You are on page 1of 25

Effects of Increased Market Access on Exports of Developing Countries (Effets d'un

accroissement de l'accès des pays en développement aux marchés d'exportation) (Efectos que un
mayor acceso a los mercados tendría para las exportaciones de los países en desarrollo)
Author(s): Naheed Kirmani, Pierluigi Molajoni, Thomas Mayer and Luigi Molajoni
Source: Staff Papers (International Monetary Fund), Vol. 31, No. 4 (Dec., 1984), pp. 661-684
Published by: Palgrave Macmillan Journals on behalf of the International Monetary Fund
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3866990
Accessed: 08-03-2016 21:19 UTC

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/
info/about/policies/terms.jsp

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content
in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship.
For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

International Monetary Fund and Palgrave Macmillan Journals are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and
extend access to Staff Papers (International Monetary Fund).

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Effects of Increased Market Access

on Exports of Developing Countries

NAHEED KIRMANI, PIERLUIGI MOLAJONI,

and THOMAS MAYER*

AN IMPORTANT ASPECT of recent concern about the rising trend

toward protectionism in industrial countries relates to devel-

oping countries' access to the markets of these countries. Many

developing countries facing balance of payments and debt diffi-

culties are undertaking adjustment programs supported by fi-

nancial assistance from the Fund. These programs often include,

among other provisions, the pursuit of more outward-oriented

development strategies and the promotion of exports with a view

to establishing a viable balance of payments and external debt

position and sustainable growth in the medium term. The external

environment facing developing countries is important for the suc-

cess of their own adjustment efforts. Although this environment

is determined by a host of factors (including economic growth in

industrial countries, developments in world commodity prices,

and the evolution of exchange and interest rates abroad), the

stance of trade policies in partner countries can be a critical con-

straint on possible export expansion in developing countries.

Against this backdrop, the present paper analyzes the impact

on the exports of developing countries if market access for a

number of their products were to be enlarged in industrial coun-

tries. The analysis bears the character of an illustrative exercise;

* Ms. Kirmani, Assistant Chief in the Trade and Payments Division of the

Exchange and Trade Relations Department, is a graduate of the University of

Maryland.

Mr. Molajoni, economist in the Trade and Payments Division of the Exchange

and Trade Relations Department, is a graduate of the University of California,

Berkeley.

Mr. Mayer, economist in the Eastern European Division of the European

Department, was in the Exchange and Trade Relations Department when this

paper was prepared. He is a graduate of the University of Konstanz and of the

University of Kiel in the Federal Republic of Germany.

661

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
662 KIRMANI, MOLAJONI, and MAYER

because it is based on partial analysis with certain simplifying

assumptions, its results must be qualified accordingly. There is

considerable scope for fruitful experimentation with alternative

methodologies, with a view to developing more refined measure-

ments of the effects of trade liberalization, particularly on the

adjustment efforts of developing countries. Although this paper

focuses rather narrowly on the effects of liberalization on exports,

the positive, longer-term effects of an open trading environment

on structural adjustment and efficient resource allocation are also

important for economic growth.

On the basis of information on recent tariff and nontariff barri-

ers to trade in four Organization for Economic Cooperation and

Development (OECD) markets for seven selected sectors during

1979-81, estimates are made of the potential impact of eliminat-

ing these barriers on the exports of ten developing countries.1

These developing countries represent a geographically distributed

sample of Fund members that are currently undertaking adjust-

ment programs with Fund financial assistance or have done so in

the recent past. In terms of World Economic Outlook classifica-

tions (International Monetary Fund (1984)), the sample consists

of non-oil developing countries: four are among the major ex-

porters of manufactures within the group of net oil importing

developing countries, and three are classified as low-income coun-

tries. Except for Kenya, the other countries in the sample belong

to the group of "major borrowers," defined as the 25 developing

countries with the largest outstanding external debt in 1982. To-

gether, the ten sample countries accounted for just under one

third of exports of non-oil developing countries in 1979-81. The

seven selected sectors include both agricultural and manufactured

products of interest to developing countries. In these sectors trade

barriers, particularly nontariff restrictions, are relatively high or

have tended to grow since the mid-1970s in many industrial coun-

tries, and the threat of future protectionism persists.2 The selected

sectors accounted for 26 percent of the total exports of the sample

lThe importing countries are the United States, the European Community

(EC), Japan, and Canada. The seven sectors considered are meat, cereals, sugar,

textiles, clothing, footwear, and iron and steel. The developing countries consid-

ered are Argentina, Brazil, India, Kenya, the Republic of Korea, Mexico, Paki-

stan, the Philippines, Turkey, and Yugoslavia.

2For a survey of recent trade policies in the seven sectors, see Anjaria and

others (1982).

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
INCREASED MARKET ACCESS 663

countries, and 25 percent of their exports to the four markets on

average in 1979-81.3

Following a brief review of selected studies from the literature,

in Section I, the analytical framework and the data base of the

exercise undertaken in this paper are outlined in Sections II and

III, respectively. Section IV presents the results, and a sensitivity

analysis is reported in Section V. The final section provides com-

ments on the interpretation of the results.

I. Review of Selected Studies

Several studies have investigated the consequences for growth

and trade in developing countries of protectionist practices in

industrial countries. Using internationally linked, econometric

country models (Project LINK), Klein and Su (1979) studied the

worldwide effects of a (5, 10, and 20 percent) tariff increase for

manufactured imports of 13 OECD countries. They concluded

that such an increase in protectionism would reduce trade and

growth in both industrial and developing countries. Brown and

Whalley (1980) evaluated the effects of alternative tariff-cutting

formulas proposed by participants in the Tokyo Round of Multi-

lateral Trade Negotiations (1973-79) and of more substantial

trade liberalization, by means of a computable general equi-

librium model of the world economy. From their analysis, one can

conclude that tariff reductions alone would slightly increase world

welfare but would redistribute income, through changes in the

terms of trade, from developing to developed countries. Abolition

of all tariff and nontariff barriers in all countries, however, would

increase the welfare of both groups. These results were broadly

confirmed by studies by Deardorff and Stern (1981, 1983), who

used the same type of analysis to study the effects of the Tokyo

Round.

In a more recent study, Whalley (1984) has investigated the

effects of trade liberalization from the standpoint of an extended

version of the general equilibrium model of world trade used in

3Calculated from OECD and United Nations statistics. These ratios have

important implications for the overall results, as discussed in a later section, but

the main criterion in selecting the developing countries of the sample was

representation of the various geographical regions (three are in the Western

Hemisphere, three in Asia, two in Europe, one in the Middle East, and one in

Africa), rather than the structure of the countries' exports.

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
664
KIRMANI, MOLAJONI, and MAYER

the earlier study by Brown and Whalley (1980). He arrives at the

result that complete trade liberalization, although increasing

world welfare, would redistribute welfare from the "South"

(developing and newly industrialized countries) to the "North"

(OECD countries and members of the Organization of Petroleum

Exporting Countries). The major reason for this result is a deteri-

oration of the terms of trade of the South after trade liberal-

ization. This decline is explained by higher average rates of

protection in the South compared with those of the North, and by

the smaller size of trade involving Southern regions compared

with trade among the countries of the North.4

Baldwin and Murray (1977), and Sapir and Baldwin (1983)

chose partial analysis to evaluate the effects of tariff reductions on

developing countries in light of their existing tariff advantages

under the Generalized System of Preferences of the United Na-

tions Conference on Trade and Development. Cline and others

(1978) used a similar approach to study the effects of the Tokyo

Round and of further trade liberalization (including a reduction of

nontariff trade barriers in agricultural trade) on trade in industrial

and developing countries, as well as on welfare and employment

in the industrial countries. These studies lead one to conclude that

gains for developing countries from tariff reductions on a most-

favored-nation (MFN) basis would be significant and would far

outweigh potential losses from an erosion of their tariff prefer-

ences. Valdes and Zietz (1980) estimated the effects of trade

liberalization in 17 OECD countries on selected agricultural ex-

ports from 56 developing countries and found that a 50 percent

reduction in trade barriers would have yielded an annual incre-

ment of 11 percent in developing countries' exports of agricultural

products during 1975-77.

A synopsis of the above studies is provided in Table 1. Most of

the studies have attributed positive overall welfare and trade ef-

fects to trade liberalization. Further, they have emphasized the

importance of lowering nontariff barriers to trade for developing

countries' growth and trade performance.5

4The studies cited above assume constant returns to scale and competitive

market structures and, hence, disregard the effects of trade liberalization on

economic efficiency. Furthermore, it can be argued that the foreign demand

elasticities for the exports of developing countries are unrealistically low. Ac-

cordingly, the results of these studies have to be qualified.

5 The studies mentioned above use static frameworks for their analyses. Easton

and Grubel (1982) have pointed out that, in a dynamic framework, the costs of

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
INCREASED MARKET ACCESS 665

In relation to the studies reviewed, the scope of the present

exercise is more limited. The country coverage is narrower, and

the analysis investigates the effects of trade liberalization on ex-

ports, making no attempt to measure welfare effects. The focus is

on developing countries that are undertaking adjustment efforts

to overcome balance of payments and debt difficulties and for

which expansion of exports is crucial to resolving these difficul-

ties. The exercise takes into account key sectors in both the man-

ufacturing and agricultural areas, and assumes complete trade

liberalization in these sectors.

II. Analytical Framework

The exercise is based on partial analysis. It utilizes a simple

framework describing demand and supply for the seven sectors by

standard two-country market models. In these, percentage

changes in import demand, export prices, and export earnings

may be written as functions of the price elasticities of import

demand and export supply, as well as of the percentage change in

the one-plus-ad-valorem tariff equivalent of trade (tariff plus non-

tariff) barriers.

Export supply and import demand for item i in a two-country

model with exporting country k and importing country j can be

described by the following equations:

M, = M,(P,) (1)

P,, = tijP, (2)

Xik = Xik(PTW) (3)

Mj = Xik (4)

Rik = Pi Xik, (5)

protection are likely to grow at the rate at which international trade expands

because protection impedes exploitation of the opportunity for gains from trade,

such as economies of scale and intra-industry trade, which grow at that rate.

They concluded that the welfare costs of protection, as measured in the eco-

nomic literature, have tended to be substantially underestimated.

6Ideally, global demand and supply models for the selected sectors would be

needed that would take info account all the producing and consuming countries,

as well as interlinkages between the sectors. There are, however, many concep-

tual and empirical problems associated with the multicountry, multisectoral

approach. Hence, for the purposes of this illustrative exercise, a simpler frame-

work was adopted in which the available parameters could be used.

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
TABLE 1. SELECTED MEASUREMENTS OF THE COSTS OF PROTECTION

Results Obtained for:

Industrial Developing Developing

Trade Policy countries' countries' countries'

Study Studied Method Used welfare welfare exports

Baldwin and 50 nercent cut in Partial analysis: - +IS$369 million

_ r_ ----, _---

Murray all tariffs in simple trade-flow

(1977) United States, model

European Com-

munity (EC),

and Japan

Cline and 60 percent cut in Partial analysis; +US$3.4 billion

others all tariffs; simi- simple trade-flow (1974 prices)

(1978) lar cuts in non- model

tariff barriers in

agriculture in

industrial

countries

Valdes and 50 percent cut in Partial analysis; +US$473 mill

Zietz trade barriers sectoral trade-

(1980) affecting 99 ag- flow model

ricultural com-

modities in 17

industrial

countries

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Klein and Su 20 percent in- Econometric
-US$22 billion -U

(1979) crease in trade model of world in 1978 and

barriers affect- economy 1979 (accu-

ing manufac-
mulated)

turers in 13 Or-

ganization for

Economic Co-

operation and

Development

(OECD)

countries

Brown and Complete trade General equilib- +US$11 billion +US$9 billion

Whalley liberalization in rium model of (1973 prices)

(1980) all countries world economy

Deardorff Effects of Tokyo General equilib- +US$4.8 billion + US$0.3 bill

and Stern Round of Multi- rium model of


(1976 prices)

(1983) lateral Trade


world economy

Negotiations

Whalley Complete trade General equilib- +US$64.3 bil- -US$31.4 bill

(1984) liberalization in rium model of lion (1977

all countries world economy prices)

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
668 KIRMANI, MOLAJONI, and MAYER

where M is import demand (in volume); X is export supply (in

volume); pD is the importing country's domestic price; pw is the

export price before duty; t is the one-plus-ad-valorem tariff rate

(the tariff equivalent of tariff and nontariff barriers); R is the

exporter's revenue (importer's expenditure at preduty prices);

and the subscripts i, j, and k denote the ith item and the jth

(importing) and the kth (exporting) country.

Differentiating equations (1) through (5) totally and solving for

the percentage changes of imports, export (preduty) prices, and

exporter's revenues yields the following equations:

dMjIMi = [n,/l(l - nijleij )] * dtijltij (6)

dPWIPw = -[nj,l(nij - eik)] ' dt,j/tij (7)

dRikIRik = n,[(l + eik)l(eik - nj )] . dtjltii, (8)

where n is the price elasticity of import demand, and e is the price

elasticity of export supply.

In this model trade flows and exporter's revenues (or importer's

expenditures in preduty prices) are a function of the percentage

change of the one-plus-ad-valorem tariff rate and of the elastici-

ties of supply and demand. For exporter's revenues, this relation

can be illustrated by tabulating the change in this revenue

(dRiklRik) for a given cut in the tariff level (or in the tariff equiv-

alent of trade barriers) and for a range of values of eik and nij

(Table 2).

TABLE 2. CHANGE IN EXPORTER'S REVENUES

Price Elasticity Price Elasticity of Export Supply

of Import Demand 0 V2 1 2 oo

-Y2 -dtit -3/4 dtlt -13 dtit -3/5s dtit -1/2 dt/t

-1 -dtlt -dtit - dtit -dt/t -dtit

-2 -dtlt -s5 dt/t -43dtIt -3/2dt/t -2dt/t

Note: Change in exporter's revenues is given by equation (8) of the text:

dRiklRik = nii[(1 + eik)/(eik - nii )] dti/ti,

where

d = differential operator

R = exporter's revenue

i, j, k = the ith item and jth (importing) and kth (exporting) countries

t = 1 + T, with T = ad-valorem tariff (tariff equivalent of trade barriers)

and dtlt = dT/(1 + T)

nii = price elasticity of import demand

eik = price elasticity of export supply.

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
INCREASED MARKET ACCESS 669

With unitary elastic demand, exporter's revenues are not af-

fected by the export supply response. Hence, the second row of

the matrix in Table 2 shows the same percentage change of ex-

porter's revenues for all export supply elasticities considered. If

import demand is elastic, however, price reductions are over-

compensated by increases in sales, so that exporter's revenues

grow more than proportionately. Hence, the higher the supply

elasticity, the larger is the change in exporter's revenues. Yet,

with inelastic import demand, price reductions owing to tariff cuts

are not compensated by respective quantity increases. Conse-

quently, the higher the export supply elasticity, the smaller is the

increase in exporter's revenues. If import demand elasticities lie in

the range between -?i and -2, one can expect exporter's reve-

nues to grow between Vi and 2 times the percentage cut in one-

plus-ad-valorem tariff rates.

Figure 1 illustrates the partial analysis cases in a two-country

model in accord with different assumptions about the price elas-

ticities of supply of the imported commodity. The panels are

drawn from the exporter's viewpoint and represent the importing

country, or market: the demand schedule for imports of the given

commodity is DD. P' is the preduty price, and pD is the postduty

(domestic) price.

In panel A, with an infinitely elastic supply of the imported

commodity (e = o), the importing economy faces a supply curve

S, which is the horizontal (price) line at the PW level. Before trade

liberalization, domestic equilibrium is indicated by E. Total do-

mestic expenditure is OQd x OPD. Exporters, however, only re-

ceive OQd x OPW, the difference accruing to the government of the

importing country as tariff revenue (or, possibly, revenue split

between the government and private importers of the importing

country if nontariff barriers are present). After trade liberaliza-

tion, domestic equilibrium is at E', and domestic expenditure on

the imported item is OQd' x OPW, all of which now goes to the

exporter.7 The extent of the gain to the exporter depends on the

elasticity of demand for imports.

The case of a zero elasticity of supply (e = 0) of the imported

commodity is illustrated in panel B. The importing country faces

7 In the case of certain nontariff barriers (for example, voluntary export re-

straints), however, it is possible that part of the difference between OQd x OPD

and OQd' x OPw accrued before liberalization to the exporter in the form of a

rent. If this is so, gains to the exporter as a result of trade liberalization are

somewhat less than assumed in the above model.

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
KIRMANI, MOLAJONI, and MAYER
670

FIGURE 1. EXPORTER'S REVENUES UNDER VARIOUS ASSUMPTIONS

OF EXPORT-SUPPLY ELASTICITY

A. e = oo

pD

pw
S

B. e =O

D
D

pL

pw

0 Qd

C. O<e<oo

0
Qd Qd'

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
INCREASED MARKET ACCESS 671

a supply curve S, which is now the vertical line at the Qd level

because supply is fixed. The point of equilibrium before trade

liberalization is at E and does not change after liberalization. The

exporter now is able to extract from the importing market the full

domestic price pD. The elasticity of import demand plays no role

in determining the gain to the exporter from liberalization.

In panel C, the case of a finite but positive elasticity of supply

(0 < e < oo) is illustrated. The importing country faces an upward-

sloping supply curve SS. In this case, trade liberalization will

determine a gain to the exporter that will be a function of both

import-demand and export-supply elasticities.

The exercise does not explicitly take account of the different

degrees of substitution or differentiation between the imported

products and similar domestically produced commodities. How-

ever, in the application of the two-market model to rather broad

product groups in a multicountry framework, it is implicitly as-

sumed that domestic and imported products, and imported prod-

ucts from different sources, are imperfect substitutes.8

III. Assumptions and Data Base

Import and export data for countries and products were taken

from OECD (various issues) and United Nations (various issues)

statistics, and averages for the period 1979-81 were used. For

estimates of the three parameters (the price elasticities of import

demand and of export supply and the height of trade barriers), the

general approach was to rely on existing studies to the extent

feasible and to use judgmental estimates and simplifying assump-

tions in other cases.

For price elasticities of import demand, estimates from Cline

and others (1978) were used (Table 3). These estimates represent

the middle values of a range of low and high values that are based

on an extensive literature survey, and they correspond closely to

8 The higher the degree of substitutability, other things being equal, the greater

would be both the shift in demand from the domestically produced to the im-

ported commodity and the reallocation among imported commodities from dif-

ferent sources induced by trade liberalization. This relation, however, may de-

pend on the time frame considered. In the short run, less competitive industries

may respond by reducing profit margins and by expanding production in an

attempt to maintain market shares. Over the medium term, however, resources

would tend to shift out of these industries, or producers would introduce greater

product differentiation.

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
672 KIRMANI, MOLAJONI, and MAYER

TABLE 3. SECTORAL PRICE ELASTICITIES OF IMPORT DEMAND

IN FOUR OECD MARKETS

United

Sector States EC1 Japan Canada

Meat and meat preparations

(SITC 01) -0.53 -1.09 -1.13 -0.84

Cereals and cereal preparations

(SITC 04)2 -0.82 -1.06 -0.56 -0.81

Sugar and sugar preparations

(SITC 06)2 -0.82 -1.06 -0.56 -0.81

Textiles, yarn, fabrics, etc.

(SITC 65) -2.43 -2.61 -1.56 -2.09

Iron and steel

(SITC 67) -1.99 -3.25 -2.36 -2.07

Apparel and clothing

(SITC 84) -2.43 -2.61 -1.56 -2.09

Footwear

(SITC 85) -1.23 -3.17 -1.42 -2.07

Note: In this and subsequent tables, SITC refers to Standard International

Trade Classification.

Source: Cline and others (1978).

'Estimates for the EC are weighted averages of individual country estimates

corrected for trade diversion effects toward imports from non-EC countries

following trade liberalization (see Cline and others (1978, p. 57) for a detailed

explanation).

2For the United States, EC, and Japan, the average of estimates for BTN

(Brussels Tariff Nomenclature) 02 (vegetable products, fats, oils), 03 (food,

beverages), and 04 (tobacco).

those published by other researchers (for example, Stern, Francis,

and Schumacher (1976)). Because information on the value of

export supply elasticities for the countries and commodities under

investigation is incomplete or unreliable, for the present exercise

it was assumed that these elasticities were uniform, both among

the countries under investigation and between these countries and

the rest of the world. This assumption implies that, after trade

liberalization, exporting countries would hold their original mar-

ket share in international trade. The two limiting values (zero and

infinity) of the elasticities were used to establish lower and upper

bounds for exporters' revenue gains from trade liberalization.

Intermediate values for the elasticities were used in performing a

sensitivity analysis (Section V).

Estimating tariff equivalents of nontariff barriers presents many

difficulties, particularly when these barriers are applied discrimi-

natorily, as in the textile and clothing sectors. Existing quantita-

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
INCREASED MARKET ACCESS 673

tive estimates of the height of trade barriers vary widely. Reasons

for the large differences include, among others, differences in

concepts of "world market" reference prices, in product defini-

tions, and in time periods for estimation. In the framework of the

current exercise, selection of representative estimates from the

available information was based on judgment informed by qual-

itative information on trade measures and policies. For agricul-

tural products, the general approach was to rely on published

coefficients of nominal protection.9 The starting point for esti-

mates for manufactures was the comprehensive work on trade

barriers existing in 1973 done by Yeats (1979). Because Yeats's

estimates may not always reflect more recent developments, nor

always match the level of commodity disaggregation chosen in this

exercise, they were adjusted to provide as uniform and current a

basis for this exercise as possible.

For meat, estimates of trade barriers in 1977-79 in the four

OECD markets for beef were used, based on United Nations

Food and Agriculture Organization (1980). More recently, the

restrictiveness of trade measures appears to have increased in this

sector, but no allowance was made for this factor. For cereals, for

the European Community (EC) the exercise used the average

coefficient of nominal protection (the percentage difference be-

tween the EC threshold price and the c.i.f. Rotterdam price) for

wheat, barley, and maize in 1979-80 as estimated by Koester

(1982). For Japan, the average of coefficients of nominal protec-

tion for rice, wheat, barley, and soybeans in 1979 was taken from

Anjaria and others (1982). For the United States, the estimate was

based on Yeats (1979). In the absence of sufficiently specific infor-

mation for Canada, and against the background of similar agricul-

tural trade policies followed in the past, protection in Canada in

the cereal and sugar sectors was assumed to be the same as in the

United States (although, admittedly, this assumption could lead

to overestimation).

In the sugar sector, for the United States the exercise used the

average 1979-80 ratio of New York postduty prices and Carib-

bean world market prices, adjusted for a transport cost compo-

nent of 6 percent, based on statistics from the U.S. Department

9 See Food and Agriculture Organization (1980), Koester (1982), Anjaria and

others (1982), U.S. Department of Agriculture (1981), Commonwealth Secre-

tariat (1982). For a discussion of the limitations of this approach, see Anjaria and

others (1982, p. 36).

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
674 KIRMANI, MOLAJONI, and MAYER

of Agriculture (1981). (In 1982 the United States imposed import

quotas and raised tariffs in this sector.) For the EC and Japan,

coefficients of nominal protection for 1979-80 (percentage differ-

ences between domestic and c.i.f. prices) were taken, for the EC,

from the study by the Commonwealth Secretariat (1982) and, for

Japan, from the study by Anjaria and others (1982).

For the commodities of the manufacturing sector, post-

Kennedy-Round levels were used for tariffs, and estimation of the

tariff equivalent of nontariff barriers was based on various studies

(Yeats (1979), Morici and Megna (1983), Jenkins (1980)). For

textiles and clothing, for the EC and the United States estimates

by Yeats (1979)10 were adjusted upward on the basis of a study by

Morici and Megna (1983).1 For Japan, in the absence of evidence

of significant nontariff barriers, only post-Kennedy-Round tariffs

were used for both textiles and clothing. Estimates for the Cana-

dian textile and clothing industries were obtained from Jenkins

(1980).

Because no estimates of nontariff trade barriers specifically for

steel were available, these were first approximated from estimates

(Yeats (1979)) of average nontariff barriers for manufacturing in

1973 in the EC and the United States. These figures were then

updated, using estimates cited by Morici and Megna (1983) that

refer to the effect of nontariff barriers in the U.S. steel industry

in the period 1976-77. (Nontariff restrictions in the steel sector

have increased significantly in the United States and in the EC

since 1980.) For Japan and Canada, the steel industry is fairly

competitive internationally, and only tariffs were included in esti-

mating the height of trade barriers in these two countries.

Finally, in the footwear sector, in the absence of evidence of

significant nontariff barriers in the United States and Japan, only

10Following Yeats (1979), estimates for France were used as indicators for the

EC in the textile, clothing, and steel industries.

t Morici and Megna (1983) give an assessment of U.S. trade policies imple-

mented in the last ten years and provide estimates of the protection afforded by

nontariff restrictions in several industries. For textiles and apparel, the authors

calculated the reduction of imports induced by the 1974 Multifiber Agreement

(MFA), and estimated the tariff equivalent of the MFA at 8.8 percent (p. 23).

From this finding, Morici and Megna concluded that the protection provided to

the U.S. clothing industry by nontariff barriers was around 8.8 percent in 1976

(p. 100). Yeats, however, estimated the tariff equivalent of nontariff barriers for

the U.S. clothing industry at 40 percent in 1973. The estimate by Morici and

Megna seems to reflect (and is used here as) additional protection by the MFA

for the U.S. clothing industry, rather than the actual height of nontariff trade

barriers in 1976.

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
INCREASED MARKET ACCESS
675

TABLE 4. SECTORAL TARIFF EQUIVALENTS OF TARIFF AND NONTARIFF

BARRIERS IN FOUR OECD MARKETS

(In percent)

United

Sector States EC Japan Canada

Meat (SITC 01) 46 118 328 52

Cereals (SITC 04) 20 81 175 20

Sugar (SITC 06) 27 31 44 27

Textiles (SITC 65) 68 59 13 39

Iron and steel (SITC 67) 35 43 8 8

Clothing (SITC 84) 79 59 18 39

Footwear (SITC 85) 9 27 16 30

Source: Own estimates based on sources listed in Section III.

tariffs were used. For the EC, qualitative information led to the

assumption that nontariff barriers in the EC footwear industry are

one third of what they are in the clothing and textile sectors. For

Canada, global quotas on footwear are applicable, but, in the

absence of available quantitative estimates, nontariff barriers in

the footwear industry were assumed to be about three fourths of

what they are in textiles and clothing.

The estimates of tariff equivalents of trade barriers are given in

Table 4. They should be taken only as a rough indication, of the

order of magnitude and relative size, of protection around 1980.

IV. Results

In this section the effects of hypothetical trade liberalization are

reported for both importers and exporters of the product groups

studied.

IMPORTING COUNTRIES

Table 5 gives the results for the percentage change of imports

induced by a complete, nondiscriminatory removal of trade barri-

ers in the selected sectors of the selected OECD countries under

the assumption of an infinite elasticity of export supply.12 The

figures reflect increases in physical trade because export prices are

12The increases in imports derive from all sources and not only from the

sample exporting countres. Of course, under the assumption of zero elasticity

of export supply, import volumes would not increase.

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
676 KIRMANI, MOLAJONI, and MAYER

TABLE 5. INCREASES OF SECTORAL IMPORTS IN FOUR OECD MARKETS

AFTER COMPLETE TRADE LIBERALIZATION

(In percent)

United

Sector States EC Japan Canada Total

Meat (SITC 01) 16.7 59.0 86.6 28.7 49.5

Cereals (SITC 04) 13.7 47.4 35.6 13.5 39.2

Sugar (SITC 06) 17.4 25.0 17.1 17.2 19.3

Textiles (SITC 65) 98.4 96.8 17.9 58.6 81.8

Iron and steel (SITC 67) 51.6 97.7 17.5 15.3 62.4

Clothing (SITC 84) 107.2 96.8 23.8 58.6 92.6

Footwear (SITC 85) 10.1 67.4 19.6 47.8 30.4

Source: Own calculations based on sources listed in Section III.

expected to remain unchanged under the assumption of infinite

export-supply elasticity. Altogether, the results indicate that a

complete removal of barriers to trade in the selected OECD mar-

kets would increase imports of agricultural products in the lib-

eralized sectors by about 20 to 50 percent and would increase

imports of manufacturing products in the liberalized sectors by

about 30 to 90 percent. As expected, given the generally higher

import-demand elasticities for manufactured products than for

agricultural products, trade liberalization for manufactured prod-

ucts would induce more imports than would liberalization for

agricultural products. For Japan, however, some differences are

noteworthy. On the one hand, the extraordinarily high import

elasticity for meat, together with the relatively high protection of

the domestic meat industry, give significantly larger estimates of

import increases for Japan than for other importing countries. On

the other hand, because of the assumed relatively low import

elasticity for clothing and the rather moderate estimate of protec-

tion of the Japanese clothing industry, Japan's imports of clothing

increase less than in the other countries.

Although this exercise was not specifically formulated to assess

the impact of trade liberalization on import penetration ratios,

some broadly indicative computations were made. The results

(Table 6) show that a complete removal of trade barriers would

raise the overall import penetration ratio in the importing coun-

tries by 2 percentage points at most. There would, however, be

large changes in the EC, U.S., and Canadian textile, clothing, and

footwear industries, ranging between 10 and 14 percentage points.

Given the assumptions of no change in consumption and of crowd-

ing out of domestic producers by importers, these figures repre-

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
INCREASED MARKET ACCESS
677

TABLE 6. SECTORAL IMPORT PENETRATION RATIOS BEFORE AND AFTER

COMPLETE TRADE LIBERALIZATION IN FOUR OECD MARKETS

(In percent)

United States EC' Japan Canada

Sector IPo IP, IPo IPx IPo IP IPo IPx

Food

(ISIC 31) 6.3 6.6 20.4 21.7 6.5 9.4 10.8 11.6

Textiles, clothing,

and footwear

(ISIC 32) 12.1 22.3 41.6 55.9 9.8 11.6 23.8 36.9

Base metals

(ISIC 37) 12.2 15.9 34.2 38.9 6.9 7.1 31.3 34.0

Manufacturing

(ISIC 3) 9.2 10.2 30.7 32.5 5.7 6.2 33.1 34.3

Note: ISIC refers to the International Standard Industrial Classification. IPo

is the average import penetration ratio in 1979-80; values are taken from World

Bank data compiled by the Bank's Economic Analysis and Projections De-

partment. IPx is the postliberalization import penetration ratio calculated on the

basis of the exercise undertaken in this paper. The computations assumed that

total consumption would not change after trade liberalization and that increased

imports would replace domestic production. Thus, the figures represent indica-

tive upper limits to the immediate effects of trade liberalization on import

penetration. Because the aggregation level is not the same, there is no exact

correspondence between the changes in imports presented in Table 5 and the

changes in import penetration ratios presented here.

Includes intra-EC trade. IPo values refer to Belgium and Luxembourg,

France, Federal Republic of Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, and the United

Kingdom only.

sent indicative upper limits to increases in import penetration

ratios.

EXPORTING COUNTRIES

Table 7 gives the effects of hypothetical trade liberalization in

major OECD markets on the exports of the sample of developing

countries. With infinite export supply, the most striking increases

occur in the clothing sector, but export growth in the meat, textile,

steel, and footwear sectors also seems substantial. Export growth

rates for sugar and cereals are smaller. When combined, increased

exports of the seven sectors would raise total exports of the ten

developing countries by about 9 percent (US$8.0 billion in aver-

age 1979-81 prices).13 Table 8 gives the results separately for

13 In calculation of the increase in total exports, both the exports of the non-

liberalized sectors and the exports of the liberalized sectors to the nonliberalizing

markets were held constant.

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
678 KIRMANI, MOLAJONI, and MAYER

TABLE 7. CHANGE IN SECTORAL EXPORTS OF SAMPLE COUNTRIES

AFTER COMPLETE TRADE LIBERALIZATION

(In percent)

Meat Cereals Sugar Textiles

(SITC 01) (SITC 04) (SITC 06) (SITC 65)

Country e = 0 e=oo e=0 e = oo e = 0 e = oo e = 0 e = oo

Argentina 26.0 26.4 8.1 6.8 10.3 8.6 31.2 78.9

Brazil 22.0 22.0 13.1 10.9 9.5 8.2 19.8 49.9

India 12.3 11.7 5.6 5.9 5.6 5.9 24.9 65.3

Kenya 27.3 29.7 25.6 14.4 7.9 8.4 8.0 20.1

Rep. of

Korea 11.6 13.1 40.3 24.2 0.2 0.2 8.1 17.9

Mexico 70.5 77.2 9.7 7.9 22.6 21.6 22.6 55.4

Pakistan - - 0.5 0.5 23.7 25.0 14.5 36.3

Philippines - - 0.5 0.4 13.8 9.1 21.3 51.8

Turkey 4.7 5.1 1.6 1.7 7.3 7.7 24.2 63.0

Yugoslavia 17.2 16.0 2.1 2.2 0.5 0.5 6.5 16.9

Weighted

average 23.4 23.5 6.1 5.2 10.0 8.2 15.0 37.0

Note: e is the price elasticity of export supply.

Source: Own calculations based on sources listed in Section III.

agricultural and manufactured exports. Thus, the increases in

exports of the three agricultural sectors would raise total agricul-

tural exports by some 4 percent; similarly, total manufactured

exports would rise by about 16 percent.

With zero elasticity of export supply, the overall export increase

for the sample of developing countries amounts to over 4 percent.

Because volumes traded now remain constant, the increase in

export earnings is attributable to the rise of export prices to the

level of domestic prices in the OECD markets. In the case of

agricultural sectors, where the import elasticities in most OECD

countries are less than unity, the increase in export earnings tends

to be larger than would be the case if export supply were infinitely

price elastic; the opposite holds true for nonagricultural products.

The increases in exports resulting from the hypothetical trade

liberalization are unequally distributed among the sample coun-

tries because the composition and geographical distribution of the

exports of the sample countries vary. The increases range from 0.6

percent for Kenya to nearly 18 percent for the Republic of Korea.

Several factors influence this distribution: (1) the countries face

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
679
INCREASED MARKET ACCESS

Iron and

Steel Clothing Footwear

(SITC 67) (SITC 84) (SITC 85) Total

e=0 e=oo e =0 e =oo e=0 e=oo e=O e =oo

3.9 9.1 8.7 21.8 10.8 24.3 6.9 7.2

12.2 29.5 19.5 49.6 10.4 21.2 2.7 4.8

3.4 7.6 38.0 95.7 11.6 32.4 6.1 15.1

~- - 29.0 75.6 0.4 1.2 0.5 0.6

9.0 19.6 29.0 69.8 11.0 22.9 7.6 17.6

15.8 31.6 43.7 106.2 10.1 17.2 1.3 2.9

13.7 44.4 23.4 59.2 16.3 51.8 6.5 15.9

6.1 16.4 57.0 140.6 10.3 20.4 4.7 9.2

19.7 61.5 20.3 52.8 2.5 7.9 4.5 11.7

8.6 24.2 24.5 63.7 3.3 9.1 2.4 5.5

9.6 22.4 30.4 74.6 9.0 19.3 4.3 9.0

different average rates of protection in the seven sectors according

to the product and geographic composition of their exports; (2)

the countries face different average elasticities of export demand

according to their trade patterns; (3) most important, the seven

sectors' shares in total exports to the world and to the four OECD

markets differ widely among the ten developing countries of the

sample. Table 9 shows these features for the sample countries.

V. Sensitivity Analysis

As noted in Section II, three important sets of parameters

determine the results of this exercise: the export-supply elastici-

ties, the import-demand elasticities, and the tariff equivalents of

tariff and nontariff barriers in the seven sectors of the four OECD

markets. Given that previous studies, taken together, do not al-

ways provide sufficient assurance of the accuracy of their esti-

mates, several tests were performed to determine the sensitivity of

the results of the illustrative exercise to variations in these three

sets of parameters.

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
KIRMANI, MOLAJONI, and MAYER
680

TABLE 8. CHANGE IN AGRICULTURAL AND MANUFACTURED EXPORTS

OF SAMPLE COUNTRIES AFTER COMPLETE TRADE LIBERALIZATION

(In percent; e = oo)

Agricultural Manufactured Total

Country Exports Exports Exports

Argentina 11.8 4.4 7.2

Brazil 2.7 9.8 4.8

India 1.0 25.2 15.1

Kenya 0.8 1.1 0.6

Rep. of Korea 0.5 19.6 17.6

Mexico 1.4 12.8 2.9

Pakistan 1.6 29.6 15.9

Philippines 3.9 35.6 9.2

Turkey 0.3 37.4 11.7

Yugoslavia 4.1 6.5 5.5

Weighted

average 3.7 16.3 9.0

Note: e is the price elasticity of export supply.

Source: Own calculations based on sources listed in Section III.

First, elasticities of export supply were varied over a broad

range. In addition to the two limiting cases of zero and infinity,

intermediate values assumed were 2 and 2 for all sectors, and one

case used combined values of V2 for agricultural and 2 for manu-

factured sectors (Table 10). For countries facing elasticities of

export demand near 1, export increases from trade liberalization

were nearly the same for all assumed elasticities of export supply.

For countries with elasticities of export demand of 2 and above

(India, Korea, Mexico, Pakistan, Turkey, and Yugoslavia), export

increases more than doubled when elasticities of export supply

tended to infinity. Export increases were smaller, however, for

countries with elasticities of export demand-lower than 2 (Brazil

and the Philippines). There was no significant change when the

elasticity of export supply of all sectors was assumed to be 2 and

those of the agricultural and manufactured sectors were assumed

to be 2 and 2, respectively.

Second, elasticities of import demand were varied: they were

lowered by 25 percent in one test and raised by 25 percent in

another. Under the assumption of infinite export supply, the cal-

culations indicated a lower limit of 6.8 percent and an upper limit

of 11.3 percent for increases in total exports of the sample coun-

tries. Finally, the estimated rates of protection were varied up and

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
INCREASED MARKET ACCESS 681

TABLE 9. STRUCTURE AND DEMAND ELASTICITY OF, AND PROTECTION

AGAINST, SECTORAL EXPORTS OF SAMPLE COUNTRIES

Exports of

Selected Average

Sectors Protection

Exports of in Total Average Against Exports

Selected Exports Elasticity of Selected

Sectors to Four of Export Sectors1

in Total OECD Demand' (As implied by

Exports Markets (As implied Table 4;

Country (In percent) (In percent) by Table 3) in percent)

Argentina 49.1 15.1 -1.1 97

Brazil 18.8 9.9 -1.7 46

India 25.6 16.9 -2.4 59

Kenya 4.3 1.4 -1.2 73

Rep. of Korea 44.8 27.6 -2.1 43

Mexico 4.6 3.9 -2.0 64

Pakistan 60.7 19.2 -2.3 54

Philippines 18.8 14.5 -1.8 52

Turkey 24.6 12.3 -2.6 59

Yugoslavia 21.7 7.1 -2.3 55

Source: Own calculations based on Tables 3 and 4 and on OECD and United

Nations statistics.

'Weighted averages according to product and geographic trade patterns.

down by 25 percent. With export supply again assumed to be

infinite, lower and upper limits of 7.5 percent and 10.3 percent

could be established for increases in total exports of the sample

countries.l4 On the whole, the sensitivity analysis indicated that

the increases in total exports of the sample countries would be in

the order of 5 to 10 percent after trade liberalization.

VI. Interpretation of Results

The illustrative exercise presented above is subject to several

limitations. First, the exercise is based on partial analysis and thus

can indicate only the static, first-round effects of trade liberaliza-

tion on developing countries. Because important second-round

4 Given the occasionally doubtful information on tariff equivalents of non-

tariff barriers in Canada, another calculation was performed on the assumption

of no change in Canadian rates of protection. The total increases in exports

attributable to trade liberalization in the remaining three markets was 8.8 per-

cent for the sample of developing countries under the assumption of infinite

export supply.

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
682 KIRMANI, MOLAJONI, and MAYER

TABLE 10. SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS OF EXPORT SUPPLY

(Percentage change in total exports)

Elasticity of Export Supply (e)

Country 0 V2 2 o0

Argentina 6.9 6.9 6.9 7.2

Brazil 2.7 3.0 3.6 4.8

India 6.1 7.6 10.1 15.1

Kenya 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.6

Rep. of Korea 7.6 9.3 12.1 17.6

Mexico 1.3 1.6 2.0 2.9

Pakistan 6.5 8.1 10.6 15.9

Philippines 4.7 5.4 6.6 9.2

Turkey 4.5 5.7 7.6 11.7

Yugoslavia 2.4 2.9 3.7 5.5

Weighted

average 4.3 5.1 6.4 9.0

Source: Own calculations based on sources listed in Section III.

effects, such as income and terms of trade effects, are not consid-

ered, it is not possible to infer the trade positions of the develop-

ing countries in the sample once all changes have worked their way

through the economies of both industrial and developing coun-

tries. Moreover, the exercise does not take account of the dynamic

effects of trade liberalization, such as exploitation of economies of

scale or intra-industrial trade. Such effects could help a country

achieve higher export growth rates, over longer periods, than it

would have achieved in the absence of trade liberalization.

Second, the exercise is based on certain simplifying assump-

tions. In particular, the assumption of uniform elasticities of ex-

port supply in all exporting countries may overstate the sample

countries' ability to meet increased export demand and to hold

their former market shares. In addition to trade-creation effects,

there could also be trade diversion against the exports from the

sample developing countries as more efficient producers undercut

existing suppliers in the expanded market. Further, those devel-

oping countries which have benefited from the Generalized Sys-

tem of Preferences or other preferential arrangements may suffer

some losses after trade liberalization. At the same time, trade

diversion toward exports of the sample countries may occur when

nontariff trade barriers that especially discriminate against these

countries are removed.

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
INCREASED MARKET ACCESS
683

Third, further research is needed to improve estimates of the

parameters used in the exercise. In particular, the estimates of the

tariff equivalents of trade barriers in the OECD markets for the

seven sectors reflect only rough orders of magnitude, partly based

on qualitative information, that can be the subject of debate. In

practice, nontariff barriers to trade take many forms and are

frequently applied on a bilateral rather than multilateral basis;

thus, liberalization of bilateral restrictions will have more differ-

ential effects than those considered here.

Notwithstanding these limitations, the exercise illustrates that

the benefits of trade liberalization for developing countries can be

significant, although the benefits would differ among countries

and might be spread over a number of years. Under the illustrative

exercise, a 5 to 10 percent real growth of exports is attributed to

trade liberalization. By way of comparison, in the course of the

1970s the volume of exports from the sample countries grew on

average at an annual rate of 8 percent. Although the exercise was

not meant to measure effects of trade liberalization on the balance

of payments of the sample countries, it indicates that an improve-

ment in market access within the industrial countries could make

a significant contribution to the export prospects and adjustment

efforts of developing countries.

REFERENCES

Anjaria, Shailendra J., Zubair Iqbal, Naheed Kirmani, and Lorenzo L. Perez,

Developments in International Trade Policy, Occasional Paper No. 16

(Washington: International Monetary Fund, November 1982).

Baldwin, R.E., and T. Murray, "MFN Tariff Reductions and Developing Coun-

try Trade Benefits Under the GSP," Economic Journal (London), Vol. 87

(March 1977), pp. 30-46.

Brown, Fred, and John Whalley, "General Equilibrium Evaluations of Tariff-

Cutting Proposals in the Tokyo Round and Comparisons with More Exten-

sive Liberalisation of World Trade," Economic Journal (London), Vol. 90

(December 1980), pp. 838-66.

Cline, William R., Noboru Kawanabe, T.O.M. Kronsjo, and Thomas Williams,

Trade Negotiations in the Tokyo Round: A Quantitative Assessment (Wash-

ington: The Brookings Institution, 1978).

Commonwealth Secretariat, Protectionism, Threat to International Order: The

Impact on Developing Countries (London, 1982).

Deardorff, Alan V., and Robert M. Stern, "A Disaggregated Model of World

Production and Trade: An Estimate of the Impact of the Tokyo Round,"

Journal of Policy Modeling (New York), Vol. 3 (No. 2, 1981), pp. 127-52.

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
KIRMANI, MOLAJONI, and MAYER
684

, "Economic Effects of the Tokyo Round," Southern Economic Journal

(Chapel Hill, North Carolina), Vol. 49 (January 1983), pp. 605-24.

Easton, Stephen T., and Herbert G. Grubel, "The Costs and Benefits of Protec-

tion in a Growing World," Kyklos (Basle, Switzerland), Vol. 36 (Fasc. 2,

1982), pp. 213-30.

Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Intergovernmental

Group on Meat, Protectionism in the Livestock Sector, Report of the Inter-

governmental Group on Meat to the Committee on Commodity Problems,

Ninth Session, Rome, December 8-12, 1980 (Rome, 1980).

International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook: A Survey by the Staff

of the International Monetary Fund, Occasional Paper No. 27 (Washington,

April 1984).

Jenkins, G.P., The Costs and Consequences of the New Protectionism, Develop-

ment Discussion Paper No. 99 (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Institute for

International Development, Harvard University, July 1980).

Klein, Lawrence R., and Vincent Su, "Protectionism: An Analysis from Project

LINK," Journal of Policy Modeling (New York), Vol. 1 (No. 1, 1979),

pp. 5-35.

Koester, Ulrich, Policy Options for the Grain Economy of the European Com-

munity: Implications for Developing Countries, Research Report No. 35

(Washington: International Food Policy Research Institute, 1982).

Morici, Peter, and Laura L. Megna, U.S. Economic Policies Affecting Industrial

Trade: A Quantitative Assessment, NPA Report No. 200 (Washington: Na-

tional Planning Association, 1983).

Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Trade by Commod-

ities (Paris, various issues).

Sapir, A., and R.E. Baldwin, "India and the Tokyo Round," World Develop-

ment, Vol. 11 (July 1983), pp. 565-74.

Stern, Robert M., Jonathan Francis, and Bruce Schumacher, Price Elasticities in

International Trade: A Compilation and Annotated Bibliography of Recent

Research (London: Macmillan, for the Trade Policy Research Centre,

1976).

United Nations, Commodity Trade Statistics (New York, various issues).

U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, Sugar and Sweet-

ener Outlook and Situation (Washington, 1981).

Valdes, Alberto, and Joachim Zietz, Agricultural Protection in OECD Coun-

tries: Its Cost to Less-Developed Countries, Research Report No. 21 (Wash-

ington: International Food Policy Research Institute, 1980).

Whalley, John, "The North-South Debate and the Terms of Trade: An Applied

General Equilibrium Approach," The Review of Economics and Statistics

(Cambridge, Massachusetts), Vol. 66 (May 1984), pp. 224-34.

Yeats, Alexander J., Trade Barriers Facing Developing Countries (New York:

St. Martin's, 1979).

This content downloaded from 128.210.126.199 on Tue, 08 Mar 2016 21:19:24 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like