You are on page 1of 15

Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 136–150

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Journal of Banking & Finance


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jbf

Libor manipulation?
Rosa M. Abrantes-Metz a,⇑, Michael Kraten b, Albert D. Metz c, Gim S. Seow d
a
AFE Consulting, Leonard N. Stern School of Business, New York University, New York, NY 10020, USA
b
School of Business, Providence College, Providence, RI 02918, USA
c
Moody’s Investors Service, New York, NY 10007, USA
d
School of Business, University of Connecticut, Storrs, CT 06269, USA

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: On May 29, 2008 the Wall Street Journal published an article alleging that several global banks were
Received 20 March 2009 reporting Libor quotes significantly lower than those implied by prevailing credit default swap (CDS)
Accepted 20 June 2011 spreads. While acknowledging that the ‘‘analysis doesn’t prove that banks are lying or manipulating
Available online 13 July 2011
Libor,’’ it nevertheless conjectures that these banks may ‘‘have been low-balling their borrowing rates
to avoid looking desperate for cash.’’
JEL classification: In this paper we compare Libor with other short-term borrowing rates, analyze individual bank quotes,
C10
and compare these individual quotes to CDS spreads and market capitalization data during three periods:
C22
G14
1/1/07–8/8/07 (Period 1), 8/9/07–4/16/08 (Period 2), and 4/17/08–5/30/08 (Period 3). We find some
G24 anomalous individual quotes, but the evidence is inconsistent with a material manipulation of the US dol-
K20 lar 1-month Libor rate.
Ó 2011 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
Keywords:
Libor
Manipulations
Conspiracies
Collusion
Price-fixing
Bid-rigging
Credit default swap spreads

1. Introduction globally. It is used as the basis for settlement of interest rate con-
tracts on many of the world’s major futures and options exchanges
A May 29, 2008 Wall Street Journal article alleges that several (including LIFFE, Deutsche Term Börse, Euronext, SIMEX and TIFFE)
global banks were reporting unjustifiably low borrowing costs for as well as most Over-the-Counter (OTC) and lending transactions.’’
the calculation of the daily London Interbank Offer Rate (Libor) For transactions that utilize Libor as a benchmark for establishing
benchmark (Mollenkamp and Whitehouse, 2008). Specifically, the borrowing costs, a slight understatement of the rate may generate
writers allege that the banks were reporting costs significantly be- sizable wealth transfers from lenders to borrowers.
low the rates justified by bank-specific cost trend movements in Following the publication of the Wall Street Journal article,
the default insurance market. Although the Wall Street Journal other major financial publications voiced similar concerns. For
article acknowledges that its ‘‘analysis doesn’t prove that banks instance, a June 2, 2008 article in The Financial Times agrees
are lying or manipulating Libor,’’ it conjectures that these banks that ‘‘. . . the rate of borrowing in Libor has lagged behind other
may ‘‘have been low-balling their borrowing rates to avoid looking market-based measures of unsecured funding used by the vast
desperate for cash.’’ majority of financial institutions. This has aroused suspicions
The British Bankers’ Association’s (BBA) website claims that that the small group of banks which supply the BBA with Libor
‘‘BBA Libor is the primary benchmark for short-term interest rates quotes have understated true borrowing rates so as not to fan
fears (that) they have funding problems’’ (Mackenzie and Tett,
⇑ Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 212 899 5311.
2008).
E-mail addresses: RAbrantes-Metz@afeconsult.com (R.M. Abrantes-Metz),
The motivation of this study is to extend the Wall Street
mkraten@suffolk.edu (M. Kraten), Albert.Metz@moodys.com (A.D. Metz), gseow@ Journal’s analysis by employing a wider array of comparative
business.uconn.edu (G.S. Seow). statistical techniques and more recent methodologies and to

0378-4266/$ - see front matter Ó 2011 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2011.06.014
R.M. Abrantes-Metz et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 136–150 137

gain a greater understanding of the issues underlying such mean calculation,2 as few as five (of 16) banks, acting in concert,
speculations.1 could conceivably influence the published Libor rate.
Statistical methods alone cannot establish the existence of a What may motivate banks to artificially inflate or deflate the
manipulation or a conspiracy in a particular market. That said, published rate? From a financial perspective, banks that are net
our findings do flag some questionable patterns with respect to borrowers would benefit from lower rates, while banks that are
the daily Libor quotes of the banks. Our analyses reveal that during net lenders would benefit from higher rates. Although an analysis
distinct periods of time, non-random patterns of reported borrow- of the protocols employed to select Libor’s 16 banks is beyond the
ing costs are in evidence beyond even the Wall Street Journal’s scope of this study, the nature of the composition of this group
findings. In particular, for the 7-month period that starts on Janu- might generate an opportunity for collusion if the majority of these
ary 1, 2007 with the beginning of our data and ends on August 8, banks tend to be net borrowers or lenders.3
2007, the intraday variance of individual bank quotes is not signif- Even if a bank is not trying to influence the published rate in
icantly different from zero. Furthermore, the ‘‘critical group’’ of any particular direction, it may have incentives to artificially ad-
banks which determine the Libor rate encompass the majority of just its submitted quote relative to its peers. The Wall Street
the institutions. Journal suggests that banks may use the Libor submission pro-
However, even assuming that the banks were artificially com- cess to manage their public reputation. In other words, they
pressing their quotes around a given point, it does not necessarily may use the Libor calculation process to signal to the market
follow that the resulting Libor was materially different from what that their operating costs are lower (i.e., that they are financially
it otherwise would have been. Using statistical standards com- healthier) than they are in reality. If all banks submit artificially
monly accepted in US courts to determine materiality, our empir- low bids, this will of course lead to an artificially low published
ical analysis indicates that the data are not consistent with a rate. But instead of trying to signal an absolutely low level of
material manipulation of the final Libor level. costs, it could be that the banks may wish to signal that their
This paper is organized in five sections. Section 1 provides borrowing costs are simply no higher than those of their peers.
background information on the topic. Section 2 presents a literature This would suggest an artificial narrowing of the cross-sectional
review of relevant theory and empirical methods, as well as infor- variation in quotes, but it does not necessarily suggest that the
mation regarding the compilation methodology of the Libor rate final published rate would be altered from what it otherwise
which addresses the reputational considerations that are raised would have been.
by the Wall Street Journal article (Mollenkamp and Whitehouse, Because Libor submissions are released to the general public,
2008). Section 3 discusses our own experimental methodology, banks may also be able to utilize the process to signal to each other
and Sections 4–6 describe our results, each devoted to a different in much the same way as airlines are alleged to use their online
empirical hypothesis. Section 7 summarizes our key results and ticket reservation systems to communicate their pricing inten-
concludes with a discussion of implications and avenues for future tions.4 This represents a third reason that individual quotes may
research. be artificially adjusted, but again it does not necessarily suggest a de-
sire to adjust the published rate. To use an analogy, such price sig-
naling could lead to a narrowing of the bid/ask spread but without
2. Literature review: the Libor rate, theory, and methods moving the midpoint.
Finally, banks which operate in multiple global markets may be
2.1. The BBA and Libor motivated to use Libor as a ‘‘hedge’’ (or, at a minimum, as an alter-
native financing resource) against rate fluctuations elsewhere. For
In 1984, the BBA initiated the standardization of contractual instance, an American bank with operations in London might ben-
terms on interest rate swaps. Two years later, the BBA introduced efit by keeping the Libor rate artificially low as compared to the
Libor as a reference rate for a number of securities, notably syndi- Federal funds effective rate.
cated loans, futures contracts, and forward rate agreements. Today, Each of these possible reasons supports an empirically testable
Libor serves as a reference rate for unsecured loans between Lon- hypothesis. In some cases, we would expect the final published
don based banks as well as for many financial instruments that Libor rate to be different (higher or lower) from what it otherwise
are transacted across the globe. Libor rates are quoted daily on would have been. In other cases, we would expect the range of sub-
ten major currencies: the Australian dollar, British pound, Cana- mitted quotes to be narrower than otherwise. In still other cases,
dian dollar, European euro, Danish krone, Japanese yen, New Zea- we would expect an increased wedge between Libor and other
land dollar, Swedish krona, Swiss franc, and US dollar. In this comparable rates.
study, we focus on the US dollar Libor. This study investigates the possibility of anticompetitive behav-
The BBA selects 16 banks to provide daily rate quotes for the ior by the sixteen banks, or, at the least, a large enough subset
calculation of Libor. According to the BBA’s website, this ‘‘reference thereof. Such behavior though can manifest itself in many forms.
panel of banks . . . reflects the balance of the market by country and In this study, the term ‘‘manipulation’’ refers to potential anticom-
by type of institution. Individual banks are selected within this petitive behavior by the sixteen banks or a subset when acting on
guiding principle on the basis of reputation, scale of market their own, i.e., without implying any coordinated actions. The term
activity, and perceived expertise in the currency concerned.’’ It is ‘‘collusion’’ refers to behavior by the banks when acting as a group
noteworthy that these factors do not include any consideration in a coordinated manner, either explicitly or tacitly.
of net borrowing or lending positions. Because the ‘‘middle Why is it important to track the Libor? Given its extensive use,
eight’’ quotes are converted into Libor through a simple arithmetic with literally trillions of dollars of contracts benchmarked against

2
The quoted Libor rate on any given day is the simple average of the rates
submitted by the middle eight banks that is, the average after dropping the highest
1
Such concerns are not unique to the recent periods of time that are examined in and the lowest four rates.
3
this study. In 1999, for instance, the Wall Street Journal reports that ‘‘. . . the BBA See Mackenzie (2008) and Mollenkamp and Norman (2008) for recent critiques of
(recently) ran into criticism when investors complained that its Yen-Libor fixings the Libor methodology. Gyntelberg and Wooldridge (2008) report anomalous Libor
were skewed by unusually high quotes from some of the banks that contributed to behavior during the second half of 2007.
4
the fixings. In response, the BBA adjusted the bank roster for the Yen benchmark in See Konrad and Sandoval (2002) for a critique of systems such as American
January.’’ (Cummings, 1999) Airline’s Sabre, Delta’s Worldspan, and United’s Apollo.
138 R.M. Abrantes-Metz et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 136–150

it, the economic consequences of a Libor manipulation could 2.3. Screening methods for anticompetitive behavior
potentially be extensive. For example, from a welfare standpoint,
if the level of Libor deviates from its market value, it will adversely In this section, we review empirical screening methods to de-
impact the efficient allocation of resources. For a too low level, bor- tect conspiracies and manipulations. A screen is a statistical test
rowers, such as homeowners, gain at the expense of lenders. A designed to identify markets where competition may be lacking.
more subtle allocative consequence is the distortion of other prices In some cases, a screen may be able to identify which firms or
in the economy. A lower Libor induces a lower mortgage rate, mak- agents are involved in a conspiracy or manipulation. Screens use
ing it easier to buy homes and substituting away from other goods commonly available data such as prices, costs, market shares, bids,
and services. This in turn artificially inflates the prices of homes transaction prices, spreads, volumes, and other data. Statistical
and related goods (such as furniture) while deflating the prices of tools are then employed to identify patterns that are anomalous
other goods. or highly improbable. A literature review on screening methodolo-
But is it plausible, as Mollenkamp and Whitehouse (2008) con- gies and their multiple applications can be found in Abrantes-Metz
jecture, that the participating banks may ‘‘have been low-balling and Bajari (2010) and Harrington (2008). The use of these methods
their borrowing rates to avoid looking desperate for cash?’’ And in litigation is detailed in the 2010 volume Proof of Conspiracy un-
is it plausible, as the Financial Times speculates on June 2, 2008, der Antitrust Federal Laws, by the American Bar Association.5
that the banks may have ‘‘understated true borrowing rates so as Economic analysis and empirical screening do trigger antitrust
not to fan fears (that) they have funding problems?’’ These state- cases, such as an Italian cartel in baby milk and a Dutch cartel in
ments suggest that reputation is such a significant asset that a the shrimp industry. Screens are also used to identify potential
bank may be willing to misrepresent its borrowing costs to anti-competitive behavior in gasoline markets by the Federal
protect it. Trade Commission, and to prioritize complaints in the Brazilian
gasoline retail market. Other agencies employing these tech-
2.2. Reputation niques include the Commodity Futures Trading Commission,
where screens for price manipulation in commodities markets
Although the Wall Street Journal and the Financial Times arti- are used to detect and prevent such behavior in all active futures
cles simply pose their questions suggestively, a review of the liter- and option contracts.
ature confirms that, historically, business reputation indeed serves Two different examples described in Abrantes-Metz (2010) on
as an asset of significant value. Using a sample of initial bank notes the power of these screens to detect anti-competitive behavior in
offered by new banks during the American Free Banking Era financial markets are the recent stock options backdating and
(1838–1860), Gorton (1996) documents larger discounts for the spring loading cases from the mid 2000’s and the 1994 break of
debt of new banks as compared to banks with maintained credit an alleged conspiracy by NASDAQ dealers in which odd-eighths
histories. More recently, Livingston and Miller (2000) find that quotes were avoided. Both of these are triggered by the application
bond underwriters with stronger reputation charge significantly of screens to financial data.
higher underwriting fees and provide higher offering prices (i.e., Broadly speaking, the literature employs two screening strate-
lower offering yields). gies. The first is to search for improbable events. This type of screen
Furthermore, a bank’s reputation plays a major role in deter- is similar to looking for a ‘‘cheat’’ in a casino. For example, the
mining its profitability. For example, Fridson and Garman (1998) probability that a gambler at a Las Vegas casino will place a winning
note that pricing is materially affected by the effectiveness of bet in a roulette is roughly 0.5%. During a shift, a roulette dealer may
underwriters in presenting issuers to investors. Narayanan et al. see a handful of players win five, or even seven, times in a row.
(2007) describe how commercial banks enhance their reputation However, the probability of winning 20 times in a row is around 1
by extending their bond underwriting activities to syndicated in a million. If a pit boss observes such an occurrence, he may not
loans and private placements in the private debt market. More re- be able to prove that cheating has occurred, and yet he would be
cent research by Ahn and Choi (2009) finds that the reputation well advised to watch closely to avoid the risk of losing a significant
(rank) of a lead bank serves as an indicator of bank monitoring amount of money. One set of collusive screens generalizes this idea
strength, which generally increases as the borrowing firm’s earn- by searching for events that are, under normal conditions, improb-
ings management behavior decreases. In each of these studies, able unless agents in a market are coordinating their actions.
the authors demonstrate that a reputation for effectiveness is cor- The second type of screen uses a control group. As an example,
related with superior financial outcomes. during the 1980s, one study finds that the price of concrete is 70%
Thus, with reputation so well established as a valuable asset in higher in New York City than in other US cities. While it is true that
the research literature, it is reasonable to assume that institutions the prices of many goods and services are somewhat higher in New
may be tempted to engage in conspiracies and manipulations in or- York City, relatively few of those prices are 70% higher than in
der to maximize the levels of respect and esteem accorded to them other large cities. It was later established that an organized crime
by the business community. In other words, as noted by the Wall syndicate in New York City had been operating a concrete club that
Street Journal and the Financial Times, it is possible to suspect that rigged bids on contracts over $2 million. Prices that are anomalous,
bankers may have harbored ‘‘fears’’ of ‘‘looking desperate’’ and compared to other markets, suggest a lack of competition. While
thus may have been willing to ‘‘low-ball their rates’’ in an anticom- this example serves as an illustration, most collusion cases are
petitive manner in order to protect their reputations. not as blatant.
Empirical methods are developed and applied to screen for It is important to emphasize that screens do not prove collusion
markers that are associated with the existence of such activities. or manipulation. Instead, screens isolate outcomes that are
Of course, there are sometimes false positives; markers can occur improbable or anomalous. A good screen possesses the following
in the absence of anticompetitive behavior. Likewise, collusions properties: (i) it should minimize the number of false positives
and/or manipulations can occur in the absence of markers. Never- and negatives; (ii) it should be easy to implement; (iii) it should
theless, although screening activities cannot provide conclusive be costly to evade; and (iv) it should have empirical and/or
evidence of the existence (or absence) of anticompetitive behavior, theoretical support.
they can be helpful in detecting patterns of observed data inconsis-
tent with what would be expected under competitive market
conditions. 5
Chapter VIII on the Role of the Economic Expert describes these methods in detail.
R.M. Abrantes-Metz et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 136–150 139

In theory, the alleged collusive and/or manipulative behavior bidders. As a result, competitive bidding implies that bids will be
within the Libor process can be modeled as some combination independent after controlling for common legitimate information
of: (1) a price-fixing conspiracy; (2) a bid-rigging conspiracy; and among all bidders. However, when firms collude, this coordination
(3) a market manipulation. These three types of screening tech- involves another common factor due to the cartel agreement. This
niques are discussed in the next section. common factor increases the correlation across bids with respect
to its value under competitive market conditions. Therefore, collu-
2.4. Examples of screens for price-fixing conspiracies sive bids remain highly correlated even after controlling for costs
and market power variables.
A price-fixing conspiracy is defined as an agreement among The key question is thus: ‘‘How much positive correlation across
cartel members on one or more terms, commonly prices. Cartel bids is sufficient to raise suspicion of collusion?’’ Sometimes the
members may also agree on market share terms, as well as on pun- correlation is so high that the likelihood that it could have been at-
ishment mechanisms for members who deviate from the terms of tained without explicit coordination approaches zero. A famous
the agreement. A number of empirical screens based on ‘‘collusive example involves the bids received by the Tennessee Valley
markers’’ have been suggested for price-fixing conspiracies (Har- Authority to install conductor cables in the 1950s. During that pro-
rington, 2006). Collusive markers typically include: (a) higher than cess, seven firms submit identical sealed bids of $198438.24. It is
expected average prices; (b) reductions in price variance; (c) lower highly unlikely that independent bidders could arrive at bid values
responsiveness of prices to costs; (d) reductions in price variations identical to eight digits.
across customers; (e) declines in imports of substitutes; (f) prices More often, the correlation across bids is significantly higher
that are strongly and positively correlated across firms or entities; across bidders in one market, say market A, than across bidders
(g) a high degree of uniformity across firms in product prices and in another comparable market, say market B. If such a difference
other dimensions; and (h) abrupt changes in prices that cannot in correlation between the two markets cannot be explained by
be explained by demand and/or cost movements. an observable and legitimate market condition relevant to firms
While these collusive markers vary in terms of ease of imple- in A but not relevant (or observable) to firms in B, then it is more
mentation, they all compare data patterns in a market against an likely that there is coordination across bidders in market A.
appropriate benchmark, developed within the same industry dur- This type of pattern is illustrated in two papers by Porter and
ing a different period, or from a comparable industry in a contem- Zona (1997, 1999). The authors provided expert testimonies for
poraneous period. Abrantes-Metz et al. (2006), for instance, first the prosecution in the case of State of Ohio vs. Louis Trauth Dairies,
proposed a screen for low price variance to detect price-fixing Inc. et al. The paper examines a set of 13 sealed bids submitted to
agreements, as observed around the collapse of a conspiracy in supply pint-size milk to Ohio schools between 1980 and 1990. The
the frozen perch industry.6 bidders are milk processors or distributors, and school milk usually
Competition authorities worldwide have adopted this variance represents less than 10% of their annual revenues. Porter and Zona
screen to identify markets with anomalously low price variance argue that a bidder’s costs can be easily explained by a small num-
(Abrantes-Metz and Froeb, 2008). Esposito and Ferrero (2006) doc- ber of readily observed variables, including the price of raw milk
ument the effectiveness of the variance screen methodology in and local transportation costs. Using a simple econometric model,7
detecting collusion in the fuel and consumer products markets in Porter and Zona show that the bids from non-colluding firms can be
Italy. explained by the model, while bids from allegedly colluding firms
An alternative screening approach makes use of price indices. are highly correlated and cannot be explained by the model. Yet an-
Indices can provide extremely good fits to observed prices. Simple other type of screen for identifying bid-rigging conspiracies relies on
price indices are found to do an excellent job in explaining prices in the economic prediction that bids should closely reflect costs in
diverse markets such as real estate, computers, cars, and televi- competitive markets. When firms collude, they break the relation-
sions. Furthermore, the methods for constructing price indices ship between bids and costs, with the objective of obtaining abnor-
are fairly standard and robust. Finally, price indices are easy to ex- mal profits. This divergence between bids and costs is evaluated by
plain, making them accessible to judges, attorneys and jurors. comparing the relationship between bids and costs in the suspected
Ewerhart et al. (2007) develop a microstructure model in which market against the relationship obtained in competitive markets.
commercial banks with strategic recourse to central bank standing This is consistent with the bid-rigging in the New York City concrete
facilities may be expected to fix money market rates. Recent gov- market in the 1980s as discussed in Section 2.3.8
ernmental efforts to develop screening devices are described in
Abrantes-Metz and Froeb (2008). 2.6. Examples of screens for other market manipulations

2.5. Examples of screens for bid-rigging conspiracies A market manipulation is, in general, quite different from a tra-
ditional price-fixing cartel in at least two ways: (a) it typically in-
Markets that use competitive bidding are frequently very rich in volves fewer members, sometimes just a single firm, and (b) it does
data. Such data have been used to evaluate whether a material con- not necessarily focus on maintaining a fixed price level per se. Its
spiracy exists. Initial screens identify bidding patterns across auc-
tions which are highly improbable under competitive bidding. 7
Bid submission and bid level are modeled as a function of costs (controlled for by
Subsequent analyses compare bidding patterns in suspected mar- the distance between a public school, the bidder’s location and the number of
kets against comparable competitive benchmarks. deliveries made by the bidder), and local market power (controlled for by variables
In sealed auctions, when firms do not know each others’ bids, measuring the locations of competing firms).
8
A related study by Bajari and Ye (2003) examines bids for seal coating by highway
the individual bids should reflect market conditions such as costs
contractors in the upper Midwest during the 1990s. Even though three of their sample
and local market power, and perhaps the idiosyncrasies of specific firms had been convicted of collusion in the previous decade, market observers
continue to believe that the industry is free of market wide collusion. In this market,
distance and backlog are important pricing determinants. Using a regression model
6
The authors find that the average price decreases by 16% and the volatility of this with a firm’s bid as the dependent variable and an engineering cost estimate, distance
price as measured by its standard deviation increases by over 200%. They also find from the project and backlog as explanatory variables, the authors find that bids
that these changes in price could not be explained by changes in cost, and that these increase with both these measures, as would be expected under competition. The
price patterns follow those of cost patterns more closely under competitive evidence is consistent with two firms (out of 11) colluding. Both firms, incidentally,
conditions than under collusive conditions. were recently sanctioned for bid rigging.
140 R.M. Abrantes-Metz et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 136–150

goal, for instance, might involve increasing price movements over a in individual bank quotes, we are able to assess whether the select
period of time. Because members of such groups implement a di- group of 16 banks (and/or some sub-groups therein) leave markers
verse array of strategies and tactics, screening processes to detect that signal the possible existence of pricing conspiracies and/or
them are more individualized. market manipulations.
While the term ‘‘manipulation’’ is defined in many ways, the
various definitions share common features such as ‘‘causation’’
and ‘‘price artificiality’’ (Russo, 1983). This term is traditionally ap- 3. Experimental methodology and hypotheses
plied to the commodities markets where large price increases often
precede sudden price collapses. 3.1. Experimental methodology
Many approaches to detecting manipulation involve searching
for price distortions which cannot be explained by seasonality The paper’s methodology is consistent with research that inves-
and common demand and supply conditions. For example, a stan- tigates potential anticompetitive behavior in real markets. Our
dard ‘‘red flag’’ for manipulations in futures markets is backwarda- screening methodology focuses on identifying patterns that are un-
tion, i.e., a condition where the price of a futures contract is lower likely to have been reached under competition, and then examines
than its spot or cash price, an inversion of the more typical contan- relationships between Libor and other variables, both at the macro/
go relationship.9 aggregate and at the micro/individual levels.
Recently, Abrantes-Metz and Addanki (2007) developed a new At the aggregate level, we look into the relationship between
method to screen for manipulations in markets for commodities. Libor and other major benchmarks, assuming those to be untainted
They hypothesize that manipulations induce noise in the market or non-manipulated at the time they are used as benchmarks.
and distort market expectations about future prices. By defining Given that Libor is essentially constant for a period of at least
the price of a futures contract as the market’s expectation of the fu- 7 months, we test whether this pattern would have been predicted
ture spot rate, and by applying their model to a well-known epi- given the historical relationship between Libor and other rates. Our
sode of manipulation in the silver market in 1979 and 1980, they evidence is consistent with the absence of a material manipulation
find that manipulation induces more volatile market forecasting of the average level of the Libor rate.
errors regarding future prices.10 Next we examine the pattern of individual quotes. First, how
Other screens are based on mathematical laws. In many data likely is it that a large number of banks will submit identical Libor
sets, the distribution of digits has a natural, regularly occurring quotes without coordinating? In this context we look at the intra-
pattern. Benford’s Law is a mathematical formula that describes day variance of these individual quotes. Similarly to the bid-rigging
this regularly occurring distribution of digits. Studies have shown literature, we compute pairwise correlations between all possible
that the law applies to a surprisingly large number of data sets bank-pairs. We also calculate the frequency with which each bank
and it is commonly used in accounting to detect accounts manage- appears in the deciding group, and identify a core group of banks
ment.11 Recently, Abrantes-Metz et al. (2011) show that Benford’s that tend to be in the deciding group very often.
Law is violated for the US Libor rate most noticeably from January Finally, we study the relationships between individual Libor
1, 2007 through August 8, 2007. Consistency between the findings quotes and proxies for individual borrowing costs as provided by
from this Benford’s Law application and those in the current paper, CDS spreads. Ceteris paribus, we may expect banks with higher bor-
point to a possible change in the variance of the Libor rather than rowing costs to have higher CDS spreads, and also higher Libor
to a material change in its average value. quotes. We find that for some banks this is not necessarily the case,
The purpose of this study is to extend this field of academic re- and put forward plausible explanations.
search by searching for markers that might signal inconsistencies We compare Libor with other short-term borrowing rates, ana-
between the observed data and what should be expected under lyze individual bank quotes, and compare these individual quotes
competitive market conditions. By analyzing trends and patterns to CDS spreads and market capitalization data during three time
periods: 1/1/07–8/8/07 (Period 1), 8/9/07–4/16/08 (Period 2), and
4/17/08–5/30/08 (Period 3).12 The three periods are separated by
9
While episodes of backwardation can occur in the absence of manipulation (e.g. 2 dates in which major news events occurred: (1) on August 9,
when supply is unable to meet unexpected demand despite the presence of
2007, there were three related press releases on (a) a coordinated
competitive market conditions), such episodes generally do not last for a long time.
Methods often used in legal practice to detect price artificiality conditions involve: (a) intervention by the European Central Bank, the Federal Reserve
comparing the allegedly manipulated price movements to those in previous periods, Bank, and the Bank of Japan; (b) AIG’s warning that defaults were
(b) observing spreads between the allegedly manipulated futures contract and the spreading beyond the subprime sector; and (c) BNP Paribas’ suspen-
next closest contract and repeating (a), (c) evaluating the futures price with sion of three mortgage-backed funds; and (2) on April 17, 2008, the
equivalent futures on other exchanges and again repeating (a), and (d) determining
the relationship between the allegedly manipulated futures with cash prices when
BBA announced its intent to investigate its Libor-setting process.
the futures are close to delivery. Individual Libor quotes are analyzed from January 1, 2007
10
Another example of a screen for manipulation is presented by Pirrong (2004). This through May 30, 2008, while the level of the Libor itself is studied
study analyzes the alleged ‘‘cornering’’ of the soybean futures market in 1989 by from 1990 using Bloomberg data sources. After verifying that the
Ferruzzi, a large Italian conglomerate. Pirrong (2004) tests two hypotheses: (a) that
patterns are essentially the same for the 1- and the 3-month Libor
the price of the manipulated contract is significantly larger than the price of the
contracts expiring at a later date, a distortion that is often largest immediately before
rates, in the paper we focus our attention on the 1-month Libor.
the manipulator liquidates his position, and (b) that the expiring futures price and the We also analyze other market indicators, both for the individual
spot price at the delivery market are significantly larger than the prices at other, non- Libor-setting banks and at the aggregate level. Our primary find-
deliverable locations. The results of this study are consistent with the hypothesis that ings are that, while there are some apparent anomalies within
Ferruzzi exercises monopoly power, thereby creating an estimated price distortion of
the individual quotes, this evidence is not consistent with a mate-
5–10%.
11
Incidentally, Benford’s Law is also used to detect data tampering in taxes, in rial manipulation of the average Libor rate during the period of
financial ratios, and in survey data. Newcomb (1881) and Benford (1938) base this study. However, certain individual banks quotes exhibit some
law on an empirical observation that, in many naturally occurring data sets, the unexpected patterns.
leading significant digits are not uniformly distributed but instead follow a
logarithmic weak monotonic distribution. Judge and Schechter (2009), Nigrini
12
(2005), and others have subsequently applied Benford’s Law to this field of research. We should note that our data for banks’ individual quotes started only on January
Ashton and Hudson (2008) examine patterns of data streams to find instances of 1, 2007. It is possible that the patterns observed since 2007 may have started
interest rate clustering in UK financial services markets. sometime in 2006, but our analysis is restricted by data availability.
R.M. Abrantes-Metz et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 136–150 141

The rest of this section contains the following analyses: (a) a individual quotes in three ways by: (1) reviewing 2007 data, (2)
comparison of Libor with other rates of short-term borrowing investigating CDS spreads for each bank in an ordinal rather than
costs, (b) an evaluation of the individual bank quotes, and (c) a in a cardinal fashion, and (3) studying other potentially relevant
comparison of these individual quotes to individual CDS spreads. indicators.Hypothesis H3 Next we study whether banks with rela-
To provide a clear presentation of our results, each of the three tively low CDS spreads are also banks with relatively low Libor
subsections begins with a research proposition expressed in a null quotes. A negative correlation between a bank’s Libor quote and
hypothesis format, and ends with a conclusion that fails to affirm its CDS spread could indicate an inconsistency.
or not the proposition.

3.2. Experimental hypotheses Thus, our Hypothesis H3 for this analysis (expressed as a null
hypothesis) is that no such inconsistencies are evident in any of our
three periods.
Hypothesis H1. To conclude that the Libor rate is materially Procedurally, we review individual Libor quotes and CDS spread
manipulated in a downward direction during Period 2 (8/9/07 data for any such unusual patterns among individual banks.
through 4/16/08), the spreads between Libor and other bench- Although such patterns would not prove the presence of manipu-
marks of borrowing costs would need to be statistically signifi- lation, they could again flag such possibility.
cantly lower during that period than during Periods 1 or 3, since In this subsection, we investigate the Wall Street Journal’s pre-
the Libor typically takes higher values than the benchmark rates sumption that CDS spreads serve as effective benchmarks for
used. assessing the reasonableness of Libor quote data from which a
‘‘but for’’ individual Libor quote can be extracted. As stated by
Thus, our Hypothesis H1 for this analysis (expressed as a null the Wall Street Journal, the borrowing costs of banks are presumed
hypothesis) is that these spreads during Period 2 are not statistically to be a function of their perceived conditions of solvency and finan-
significantly lower than these spreads in Periods 1 or 3. cial strength. Pricing of CDS contracts is presumed to depend on
We assume that neither the Federal funds effective rate, a rate the bank’s financial strength, and thus serve as a useful indicator
determined by actual exchanges between banks, nor the Treasury of the cost of borrowing. Unlike the Wall Street Journal, we do
bill rate, as directly determined in the market place, are simulta- not use the CDS spread to estimate what the Libor quote should
neously tainted by a possible Libor manipulation. Even if the Libor have been, as we believe that these spreads encompass significant
rate is materially manipulated and in turn influences other rates, noise. Instead, we investigate the ordinal relationships between
that effect would likely not be contemporaneous and in exactly CDS spreads and quotes.
the same proportion. Hence, we would expect a contemporaneous
comparison between an allegedly manipulated Libor and the other
4. Results of tests of Libor and benchmarks (H1)
benchmark rates to exhibit unusual patterns.
Procedurally, we adjust the actual (reported) Libor rate to re-
We begin by comparing the 1-month Libor against the 1-month
flect what the rate would have been ‘‘but for’’ any alleged manip-
Treasury bill and the Federal funds effective rate.14 Fig. 1 presents
ulation. If the adjusted (or estimated) Libor rate produces
the January 2007 through May 2008 period for these rates. It is clear
spreads that are not statistically significantly lower during Period
that the Libor closely follows the other rate indicators for both matu-
2 than during Periods 1 or 3, we will not reject the null Hypothesis
rities. Analogous patterns are found for the 3-month Libor.
H1.
We continue this analysis by examining the spreads between
Libor and other rates; we focus our attention on the recent period
Hypothesis H2. To conclude that the Libor rate is materially
beginning January 2007. Fig. 2A shows the spread of 1-month Libor
manipulated during Period 2, the individual Libor quotes of
over 1-month Treasury bill, separately identifying the mean spread
‘‘manipulative’’ banks should cluster together in non-random
within the periods 1/1/07–8/8/07 (Period 1), 8/9/07–4/16/08
patterns.
(Period 2), and after 4/17/08 (Period 3). Table 1 restates these time
Thus, our Hypothesis H2 for this analysis (expressed as a null period definitions.15
hypothesis) is that no such clustering patterns are evident in any of An increase in the spread beginning August 9, 2007 is evident,
our three periods. and is statistically significant. Fig. 2B is a similar presentation of
Procedurally, we review the individual Libor quote data, as well the spread over the Fed funds effective rate; again we see a signif-
as various other benchmark indicators of borrowing costs, for non- icant widening of this spread, beginning August 9. The same qual-
random clustering patterns. Although such patterns would not itative patterns are found for the 3-month Libor.
prove the presence of manipulation, they could ‘‘flag’’ such a Table 2 presents summary statistics for graphs depicted in the
possibility. figures above and the t-statistics for the respective Libor spreads.
According to the Wall Street Journal (Mollenkamp and On August 9, 2007, three major news items were announced in
Whitehouse, 2008), the sixteen banks may ‘‘have been low-balling the press: (a) a ‘‘coordinated intervention’’ by the European Central
their borrowing rates to avoid looking desperate for cash.’’ By that, Bank, the Federal Reserve Bank, and the Bank of Japan; (b) an AIG
the Wall Street Journal means that during our Period 2, the banks warning that defaults are spreading beyond the subprime sector,
might have provided lower quotes than they should have, implying and (c) BNP Paribas’ suspension of three funds that hold mort-
that the reported Libor was effectively manipulated downwards.13 gage-backed securities. On the same day, a widening of spreads oc-
In this section we extend the Wall Street Journal’s analysis of curs in terms of both the mean level and the variance. In short, it
would appear that there is a ‘‘structural break’’ on August 9 which
13
However, the Wall Street Journal does not present an analysis of the type we may explain the observed changes in these spreads. Furthermore,
conduct (i.e., an examination of the level of the Libor against a suitable ‘‘but-for’’ we consider a second ‘‘structural break’’ on April 17, 2008, the
predictor), but instead examines patterns among the individual bank quotes. In
14
particular, the Wall Street Journal notes that the intraday variances for the bank The effective rate is the weighted average of rates of actual exchanges between
quotes are unusually small as compared to the intraday means since January 2008, banks.
15
and suggests that this is evidence of a pattern of manipulation. They also investigate Future researchers may wish to search for other structural breaks that are less
the credit default swap (CDS) market and develop estimates of the banks’ ‘‘but-for’’ significant than these two breaks and occurring during the period of analysis. Any
individual Libor quotes. such additional breaks, though, fall outside of the scope of this study.
142 R.M. Abrantes-Metz et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 136–150

Libor 1m, Fed Funds Effective Rate and Treasury-Bill 1m


7.00

4/17/08
8/9/07
6.00

5.00

4.00

3.00

2.00

1.00

0.00

10/1/2007

11/1/2007

12/1/2007
1/1/2007

2/1/2007

3/1/2007

4/1/2007

5/1/2007

6/1/2007

7/1/2007

8/1/2007

9/1/2007

1/1/2008

2/1/2008

3/1/2008

4/1/2008

5/1/2008

6/1/2008
Libor 1m Fed Funds Effective Treasury-Bill 1m

Fig. 1. Libor 1 month, Fed funds effective rate and Treasury-bill 1 month.

Spread: LIBOR 1m over Treasury-Bill 1m


3.50
8/9/07 4/17/08

3.00

2.50

2.00

1.50

1.00

0.50

0.00
7

7
07

08
07

07
07

07

07

07

07

07

08

08

08

08
8
7
00

00

00
00
20

20

20
20

20

20

20

20

20

20
20
20

20

20
/2

/2

/2
/1/2
1/

1/

1/
1/

1/
1/

1/

1/

1/

1/
1/

1/
1/

1/
/1

/1

1/1
9/

6/
1/

2/

3/

4/

5/

6/

8/

2/
7/

3/

4/

5/
10

11

12

Fig. 2a. Spread: Libor 1 month over Treasury-bill 1 month.

day when the Wall Street Journal first published the news of the While it is true that spreads widened significantly beginning
BBA’s intent to investigate the accuracy of Libor quotes. August 9, 2007, these spreads are not necessarily and conclusively
suspicious. If it is true, as the Wall Street Journal alleges, that Libor
is manipulated downwards since January 2008 (i.e., during Period
2), the spreads of Libor over one or more of these other benchmark
Table 1
Time periods. rates would be significantly low. To test for this effect, we generate
an estimate of what the Libor would be ‘‘but for’’ this alleged
Time periods
manipulation. We study the relationship between the Libor rate
Period 1 January 2, 2007–August 8, 2007 and the Federal funds effective rate in a past (presumed) clean
Period 2 August 9, 2007–April 16, 2008
period. We assume that this untainted relationship would prevail
Period 3 April 17, 2008–May 30, 2008
during the suspected manipulative periods, and we then predict
R.M. Abrantes-Metz et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 136–150 143

Spread: LIBOR 1m over Fed Funds Effective Rate


2.00
8/9/07 4/17/08

1.50

1.00

0.50

0.00

-0.50

10/1/2007

11/1/2007

12/1/2007
1/1/2007

2/1/2007

3/1/2007

4/1/2007

5/1/2007

6/1/2007

7/1/2007

8/1/2007

9/1/2007

1/1/2008

2/1/2008

3/1/2008

4/1/2008

5/1/2008

6/1/2008
Fig. 2b. Spread: LIBOR 1 m over Fed funds effective rate.

Table 2
Summary statistics.

Libor 1-month
Treasury-bill spread Fed funds effective rate spread
Mean Stand deviation Coeff. variation Mean Stand deviation Coeff. variation
Period 1 0.395 0.243 0.616 0.064 0.03 0.469
Period 2 1.404 0.495 0.352 0.342 0.312 0.912
Period 3 1.069 0.642 0.6 0.532 0.165 0.31
Libor 1 month over Treasury-bill month Libor 1 month over Fed funds effective rate
Coeff. T-stat. T-(robust) Coeff. T-stat. T-(robust)
Intercept 0.395 11.648 5.414 0.064 3.573 24.724
8/9/07–4/16/08 1.009 21.738 12.157 0.279 11.433 5.203
4/17/08–5/30/08 0.335 4.259 1.429 0.189 4.577 2.699

the Libor rate, based on the observed Federal funds effective rate knowledge of the Federal funds effective rate is very helpful in
and the relationship between the two rates that we previously esti- predicting the Libor rate, as indicated by the very high adjusted
mated. Our last step is to test whether this ‘‘but-for’’ Libor rate is R-squared (0.98). If there is a structural break in one of the time
statistically different from the actual Libor rate to address whether series, a similar structural break should occur in the other time ser-
a material manipulation may have been in place. ies. The estimation period covers two major cycles, and the two rates
The Federal funds effective rate is the interest rate at which respond in a very similar fashion. We can also see that there is essen-
banks (and other depository institutions) lend balances through tially no statistical or numerical difference between the contempora-
the Federal Reserve Bank to other depository institutions; it neous and the lagged 1 day relationships.18 Further lags of the
represents an overnight rate. It thus serves as a primary short-term Federal funds effective rate are also tested and qualitatively equiva-
borrowing rate between banks, allegedly untainted and therefore a lent results are produced.19,20
suitable candidate for a benchmark for our study.16 This relationship between the Libor rate and the Federal funds
We first estimate the 1-month Libor as a function of a constant effective rate may be viewed strictly as a reduced-form predictive
term and of the Federal funds effective rate from 1987 through relationship. We are not focused on arguments about ‘‘causation’’
2006.17 We consider both contemporaneous and lagged relation-
ships. These regression results presented in Table 3 show that the
18
correlation level between these two rates is very strong, and that The same is true for higher levels of lags introduced.
19
The ‘‘robust’’ t-statistics are based on a modified White standard error adjusted to
account for serial correlation, derived as the General Method of Moments covariance
matrix.
16 20
We should note that other rates such as the Overnight Indexed Swap Rate and Granger causality tests, not reported herein, indicate that each series Granger
results are qualitatively identical. causes the other. On the other hand, a variance decomposition analysis, performed
17
We recognize that if any alleged anticompetitive behavior started occurring under the assumption that shocks to the Fed funds effective rate have no
before January 1, 2007, the inclusion of the data up to December 31, 2006 in our contemporaneous impact on Libor, indicates that innovations to the Libor rate
‘‘presumably clean’’ pre-period could potentially bias some econometric results. But account for 91.0% of the long-run (1000 day) variance in Libor and 88.7% of the
unless such distortions occurred for a very long period of time prior to 2007 or/and variance in the Fed funds effective rate. It should be noted, however, that as the Fed
were very pronounced, it is unlikely that estimates will be significantly affected given funds effective rate is strongly influenced by a policy rate, it is not obvious that the
the very large time series data studied and presumably untainted. requisite conditions of stationarity are met in this case.
144 R.M. Abrantes-Metz et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 136–150

Actual and Predicted Libor 1m, based on Fed Funds Effective Rate
7.00

8/9/07

4/17/08
6.00

5.00

4.00

Estimation Window: 7/13/90 - 31/12/06


3.00 Projected Window: 1/1/07 - 30/5/08

Model: Regress Libor 1 month onto Fed Funds


Effective Rate
2.00
Constant = 0.17
Slope = 1

R-Squared = 0.98
1.00

0.00
1/1/2007

2/1/2007

3/1/2007

4/1/2007

5/1/2007

6/1/2007

7/1/2007

8/1/2007

9/1/2007

1/1/2008

2/1/2008

3/1/2008

4/1/2008

5/1/2008

6/1/2008
10/1/2007

11/1/2007

12/1/2007
Actual Libor 1m Predicted Libor 1m 95% Confidence Interval 95% Confidence Interval

Fig. 3. Actual and predicted Libor 1 month, based on Fed funds effective rate.

or ‘‘exogeneity.’’ We simply note that, historically, if one knows the 2007 is evident. The intraday coefficients of variation (equal to
Federal funds effective rate (that day or the preceding day), one can the standard deviation divided by the mean of the Libor quotes
form a very accurate guess about the Libor rate as well. for the banks on a daily basis) significantly increase during Period
Next we estimate the historical relationship using data through 2 and remain high throughout Period 3.
the end of 2006, to predict the 1-month Libor from January 2007 It appears that the individual quotes are very tightly clustered
onwards, given the Federal funds effective rate for Periods 1, 2 in Period 1 relative to the later periods. Period 1 volatility levels,
and 3, as previously defined. The intuitive rationale is a simple demonstrating nearly identical quotes on a daily basis, provide a
one: if the Libor rate has been effectively manipulated upwards candidate for a conspiracy in fixing the level of the Libor rate, (at
or downwards, it should manifest itself as a break in the histori- least) as early as January 2, 2007 (possibly before) and until August
cally powerful predictive relationship between the two rates. Our 8, 2007. Although it is not clear why the banks might manipulate
results are presented in Fig. 3. their quotes for such an extended period of time, the very low var-
When comparing the actual Libor for the post-2007 period iability in the intraday quotes during Period 1 appears to be anom-
against the projected Libor based on the historical relationship alous, in particular when that implies an essentially constant Libor
between the Libor and the Federal funds effective rate through rate for the entire period. Nevertheless, we previously found that
December 2006, we find that after January 2007 and through on average the Libor level does not seem to be materially impacted,
May 2008 the actual Libor is not significantly different from its pre- given that the Libor level does not significantly differ from what it
dicted values based on our simple model, and for each of the three ‘‘should have been’’ when benchmarking against the Federal funds
periods that we consider. In other words, the empirical evidence is effective rate (though other moments, such as the variance rather
not consistent with the hypothesis that the average values of the than the mean, may have been affected).
Libor rate are materially manipulated downward during Period 2, The Libor is established as the simple average of the middle set
as the Wall Street Journal alleges. Similar results are found when of eight quotes that are submitted by the sixteen participating
studying the 3-month Libor series, and also when using other banks. In other words, the BBA ranks the quotes from 1st to 16th
benchmark rates. and then calculates Libor as the average of the 5–12th quotes. If
In sum, the null hypothesis of H1 is not rejected. The statistical several banks submit identical quotes, more than eight banks
evidence is not consistent with a material manipulation of the may produce quotes that are tied for 5th place or 12th place; i.e.,
Libor rate. more than eight banks on any given day may join the deciding
group.
5. Results of tests of individual bank quotes (H2) Table 4 reports summary statistics on rates of inclusion in the
deciding group by period for the 1-month Libor. We report: (a)
Fig. 4 shows the cross-sectional coefficients of variation of indi- how often each bank joins the deciding group, (b) how often each
vidual 1-month Libor quotes, distinguishing the entire set of 16 bank submits a quote lower than the deciding set, (c) how often
banks from the ‘‘deciding group’’ of eight which determine the ac- each bank submits a higher quote, and (d) how often each bank
tual Libor. Again, similar patterns are also found for the 3-month submits a quote that is less than or equal to the median quote
Libor. Once again, a structural break which begins on August 9, on each day.
R.M. Abrantes-Metz et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 136–150 145

During Period 1, a somewhat surprising result emerges: the vast second group: HBOS, Lloyds, and UBS AG. This group is distantly
majority of the banks join the deciding group more than 95% of the followed by a single bank, Barclays, which participates about 50%
time. Owing to the large number of identical quotes, this finding of the time. The Royal Bank of Scotland participates the least often,
produces the very low intraday variance mentioned above. In par- at a rate of approximately 5%. It would thus appear that the com-
ticular, BTMU, JPM Chase, Citigroup, HSBC, West LB, Royal Bank of position of the deciding group is relatively constant during Period
Canada and CSFB are members of the deciding group virtually each 1, a period with many instances when more than eight banks
day. This nearly perfect participation rate is followed closely by a determine the Libor due to identical quote submissions.

Libor 1m: Cross-Sectional Coefficient of Variation for Banks Quotes


0.01
8/9/07 4/17/08

0.01

0.01

0.01

0.01

0.00

0.00

0.00
7
7

7
07
07

07
07

07

07

08

08
07

08

08

08
07

07

00

00

00
20
20

20
20

20

20

20

20

20

20

20
20
20

20

/2

/2

/2
2/

2/

2/

2/

2/

2/
2/

2/
2/

2/

2/

2/

2/
2/

/2

/2

/2
1/

7/

9/

1/

3/
2/

3/

4/

5/

6/

8/

2/

4/

5/
10

11

12

All 16 Banks Deciding Group

Fig. 4. Libor 1 month: cross-sectional coefficient of variation for banks’ quotes.

Table 3
Regression results.

Libor 1-month
Libor 1 month (t) on Fed funds effective rate (t) Libor 1 month (t) on Fed funds effective rate (t 1)
Coeff. T-stat. T-(robust) Coeff. T-stat. T-(robust)
Intercept 0.1692 18.37 7.05 0.1691 18.38 6.88
Fed funds E rate (t) 0.997 577.74 178.95 0.9969 578.82 174.59
# Observations 5159 5158
Adjusted R-squared 0.9848 0.9848

Table 4
Percent in deciding group.

Percent in deciding group Percent below Percent above Percent in low half
Period 1 Period 2 Period 3 Period 1 Period 2 Period 3 Period 1 Period 2 Period 3 Period 1 Period 2 Period 3
BTMU 99.3 75.3 13.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.7 24.7 86.7 99.3 31.6 3.3
Bank of America 92.8 70.1 23.3 4.6 10.9 76.7 2.6 19.0 0.0 97.4 55.7 93.3
Barclays 55.6 45.4 53.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 44.4 54.6 46.7 55.6 23.6 26.7
JPM Chase 98.0 89.1 56.7 0.0 9.2 43.3 2.0 1.7 0.0 98.0 80.5 93.3
Citigroup 99.3 61.5 93.3 0.7 37.4 3.3 0.0 1.1 3.3 100.0 93.1 90.0
CSFB 99.3 77.6 86.7 0.0 7.5 3.3 0.7 14.9 10.0 99.3 58.0 76.7
Deutsch Bank 94.8 21.8 20.0 3.9 75.9 76.7 1.3 2.3 3.3 98.7 96.0 96.7
HBOS 96.7 80.5 86.7 3.3 2.3 0.0 0.0 17.2 13.3 100.0 50.0 56.7
HSBC 98.0 67.8 86.7 1.3 30.5 0.0 0.7 1.7 13.3 99.3 88.5 50.0
Lloyds 96.1 78.7 53.3 0.0 4.0 46.7 3.9 17.2 0.0 96.1 55.2 100.0
Norinchukin 85.0 33.3 10.0 0.0 0.6 0.0 15.0 66.1 90.0 85.0 13.8 6.7
Rabo Bank 75.8 48.3 46.7 0.0 50.0 53.3 24.2 1.7 0.0 75.2 91.4 100.0
Royal Bank of Canada 98.0 87.4 80.0 1.3 7.5 6.7 0.7 5.2 13.3 98.7 66.1 70.0
Royal Bank of Scotland 4.6 61.5 80.0 95.4 33.9 6.7 0.0 4.6 13.3 100.0 86.8 66.7
UBSAG 96.7 59.2 86.7 2.0 38.5 6.7 1.3 2.3 6.7 98.7 92.0 76.7
West LB 99.3 93.1 70.0 0.7 0.6 0.0 0.0 6.3 30.0 100.0 60.9 40.0
Table 5

146
Banks’ pairwise participation rates.

BTMU Bank of Barclays JPM Citigroup CSFB Deutsch HBOS HSBC Lloyds Norinch Rabo Bank Royal Bank Royal Bank UBS AG West LB
America Chase Bank of Canada of Scotland
Banks pairwise participation rates, 2/1/07–8/8/07
BTMU 100.0 93.4 55.3 98.7 99.3 99.3 94.7 96.7 98.0 96.1 84.9 75.7 98.0 4.6 96.7 99.3
Bank of America 100.0 100.0 52.8 98.6 99.3 99.3 95.1 96.5 98.6 97.2 85.2 73.9 98.6 4.2 97.2 99.3
Barclays 98.8 88.2 100.0 97.6 98.8 98.8 95.3 95.3 98.8 97.6 72.9 88.2 100.0 2.4 97.6 100.0
JPM Chase 100.0 93.3 55.3 100.0 99.3 100.0 94.7 96.7 98.0 96.0 85.3 76.7 98.0 4.7 96.7 99.3
Citigroup 99.3 92.8 55.3 98.0 100.0 99.3 94.7 96.7 98.0 96.1 85.5 76.3 98.0 4.6 97.4 99.3
CSFB 99.3 92.8 55.3 98.7 99.3 100.0 94.7 96.7 98.0 96.1 85.5 76.3 98.0 4.6 96.7 99.3
Deutsch Bank 99.3 93.1 55.9 97.9 99.3 99.3 100.0 97.2 98.6 98.6 84.1 75.9 100.0 2.8 98.6 100.0
HBOS 99.3 92.6 54.7 98.0 99.3 99.3 95.3 100.0 98.6 95.9 85.1 75.0 98.6 4.1 97.3 100.0
HSBC 99.3 93.3 56.0 98.0 99.3 99.3 95.3 97.3 100.0 97.3 84.7 75.3 98.7 3.3 97.3 99.3
Lloyds 99.3 93.9 56.5 98.0 99.3 99.3 97.3 96.6 99.3 100.0 84.4 76.2 99.3 2.7 98.0 99.3
Norinchukin 99.2 93.1 47.7 98.5 100.0 100.0 93.8 96.9 97.7 95.4 100.0 77.7 97.7 5.4 97.7 99.2
Rabo Bank 99.1 90.5 64.7 99.1 100.0 100.0 94.8 95.7 97.4 96.6 87.1 100.0 98.3 4.3 97.4 99.1

R.M. Abrantes-Metz et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 136–150


Royal Bank of Canada 99.3 93.3 56.7 98.0 99.3 99.3 96.7 97.3 98.7 97.3 84.7 76.0 100.0 3.3 98.7 100.0
Royal Bank of Scotland 100.0 85.7 28.6 100.0 100.0 100.0 57.1 85.7 71.4 57.1 100.0 71.4 71.4 100.0 71.4 85.7
UBS AG 99.3 93.2 56.1 98.0 100.0 99.3 96.6 97.3 98.6 97.3 85.8 76.4 100.0 3.4 100.0 100.0
West LB 99.3 92.8 55.9 98.0 99.3 99.3 95.4 97.4 98.0 96.1 84.9 75.7 98.7 3.9 97.4 100.0

Banks pairwise participation rates, 8/9/07–4/16/08


BTMU 100.0 71.8 48.9 89.3 59.5 77.9 22.1 77.9 71.0 81.7 35.1 45.8 88.5 60.3 56.5 93.1
Bank of America 77.0 100.0 41.0 86.9 64.8 81.1 20.5 78.7 72.1 75.4 28.7 45.9 86.9 60.7 63.1 94.3
Barclays 81.0 63.3 100.0 92.4 67.1 74.7 16.5 77.2 77.2 77.2 29.1 53.2 86.1 55.7 54.4 88.6
JPM Chase 75.5 68.4 47.1 100.0 57.4 78.1 22.6 81.3 66.5 78.7 31.6 49.7 88.4 62.6 58.7 92.3
Citigroup 72.9 73.8 49.5 83.2 100.0 82.2 16.8 79.4 65.4 76.6 34.6 45.8 86.0 55.1 57.9 91.6
CSFB 75.6 73.3 43.7 89.6 65.2 100.0 21.5 83.0 65.2 77.0 33.3 45.9 87.4 59.3 60.0 91.9
Deutsch Bank 76.3 65.8 34.2 92.1 47.4 76.3 100.0 84.2 55.3 73.7 26.3 42.1 94.7 63.2 65.8 94.7
HBOS 72.9 68.6 43.6 90.0 60.7 80.0 22.9 100.0 66.4 78.6 36.4 50.0 87.1 62.9 60.0 92.9
HSBC 78.8 74.6 48.3 87.3 59.3 74.6 17.8 78.8 100.0 78.8 31.4 52.5 85.6 56.8 56.8 92.4
Lloyds 78.1 67.2 44.5 89.1 59.9 75.9 20.4 80.3 67.9 100.0 35.8 44.5 86.9 59.1 58.4 94.2
Norinchukin 79.3 60.3 39.7 84.5 63.8 77.6 17.2 87.9 63.8 84.5 100.0 48.3 89.7 69.0 56.9 91.4
Rabo Bank 71.4 66.7 50.0 91.7 58.3 73.8 19.0 83.3 73.8 72.6 33.3 100.0 86.9 61.9 50.0 91.7
Royal Bank of Canada 76.3 69.7 44.7 90.1 60.5 77.6 23.7 80.3 66.4 78.3 34.2 48.0 100.0 63.2 59.2 94.1
Royal Bank of Scotland 73.8 69.2 41.1 90.7 55.1 74.8 22.4 82.2 62.6 75.7 37.4 48.6 89.7 100.0 56.1 92.5
UBS AG 71.8 74.8 41.7 88.3 60.2 78.6 24.3 81.6 65.0 77.7 32.0 40.8 87.4 58.3 100.0 95.1
West LB 75.3 71.0 43.2 88.3 60.5 76.5 22.2 80.2 67.3 79.6 32.7 47.5 88.3 61.1 60.5 100.0

Banks pairwise participation rates, 4/17/08–5/30/08


BTMU 100.0 0.0 25.0 75.0 75.0 75.0 25.0 50.0 100.0 25.0 75.0 50.0 75.0 50.0 100.0 50.0
Bank of America 0.0 100.0 57.1 71.4 85.7 85.7 14.3 85.7 85.7 28.6 0.0 28.6 100.0 85.7 100.0 42.9
Barclays 6.3 25.0 100.0 56.3 87.5 93.8 18.8 87.5 87.5 68.8 6.3 37.5 68.8 68.8 81.3 75.0
JPM Chase 17.6 29.4 52.9 100.0 88.2 94.1 29.4 82.4 94.1 52.9 11.8 41.2 88.2 76.5 88.2 52.9
Citigroup 10.7 21.4 50.0 53.6 100.0 85.7 17.9 89.3 85.7 57.1 7.1 46.4 82.1 82.1 85.7 71.4
CSFB 11.5 23.1 57.7 61.5 92.3 100.0 23.1 84.6 84.6 57.7 7.7 42.3 76.9 76.9 84.6 65.4
Deutsch Bank 16.7 16.7 50.0 83.3 83.3 100.0 100.0 66.7 100.0 33.3 16.7 33.3 66.7 83.3 83.3 66.7
HBOS 7.7 23.1 53.8 53.8 96.2 84.6 15.4 100.0 84.6 57.7 7.7 46.2 84.6 84.6 84.6 69.2
HSBC 15.4 23.1 53.8 61.5 92.3 84.6 23.1 84.6 100.0 53.8 11.5 46.2 84.6 80.8 84.6 65.4
Lloyds 6.3 12.5 68.8 56.3 100.0 93.8 12.5 93.8 87.5 100.0 0.0 43.8 75.0 68.8 87.5 68.8
Norinchukin 100.0 0.0 33.3 66.7 66.7 66.7 33.3 66.7 100.0 0.0 100.0 66.7 66.7 66.7 100.0 66.7
Rabo Bank 14.3 14.3 42.9 50.0 92.9 78.6 14.3 85.7 85.7 50.0 14.3 100.0 78.6 71.4 85.7 78.6
Royal Bank of Canada 12.5 29.2 45.8 62.5 95.8 83.3 16.7 91.7 91.7 50.0 8.3 45.8 100.0 83.3 83.3 62.5
Royal Bank of Scotland 8.3 25.0 45.8 54.2 95.8 83.3 20.8 91.7 87.5 45.8 8.3 41.7 83.3 100.0 91.7 75.0
UBS AG 15.4 26.9 50.0 57.7 92.3 84.6 19.2 84.6 84.6 53.8 11.5 46.2 76.9 84.6 100.0 69.2
West LB 9.5 14.3 57.1 42.9 95.2 81.0 19.0 85.7 81.0 52.4 9.5 52.4 71.4 85.7 85.7 100.0
R.M. Abrantes-Metz et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 136–150 147

These patterns change significantly during Period 2. The compo- Table 6


sition of the deciding group becomes less stable. Although JPM Correlation between quotes and CDS spreads.

Chase and West LB continue to experience relatively high partici- Period 1 Period 2 Period 3
pation rates, they are significantly less than their Period 1 rates. Correlation between quotes and CDS spreads
Conversely, the participation rate of the Royal Bank of Scotland BTMU 0.58 0.76 0.50
soars to approximately 60%, while the rate of Deutsche Bank plum- Bank of America 0.53 0.85 0.44
mets to about 21%. Barclays 0.58 0.82 0.35
JPM Chase 0.51 0.84 0.41
These patterns change, once again, during Period 3. The partic- Citigroup 0.58 0.85 0.00
ipation rate of JPM Chase declines significantly, while the rates of CSFB 0.57 0.82 0.16
Citigroup and the Royal Banks of Canada and Scotland increase. Deutsch Bank 0.19 0.79 0.24
To test the stability of the deciding group in each Period, we HBOS 0.46 0.84 0.18
HSBC 0.52 0.86 0.39
now explore the joint (pairwise) inclusion of banks. In other words,
Lloyds 0.71 0.89 0.24
for any given reference bank, we ask the question, ‘‘when this bank Norinchukin NaN NaN NaN
joins the deciding group, how often do each of the other banks also Rabo Bank 0.24 0.88 0.15
join the group?’’ The results are presented in Table 5 for the Royal Bank of Canada NaN NaN NaN
1-month Libor, with very similar results presented for the 3-month Royal Bank of Scotland NaN NaN NaN
UBSAG 0.40 0.85 0.18
Libor.
West LB 0.71 0.85 0.51
For example, when we report 93.4% in row ‘‘BTMU’’ and column
Correlation between quotes and market cap.
‘‘Bank America’’ for Period 1, it should be interpreted as ‘‘when
BTMU NaN NaN NaN
BTMU is in the deciding group, Bank of America joins the group Bank of America 0.14 0.78 0.73
93.4% of the time’’. Note that this matrix is not symmetric. For in- Barclays 0.05 0.84 0.85
stance, by reviewing the row ‘‘Bank of America’’ and column JPM Chase 0.30 0.36 0.53
Citigroup 0.30 0.85 0.78
‘‘BTMU,’’ we note that each time Bank of America joins the group,
CSFB 0.19 0.85 0.37
BTMU does so as well. From this sequence of tables, we can identify Deutsch Bank 0.00 0.81 0.67
groups of banks that tend to cluster together in each of the three HBOS 0.22 0.91 0.77
periods in order to form the deciding group. HSBC 0.21 0.68 0.03
As expected, we see many joint inclusion rates in excess of 90% Lloyds 0.00 0.78 0.88
Norinchukin NaN NaN NaN
during Period 1, including several that exceed 99%. These rates fall
Rabo Bank NaN NaN NaN
significantly in Period 2, when we fail to see a single pairwise Royal Bank of Canada 0.06 0.58 0.89
inclusion rate of 100%. Period 3, though, is mixed, with an average Royal Bank of Scotland 0.12 0.91 0.46
pairwise inclusion rate that is lesser in comparison to Period 1, but UBSAG 0.19 0.93 0.75
West LB NaN NaN NaN
greater in comparison to Period 2. It should be noted that Period 3
contains significantly fewer days than do Periods 1 or 2.
Thus, the null hypothesis of H2 is rejected. Although the non-
random clustering patterns that we detect in this section cannot creditors whole for the future. Such situation can only occur in se-
establish the presence of a conspiracy or manipulation, they do vere macroeconomic conditions. Therefore, it is possible for the lar-
‘‘flag’’ such a possibility. ger banks to present higher CDS spreads without necessarily having
a higher physical probability of default.
6. Results of tests of consistency of bank quotes with CDS Fig. 5 plots the CDS spreads on 5-year senior bonds from Janu-
spreads (H3) ary 2007 onwards. Apparently, consistent with the trend of Libor
quotes, the spreads are much more compressed in Period 1 than
Table 6 presents the correlations between individual bank’s Li- in later periods. Furthermore, Fig. 5 also clearly shows that the dai-
bor quotes and CDS spreads for each of the three periods, and also ly dispersion of CDS spreads increases significantly in Periods 2 and
between quotes and bank’s market capitalization (i.e., size). 3 with respect to Period 1, a pattern that also exists in the banks’
Of course, there are many reasons why significant discrepancies daily Libor quotes.
may exist between CDS spreads and short-term borrowing costs. Additionally, we compare the ordinal content of the CDS spread
For instance, the time horizons of interest may be different, i.e., a data with the individual Libor quotes. Specifically, for each period
creditor may believe that a bank is fully able to meet its obligations we compare: (a) the percentage of the time that each bank’s CDS
over the next 30 days and thus may lend to it at a low rate during spread is less than or equal to the median spread, with (b) the per-
that time, but may doubt the borrower’s ability to meet its obliga- centage of the time that each bank’s Libor quote is less than or
tions over the next 5 years. If there is significant segmentation be- equal to the median rate. Our results are presented in Table 7.
tween short- and long-term markets, then there may be additional We are interested in ‘‘outliers,’’ defined as banks which consis-
liquidity premia associated with a specific CDS contract.21 These tently provide relatively low Libor quotes while exhibiting rela-
(and many other) observations notwithstanding, it is reasonable to tively high CDS spreads. During Period 1, JPM Chase, CSFB, and
expect ceteris paribus that a ‘‘riskier’’ bank should have higher bor- Deutsche Bank meet this criterion. Their Libor quotes are always
rowing costs and an accompanying higher CDS spreads than a ‘‘less essentially less than or equal to the median, but their CDS spreads
risky’’ bank. Nevertheless, we should note that it is possible for more are never less than or equal to the median. Bank of America’s
systemic risk to be incorporated in the CDS spreads for the largest quotes are quite similar, with low Libor quotes 97% of the time
banks than for the smallest. The realization of a default by a large but low CDS spreads only 2.6% of the time. Citigroup’s quotes are
bank means that the bank itself not only fails, but that it also does low 100% of the time, but its CDS spreads are low only 3.3% of
not receive sufficient support from a sovereign to make its long term the time.22 In sum, this cross-sectional analysis reveals that banks

21 22
If, in fact, such segmentation between short-term and long-term investments An exploratory analysis for West LB produces results that are consistent with
exists in this market, a comparison of the (short-term) Libor rate against other short (albeit less significant than) the results that are generated by these other banks. The
term borrowing rates paid by the banks at similar time horizons, such as commercial quotes by West LB are low 36.6% of the time, but its CDS spreads are only low 0.7% of
paper, may represent a fairer comparison. the time.
148 R.M. Abrantes-Metz et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 136–150

CDS Spreads, Senior 5 years


January 2, 2007 - May 30, 2008
300
8/9/07 4/17/08
250
CDS Spreads
200

150

100

50

10/2/2007

11/2/2007

12/2/2007
1/2/2007

2/2/2007

3/2/2007

4/2/2007

5/2/2007

6/2/2007

7/2/2007

8/2/2007

9/2/2007

1/2/2008

2/2/2008

3/2/2008

4/2/2008

5/2/2008
BTMU Bank of America Barclays JPM Chase
Citigroup CSFB Deutschbank HBOS
HSBC Lloyds Rabobank Royal Bank of Scotland
UBS AG West LB

Fig. 5. CDS spreads, senior 5 years.

Table 7
CDS spreads, market capitalizations and Libor quotes.

CDS spreads Market cap. Libor quotes


Percent in low half Percent in low half Percent in low halfa
Period 1 Period 2 Period 3 Period 1 Period 2 Period 3 Period 1 Period 2 Period 3
BTMU 68.0 98.3 100.0 NaN NaN NaN 96.7 36.2 3.3
Bank of America 2.6 41.4 16.7 0.0 0.0 0.0 97.4 58.0 93.3
Barclays 94.1 45.4 63.3 100.0 100.0 100.0 55.6 26.4 23.3
JPM Chase 0.0 32.8 6.7 0.0 0.0 0.0 98.0 85.1 93.3
Citigroup 3.3 8.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 100.0 92.5 86.7
CSFB 0.0 42.5 70.0 99.3 99.4 100.0 99.3 61.5 76.7
Deutsch Bank 0.0 64.9 100.0 100.0 98.9 100.0 98.7 96.0 96.7
HBOS 99.3 8.0 0.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 99.3 54.0 53.3
HSBC 84.3 98.9 100.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 99.3 90.8 46.7
Lloyds 100.0 99.4 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 96.1 59.2 100.0
Norinchukin NaN NaN NaN NaN NaN NaN 85.0 13.8 6.7
Rabo Bank 100.0 100.0 100.0 NaN NaN NaN 75.2 91.4 100.0
Royal Bank of Canada NaN NaN NaN 100.0 97.7 76.7 98.7 66.1 70.0
Royal Bank of Scotland NaN NaN NaN 0.0 0.0 3.3 100.0 86.8 66.7
UBSAG 83.7 59.8 46.7 0.0 4.0 20.0 98.7 93.1 76.7
West LB 0.7 1.7 0.0 NaN NaN NaN 36.6 66.1 36.7
a
Computed only among the 13 banks for which we also have CDS spreads and market cap. data.

with low Libor quotes do not necessarily enjoy low CDS spreads dur- we note that many of the ‘‘outlier’’ banks are relatively large as de-
ing Period 1. fined by their market capitalization. In other words, as shown in
During Period 2, for instance, Libor quotes of Citigroup and Table 7, very large banks appear to have borrowing costs that are
HBOS are low 93% and 54% of the time, respectively, but their low in relation to their CDS spreads. In Period 1, for instance, the
CDS spreads are low only 8% of the time. The rate quotes of West low borrowing costs of JPM Chase and Citigroup may provide a po-
LB are low 66.1% of the time, but its CDS spreads are low only tential explanation for the disparities that are found when compar-
1.7% of the time. Similarly, the Libor quotes of JPM Chase are low ing their CDS spreads with their Libor quotes.
85.1% of the time, but its CDS spreads are low only 32.8% of the Why may this be true? One explanation is that larger banks may
time.23 Similar examples are found during Period 3. be able to obtain ‘‘volume discounts’’ and thus may have the ability
These results suggest that either: (a) CDS spreads are not effec- to borrow at lower rates than smaller banks due to their higher
tive ordinal indicators of borrowing costs, or (b) the sample banks bargaining power. But it may also be that their systemic risk is sig-
are unusual and atypical in some manner, or (c) that the portion of nificantly higher than that of smaller banks. Other explanations, of
systemic risk in the larger banks’ CDS spreads is significantly larger course, are possible as well, and deserve additional study in future
than in the smaller banks’ CDS spreads, so that a higher CDS spread research.
may well be consistent with a lower Libor rate quote by a large Next, we discuss our use of credit ratings as reflecting the credit
bank. Although this question falls beyond the scope of our analysis, premium of the participating banks. In particular, we look at mar-
ket implied ratings. The first aspect to keep in mind is that credit
ratings are designed to be stable over time (i.e., stable for at least
23
Interestingly, BTMU serves as an outlier on the ‘‘high side.’’ Its quotes are high many months or even years), and hence do not respond to market
36.2% of the time, but its CDS spreads are low 98% of the time. conditions at a high frequency. Second, higher ratings tend to be
R.M. Abrantes-Metz et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 136–150 149

Coefficient of Variation of Market-Implied Bond Ratings


January 2006 to January 2009
0.75

0.60

Rating Notches 0.45

0.30

0.15

0.00
May-06

May-07

May-08
Nov-06

Nov-07

Nov-08
Mar-06

Mar-07

Mar-08
Jul-06

Jul-07

Jul-08
Sep-06

Sep-07

Sep-08
Jan-06

Jan-07

Jan-08

Jan-09
Fig. 6. Coefficient of variation of market-implied bond ratings. Source: Moody’s Market Implied Ratings.

more stable over time than are lower ratings. The group of banks variability in their Libor quotes during the same period. Finally,
participating in the Libor is composed of highly rated banks; their we should also notice that these ratings cannot explain the dras-
long term debt ratings are all between A and Aaa, and similarly tic changes in Libor quotes after August 9, 2007. Fig. 6 shows
their short term deposit ratings are all P1 during the relevant time that, on average, the coefficient of variation slightly increases
period. Hence, credit ratings by themselves cannot explain varia- from before to after August 9, 2007, but such a change is not
tion (or the absence of variation) in the daily Libor rate, since credit sufficient to explain the drastic increase in dispersion in banks’
ratings are highly stable by design while the stability of the Libor Libor quotes during that time period.
varies across different periods. Thus, the null hypothesis of H3 is rejected. Although the Libor
Instead we study the pattern in market-implied ratings as pro- quote and spread patterns detected in this section cannot establish
vided by the ratings agency Moody’s. These market-implied ratings the presence of a conspiracy or a manipulation of the Libor rate,
transform market indicators such as bond prices into a scale that is certain patterns do ‘‘flag’’ such a possibility.
comparable to credit ratings. Market-implied ratings typically
change on a daily basis with the market, and though on average
7. Key results, conclusions, and implications
they are expected to be equal to credit ratings, they are more
responsive to market conditions at a very high frequency. From
The analyses presented in this study screen for markers that are
an overly-simplified perspective, if Moody’s credit ratings are seen
associated with the presence of conspiracies and manipulations in
by the market as ‘‘correct,’’ market-implied ratings will be close to
various industries. Such markers may indeed exist in the absence
these ratings. But when the market perceives the actual ratings as
of anticompetitive behavior. Conversely, collusions and/or manip-
incorrect, statistically significant differences will be observed
ulations may be present without triggering such markers. Although
between the actual ratings and market-implied ratings. Hence,
this study does not intend to provide conclusive evidence of the
comparisons between actual and implied ratings help credit pro-
presence of anticompetitive market behavior (or, for that matter,
fessionals anticipate ratings changes, identify default candidates,
of a material manipulation of Libor) by the participating banks,
detect relative value trading opportunities, and are therefore a ma-
we do present statistical evidence of patterns that appear to be
jor indicator of how the market perceives the underlying issuers in
inconsistent with those expected to occur under conditions of mar-
terms of risk. On average, market implied ratings and actual ratings
ket competition for certain periods under study.
are not statistically different from each other.
The experimental analyses that we conduct to assess Hypothe-
If there is no variability in (relative) credit risk across the partic-
sis H1 are designed to detect evidence of a material manipulation
ipating banks, we should expect the coefficient of variation for the
of the Libor level in a downwards direction during Period 2 by
market-implied ratings across this group to be approximately zero,
comparing Libor to its predicted level, where that prediction is
because their market-implied ratings would be identical. What we
based on benchmark data. We find that the actual Libor is not sta-
find when we look into Fig. 6 is that Moody’s bond-implied ratings
tistically different from its predicted values in Periods 1, 2 or 3. In
for these banks present variability.24
other words, the empirical evidence is not consistent with the
Given this, we would not expect to observe the banks’ Libor
hypothesis that the Libor was materially manipulated downward
quotes to be completely identical on a daily basis such as in Per-
during Period 2, as the Wall Street Journal alleges.
iod 1, though it would be fair to expect these quotes to be close
The analyses that we conduct to assess Hypothesis H2 are de-
to each other since the variability in bond-implied ratings is not
signed to detect evidence of a conspiracy and manipulation by
very great. Additionally, the coefficient of variation of intraday
searching for quotes that cluster together in non-random patterns.
implied ratings is increasing from January through August
Based on our analyses, it appears that the individual quotes are
2007, meaning that the differences in risk across the participat-
very tightly clustered in Period 1 relative to the later periods. Re-
ing banks are widening, which is not reflected in an increase in
sults for Period 1 would be more consistent with a possible con-
spiracy to manipulate the Libor rate than in Period 2. Thus,
24
All available individual banks’ implied ratings are averaged out monthly; the although we are unable to reject the null Hypothesis H1, we reject
intra-month standard deviations are also computed. the null Hypothesis H2.
150 R.M. Abrantes-Metz et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 136–150

To assess Hypothesis H3, we explore whether banks with rela- Abrantes-Metz, R., Froeb, L., Geweke, J., Taylor, C., 2006. A variance
screen for collusion. International Journal of Industrial Organization 24, 467–
tively low (high) CDS spreads are also banks with relatively high
486.
(low) Libor quotes. Such a negative correlation between a bank’s Li- Abrantes-Metz, R., Villas-Boas, S., Judge, G., 2011. Tracking the Libor rate. Applied
bor quote and its CDS spread might suggest an inconsistency be- Economics Letters 18, 1–7.
tween the actual borrowing costs of banks and their perceived Ahn, S., Choi, W., 2009. The role of bank monitoring in corporate governance:
evidence from borrowers’ earnings management behavior. Journal of Banking
conditions of solvency and financial strength. Based on our analyses, and Finance 33, 425–434.
we find the existence of several noteworthy outliers, meaning banks Ashton, J.K., Hudson, R.S., 2008. Interest rate clustering in UK financial services
whose ordinal positions in Libor quotes may be unrelated to their markets. Journal of Banking and Finance 32, 1393–1403.
American Bar Association, 2010. Proof of Conspiracy under Antitrust Federal Laws.
ordinal positions in CDS spreads. Although the Libor quote and American Bar Association, Chicago, USA.
spread patterns cannot establish the presence of manipulation, we Bajari, P., Ye, L., 2003. Deciding between competition and collusion. The Review of
identify certain patterns in this study that do flag that possibility. Economics and Statistics 85, 971–989.
Benford, F., 1938. The law of anomalous numbers. Proceedings of the American
Interestingly, many of the markers that we review in this study Philosophical Society 78, 551–572.
are, on a contemporaneous basis, readily available for review by British Bankers’ Association, 2008. BBA Libor – Frequently asked
market analysts. CDS spreads begin to increase several months Questions, June 7. <http://www.bba.org.uk/bba/jsp/polopoly.jsp?d=225&a=
1416>.
prior to Period 2, and yet individual Libor quotes remain un- Cummings, C., 1999. London banks’ Euro-Libor rate fixing appears to be losing to
changed. Many of the banks’ quotes actually decrease while rival Euribor. Wall Street Journal (February 10), 1.
spreads on a wide variety of instruments increase. Finally, when Esposito, F., Ferrero, M., 2006. Variance Screens for Detecting Collusion: An
Application to Two Cartel Cases in Italy. Working Paper, Italian Competition
allegations of potential manipulation are published on April 17,
Authority.
2008, these patterns shift again. Ewerhart, C., Cassola, N., Ejerskov, S., Valla, N., 2007. Manipulation in money
Better proxies of short-term borrowing costs may help explain markets. International Journal of Central Banking 3, 113–148.
some of the statistical behavior that we document in this study. Fridson, M.S., Garman, M.C., 1998. Determinants of spreads on new high-yield
bonds. Financial Analysts Journal 54, 28–38.
For instance, commercial paper rates may prove to be more effec- Gorton, G., 1996. Reputation formation in early bank note markets. Journal of
tive Libor predictors than are CDS spreads. Stress measures (e.g., Political Economy 104, 346–397.
VaR or value-at-risk), net borrowing or lending positions, and other Gyntelberg, J., Wooldridge, P., 2008. Interbank rate fixings during the recent
turmoil. BIS Quarterly Review (March), 59–72.
observable characteristics may emerge to provide superior expla- Harrington, J., 2006. Behavioral screening and the detection of cartels. In: Claus-
nations for the observed Libor quotes and CDS spreads. In addition, Dieter, E., Atanasiu, I. (Eds.), European Competition Law Annual 2006:
event studies may identify other structural breaks in the sample Enforcement of Prohibition of Cartels. Hart Publishing, Oxford, UK.
Harrington, J., 2008. Detecting cartels. In: Buccirossi, P. (Ed.), Handbook in Antitrust
period. There may be plausible explanations for the presence of Economics. MIT Press, Cambridge, USA.
markers in competitive markets. Future researchers may choose Judge, G., Schechter, L., 2009. Detecting problems in survey data using Benford’s
to explore such explanations for these anomalies. law. Journal of Human Resources 44, 1–24.
Konrad, R., Sandoval, G., 2002. Orbitz Rivals Cry Foul, Claim Monopoly in Air Travel.
CNET News.com, April 11, 2002. <http://www.news.cnet.com/2009-1017-
Acknowledgements 879314.html>.
Livingston, M., Miller, R.E., 2000. Investment bank reputation and the underwriting
of nonconvertible debt. Financial Management 29, 21–34.
The authors gratefully acknowledge the suggestions of Mukesh
Mackenzie, M., 2008. Libor bankers brush off calls to reform way key rate is
Bajaj, John Cochrane, John Connor, Guy Erb, George Judge, Cathy calculated. Financial Times (May 31), 1.
Niden, Sofia Villas-Boas, and the assistance of Marissa Rich, Shelly Mackenzie, M., Tett, G., 2008. Libor remarks fail to put unease to rest. Financial
Yang, and especially Susan Press. We also thank participants at the Times (June 2), 16.
Mollenkamp, C., Norman, L., 2008. British bankers group steps up review of widely
Microeconomics Lunch Seminar in Economics at Leonard Stern used Libor. Wall Street Journal (April 17), C7.
School of Business, New York University, for suggestions. The views Mollenkamp, C., Whitehouse, M., 2008. Study casts doubt on key rate; WSJ analysis
expressed in this study belong solely to the authors and should not suggests banks may have reported flawed interest data for Libor. Wall Street
Journal (May 29), A1.
be attributed to the organizations with whom they are affiliated or Narayanan, R.P., Rangan, K.P., Rangan, N.K., 2007. The effect of private-debt
their clients. underwriting reputation on bank public-debt underwriting. Review of
Financial Studies 20, 597–618.
Newcomb, S., 1881. Note on the frequency of use of the different digits in natural
References numbers. American Journal of Mathematics 4, 39–40.
Nigrini, J., 2005. An assessment of the change in the incidence of earnings
Abrantes-Metz, R., 2010. The power of screens to trigger investigations. Securities management around the Enron–Andersen episode. Review of Accounting and
Litigation Report 10, 17–22. Finance 4, 92–110.
Abrantes-Metz, R., Addanki, S., 2007. Is the Market Being Fooled? An Error-Based Pirrong, C., 2004. Detecting manipulation in futures markets: the Ferruzi soybean
Screen for Manipulation. Working Paper. <http://www.papers.ssrn.com/sol3/ episode. American Law and Economics Review 6, 28–71.
cf_dev/AbsByAuth.cfm?per_id=339863>. Porter, R., Zona, J.D., 1997. Ohio School Milk Markets: An Analysis of Bidding. NBER
Abrantes-Metz, R., Bajari, P., 2010. Screens for conspiracies and their multiple Working Paper No. 6037.
applications. Competition Policy International 6, 129–144. Porter, R., Zona, J.D., 1999. Ohio school milk markets: an analysis of bidding. The
Abrantes-Metz, R., Froeb, L., 2008. Competition Authorities are Screening for RAND Journal of Economics 30, 263–288.
Conspiracies: What are They Likely to Find? The American Bar Association Russo, T., 1983–1993. Regulation of the Commodities Futures and Options Markets.
Section of Antitrust Law Economics Committee Newsletter, March 2008, pp. Shepard’s/McGraw-Hill, Colorado Springs, USA.
10–16.

You might also like