You are on page 1of 15

Vol. 13(1), pp.

1-15, January-March 2021


DOI: 10.5897/JAT2020.0429
Article Number: E7D489D65897
ISSN 2141-6664
Copyright © 2021
Author(s) retain the copyright of this article Journal of Accounting and Taxation
http://www.academicjournals.org/JAT

Full Length Research Paper

Closed form solution for the valuation of deferred


tax assets
João Marques Silva1, Nuno Souto1 and José Azevedo Pereira2
1
Instituto de Telecomunicações - IUL (ISTA), Universitário de Lisboa (ISCTE-IUL), Lisbon, Portugal.
2
Department of Management, Advance/CSG, ISEG, Universidade de Lisboa, Lisboa, Portugal.
Received 9 October, 2020; Accepted 12 November, 2020

Deferred tax asset (DTA) is a tax/accounting concept that refers to an asset that may be used to reduce
future tax liabilities of the holder. In the banking sector, it usually refers to situations where a bank has
either overpaid taxes, paid taxes in advance or has carry-over of losses (the latter being the most
common situation). In fact, accounting and tax losses may be used to shield future profits from
taxation, through tax loss carry-forwards. In other words, DTAs are contingent claims, whose
underlying assets are banks future profits. Consequently, the correct approach to value such rights
implies necessarily, the use of a contingent claim valuation framework. Despite that, one common
practice consists of valuing DTAs as though they would be used at 100% without even discounting for
the time value of money. Another common procedure consists of considering a subjective “valuation
allowance”, valuing the deferred tax asset as a certain percentage of the corresponding maximum
value, according to future expectations on the company’s financial performance. The purpose of this
paper is exactly to propose a precise and conceptually sound mathematical approach to value DTAs,
considering future projections of earnings and rates, alongside the DTA’s legal time limit. It will be
shown that with the proposed evaluation techniques, the DTA’s expected value will be much lower than
the values normally used in today’s practice, and the bank’s financial analysis will lead to much more
sound and realistic results.

Key words: Valuation, deferred tax asset, banking sector, balance sheet, binomial.

INTRODUCTION

There have been many attempts to reach a conformity The potential benefits would include lower compliance
about the way income tax is treated, that is, to uniformize costs for reporting income and the potential lowering of
tax rates and regulations across international entities, but incentives to mislead the Internal Revenue Service (IRS)
the complexity of this topic has raised some issues and and capital markets (basically deterring entities from
critics; Hanlon and Shevlin (2005) and Atwood et al. engaging into tax shelters and schemes).
(2010) stated that earnings persistence and the association The tax return of a company is based on its accounting
between current earnings and future cash flows are lower financial statements. To provide comparable information,
when the level of required book-tax conformity is higher. financial statements are prepared according to the

*Corresponding author. E-mail: joao.silva@iscte.pt, nuno.souto@iscte.pt, jpereira@iseg.ulisboa.pt.

Author(s) agree that this article remain permanently open access under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution
License 4.0 International License
2 J. Account. Taxation

International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS), for a certain period, therefore eliminating deferred tax
issued by the International Accounting Standards Board assets and liabilities. The idea of removing deferred taxes
(IASB). The IASB was formed in 2001 to replace the from the balance sheet has been supported by other
International Accounting Standards Committee that authors like Chaney (1994) and Ketz (2010) that argue
issued International Accounting Standards (IAS). Since that deferred tax accounting is too complex, too
the previously issued IASs remain effective, we have that expensive and too inconsistent with the US GAAP.
the main body of standards that are used worldwide by
several countries comprised IFRSs and IASs. The
companies’ income, depicted by the IFRSs and IASs Valuation and accounting of DTAs
(refereed to simply by the Generally Accepted Accounting
Principles GAAP) are their accounting profits, but these The valuation and accounting of DTAs is the topic that
may be (and are) different from the taxable profit, since must be discussed and clarified. The most important
the taxable profit is calculated as a function of the tax law thing to notice is that deferred tax assets add value to the
inherent to each country. The number of factors that lead balance sheet since they represent the net present value
to differences between tax and accounting returns is of the future tax benefits (it is important to note that
huge and varies from country to country. One of those classical accounting relations only hold when the DTA
factors is of relevance to the present work, the deferral of value is indeed adjusted to its net present value (Eli Amir
taxes. et al., 1997)). To determine the best way to account for
deferred taxes, Amir et al. (1997) conducted some
research where they introduced net deferred taxes as a
Remove DTAs from the balance sheet completely distinct category of assets, using the market
value of equity per share as the dependent value. Amir et
Laux (2013) conducted a study to analyse the al. (1997) found that the valuation coefficient on deferred
relationship between the information content of financial tax liabilities from depreciation and amortization was
statements and the net deferred taxes account. Naturally, close to zero; also, deferred taxes from restructuring
as we evaluate deferred taxes, we may find both deferred charges had valuation coefficients larger than other
tax assets and deferred tax liabilities; the difference will deferred tax components. They also concluded that the
result in net deferred taxes (we will henceforth refer to net realizable value of deferred taxes from losses and
these net deferred taxes simply as deferred tax assets, or credits carried forward were negatively correlated with
DTAs). The main conclusion was that the exclusion of stock prices. In the end they concluded that even though
DTAs from the results helped access the main these types of assets are very different in nature from the
differences from the different company’s performance. rest of the assets in the balance sheet, they should
This is highly related to the cost/benefit of disclosing nonetheless be accounted for (with some subjective
information on DTAs since that the cost of acquiring and adjustments) in a way like any other asset or liability.
utilizing this information seems to nullify the benefits.
Also, on the same topic, Burgstahler et al. (2002)
concluded that in some occasions, managers tend to Focus on bank’s DTAs
manipulate the net deferred tax asset account to increase
earnings and avoid losses. This possible manipulation is On the special case of the banking sector, banks are
also something that should be kept in mind when required to maintain certain levels of regulatory capital to
evaluating balance sheets where such accounts are provide a buffer against potential future losses (Kim and
present. Santomero, 1988; Ryan, 2007; Baesens and van Gestel,
The problem of accounting DTAs on a present value 2009). In many countries (Kara, 2016), banks can count a
basis is that under the actual rules adopted by Financial portion (or all) of their DTAs towards regulatory capital
1
Accounting Standards Board (FASB), the deferred tax requirements (since the adoption of SFAS No. 109 in
accounts are, in many cases, unlikely to reverse in the 1992 – specifically the establishment of valuation
foreseeable future, since companies seem to be able to allowances).
defer taxes indefinitely (Colley et al., 2007). These Under normal circumstances, a bank’s DTAs usually
authors address this statement in the study “Deferred originates in the carry-over of losses (though it can also
Taxes in the Context of the Unit Problem” where they arise from overpaying some taxes). The corresponding
remove the deferred tax assets from the balance sheets. rights are registered in the balance sheet as assets,
The authors state that income taxation is an aggregate although in Amir and Sougiannis (1999) it also argued
phenomenon and that an aggregate approach is required, that DTA may have implications for the perception of the
making use of the flow-through accounting method. The firm as a going concern (dubbed as the information
main argument states that, if we see taxation as a
transaction between the private/public sectors and the
governmental authority, then this method would result in
an equality of the tax provision and the cash outflow 1
Statement of Financial Accounting Standards
Silva et al. 3

effect), since if the DTA arose from past operating losses, deferred taxes were associated with higher risks and
future losses would be likely to incur; this means that lower earnings quality, resulting in a decline of
future liabilities could be more than likely, and thus such creditworthiness. Additionally, studies of the impact of
“assets” should be regarded with great suspicion). DTAs on credit ratings led to the conclusion that deferred
tax positions are substantial for many firms (between 5
and 10% of all assets according to Poterba et al. (2011)).
DTAs and European options Gallemore (2011) investigated the credit risk
associated with the deferred tax asset component of
DTAs may be hard to value, since they are time-limited bank regulatory capital. He hypothesized that banks that
and may never be used at all. Their value is contingent have a larger proportion of regulatory capital composed
on the future earnings of the company, and they can be of deferred tax assets were more likely to fail. He
used to shield these future profits from taxation, IAS 12 employed a hazard model to test a sample of commercial
states that “a DTA should be recognised for all deductible banks and found that the proportion of regulatory capital
temporary differences, to the extent that it is probable composed of deferred tax assets which was positively
that taxable profit will be available against which the associated with the risk of bank failure during the recent
deductible temporary difference can be utilised”. Since financial crisis. Gallemore (2011) attributed his findings to
corporate income taxation works on an annual basis, the the fact that the benefits of deferred tax assets could not
shielding opportunities occur once a year. This is be realized unless banks generated positive taxable
equivalent to saying that we are faced with a compound income in the future.
European option (or an annual Bermuda option) that
might be exercised until the last year in which the law will
permit shielding, or until the DTAs value has been How to value
completely depleted by its use. Consistent with this line of
thinking, there is an ongoing debate regarding the It is thus clear that the DTAs must be correctly valued,
appropriateness of including DTA in the banks’ regulatory and that simply adding them to a bank’s or company’s
capital calculation, since by doing so we are assuming its balance sheet in full as an asset might contribute to
“full” worth; something that is clearly misleading. obfuscate the institution’s true financial condition, even a
situation in which the DTA is fully used before its
expiration date, we still must account for the cost of
Basel committee vs. banking industry capital. Moodys (2015) reported DTAs were considered
“a low-quality form of assets, and thus a low-quality
Throughout the recent financial crisis (2008-2013), major source of capital”, and consequently, Moody’s decided to
media outlets routinely drew attention to the banks’ DTA “limit the contribution of DTAs in its calculations of banks'
positions, classifying them as tenuous contributions tangible common equity (TCE)”. As analysed in De Vries
towards regulatory capital. In Reilly (2009), it was noted (2018), several DTA valuation methods can be used, but
that tier 1 capital ratios contained “fluff” mentioning DTA they are essentially very subjective, and basically result
as the primary culprit, calling in an “airy asset”. The Basel in a valuation allowance, for which there is no consistent
Committee on Banking Supervision specifically targeted accepted method to calculate, this paper aims to resolve
the removal of DTAs as a potential method for improving such shortcomings, by solving for the expected value of
the ability of regulatory capital to protect banks from the DTA, in the sense of calculating exactly which
2
losses . At the same time, the banking industry has amounts are expected to be discounted as tax payments,
pushed for the opposite; namely a greater inclusion of and when.
DTA in the regulatory capital calculation, in an attempt to
“ease” the amount of (real) regulatory capital.
DTA MATHEMATICAL MODEL

High DTAs = Low credit worthiness Let us consider a DTA with official book value Dmax and a lifespan
of T (in years). The effective (realistic) value of such DTA is
The relationship of DTAs with the creditworthiness of a contingent on future profits and shall always be (equal or) lower
company has already deserved some work from
academic community. The effects of book-tax differences than Dmax . The effective value of the considered DTA, D, can be
on a firm’s credit risk were analysed in Crabtree and represented as:
Maher (2009), Ayers et al. (2010), Edwards (2011) and
Gallemore (2011), all agreeing that great amounts of T
Rt   Rt 1
D= , (1)

 1   
t
t 1
2
Consultative document of December 2009, entitled “Strengthening the j
resilience of the banking sector”. j 1
4 J. Account. Taxation

where j is the interest yield in year j, Rt is the remaining book


Computing D basically requires finding expressions for the
value DTA in the beginning of year t defined as:
 
 1   
t
expected value of the interest yield weight E 1 j
t 1
 
Rt = Dmax   ui 
j 1
and for the expected value of the positive part of the remaining DTA
i 1 , (2) in the beginning of each year t, E  Rt   .
ui is the profit in year i multiplied by taxes (basically, it is the tax
Expected value of the interest yield weight .
 

payment that is discounted from the DTA) and denotes the

x  max x,0 . Both the yearly profits and yields  


 1    , we
t
operation In order to compute the expected value E 1 j
are assumed to be independently distributed random variables  j 1 
(RVs). Then, the following the objective will be to find the expected first write it as:
value of D which can be expressed as:

 
 1     E  R 
T t
D =  E 1 j t

  E  Rt 1  (3)
t 1  j 1 

   

1   j  = 
t
1
E 1   p1  1  p t  t  d 1 d t (4)

 1   j 
t
 j 1   

j 1

p j  j 
Expected value of remaining DTA
where is the probability density function (PDF) of the

interest yield in year j. We will consider that all the j are According to Equation 3, the computation of D also requires the
evaluation of the expected value of the positive part of the
independently distributed and follow the same PDF but with
E  Rt   . In
different means j and standard deviations  j
.
remaining DTA in the beginning of each year t, that is,

According to the Cox-Ingersoll-Ross (CIR) model (Cox et al., order to obtain an expression for E  Rt   , we start with the
1985), the interest yield would follow a non-central Chi-squared
distribution, but in this paper, due to the reduced time spans of the derivation of the PDF of Rt . First we rewrite Equation 2 as:
DTAs and ability to limit the estimated variability of the interest
yield, we will assume a uniform distribution for the interest yield in
order to provide mathematical tractability (and obtain a closed form
solution). So being, we have:
Rt = Dmax  Ut , (8)

 1 Ut
 ,  j   j  3  j , j  3  j  where is the sum of all profits multiplied by taxes up until the
p j  j    2 3  j   year t-1, which is defined as:

0, otherwise t 1
U t =  ui  ,
(5)
(9)
It is now easy to show that: i 1

  1   j  3   ui  . If each non
1
p  
 1   j   j j j 2 3
 d 
1
log 
  
j


comprising a sum of independent, rectified, RVs

j 
1  j  3 j  (6) rectified RV ui is described by a PDF pui  ui  , then ui  follows
the associated rectified PDF which is given by:
which results in
pu  ui  = 1  pi    ui   pui  ui  H  ui  (10)
   1   j  3   i

 j   2 3  1    3 j
t t
1
E 1  1   = log 
 j 1  j 1 j  j j

 (7)
where   x is the Dirac delta function, H  x is the unit step
Silva et al. 5

pui  ui 
function:
pi , it represents the truncated PDF associated with
0, x  0 which can be written as:
H  x  
1, x  0 (11) pui ui 0  ui   pui  ui  H  ui  pi
.
(13)
and pi is the probability of having positive profit, that is,
Knowing that the PDF of a sum of independent RVs can be found
 using the convolution of the individual PDFs (Hogg et al., 2004), we
pi   p  u  du
0
ui i i
(12) can write the PDF of Ut as:

Note that when the second term in Equation 10 is normalized by pUt U t  = pu   1


 pu 
t 1
 U 
t

1 1
=  pt kt 1 1  p1  1  pt  U t 
1 k1 1 kt 1
p1k1 Ck (14)
 i ti11
k1 0 kt 1 0

where * denotes the convolution operation which, for two functions Therefore, in Equation 14 C k t 1 U t  corresponds to the (t-1)-
f  x g  x
 i1
and is defined as:
fold convolution:



 f  g  x    f   g  x   d (15)


Ck
 i ti11
Ut   1  k1    k1 pu u 0   1 1

 1  kt 1    kt 1 put1 ut1 0  U t  .
  (16)

The second form in Equation 14 makes it explicit all the possible


outcomes in terms of years with positive profit and with loss during express the PDF of Rt as:
the timeframe in use. Combining Equation 8 and 14, we can

1 1
pRt  Rt  =  p pt kt1 1  p1  1  pt   Dmax  Rt 
k1 1 k1 1 kt 1
Ck
1  i ti11 (17)
k1 0 kt 1 0


E  Rt  
 max R , 0 p  R  dR
which allows us to compute using
E  Rt    t Rt t t


1 1
= p pt kt1 1  p1  1  pt   Dmax 
k1 1 k1 1 kt 1
Ik (18)
1  i ti11
k1 0 kt 1 0

where we defined the following auxiliary coefficient required for the years with profit, one year with profit, two years with profit and three
summation terms:
or more years with profit. A uniform distribution with mean ui and

Ik  Dmax    Rt Ck   Dmax  Rt  dRt . (19) standard deviation u
i
will be assumed for each yearly profit, ui ,
 i ti11 t 1
i i 1
0 with the PDF expressed as:

 1
In order to evaluate the integral in Equation 19 we will consider four
 , ui   ai , bi  ,
different cases in terms of number of years with positive profit (that pui  ui    bi  ai (20)

is, #i : ki  0 , where # denotes the cardinality of the set): no 0, otherwise

6 J. Account. Taxation

where which is also a Dirac delta function. Therefore Equation 19 results


simply in:
ai  ui  3 ui
 Dmax   Dmax .
(21)
I (24)
ki ti11
and

bi  ui  3 ui .
Case of only one year, i, with positive profit
(22)
The convolution in Equation 16 is also trivial to compute for the
For this PDF the probability of having positive profit, Equation 12, is sequences with only one year with positive profit (
simply: #i : ki  0  1 ) as it consists in the convolution of Dirac delta
bi  ai  functions with a single truncated (and normalized) PDF obtained
pi  (23) from Equation 20, resulting in:
bi  ai
Ck
 i ti11
 Dmax  Rt   pu u 0  Dmax  Rt  .
i i
(25)

Case of no years with positive profit


Inserting Equation 25 into Equation 19, then gives:
The sequence without positive profit years ( # i : ki  0   )
results in a trivial convolution of Dirac delta functions in Equation 16

  2
 
2
1  
Ik  Dmax    
D  a   Dmax  bi    . (26)
 i ti11 2  bi  ai       
max i

Case of two years, i and j, with positive profit a convolution of two truncated (and normalized) PDFs obtained
from Equation 20, whose resulting expression can be written as:
For the sequences with only two positive profit years (
#i : ki  0  2 ), indexed by i and j, Equation 16 simplifies to

 Dmax  Rt  ai   a j  , Dmax  ai   a j   min li , l j   Rt  Dmax  ai   a j 



1  min li , l j  , Dmax  ai   a j   max li , l j   Rt  Dmax  ai   a j   min li , l j 
Ck
 i ti11
 Dmax  Rt   
(27)
li l j  R  D  b  b ,
t max i j Dmax  bi  b j  Rt  Dmax  ai   a j   max li , l j 


0, otherwise

where
After inserting Equation 27 into Equation 19 and performing the

li  bi  ai
integral we obtain:
. (28)

  Dmax ai a j   maxli ,l j 


1  1 3  i
 b  b  Dmax 

I k t 1  Dmax    Rt  Rt 2  
j
 i i1 li l j  3 2 
   Dmax bi b j 

 Dmax ai a j  minli ,l j   Dmax ai a j   
 


 min li , l j 
Rt 2
  1
   Rt  3 
Dmax  ai  a j  

Rt 
2
  
   3   (29)
2 2
   Dmax ai  a j   maxli ,l j     Dmax ai  a j   minli ,l j  

d
where we adopt the notation
 f  x  c
 f d   f c .
Silva et al. 7

Case of three or more years with positive profit Case of independent and identically distributed profits

For all the sequences with three or more years with profit (
#i : ki  0  3 ), instead of trying to compute all subsequent
If we assume that the RVs ui are not only independent but also

convolutions we can apply the Central Limit Theorem (CLT) and identically distributed with mean u , standard deviation u and

approximate the sum of the nonzero ui as a Gaussian distribution
t 1 t 1 PDF pu  u  , then most of the previous expressions can be
with mean  ki ui
i 1
and squared standard deviation  ki u 2
i 1
i
simplified. In this case Equation 18 becomes:

t 1 t  1
where
  k
E  Rt       p 1  p  I k  Dmax 
t 1 k

b  a  k 0  k 
 2
(37)
u 
2 i i

(30)
i
12
 t  1
and
where   denotes number of combinations of t-1 elements
 k 

ai   bi
u  
i . (31)
taken k at a time, p  p  u  du ,
u
2 0

In this case we can write: 


I k  Dmax    R C D
t k max  Rt  dRt , (38)
 Rt   2
1  0
Ck
 i ti11
 Dmax  Rt   e 2 2 (32)
2 
Ck U t 
2
is simply the k-fold convolution of the truncated PDF

pu u 0  u 
where
with itself and p is the probability of having positive
t 1
 2   ki u 2
profit which, for uniformly distributed RVs (23), simplifies to
(33)
b  a
i
i 1
p . (39)
and ba
t 1
   Dmax   ki ui
Repeating the explicit computation of Equation 38 for the four
(34) different cases in terms of years with positive profit we obtain:
i 1
I 0  Dmax   Dmax (40)
Performing the integration in Equation 19 then results in

 2 for the sequences of no years with positive profit,


   2  1   
t 1  Dmax     erfc  
2
(35)
I
ki i1
e 
2 2  2     2
 
2
1  
I1  Dmax    D  a    D  b   ,
2  b  a       max  
max

where erfc  x  is the complementary error function defined as: (41)

 for the sequences with only one year with positive profit,
2
erfc  x   e
 2
d (36)
 x

 Dmax  2b 
2

  Dmax  b  a     Dmax  b  a   
3  2
1  
I 2  Dmax   
b  a   2
3 2

 Dmax  2b    Dmax  2b  
 2

   13  D  
3
1  3  
  Dmax  2b  max  2a 
3 2
8 J. Account. Taxation


 Dmax  2a    Dmax  2a  
 2
 D  2a  

 D   
2
 
  ba
max
max , (42)
2 2 

for the sequences with two years with positive profit and a simple example of the computation of the expected value of a
(approximately: DTA with a lifespan of T=3 years, considering independent and
identically distributed uniform RVs for the profits. In this case,
 2 according to Equation 3, the intended value is computed using:
   2  1   
I k 3  Dmax     erfc  
2
e  (43)
2  2    
 1     E  R .
2 3 t
D =  E 1 j t

  E  Rt 1  (44)
for all the remaining sequences (three or more years with positive t 1  j 1 
profit). In Equation 43, we use  2  k u 
2
and where the terms inside the summation are

   Dmax  ku 
.
E  R1   Dmax , (45)

Putting the mathematical model to use (obtained from Equations 37 and 40),

In order to clarify the use of the presented expressions, we describe

 a  a    2
  Dmax  a     Dmax  b    ,
2
1  
E  R2      Dmax 
(46)
 ba  2 b  a   

(obtained from Equations 37, 40 and 41),

 a  a   a  a  
2
 D  a        D  b    
2 2  b  a 
2

   b  a  2  max 
E  R3   

 Dmax     I D (47)
 ba   b  a    
2 max max

(obtained from Equations 40, 41, and 42), and

3 a  a  
3 2
 a  a   Dmax  b   
3   
2
  
2
E  R4   

   
 max  
D D a
 ba  2  b  a  
max
  
  Dmax 3u   
2 (48)

   I D   b  a   3  e 6 u 2  1 D  3u  erfc   Dmax  3u 
2
 
 
 
 
  3
b a a a
3 2 max    
b  a 
3
 b  a   2
u
2
max
 6 u  
  
 
(obtained from Equations 37, 40, 41, 42, and 43). Therefore, the expected value for the DTA is given as:

  3  t  1   j  3  
 1     E  R   
3 t
1
D =  E 1 
  E  Rt 1     log  j
  E  Rt    E  Rt 1  

j

t
t 1  j 1 2 3   1   j  3  
t 1 j 1
 j  j 
 1   1  3   2   1   j  3  

1
2 3 1
log 
 1   1  3 
1


 E  R1   E  R2     
1

j 1  2 3 
log 
 1   j  3 
j



  E  R2    E  R3   
 1   j  j 
3   1   j  3  
 
1
j 1  2 3 
log 
 1   j  3 
j



  E  R3   E  R4   
 j  j 
Silva et al. 9

Figure 1. Expected cumulated DTA; increasing mean profits – analytical vs. simulated results.

Figure 2. Expected yearly DTA consumption; increasing mean profits – analytical vs simulated results.

SIMULATION RESULTS always matched the simulated values almost to


perfection, proving that the CLT based approximation
Monte Carlo simulations were run for 10.000 loops, adopted for 3 or more years with positive profit proved to
and the DTA’s lifespan was assumed to be 10 years, with be very accurate. The curves of
book value Dmax=100 (a dimensional). Both the yearly Figure 11 represent the cumulated DTA usage (to the
3
interest yield and each year’s mean expected profit present value) at the end of each year ; whereas the
multiplied by the tax, ui, assumed a uniform distribution curves of
(that ui =10 is equivalent to a profit of 50 and tax rate of Figure 22 portray the yearly DTA consumption under
20%, for instance). In the same conditions.
Figure 11, we compare the simulated values to the
analytical values obtained by the deduced formulas, to 3
Note that only the annual results are simulated, and thus the results could be
find that they coincide. This test was actually executed for represented only by points; lines joining the points were chosen in order to
all figures and it was observed that the analytical values improve the readability of the results
10 J. Account. Taxation

Figure 3. Expected cumulated DTA; increasing mean profits.

Figure 4. Expected yearly DTA consumption; increasing mean profits.

Figure 3 and Figure 4 present the same simulations almost 100 (if there was no discount factor, the cumulated
present in Figure 1 and Figure 2, but now with only the DTA would reach 100). As expected, the higher yield will
simulated results. The variable ui was made to increase output the lowest DTA value. Looking at Figure 4, we can
from 20 (adimensional) with increments of 5 units each see that by year 6 the DTA was all used up, which means
year; all having a fixed standard deviation δ ui of 10. From that it only took 5 years for these DTA to be fully used,
Figure 3, it was noticed that the initial DTA value is a bit each with different present values due to the different
less than 20 (due to the discount factor), climbing up to yields.
Silva et al. 11

Figure 3. Expected cumulated DTA; increasing mean profits and profit deviation.

Figure 4. Expected yearly DTA consumption; increasing mean profits and profit deviation.

In Figure 5 and Figure 6, we have a similar situation as identical distributions (IID), meaning that both ui and the
before, but now with the standard deviation starting at interest yield follow the same distribution and have the
10 and increasing 4 units each year. With this increasing same mean and variance throughout all the years.
deviation, note that the expected use of the totality of the Comparing to the previous case, we can see that most of
DTA is deferred to the seventh year (previously it was the the DTA is used in the fourth year, with just a small
fifth year). remainder being used in the fifth year.
In Figure 7, we have conditions of independent and The rest of the figures explore different combinations.
12 J. Account. Taxation

Figure 5. Expected yearly DTA consumption; IID.

Figure 6. Expected yearly DTA consumption; increasing profit deviation.

In Figure 8 we have identical means for the ui and the simulated themean interest yield varying throughout the
interest yield, but also have an increasing profit deviation, years (all other component remaining identical), and saw
delaying the DTA’s full use to year 7. In Figure 9 we a little loss of value for the DTA compared to the IID
Silva et al. 13

Figure 7. Expected yearly DTA consumption; varying mean yield.

Figure 8. Expected yearly DTA consumption; varying mean yield and increasing profit deviation.

of Figure 7, as expected. In Figure 10, we reproduce the noticing a delay in the time the DTA is fully used up. In
scenario of Figure 9 with increasing profit variance, Figure 11 we reproduced the scenario of Figure 9, but
14 J. Account. Taxation

Figure 9. Expected yearly DTA consumption; varying mean yield and increasing profits.

Figure 10. Expected yearly DTA consumption; varying mean yield and increasing mean profit and profit
deviation.

now also with increasing mean ui each year, allowing the Conclusions
curves to peak a bit earlier. Finally, in Figure 12, we have
varying mean yields and profit alongside a varying In this work, we valued Deferred Tax Assets (DTAs)
standard deviation, with some subtle differences from the according to future projected profits, which is the only
two previous cases. correct way that they should be valued. Using this
Silva et al. 15

valuation technique, the DTA’s value on the balance Hanlon M, Shevlin T (2005). Bank-Tax Conformity for Corporate
Income: An Introduction to the Issues.
sheet would always be smaller than its nominal value
Hogg R, McKean V, Joseph W, Craig AT (2004). Introduction to
used nowadays and reflect its realistic value, providing all mathematical statistics (6th ed.). Upper Saddle River, New Jersey:
stakeholders with the company’s real asset worth, Prentice Hall P 692. ISBN 978-0-13-008507-8. MR 467974.
henceforth preventing future (unavoidable) dis- Kara GI (2016). “Bank Capital Regulations around the World: What
Explains the Differences?. Finance and Economics Discussion Series
appointments. Via the projection of future profits and
2016-057. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
yields using a uniform distribution with associated System, http://dx.doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2016.057
standard deviations, we account for the most likely Ketz JE (2010). “Deferred Income Taxes Should Be Put to Rest,” The
scenarios and reach precise deterministic values for the Accounting Cycle http://accounting.smartpros.com/ x68912.xml
KPMG.
DTAs, allowing the company and its shareholders to Kim D, Santomero AM (1988). Risk in banking and capital regulation.
possess all necessary information to correctly estimate Journal of Finance 43:1219-1233.
the company’s financial stance and allow for a realistic Laux RC (2013). The Association between Deferred Tax Assets and
strategy for the future. Liabilities and Future Tax Payments. SSRN Electronic Journal.
Sansing, R. C., & Guenther, D. A. (n.d.). The Valuation Relevance of
Reversing Deferred Tax Liabilities.
Moodys Research Report (2015) -
CONFLICT OF INTERESTS https://www.moodys.com/research/Moodys-Reliance-on-global-
banks-deferred-tax-assets-poses-potential--PR_340219
Poterba JM, Rao NS, Seidman JK (2011). “Deferred tax positions and
The authors have not declared any conflict of interests.
incentives for corporate behavior around corporate tax changes”.
National Tax Journal 64(1):27-57.
Reilly D (2009). Citi, BofA Show Investors Can’t Bank on Capital.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENT Bloomberg 28:1.
Ryan S (2007). Financial Instruments and Institutions: Accounting and
Disclosure Rules. 2nd ed. John Wilen & Sons, Hoboken, NJ.
We gratefully acknowledge financial support from FCT-
Fundação para a Ciencia e Tecnologia (Portugal),
national funding through research grant UIDB/
04521/2020".

REFERENCES

Amir E, Kirschenheiter M, Willard K (1997). The Valuation of Deferred


Taxes. Contemporary Accounting Research 14(4):597-622.
Amir E, Sougiannis T (1999). Analysts' interpretation and investors'
valuation of tax carryforwards. Contemporary Accounting Research,
16(1):1-33.
Atwood T, Drake MS, Myers LA (2010). Book-tax conformity, earnings
persistence and the association between earnings and future cash
flows. Journal of Accounting and Economics 50(1):111-125.
Ayers BC, Laplante SK, McGuire ST (2010). Credit Ratings and Taxes:
The Effect of Book-Tax Differences on Ratings Changes.
Contemporary Accounting Research 27(2):359 402.
Baesens B, van Gestel T (2009). Credit Risk Management. Oxford,
Oxfordshire, England: Oxford University Press.
Burgstahler DC, Elliott WB, Hanlon M (2002). How Firms Avoid Losses:
Evidence of Use of the Net Deferred Tax Asset Account.
Chaney PK, Jeter DC (1994). The Effect of Deferred Taxes on Security
Prices. Journal of Accounting, Auditing and Finance 9(1):91-116. doi:
10.1177/0148558X9400900106.
Colley R, Rue J, Valencia A, Volkan A (2007), “Deferred Taxes in the
Context of the Unit Problem. Journal of Finance and Accountancy
2:1.
Cox JC, Ingersoll JE, Ross SA (1985). An intertemporal general
equilibrium model of asset prices. Econometrica: Journal of the
Econometric Society 53(2):363-384.
Crabtree A, Maher JJ (2009). The Influence of Differences in Taxable
Income and Book Income on the Bond Credit Market. Journal of the
American Taxation Association 31(1):75-99.
De Vries T (2018). “Market Consistent Valuation of Deferred Taxes”,
MSc thesis, Technical University Delft.
Edwards A (2011). Does the Deferred Tax Asset Valuation Allowance
Signal Firm Creditworthiness?: Working paper, University of Toronto.
Gallemore J (2011). Deferred Tax Assets and Bank Regulatory Capital:
Working paper, University of North Carolina.

You might also like