: U GD ¼ U GAD þ εGD and U GN ¼ U GAN þ
εGN , and εGD , εGN are normally distributed random variables. ðBR1 ; RANDOM NORMAL ð0; 2; 1; 0.1; 0Þ; BR1 Þ ð5Þ
Similarly, the average expected payoffs of SEs for choosing
“apply” and “not apply” strategies can be obtained as: U SA ¼ BR1 ¼ xð1 − xÞ½∅ðU GD − U GN Þ − ∅ðU GN − U GD Þ ð6Þ
U SAA þ εSA and U SN ¼ U SAN þ εSN respectively, and εSA , εSN
are normally distributed random variables. If an i-enterprise sam- GDt ¼ GDt−1 þ DR1 ð7Þ
ples a j-enterprise, then the i-enterprise will possibly switch to
GN t ¼ GN t−1 − DR1 ð8Þ
j-enterprise’s strategy if the observed payoff difference is positive
(Tian et al. 2014). The conditional probability of GCEs deciding to where DR1 = the promoting rate of BT in the population of GCEs;
switch from strategy i to j is ∅ðU Gi − U Gj Þ calculated as GT = the total number of GCEs; TR1 = the dynamic changing rate
8 after implementation time; BR1 = the basic changing rate of prob-
< U Gj − U Gi ; if U − U ≤ 0
>
ability of GCEs for choosing develop strategy; GDt = the number
Gi Gj
∅ðUGi − UGj Þ ¼ U Gi ði; j ¼ D; NÞ of GCEs choosing the develop strategy after time period t; and
>
:0 ifU Gi − U Gj ≥ 0 GN t = the number of GCEs choosing the not develop strategy after
time period t.
ð1Þ

Assumption 4: Assuming the probability of GCEs to choose the Microdiffusion Module


“develop” strategy is x, and 1 − x for choosing “not develop.”
Similarly, the probability of SEs to choose “apply” strategy is y, Compared with macro module, micro diffusion module illustrates
and 1 − y for “not apply”; and x and y are the functions of time t. the diffusion of BT among SEs from the project level. Implemen-
The basic dynamic changing rate of x and y be expressed as tation time is set to be 1 year (maximization), 0.5 years (average),
replicator dynamics equations (Weibull and Press 1997): while others are similar with those in the macrodiffusion module. It
shares a similar structure with the macrodiffusion module because
ẋ ¼ xð1 − xÞ½∅ðU GN − U GD Þ − ∅ðU GD − U GN Þ ð2Þ different stakeholders make decisions in the process of BT diffu-
sion in a similar way, based on the principle of interest maximiza-
ẏ ¼ yð1 − yÞ½∅ðU SN − U SA Þ − ∅ðU SA − U SN Þ ð3Þ tion. The main difference lies in the diffusion rate which is
fundamentally determined by the SEs’ payoff module
Assumption 5: Owing to the distributed nature of BT, its adop-
tion requires fully cooperation from all participants involved. DR2 ¼ ST × TR2 ð9Þ
Thus, GCEs choosing the develop strategy are cooperating with
SEs choosing apply while GCEs choosing not develop strategy TR2 ¼ DELAY FIXED
can only cooperate with SEs choosing not apply.
ðBR2 ; RANDOM NORMALð0; 1; 0.5; 0.1; 0Þ; BR2 Þ ð10Þ
Assumption 6: Unlike the diffusion of other ICTs such as BIM,
Barcode, and radio frequency identification (RFID) which have
BR2 ¼ yð1 − yÞ½∅ðU SA − U SN Þ − ∅ðU SN − U SA Þ ð11Þ
direct and visible effects in improving management performance,
the main benefits brough by BT implemented come from the
SAt ¼ SAt−1 þ DR2 ð12Þ
reinforcement of mutual trust among various stakeholders (Qian
and Papadonikolaki 2021). Thus, the additional profits brought SN t ¼ SN t−1 − DR2 ð13Þ
by BT in initial stage are low and increase quickly with BT diffu-
sion, and finally slow down till the limitation. where DR2 = the diffusion rate of blockchain in the population of
SEs; ST = the total number of SEs; TR2 = the dynamic changing
rate after implementation time; BR2 = the basic changing rate of
System Dynamics Model
probability of SEs for choosing the apply strategy; SAt = the
The SD model describes the evolutionary path of BT diffusion with number of SEs choosing the apply strategy after time period t; and
four modules: Macrodiffusion module, Microdiffusion module, SN t = the number of SEs choosing the not apply strategy after time
GCEs’ payoff module, and SEs’ payoff module. period t.

© ASCE 04023016-4 J. Constr. Eng. Manage.

J. Constr. Eng. Manage., 2023, 149(5): 04023016


Payoff Module of GCEs improvements in supply chain management efficiency, P1 for
the reduction in potential risks; α; β = the coefficient of profit-
In this module, the average expected payoff of GCEs choosing the
sharing and cost sharing between GCEs and SEs; C = the total cost
develop strategy U GAD and not develop strategy U GAN are estab-
of BT adoption, C0 = initial investment cost, and C1 = operation
lished. Payoffs of GCEs consist of two parts: the basic part and the
cost; and q = the degree of BT implementation.
BT part. Basic part refers to the basic profit of GCEs without BT
adoption. BT part refers to the additional benefits and costs in-
curred by BT implementation. In general, initial investment cost, Payoff Module of SEs
which may include procurement cost and training cost, decreases In this module, the average expected payoffs of SEs choosing apply
gradually with time passing and technology development (Yuan U SAA and not apply strategy U SAN are constructed. Similarly, SEs
and Yang 2020). Conversely, given the information storage char- choosing not apply can only obtain basic profit from project while
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by Natl Inst. Of Cons. Mgmt & Rsrch (nicmar) on 04/09/23. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

acteristics of BT, operation cost increases gradually with time. SEs choosing apply share additional costs and benefits with GCEs
Additional profits brought by BT embody in enhancement in mutual
trust among various stakeholders. It contains two main parts: GN
U SAN ¼ BS  ð20Þ
(1) improvements in supply chain management efficiency. Owing SN
to the automated characteristics of BT, labor cost, inventory cost,
quality cost and delivery cost can be decreased significantly (Wang GD
U SAA ¼ ðBS þ αPB − βCÞ ð21Þ
et al. 2020b); and (2) reduction in projects disputes. Owing to trans- SA
parent and traceable characteristics of BT, each procedure in con-
struction projects can be traced by each participant at any time. U SN ¼ U SAN þ εSN ; U SA ¼ U SAA þ εSA ð22Þ
Under this circumstance, costs for dispute resolution can be
reduced since BT provides a trustworthy platform (Li et al. 2018) εSA ; εSN ¼ RANDOM NORMALð−25; 25; 0; 10; 0Þ ð23Þ

SN Based on the previous analysis, the system dynamics model of


U GAN ¼ ðB − BS Þ ð14Þ BT diffusion among tripartite organizations is established and pre-
GN
sented in Fig. 2, with 4 level variables, 2 rate variable, 8 constant
SA variables, and 16 auxiliary variables.
U GAD ¼ ½B − BS þ ð1 − αÞPB − ð1 − βÞC þS ð15Þ
GD
t
C ¼ C0 e−qt þ C1 eq ð16Þ Simulation Results and Discussions

P1 þ P2 The proposed EG-SD model is customarily designed for the BT


PB ¼ ð17Þ diffusion in the construction industry. In this section, a numerical
1 þ e−qt
simulation collecting data from the China’s construction industry
U GN ¼ U GAN þ εGN ; U GD ¼ U GAD þ εGD ð18Þ was conducted. Since precast construction has been trending up
rapidly in China owing to its technical, economic, and environmental
εGN ; εGD ¼ RANDOM NORMALð−100,100; 0; 50; 0Þ ð19Þ advantages, incentive policies for promoting adoption of advanced
technologies are highly related with the precast construction mode.
where B = the total profit of project without BT implementation; Thus, this paper collected data from the China’s precast construction
BS = the basic profit for SEs without BT implementation; PB = market for further simulation. It is important to note, the simulation
the additional profit with implementation of BT, P1 = the results in this paper are supposed to be applicable for analysis of

Fig. 2. BT diffusion modules of GCEs and SEs.

© ASCE 04023016-5 J. Constr. Eng. Manage.

J. Constr. Eng. Manage., 2023, 149(5): 04023016


Table 1. Initial values of the simulation performance and reduction in risks. Wang et al. (2020b) con-
Variables Type Value Unit ducted a comprehensive simulation for analyzing the improve-
ments of BT implementation in construction management such
GD Level 35 1
as reduction in operation times and lead times. Further by collect-
SA Level 70 1
GT Constant 100 1
ing data from industry practices, the economic benefits of BT
ST Constant 330 1 implementation were quantified. Results in the study indicate
PB Constant 1.2 Million RMB that BT can decrease supply chain cost by 38%. The second part
S Constant 1 Million RMB of additional profits brought by BT lies in the reduction in dis-
B Constant 1 Million RMB putes in construction projects. Gebken and Gibson (2006) col-
BS Constant 3 Million RMB lected practical data from 46 construction projects to quantify
C0 Constant 0.7 Million RMB the costs for disputes resolution in the construction industry. Re-
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by Natl Inst. Of Cons. Mgmt & Rsrch (nicmar) on 04/09/23. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

C1 Constant 0.2 Million RMB sults in the study indicate that costs for disputes take 1.75% of the
total benefits. Combining the simulation results of existing stud-
ies with interviews with the related staff in Shanghai Jiangong
construction company, this paper assumes the additional profits
BT diffusion in the construction industry, not limited for precast
of BT account for 40% of the total profit of project. The rest of the
construction.
values were collected based on the interviews also. The initial
The initial values in this model were set up based on the situa-
values of the simulation are shown in Table 1. Working with
tion of technology diffusion in Shanghai’s AEC sector, with some
those values, the initial simulation results of BT diffusion among
specific modifications. In the model, the degree of BT adoption
GCEs are presented in Fig. 3 (q ¼ 1). It shows that GD (the num-
among multiple stakeholders was simplified as a variable owing
ber of GCEs choosing the develop strategy) increases gradually,
to its immeasurability. The subsidy for GCEs with BT implementa-
and after approximately 30 years of diffusion, all GCEs will
tion was set up according to “Policies for Promoting the Upgrading
adopt BT eventually. Meanwhile, the diffusion performance of
and Development of Blockchain Industry” issued by Shanghai,
different strategies is evaluated from both time and cost perspec-
China. According to statics published by the Ministry of Housing
tives. From the time perspective, diffusion performance is evalu-
and Urban-Rural Development of the People’s Republic of
ated by the time it takes when the adoption of BT in the
China, there were 9834 GCEs qualified for First Grade in China,
construction industry reaches the mature state. From the cost per-
with 7061 in architectural engineering construction. For Shang-
spective, diffusion performance is evaluated by the total amount
hai, there were 152 GCEs, with approximately 104 in architec-
of subsidies provided by the local government when the adoption
tural engineering construction. For the sake of perspicuity in
of BT reaches the mature state. Specifically, some criteria are se-
evaluation, there were assumed to be 100 GCEs and 330 SEs
lected in this paper, shown as follows:
in Shanghai, and respectively 35 and 70 of them have already
applied BT in their operations. It represented the initial values T 80 ∶diffusion time when 80% of totoal GCEs choose to
of xðtÞ and yðtÞ respectively. As for the additional profits of
BT, as aforementioned, it contains two parts: improvements in develop BT ð24Þ

Fig. 3. Simulation of BT diffusion under different implementation degrees.

© ASCE 04023016-6 J. Constr. Eng. Manage.

J. Constr. Eng. Manage., 2023, 149(5): 04023016


Z T 80 performance. These results are convergent with technical character-
S80 ¼ St  ðGDtþ1 − GDt Þdt ð25Þ istics of blockchain: decentralization. In blockchain networks,
o
all participants are bookkeepers, participating collaboratively to
In this model, it was assumed that the diffusion of BT has tended improve network security and efficiency.
to mature when 80% of total GCEs choose to adopt BT. The
remained part was believed to be caused by inherent resistance to
new technologies in construction industry and perceived lack of Impacts of Static and Dynamic Subsidy on BT
suitability of BT for all construction project management (Reza Diffusion Performance
et al. 2018). Specifically, diffusion performance of some strategies In static scenario, government subsidy will not change with time.
was evaluated by the T 80 criterion. The lower value of T 80 , the more The curves of the number of GD are shown in Fig. 4. It clearly
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by Natl Inst. Of Cons. Mgmt & Rsrch (nicmar) on 04/09/23. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

efficient the strategy is. For those subsidy-related strategies, an- shows that the increase of subsidy amount will accelerate the
other criterion S80 , the total amount of subsidies till T 80 , was also diffusion process, which is convergent with previous experience.
used for evaluation. The lower value of S80 , the more efficient the In dynamic scenario, the subsidy from government varies with
strategy is. the development and implementation of blockchain, presented as:

S ¼ ð1 − xÞS0 e−qt ð26Þ


Simulation under Different Scenarios
In the simulation, three pairs of comparisons between static
and dynamic subsidy strategies were selected and compared:
Impacts of Implementation Degree on BT Diffusion
(1) S ¼ 100 versus S ¼ ð1 − xÞ300e−qt ; (2) S ¼ 150 versus
Performance
S ¼ ð1 − xÞ400e−qt ; and (3) S ¼ 200 versus S ¼ ð1 − xÞ
In this situation, the degree of BT implementation (q) was changed 500e−qt . The curves of GD under different subsidy strategies were
from 20%, 40%, 60%, 80%, and 100% to simulate its effects on shown in Fig. 4. Apparently, all dynamic subsidy strategies have
diffusion performance. The curves of GD with time are shown advantages over corresponding static strategies on diffusion time.
in Fig. 3. In the initial scenario with q of 100%, it takes approx- Further, Fig. 5 illustrates the cumulative amount of subsidy with
imately 11 years to achieve mature diffusion in market and more time under those strategies visually. Compared with static subsidy,
than 30 years to fully diffused (fully diffusion is only for theoretical expenditure under dynamic scenarios increase rapidly in initial
reference, not represents practical situations in reality). At imple- stage but stabilize at a relatively lower level. Thus, it can be con-
mentation degrees of 20% and 40%, the number of GD will sta- cluded dynamic subsidy is more appealing from the whole life
bilize at 38 and 64 respectively after long-term diffusion process, cycle perspective of technology diffusion. Meanwhile, to evaluate
failing to reach maturity. At degree of 60% and 80%, market matu- the diffusion performance quantitatively, the exact data of evalu-
rity is achieved eventually while T 80 are much higher than that in ation criteria are collected and summarized in Table 2. Comparing
the initial scenario. According to the simulation results, degree the three sets of simulation, it can be observed that the time to reach
of BT implementation which represents the level of cooperation market maturity (T 80 ) under the dynamic subsidy has been short-
among various stakeholders, positively influences the diffusion ened by 1.80%, 2.17%, and 0.95% respectively. Meanwhile, S80 of

Zoom in

Fig. 4. Simulation of BT diffusion under different subsidy strategies.

© ASCE 04023016-7 J. Constr. Eng. Manage.

J. Constr. Eng. Manage., 2023, 149(5): 04023016


Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by Natl Inst. Of Cons. Mgmt & Rsrch (nicmar) on 04/09/23. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

Fig. 5. Total subsidy amount under different subsidy strategies.

Table 2. Diffusion performance under different subsidy strategies In this simulation, the penalty was increased from 0 to 200 with
T s80− T d80 Ss80 − Sd80 the step of 20. The number of GD with time are presented in Fig. 6.
T d80 Sd80
However, T 80 has never changed under different scenarios. It seems
Subsidy T 80 S80
that penalty-settings have no influence on BT diffusion, inconsis-
100 11.31 — 4,795.3 — tent with previous studies.
ð1 − xÞ300e−t 11.11 1.80% 4,442.8 7.93%
150 10.35 — 6,750.7 —
ð1 − xÞ400e−t 10.13 2.17% 6,688.0 0.94% Impacts of Revenue Sharing Strategies on BT
200 9.56 — 8,996.6 — Diffusion Performance
ð1 − xÞ500e−t 9.47 0.95% 8,462.9 6.31%
In this simulation, the coefficient of revenue-sharing (α) between
GCEs and SEs was increased from 0% to 100% with the step of
10% to evaluate its influences. The curves of GD with time are
dynamic subsidy strategies in each group are also less by respec-
shown in Fig. 7. It can be found T 80 decreased remarkably with
tively 7.93%, 0.94%, 6.31%. In other words, it takes less time and
increase in α but rebounded slightly in the end. Similarly, exact
less financial expenditure for government to promote BT adoption
data of evaluation criteria were collected and summarized in
under dynamic subsidy.
Table 3. When α is less than 70%, increase in α will shorten T 80
prominently, from 11.31 to 8.54 years. It proves the positive effects
Impacts of Penalty-Settings on BT Diffusion on BT diffusion. But to mention, the marginal increase in diffusion
Performance performance brought by α is also decreasing, which means diffu-
sion performance increases slower and slower with continuous
In practice, some safeguards are always taken to secure the effec- increase in α. When exceeding more than 70%, an increase in α
tiveness of government subsidies. Besides deterrence from admin- will cause longer time for market mature. It is natural to conclude
istrative measures, the penalty for breach of contract is always that there exists an optimum proportion of revenue-sharing between
recognized as an effective method. In following simulation, effects GCEs and SEs for BT diffusion, between 60% to 80%. However, in
of penalty-setting for GCEs were evaluated. GD obtain direct sub- practice, it is difficult to distribute such additional profits from
sidy from government while a penalty will be imposed if breaching GCEs to SEs to achieve the optimum diffusion of BT.
the contract (switching to the Not develop strategy). In this model,
penalty-setting is directly associated with payoffs of GCEs, influ-
encing the conditional probability function of switching from Impacts of Cost-Sharing Strategies on BT Diffusion
strategy j to i. The equations are represented in the followings: Performance
8
< U GN − U GD − PG ; if U − U − P ≥ 0 In practice, cost-sharing has been viewed as an effective collabo-
∅ðU GD − U GN Þ ¼ U GD GN GD G rative measure to bind the interests of different organizations up to
: foster common goals among upstream and downstream enterprises
0 if U GN − U GD − PG ≤ 0
in the construction supply chains. In following simulation, the
ð27Þ effects of cost-sharing strategies on diffusion performance were

© ASCE 04023016-8 J. Constr. Eng. Manage.

J. Constr. Eng. Manage., 2023, 149(5): 04023016


Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by Natl Inst. Of Cons. Mgmt & Rsrch (nicmar) on 04/09/23. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

Fig. 6. Simulation of BT diffusion under different penalty-setting strategies.

Zoom in

Fig. 7. Simulation of BT diffusion under different profit-sharing strategies.

analyzed. The coefficient of cost-sharing between GCEs and SEs cost-sharing strategies hinder BT diffusion process. Compared with
(β) was increased from 0 to 0.5 with the step of 5% and the curves profit-sharing strategy, conversely, the marginal decrease in diffusion
of GD under each scenario were shown in Fig. 8. It can be found performance brought by β is increasing. In other words, diffusion
that T 80 increased continuously with increase in β, which indicates performance decreases much faster with continuous increase in β.

© ASCE 04023016-9 J. Constr. Eng. Manage.

J. Constr. Eng. Manage., 2023, 149(5): 04023016


Table 3. Diffusion performance under different profit-sharing strategies incentive policies to balance financial burdens and promotion
a T 80 Margin (%) performance.
3. Sharing of additional profits brought by BT adoption between
0 11.3 0
GCEs and SEs promotes the diffusion performance while sharing
0.1 10.25 9.4
0.2 9.6 6.3
of implementation and operation costs hinders it. Meanwhile,
0.3 9.17 4.5 strategy of penalty will also not contribute to the BT diffusion.
0.4 8.88 3.2 However, there remained a question: Why did cost-sharing and
0.5 8.69 2.1 penalty-setting strategies fail to contribute to BT diffusion? Driven
0.6 8.58 1.3 by this doubt, we further investigated into the payoffs of GCEs
0.7 8.54 0.5 and SEs and the reasons behind them were revealed. This is owing
0.8 8.57 −0.4 to the higher capacity of cost-bearing of GCEs compared with
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by Natl Inst. Of Cons. Mgmt & Rsrch (nicmar) on 04/09/23. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

0.9 8.64 −0.8 SEs. Compared with GCEs which obtained direct subsidy from
1 8.78 −1.6 government, SEs were more vulnerable to costs incurred by BT
adoption. Any increase in costs will decrease SEs’ enthusiasm for
adopting BT. As for the invalidity of penalty-settings strategies,
since the payoffs of GCEs choosing develop strategies were higher
Discussion that of GCEs choosing not develop from the beginning of the
Based on the simulation results of the proposed model, some simulation to the end, it is not rational for GCEs breaching the
important conclusions regarding better diffusion of BT can be contract of subsidy. Thus, the conditional probability functions of
GCEs were not influenced. Consequently, it failed to promote BT
obtained as the follows:
diffusion eventually.
1. Degree of BT implementation affects its diffusion performance
significantly. The higher degree of BT implementation, which
also means higher level of cooperation among stakeholders, Implications
could bring more additional profits, and accelerate the diffusion
process prominently. This finding is also consistent with the
technical characteristics of blockchain: decentralization, which Theoretical Implications
requires fully coordination among participants. Based on the previous theoretical and numerical simulation analy-
2. Dynamic subsidies are proved to be more effective in promot- sis, this study provides theoretical implications to further research
ing BT adoption and implementation than static subsidies. in the technology diffusion field from three aspects.
Static subsidies can be replaced with dynamic ones which First, based on the combination of evolutionary game theory and
provide higher subsidies when the potential benefits of BT system dynamics, this study has revealed the main stakeholders
implementation are not appealing and decrease gradually (LG, GCEs, SEs), the diffusion channels (industry-level diffusion
with the influx of adopters. This finding will provide practical channel: diffusion within GCEs’ population; and project-level
suggestions for local governments as they issue relevant diffusion channel: diffusion within SEs’ population), the related

Fig. 8. Simulation of BT diffusion under different cost-sharing strategies.

© ASCE 04023016-10 J. Constr. Eng. Manage.

J. Constr. Eng. Manage., 2023, 149(5): 04023016


influencing factors (additional profits, investment costs, gov- issue guidelines for better BT diffusion to those subsidized
ernment subsidy, profit-sharing coefficient, and cost-sharing coef- enterprises.
ficient), and the interorganizational interactions among main For construction enterprises, the simulation results also show
stakeholders (evolution within GCEs’ and SEs’ population; com- that the supply chain collaboration measures significantly influence
petition and cooperation between GCEs and SEs choosing different BT technology diffusion. The profit-sharing strategy successfully
strategies; and subsidizing and subsidized relations between LG binds the interests of GCEs with SEs to form a common goal in
and GCEs) of BT diffusion. Such findings contribute to a new the BT diffusion process. Therefore, it is recommended that an ap-
perspective for understanding BT diffusion process, serving as propriate division of additional profits between GCEs and SEs,
theoretical foundations for further research into the comprehensive generally not the optimum in practice, is needed to promote the
diffusion mechanism. diffusion performance. While how to balance the interests of differ-
Second, findings in this paper further validate the feasibility of ent organizations in the technology promotion process requires
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by Natl Inst. Of Cons. Mgmt & Rsrch (nicmar) on 04/09/23. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

dynamic government subsidy in promoting technology diffusion further investigation. GCEs are also suggested to adjust the profit-
performance. On one hand, the conclusion echoes earlier studies sharing strategies dynamically to balance their profits and the social
emphasizing the government’s significant role in promoting emerg- responsibility of technology promotion. Another noteworthy impli-
ing technology adoption and implementation (Reza et al. 2018; cation is that the degree of technology implementation plays an
Yuan and Yang 2020) and the efficiency of dynamic subsidy in important role in promoting BT adoption. In real practice, the
balancing diffusion performance and financial burdens of local degree of implementation (q) would depend on various factors such
governments (Tian et al. 2014). On the other hand, this paper pro- as the information compatibility and interchangeability (Wang et al.
poses a representation of dynamic government subsidy which 2020b), price volatility (Hamledari and Fischer 2021), organiza-
varies with time and technology implementation. Further investi- tional culture (Kar and Navin 2021; Khan et al. 2021), and stake-
gation into policy-making efficiency could be achieved based on holders’ involvement (Khan et al. 2021). Thus, construction firms
modifications of this representation. Meanwhile, this study pro- are suggested to conduct explorative projects for blockchain
posed some criteria for efficiency evaluation of government sub- research, development, and maintenance collaboratively to improve
sidy (e.g., T 80 ; S80 ). More complicated cost-effectiveness analysis their BT adoption efficiency.
of government subsidy can be conducted by referring to the pro-
posed criteria and simulation results.
Finally, the stakeholder identification, parameter and variable Conclusions
settings; simulation scenarios, data collection, and the analytical
process in this paper could provide references for research of tech- Owing to the revolutionary reform of mutual trust brought by
nology diffusion in other countries whose situations are similar blockchain technology, its diffusion mechanism, as a new-developing
to China. stream of research though, has attracted considerable attention from
both practitioners and scholars worldwide. The primary objective
of this paper was to explore the complicated relationships of BT
Practical Implications diffusion among multiple stakeholders to deepen their understand-
Meanwhile, analysis and findings in this study have significant ings of how to enhance BT adoption. Through an in-depth inves-
implications for both local government and construction enterprises tigation, some theoretical and practical contributions of this study
in industry practices. can be concluded as follows:
For government, the simulation results prove that dynamic 1. This study for the first time introduces the evolutionary game
government subsidies are more effective in promoting BT diffusion theory and system dynamics into explaining the BT diffusion
than static subsidies. The findings are very inspiring for the local in the construction industry and further proposes an EG-SD
governments since it indicates the current paradigm of uniform sub- model to identify and analyze the influencing factors, related
sidy policy for construction firms is not optimal from both time and stakeholders, spread channels, and interorganizational interac-
monetary perspectives. Conversely, dynamic subsidy policy varies tions in BT diffusion processes. It provides theoretical founda-
with time and technology development is more appealing. In prac- tions for further investigation into BT adoption;
tice, government should provide high fiscal subsidy to appeal 2. This study contributes to the body of knowledge by providing a
GCEs for BT adoption in the initial stage, owing to the resistance quantitative perspective for understanding BT adoption behav-
caused by technology barriers and difficulty in development. With iors among construction enterprises and revealing the diffusion
the rapid development of BT, technical and economic thresholds for mechanism of BT from a multilevel perspective; and
new enterprises adopting BT decrease. Consequently, government 3. This study simulated the diffusion performance of BT under dif-
may adjust its subsidy policy since more GCEs will adopt BT even ferent strategies through data collection in China’s construction
less subsidies provided. When the market maturity is achieving, industry. Based on simulation results, some important implica-
GCEs will adopt and implement BT spontaneously driven by com- tions are drawn to provide practical help to governments for bet-
petition from market. To conclude, the government is suggested to ter policymaking and construction firms to promote BT adoption
design appropriate policies according to BT diffusion characteris- in practice. Also, this model can be modified and further applied
tics to balance the effectiveness of incentive policies and techno- in construction industries of countries similar to China.
logy promotion needs, and develop pilot projects to examine the Nevertheless, there are also some limitations in this study. For
efficiency of different dynamic subsidies (linear, polynomial, or instance, the stakeholder network in this model is relatively sim-
exponential). plified. Consideration of the upstream and downstream enterprises
The industry-level diffusion of BT mainly relies on government in a construction supply chain has not been involved. In practice,
subsidy, while the project-level diffusion requires efforts from gen- there are additional stakeholders who play important roles in the
eral contractors. Thus, authors highly suggest local government diffusion of BT, such as banks, insurance companies, and other
to attach more deterrent clauses for diffusion performance when financial institutions. Another limitation is the simplification of
subsidizing construction enterprises, shifting part of pressure to preference and unique characteristics of different subcontractors
them. Also, findings from this study may help local government toward BT implementation. Different subcontractors hold different

© ASCE 04023016-11 J. Constr. Eng. Manage.

J. Constr. Eng. Manage., 2023, 149(5): 04023016


views toward adoption of advanced ICTs. Thus, in the future, a 1135–1141. https://doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)0733-9364(2005)131:10
more complicated model will be needed to explore the path of (1135).
BT diffusion more comprehensively, considering more stakehol- Kar, A. K., and L. Navin. 2021. “Diffusion of blockchain in insurance
ders and their various preferences. industry: An analysis through the review of academic and trade literature.”
Telemat. Inform. 58 (May): 101532. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tele.2020
.101532.
Khan, S., R. Singh, and M. Kirti. 2021. “Critical factors for blockchain
Data Availability Statement technology implementation: A supply chain perspective.” J. Ind. Integr.
Manage. 2021 (Mar): 2150011. https://doi.org/10.1142/S24248622
Some or all data, models, or code that support the findings of this 21500111.
study are available from the corresponding author upon reasonable Lee, D., S. H. Lee, N. Masoud, M. S. Krishnan, and V. C. Li. 2021.
request. “Integrated digital twin and blockchain framework to support account-
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by Natl Inst. Of Cons. Mgmt & Rsrch (nicmar) on 04/09/23. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

able information sharing in construction projects.” Autom. Constr.


127 (Jul): 103688. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.autcon.2021.103688.
References Li, J., W. Jiang, and J. Zuo. 2018. “The effects of trust network among
project participants on project performance based on SNA approach:
Cao, D., G. Wang, H. Li, M. Skitmore, T. Huang, and W. Zhang. 2015. A case study in China.” Int. J. Constr. Manage. 20 (8): 837–847.
“Practices and effectiveness of building information modelling in con- https://doi.org/10.1080/15623599.2018.1494672.
struction projects in China.” Autom. Constr. 49 (Jan): 113–122. https:// Liu, Q., X. Li, and M. Hassall. 2015. “Evolutionary game analysis and
doi.org/10.1016/j.autcon.2014.10.014. stability control scenarios of coal mine safety inspection system in
Chen, K., W. Lu, Y. Peng, L. Zheng, Y. Niu, and S. Rowlinson. 2017. China based on system dynamics.” Saf. Sci. 80 (Dec): 13–22. https://
“An investigation of the latent barriers to BIM adoption and develop- doi.org/10.1016/j.ssci.2015.07.005.
ment.” In Proc., 20th Int. Symp. Advance Construction Management Liu, Y. 2020. “Evolutionary game between developers and governments
Real Estate, 1007–1017. Berlin: Springer. in the development of BIM technology.” In Proc., ICCREM 2020:
Cheng, B., Y. Wei, W. Zhang, X. Zhou, H. Chen, L. Huang, J. Huang, Intelligent Construction Sustainable Buildings, 704–711. Reston, VA:
X. Kang, and M. I. Uddin. 2020. “Evolutionary game simulation on ASCE.
government incentive strategies of prefabricated construction: A system Lu, W., L. Wu, R. Zhao, X. Li, and F. Xue. 2021. “Blockchain technology
dynamics approach.” Complexity 2020: 1–11. https://doi.org/10.1155 for governmental supervision of construction work: Learning from
/2020/8861146. digital currency electronic payment systems.” J. Constr. Eng. Manage.
Clohessy, T., and T. Acton. 2019. “Investigating the influence of organi- 147 (10): 04021122. https://doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)CO.1943-7862
zational factors on blockchain adoption.” Indus. Manage. Data Syst. .0002148.
119 (7): 1457–1491. https://doi.org/10.1108/IMDS-08-2018-0365. Lv, J., M. Lin, W. Zhou, and M. Xu. 2021. “How PPP renegotiation behav-
Dou, Y., X. Xue, C. Wu, X. Luo, and Y. Wang. 2020. “Interorganizational iors evolve with traffic changes: Evolutionary game approach.”
diffusion of prefabricated construction technology: Two-stage evolution J. Constr. Eng. Manage. 147 (5): 04021032. https://doi.org/10.1061
framework.” J. Constr. Eng. Manage. 146 (9): 04020114. https://doi /(ASCE)CO.1943-7862.0002024.
.org/10.1061/(ASCE)CO.1943-7862.0001904. Peña-Mora, F., S. Han, S. Lee, and M. Park. 2008. “Strategic-operational
Eadie, R., M. Browne, H. Odeyinka, C. McKeown, and S. McNiff. 2013. construction management: Hybrid system dynamics and discrete event
“BIM implementation throughout the UK construction project lifecycle: approach.” J. Constr. Eng. Manage. 134 (9): 701–710. https://doi.org
An analysis.” Autom. Constr. 36 (Dec): 145–151. https://doi.org/10 /10.1061/(ASCE)0733-9364(2008)134:9(701).
.1016/j.autcon.2013.09.001. Qian, X., and E. Papadonikolaki. 2021. “Shifting trust in construction supply
Eissa, R., M. S. Eid, and E. Elbeltagi. 2021. “Current applications of game chains through blockchain technology.” Eng. Constr. Archit. Manage.
theory in construction engineering and management research: A social 28 (2): 584–602. https://doi.org/10.1108/ECAM-12-2019-0676.
network analysis approach.” J. Constr. Eng. Manage. 147 (7): Reza, H., E. A. Pärn, D. J. Edwards, E. Papadonikolaki, and M. Oraee.
04021066. https://doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)CO.1943-7862.0002085. 2018. “Roadmap to mature BIM use in Australian SMEs: Competitive
Gebken, R. J., and G. E. Gibson. 2006. “Quantification of costs for dispute dynamics perspective.” J. Constr. Eng. Manage. 34 (5): 05018008.
resolution proceduresin the construction industry.” J. Civ. Eng. Educ.
https://doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)ME.1943-5479.0000636.
132 (3): 264–271. https://doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)1052-3928(2006)
Rogers, E. 1983. Diffusion of innovations. New York: The Free Press.
132:3(264).
SCPRC (State Council of the People’s Republic of China). 2021. National
GOS (Government Office for Science). 2016. Distributed ledger techno-
standardization development outline. Beijing: SCPRC.
logy: Beyond blockchain. London: GOS.
Guo, S., P. Zhang, and J. Yang. 2018. “System dynamics model based on Teisserenc, B., and S. Sepasgozar. 2021. “Project data categorization, adop-
evolutionary game theory for quality supervision among construction tion factors, and non-functional requirements for blockchain based
stakeholders.” J. Civ. Eng. Manage. 24 (4): 318–330. https://doi.org/10 digital twins in the construction industry 4.0.” Buildings 11 (12): 626.
.3846/jcem.2018.3068. https://doi.org/10.3390/buildings11120626.
Hamledari, H., and M. Fischer. 2021. “The application of blockchain-based Tian, Y., K. Govindan, and Q. Zhu. 2014. “A system dynamics model based
crypto assets for integrating the physical and financial supply chains in on evolutionary game theory for green supply chain management
the construction and engineering industry.” Autom. Constr. 127 (Jul): diffusion among Chinese manufacturers.” J. Cleaner Prod. 80 (Oct):
103711. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.autcon.2021.103711. 96–105. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2014.05.076.
ITMMV (Industry and Technology Minister Mustafa Varank). 2019. Vu, N., A. Ghadge, and M. Bourlakis. 2021. “Blockchain adoption in
Turkey’s 2023 industry and technology strategy. Ankara, Turkey: food supply chains: A review and implementation framework.” Prod.
ITMMV. Plan. Control 2021 (Jun): 1–18. https://doi.org/10.1080/09537287
Ji, S.-F., D. Zhao, and R.-J. Luo. 2019. “Evolutionary game analysis on .2021.1939902.
local governments and manufacturers’ behavioral strategies: Impact Wang, J., P. Wu, X. Wang, and W. Shou. 2017. “The outlook of blockchain
of phasing out subsidies for new energy vehicles.” Energy 189 (Dec): technology for construction engineering management.” Front. Eng.
116064. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2019.116064. Manage. 4 (1): 67–75. https://doi.org/10.15302/J-FEM-2017006.
Jia, C., R. Zhang, D. Wang, and D. Salvati. 2021. “Evolutionary game Wang, T., C. Li, and P. Zhang. 2020a. “A system dynamics model for the
analysis of BIM adoption among stakeholders in PPP projects.” diffusion of cloud manufacturing mode with evolutionary game theory.”
Complexity 2021: 1–14. https://doi.org/10.1155/2021/5553785. IEEE Access 9 (Dec): 1428–1438.
Kale, S., and D. Ardit. 2005. “Diffusion of computer aided design technol- Wang, Y., J. H. Han, and P. Beynon-Davies. 2019. “Understanding block-
ogy in architectural design practice.” J. Constr. Eng. Manage. 131 (10): chain technology for future supply chains: A systematic literature review

© ASCE 04023016-12 J. Constr. Eng. Manage.

J. Constr. Eng. Manage., 2023, 149(5): 04023016


and research agenda.” Supply Chain Manage. Int. J. 24 (1): 62–84. Manage. 148 (2): 03121008. https://doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)CO
https://doi.org/10.1108/SCM-03-2018-0148. .1943-7862.0002235.
Wang, Z., T. Wang, H. Hu, J. Gong, X. Ren, and Q. Xiao. 2020b. “Block- Yuan, H., and Y. Yang. 2020. “BIM adoption under government sub-
chain-based framework for improving supply chain traceability and sidy: Technology diffusion perspective.” J. Constr. Eng. Manage.
information sharing in precast construction.” Autom. Constr. 111 (Mar): 146 (1): 04019089. https://doi.org/10.1061/(ASCE)CO.1943-7862
103063. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.autcon.2019.103063. .0001733.
Weibull, J. W., and M. Press. 1997. Evolutionary game theory. New York: Zhang, L., L. Xue, and Y. Zhou. 2019. “How do low-carbon policies pro-
MIT Press. mote green diffusion among alliance-based firms in China? An
Xu, Y., H.-Y. Chong, and M. Chi. 2022. “Blockchain in the AECO industry: evolutionary-game model of complex networks.” J. Cleaner Prod.
Current status, key topics, and future research agenda.” Autom. Constr. 210 (2019): 518–529. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.11.028.
134 (21): 104101. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.autcon.2021.104101. Zhang, R., and W. Ma. 2020. “Assessing the role of reward and punishment
Yang, R., R. Wakefield, S. Lyu, S. Jayasuriya, F. Han, X. Yi, X. Yang, mechanism in house price regulation in China: A game-theoretic ap-
Downloaded from ascelibrary.org by Natl Inst. Of Cons. Mgmt & Rsrch (nicmar) on 04/09/23. Copyright ASCE. For personal use only; all rights reserved.

G. Amarasinghe, and S. Chen. 2020. “Public and private blockchain in proach.” J. Urban Plann. Dev. 146 (3): 04020030. https://doi.org/10
construction business process and information integration.” Autom. Constr. .1061/(ASCE)UP.1943-5444.0000602.
118 (20): 103276. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.autcon.2020.103276. Zhu, K., and J. Weyant. 2003. “Strategic decisions of new technology adop-
Yoon, J. H., and P. Pishdad-Bozorgi. 2022. “State-of-the-art review tion under asymmetric information: A game theoretic model.” Decis. Sci.
of blockchain-enabled construction supply chain.” J. Constr. Eng. 34 (4): 643–675. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5414.2003.02460.x.

© ASCE 04023016-13 J. Constr. Eng. Manage.

J. Constr. Eng. Manage., 2023, 149(5): 04023016

You might also like