You are on page 1of 12

American Economic Association

Trade in Producer Services and in Other Specialized Intermediate Inputs


Author(s): James R. Markusen
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 79, No. 1 (Mar., 1989), pp. 85-95
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/1804775
Accessed: 27-11-2015 02:48 UTC

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/
info/about/policies/terms.jsp

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content
in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship.
For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The American Economic
Review.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 128.252.67.66 on Fri, 27 Nov 2015 02:48:41 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Trade in Producer Services and in Other
Specialized Intermediate Inputs

By JAMES R. MARKUSEN*

Many producer services are knowledge-intensive,requiring a high initial invest-


ment in learning, after which the knowledgecan be provided to additional users at
low cost. A monopolistic-competitiontype model is developed to analyze these
producer services. Trade only in final goods is an imperfectand inferiorsubstitute
for trade in the specialized inputs, due to the complementaritybetween domestic
and foreign specialized inputs, or alternatively the gains from an increased
division of labor.

It has long been observed that over half of tant selling the same blueprints to different
international trade occurs in intermediate firms).
goods. Much of this is in foodstuffs, raw The theory of international trade today
materials, and so forth, but much of the consists of a relatively small literature on
trade in intermediates is also in produced intermediate inputs (for example, Kalyan
intermediate manufacturers. A rapidly grow- Sanyal and Ronald Jones, 1982) and a litera-
ing category of trade in intermediates is pro- ture on scale economies and imperfect com-
ducer services, which include such areas as petition in final goods production (many ref-
management consulting, engineering consult- erences are found in Elhanan Helpman and
ing, banking, insurance, marketing, and fi- Paul Krugman, 1985). The two are combined
nancial services. in Wilfred Ethier (1982), Paul Romer (1987),
Many of the intermediate manufactures and Markusen (1988). These authors have a
and producer services that enter into inter- simple model in which intermediate inputs,
national trade are probably characterized produced with increasing retums to scale are
by significant degrees of scale economies assembled to produce final output.
and/or product differentiation. Factor-in- The purpose of this paper is to develop a
tensity data suggest, for example, that inter- model of trade in differentiated intermediate
mediate manufactured goods are on average inputs along the lines proposed by Ethier. I
significantly more capital-intensive than final will be particularly interested in normative
manufactured goods (James Markusen and issues not dealt with by Ethier (1979, 1982)
James Melvin, 1984b). Many producer ser- and Romer (1987). In the model, each of two
vices are both differentiated and knowledge- countries has a competitive sector (Y) and a
intensive. Knowledge intensity in turn sector (X) which produces a composite good
suggests strong scale economies in that from intermediate inputs or services (S).
knowledge must be acquired at an initial The latter are produced with increasing re-
learning cost, after which the knowledge- turns and are complementary in production.
based services can be provided at a very low The results demonstrate that allowing
marginal cost (as in an engineering consul- trade in specialized inputs is superior to al-
lowing trade in final goods only in two dis-
tinct senses. First, free-input trade guaran-
*Department of Economics, University of Western tees that both countries will be made better
Ontario, London, Canada N6A 5C2. Funded under a off relative to autarky while, due to the dis-
grant from The Institute for Research on Public Policy
and the Department of Regional and Industrial Expan- tortion between prices and marginal costs,
sion, Ottawa. The thorough and constructive comments goods trade only does not guarantee that
of an anonymous referee are gratefully acknowledged. free trade will be Pareto-improving. Free-
85

This content downloaded from 128.252.67.66 on Fri, 27 Nov 2015 02:48:41 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
86 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 1989

input trade guarantees that both countries services or specializedinputs. The produc-
experience an expansion of production in tion functionsin (2) have constantreturnsto
the distorted sector which has been shown to the S for a fixed n.
be a sufficient condition for gains from trade Each S is producedby a single firmand,
when price exceeds marginal cost (Markusen for simplicity, we assume that the produc-
and Melvin, 1981, 1984a). Free trade in final tion of S. requiresonly labor. S producers
goods only may result in the contraction of and X producersare disjoint,and the Sj are
this sector for the smaller or otherwise producedwith increasingreturnsundertech-
" technically disadvantaged" country and nology and behavioral assumptions dis-
thus the sufficient condition for gains fails to cussed below. Given constantreturnsin (2),
hold. Second, free-input trade is superior to we can then aggregatethe individual firm
free trade in goods from the point of view of outputs to arrive at an industryproduction
the world as a whole, although not necessar- function identical to (2) with the i subscript
ily from the point of view of both countries. deleted. In order to keep the problem
This result follows from the complementar- tractable,we assume that the S production
ity of domestic and foreign specialized in- functions are identical and the S are sym-
puts in final goods production, or alterna- metric but imperfectsubstitutesin produc-
tively from the increased division of labor ing X. Assume in particularthat the X in-
supported by trade. With free-input trade, dustry productionfunctionis given by
each country essentially confers a positive
technological externality on its trading part- (3) X- [s#]1 0 < p < 1.
ner.
These results have a good deal of policy Productionof S. uses only labor, and re-
relevance given the current discussions on quires a fixed cost plus a constantmarginal
liberalizing trade in producer services. These cost. For simplicity,the marginalcost of S
services generally face higher trade barriers is assumed to be one in terms of labor.
than do commodities since the former in- Letting Y be numeraire,the cost of produc-
trude on immigration and foreign invest- ing Sj in terms of Y is then
ment policies which are in turn more restric-
tive than goods-trade policies. (4) wSj + wF,

I. ProducerServices,SpecializedInputs,and where w is the wage rate in termsof Y and


the Division of Labor F is the fixed cost (in units of labor).
Let p denote the priceof X in termsof Y.
Consider a two-sector general-equilibrium For a given p and w, the socially optimal
model with a competitive sector Y. Good Y allocation in the X industry is found by
is produced with labor (L) and sector- solving the followingprogrammingproblem,
specific capital (K) by a competitive indus- equatingprice and marginalcosts.
try with constant returns to scale.
(S) MaxvX= p [7.Sr] -2E(wSi +wF )
(1) Y=G(Ly,K); GI>O, G,,<O.
with respect to Si, n.
To keep things very simple, suppose that
production in the X sector consists of cost- We can take advantageof the fact that the
lessly assembling (as in Ethier, 1982) the symmetryof the S ensurethat each Si that is
produced inputs S1,..., Sn. The identical produced will be produced in the same
production functions for the competitive quantity (implying that ESi = nSi, where n
firms in the X industry are given by is endogenous).' The first-orderconditions

(2) Xi = XI(Sl,..* Sin),


IAs is common practice in the monopolistic-competi-
where the Sj will be referred to as producer tion literature, the integer constraint on n is ignored.

This content downloaded from 128.252.67.66 on Fri, 27 Nov 2015 02:48:41 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 79 NO. I MARKUSEN: TRADE IN PRODUCER SER VICES 87

relating to S and n are then given as follows. The first-order condition for Si is

(6) = (P/i)[n(Sj)"] (12) as, = q/32S-I w = O.


as aIS-W_w

=pn -w =; a=--(I - PVP The second-order condition holds since q


and w are viewed as exogenous. Free entry
of S producers results in zero profits, so
(7) an =(p/3)[n(SJ)"] S1
(13) qf3S/-wS,-wF= O.
-(wS, + wF) = 0
Substituting for q from (10), (12) and (13)
are respectively
= (p/li)naS,-wS,-wF =O
(14) pI3na-w=O;
Multiply (6) through by Si. Then subtract (6)
from (7). (p//3)n 3S, - wS, - wF= 0.

(8) ((1-, )/,B)pnaSj =wF. Multiply the first equation through by Si.
Combining the two equations in (14), we get
But from (6) we see that n= (w/p), so that the values of Si and n at the monopolistic-
the solution values are competition equilibrium.

A
(9) Si 1i F; n =( wlp ) /l (15) Si F;

Now consider the monopolistic-competi- n= (W/p3)#/('-").


tion equilibrium. The price faced by an indi-
vidual Si producer is the marginal product Compare the monopolistic-competition
of Si in producing X. Denoting this price as values in (15) to the socially optimal values
ri (the same for all S producers due to in (9). Si is the same in both cases and
symmetry), this is given from (6) as constant. The X industry expands via in-
creases in n and the market equilibrium
r= ( p3) produces the optimal amount of any Si that
(10) n (Sj) ] aS- is produced. The former property implies
increasing returns to scale in X since X=
- qI3Sf'; n"'IS (/B < 1). The latter property implies
that the market equilibrium will be on the
q pl-(P )n (S,) . economy's efficient production frontier.2
Comparing the values of n from (9) and
Suppose that there are many S producers, (15), we see, however, that the two equilibria
such that we can assume relatively "competi- cannot be the same. For a given allocation of
tive" conjectures. Assume that S producers
view p as exogenous and also view X as
exogenous. Then the individual S producers
2This result relies on the assumption that X is pro-
view q in (10) as fixed. An S producer's duced from the Si only. If other factors are used,
programming problem is given by inefficient combinations of the latter with the Si will
generally result, leading to production interior to the
(11) MaxT*= (qSJ-1))Si-wSi-wF efficient production frontier. The algebra of the gains-
from-trade analysis is largely unaffected by this assump-
tion, but one result is dependent upon it. This is dis-
w.r.t. Si. cussed in Section III below.

This content downloaded from 128.252.67.66 on Fri, 27 Nov 2015 02:48:41 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
88 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC RE VIEW MARCH 1989

labor to the X and Y sectors, w and n are y

the same in the optimal and market situa-


tions. (15) and (9) therefore imply that p
must be higher in the market equilibrium by
T pI3=MRT
the factor P3.This result is the familiar dis-
tortion whereby the price ratio (p) will ex-
ceed the marginal rate of transformation
(MRT) at the market equilibrium. The MRT
is simply given by the ratio of the marginal
product of labor in Y to its marginal prod-
uct (MP) in Si.

MP _G1 MRT
(16) MRT - My p
MPX n a

where MPx is the "social" marginal product


of labor in X, given in (6). But the equilib- 0 T X
rium price ratio involves the private marginal
product of labor (MPx*), given in (11) and FIGURE 1
(14),

P= MPy GI The production frontier will be locally con-


(17) -
cave if the MRT is increasing in Lx; that is,
when (19) is positive. w' is positive and
Combining the results in (16) and (17), we increasing in X (G is strictly concave) but
have MPX'is also positive (we are referring to how
the MP of labor changes as we change n,
(18) p > pB = MRT. since S is constant in general equilibrium).
(19) can also be written as
The results in (18) combined with the ear-
lier result that the market equilibrium will be d(MRT) w [nw' nMP' 1
on the production possibility frontier is
shown in Figure 1. TT' is the production dLx nMPx L w MPx ]
possibility frontier, which may take on a
w
number of shapes. =M [nw*-?a],
Differentiating MRT = G,/MPx = w/MP, nMPx
and denoting derivatives with primes ('), we
have since MP, = ana-l, MPx= na, and where w*
w'/w denotes the proportional change in
d (MRT) MPxw'- wMPx w. The production frontier will be locally
( ) dLx MPx, concave if the concavity of G outweighs
scale economies so that (nw* - a) > 0.
- MPx] If Y is Cobb-Douglas, for example, Y=
=~ w w L7K1'- and w*=-G,,/G,=(1-y)/L,.
MPx MPx
(20) will be negative (TT' convex) in the
neighborhood of X = 0 (n = 0) but will
quickly become positive (TT' concave) as X
=MPx ('pPMPX) increases (n (1 - -y)/LY increases) if -y and a
are small (recall a = 1/ -1 approaches zero
w
since p, = MP as /B approaches 1). The production frontier
MPx will have the shape shown in Figure 1. For

This content downloaded from 128.252.67.66 on Fri, 27 Nov 2015 02:48:41 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 79 NO. I MARKUSEN: TRADE IN PRODUCER SER VICES 89

the remainder of the paper, we assume that profits would be negative from doing so. The
a is sufficiently small, G is sufficiently con- sufficient condition for gains from trade thus
cave, and demand for X is sufficiently high becomes
such that equilibrium occurs on the con-
cave portion of the production frontier in (25) (PgXa-WgLxa)
Figure 1.
= (Pg-wg(Lxa/Xa))Xa <?
II. GainsfromTrade
iff (Lxa/Xa) ? (Lxg/xg).
Consider first a situation in which there is
free trade in goods only. Let subscripts g This result is shown by first noting that
and a denote quantities evaluated at the free (pg - wg(L /Xg))=0 (zero profits). Since
goods-trade and autarky equilibria, respec- X uses ony labor and since X = n7/S,
tively. Cy and C, will denote consumption of (LX/X) falls with increases in X and (25)
goods Y and X, respectively. By the usual holds if and only if Xg Xa. The latter is a
revealed preference criterion, a country gains sufficient condition for gains from trade.
from trade if The "product expansion condition" Xg >
Xa for gains from trade is by now familiar to
(21) Cyg+ PgCxg2 Cya+ PgCxa. most international trade economists. Intu-
itively, with the price of X (private marginal
In autarky, we have market clearing, while in cost) greater than true social marginal cost,
free trade we have balance-of-payments there is a " Harberger trapezoid" associated
equilibrium. with changes in X output, (p - MC) X,
which is positive if A X> 0. In our case,
(22) Cya= Ya, Cxa=Xa; MC = w/MPx = p,, so (p-MC) = p(1-
i) >0.
Cyg+ pgCxg= Yg+ pgXg. It is also reasonably well known that this
condition may not hold in practice. Figure 2
Substituting (22) into (21), we have shows a situation where the small home
country (superscript h) is at a cost disadvan-
(23) yg + PgXg > Ya + PgXa. tage relative to the large foreign country
(superscript f). Relative to autarky equilib-
Now subtract the value of the factor endow- ria at Ah and A1, country h could lose at the
ment at free-trade prices from both sides of free-trade equilibria Ch, Cf (consumption)
(23), and let k denote the return to Y-sector Qh, Qf (production) due to the distortion
capital, between p and the MRT as shown in Figure
2 and as demonstrated by Markusen and
(24) (Yg-wgLyg -kgK) Melvin (1981, 1984a).
Now we consider free trade in specialized
+ ( pgXg - WLxg) inputs versus autarky, assuming countries
trade S and Y but cannot trade X. Note
with respect to (10)-(14) that free trade in S
> ( Ya- Lya- kgK) equalizes the ri across countries. The fact
that the same number of inputs n = nh + nf
+ (PgXa -
wgLxa). is available in each country at the same
prices implies that they are used in the iden-
The left-hand side of (24) is zero since both tical relative amounts in each country. Con-
industries make zero profits in equilibrium. stant returns to the Si in X then imply that
The first term on the right-hand side of (24) the marginal products of additional inputs
is non-positive: the autarky factor propor- are equal across countries and, from (10)
tion (K/Lya) is not the most efficient way to and (14), that the product price ratio p'=
produce Ya at free-trade factor prices, hence r/na must be equal. Factor prices are also

This content downloaded from 128.252.67.66 on Fri, 27 Nov 2015 02:48:41 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
90 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 1989

nS
cf

Th B

nh
m

nh

u~~~h
p~~~~
f
a~~~~~~~~~~~
A

T T X 0 ff h f
? na nfm ns nf
FIGURE 2
FIGURE3

equalized (equal r imply equal w imply equal


k). The ability to trade X would be redun- zero since profits in both industries are zero.
dant. A discussion of the robustness of this We are left with the condition for gains from
and several other results is postponed until trade as
Section III.
The free-input trade (subscript s) is re- (29) O> (Yh-w,Lha- kKh)
vealed preferred to the autarky bundle if
+ (p- Ws(LLa/Xh )Xhh.
(26) Cys + PsCxs - Cyha xpsC,a.
The first term in (29) is negative as before.
The balance-of-payment and market-clear- Since inputs are freely traded at equal prices,
ing conditions are given by the average cost (Lix/Xi) depends only on
the number of inputs available. We can
Ch + p Ch =yh + rnhS;
demonstrate using Figure 3 and results de-
(27) rived below that nS n5 + n > ni (i = h, f)
-

under certain restrictions.Hence Lha/Xh >


chya =Yha-' Ch xha' ps/ws and both countries are assured of
xa
gains from free trade relative to autarky.
The proof involves the construction of re-
where rs is the free-trade price of a repre- action curves in (nh, nf) space. One simpli-
sentative service and S is the constant /BF/ fying assumption, not at all crucial to the
(1 -,B). Substituting (27) into (26), we have results, will be made in order to simplify the
exposition and to permit a clear, intuitive
interpretation of the results. I will assume
(28, {h?+ r nhS > yh + psXah
the absence of income effects such that the
price of X depends on the world output of
Subtracting the value of the factor endow- X: p = p(X). This can be generated by a
ment at free input-trade prices from both utility function of the form U(X, Y) = U(X)
sides of (28), the left-hand side will equal +Y, U,,<O.

This content downloaded from 128.252.67.66 on Fri, 27 Nov 2015 02:48:41 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 79 NO. I MARKUSEN: TRADE IN PRODUCER SERVICES 91

Equilibrium in the domestic X industry is = -(p/X)(dX/dp). Finally note that


given by p (X)MPX = rh from the first-ordercondition
in (30). These results and definitions allow us
(30) p(X)MPx-r(nh) = 0, to express (33) as
X = Xh + Xf, dnh Ih
ax (36) ]
d[n
(31) p'(X)(MPx)-(dnf + dnh)
dn
1/(f) - (1/f - 1)
8MP
+ p(X) dn x(dnf + dnh)r'dnh = 0. 1/( B7e)(1/,-1)+ nrh

Note that nh and nf enter X symmetrically where


so that superscripts on n in (dX/dn) and
rh* rh'/rh > 0.
(dMPx/dn) can be dropped. The slope of
country h's reaction curve is then given by
The reaction curve may be either posi-
tively or negatively sloped. Of interest is the
(32) [-] case in which the slope is globally greater
than minus one. Restrictions which guaran-
-p'(X)(MP,)(dXX/dn)-p(X)(dMP /dn) tee this outcome are, from (36)
-p'(X)(MPx)(dX/dn)-p(X)(dMPx/dn)+ r'

Factor out p(X)(MPx)/n from both the (37) -1< (dnh/dnf) h<O
numerator and denominator of (32) and can-
iff r <17(1-3),
cel. This leaves

(33) dnf] (38) ? < (dnh/dnf)h

if 1/(1-/ )?1< and nrh* >(1/fB1).


p'(X)XndX nMP'
p(X) Xdn MP, With the restriction (37), both the numerator
p'(X)X ndX nrh'
and denominator of (36) are positive, with
nMPx'
the denominator larger in absolute value.
p(X) Xdn MPr p(X)MP+ With restriction (38), the numerator of (36)
give us is negative while the denominator is positive.
X-n17/S and MPx=n '1-1)
The reaction curve for country f is simply
d (MPx) -2 the inverse of (36). Thus
()-1/-1 ( n'l/#
an
(39) (dnh/dnf)f < -1
nd(MPx)
MPx d n 1 - iff ic<1/(1-3)

dX 1 (40) 0 < ( dnh/dnf )f _<o


(35) n-ni/3-S
if 1/(1- ,B) <?7 and nrf *> (1/ -1).
n dX
- =1/fl.
X dn We can summarize the results of (37) and
(38) as follows: sufficient conditions for the
Denote (minus) the elasticity of demand as slope of h's reaction function to be globally

This content downloaded from 128.252.67.66 on Fri, 27 Nov 2015 02:48:41 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
92 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 1989

greater than minus one are that either r1< than -1 or greater than 0 under restrictions
17(1-fl) or nri* > (1/-1). The same re- (37) or (38).
strictions imply that the slope of f 's reac- These slope restrictions along with n h> n h
tion function is less than minus one or posi- and nf > n f imply that the equilibrium
tive. The first restriction will be satisfied if in Figure 3 must involve nS n + nf >
demand is sufficiently inelastic and scale max(n nf ). More inputs are available with
economies are sufficiently weak (1Bclose to free-input trade than in either country in
1), where we use the term "sufficiently" in autarky. Since the average cost of labor in X
the tautological sense of values that satisfy declines with n, and since ps and ws are the
(37). The second restriction (38) was the free-trade values in both countries, the in-
condition that the production frontier be equality in (29) must hold. Both countries
locally concave in the case of goods trade are assured of gains from trade.3
only, as can be seen by referring back to Now consider the comparison of goods
equation (20) (w* = r* since w = fir). Note trade only with free trade in specialized in-
that, unlike the case of no input trade of puts. Input trade is revealed preferred to
Figures 1 and 2, n = (n h + n f ) never ap- goods trade if
proaches zero along the reaction curve, and
thus nrh > (1/fl -1) may hold globally over (41) CYh+ pCxh Cyhg+ psChg
the reaction curve.
Two sets of reaction curves satisfying the By adding and subtracting the same terms,
restrictions in (37) to (40) are illustrated in the goods-trade balance-of-payments con-
Figure 3. n h and nf are the autarky values straint can be written as
of n in countries h and f, respectively. n h
(n f ) is the n that country h(f ) would pro- (42) + (pscxhg- psc)
Ch + pgCxhg
duce if country f(h) were constrained from
producing any n in the free-trade situation. hxg)-
= yh + pgXh + (px h-px
Positive demand for the other country dic-
tates that nh > nh (nf > nf).
The reaction curves, which give the opti- Substituting this into (41) and replacing the
mal n' for one country given the exogenous left-hand side of (41) with the input-trade
ni for the other country, may be both down- balance-of-payments constraint in (27), (41)
ward sloping or both upward sloping (or becomes
combinations therefore, since r1is not a con-
stant). The reaction curves nhnh for the (43) Ys + rsnhS>yh/+p Xh
home country and nf nf for the foreign
country illustrate the former case. The re- -
strictions (37) and (39) imply that nhnh has +(pg ps)( X-Cxg).
a slope between 0 and -1 in this case and
n nf has a slope less than - 1. Subject to Subtract the value of the factor endow-
the economies being of similar size, the reac- ment at input-trade prices from both sides of
tion curves cross and produce a stable equi- (43) and the left-hand side will be zero as
librium at A in Figure 3. before. The condition for superiority of in-
The reaction curves could both slope up-
ward as illustrated by n hn h' and nf nf' in
Figure 3. An equilibrium occurs at a point 3If the restrictions in (37)-(40) fail to hold, the slope
like B, where one or even both countries of h's reaction function could be less than -1 and that
could be specialized (nhnh' becomes flat, or for f between zero and -1. The reaction functions
nf nf' becomes vertical). Combinations of could cross at a value of nh + nf < max(n , n f )) so that
these cases may occur, but the important one country could be worse off. But such an equilibrium
is presumably unstable under some adjustment mecha-
point for our purposes is that the slope of nism, implying an equilibrium at n or nf in which
h's reaction curve must be greater than mi- case the gains-from-trade result goes through. (37)-(40)
nus one, and the slope of f 's must be less are thus not necessary conditions for bilateral gains.

This content downloaded from 128.252.67.66 on Fri, 27 Nov 2015 02:48:41 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 79 NO. 1 MARKUSEN: TRADE IN PRODUCER SER VICES 93

put trade becomes y

(44) 0(YhwLhg _ k Kh)


T
( -W h(Lh/Xh)) Xh $

(pg - ) ( Xgh- C .

The first term is negative as before: using


goods-trade factor proportions is not the
most efficient way to produce Y at input-
trade factor prices and hence profits in Y are
negative. P9~~~P
The third term in (44) is a terms-of-trade
effect. It states, for example, that if h ex-
ported X at the goods-trade equilibrium (Xg
> Cxg) and the price of X is higher at the o T9 TS X
input-trade equilibrium, then the term is
negative and produces the desired direction FIGURE4
of inequality in (44). But note that a favor-
able terms-of-trade effect for one country
must be exactly matched by a negative
terms-of-trade effect in the other country. TTg as in the case for each country individu-
Since the larger (as in Figure 2) and/or ally.
more labor-abundant country is likely the We can also aggregate the free-input trade
exporter of X in goods-trade equilibrium, production frontiers to arrive at the world
and since the price of X in input trade is production frontier TTs by virtue of the fact
likely less than in goods trade (discussed that commodity and factor prices are equal-
below), the larger/labor-abundant country ized in input trade. Indeed TTsin Figure 4 is
likely loses from the effect. Bilateral im- the world Pareto-optimum frontier. To see
provement at the input-trade equilibrium is that TT, lies everywhere outside of TTg ex-
not guaranteed unless the volume of trade at cept at T, simply note that, holding ng and
the goods-trade equilibrium is small. nf (yh and Yf ) constant, each country could
The second-term in (44) is once again our exchange a portion (1- 8) of each of its ni's
product expansion condition. Again, since for a portion 8 of each of the other coun-
h
the average product of labor depends only tries n 's, whereSh = nhg(n+ nf) Inh/,g.
on the number of n available, this term will Trade balances under such a scheme. The
be negative for both countries if ns h +n
- output of X in h becomes
> max(ngh, n f.)
The argument 'that n > (n , ngf) is made (45) Xh =
(ng)17"(8s)
with respect to Figure 4. Since both coun-
tries face the same producer prices (and = =
(nhIS) I(asS) >> Xh
MRT's) in goods-trade equilibrium, we can
aggregate their production frontiers together
to arrive at the aggregate frontier TTg in (nh S
Figure 4. Assume also that countries have
identical, homothetic utility functions so that and similarly for country f. In general fur-
we can aggregate their tastes. Given these ther adjustments are optimal.
results, the goods-trade equilibrium at the World income increases with service/in-
common price ratio pg will occur at a point put trade over goods-only trade due to com-
like G in Figure 4, where pgI3= MRT along modity and factor price equalization and the

This content downloaded from 128.252.67.66 on Fri, 27 Nov 2015 02:48:41 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
94 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW MARCH 1989

increasing returns to n. Because consumers the world as a whole does, however, rely on
are identical and face the same prices, the free trade in inputs equalizing commodity
aggregate preference map in Figure 4 is the prices and hence making trade in X-sector
same as with goods trade. Third, the distor- goods redundant.
tion ratio p,8 = MRT holds along TTs as in This will generally not be the case if the X
the case of TTg and the individual country sector uses other scarce factors of produc-
production frontiers. Finally, the slope of tion that are unevenly endowed between the
TTs must be less at S than the slope of the countries. Non-constant returns in final
point on TTg directly below, G. The marginal goods production would also result in non-
product of labor in Y must be less at the equalization of commodity prices. In these
former (Y, > Yg) and the marginal product of cases, free trade in inputs only and free trade
labor in X greater (X, = Xg, but with less in goods only each offers something that the
labor in X at Xs, it follows that nS > ng and others do not. Free trade in inputs offers
hence MPXs> MPXg).The equilibrium along higher technical productivity in final goods
TTs must then be at a point like S' where production than free trade in goods. But if
Xs 2 Xg if X is non-inferior in consumption. free trade in inputs leaves commodity prices
This last result implies that the total num- unequalized, there exist unexploited gains
ber of inputs produced in the input-trade from the exchange of scarce factor services
equilibrium must exceed the total produced embodied in final goods. Goods trade only
in either country in the goods-trade equilib- captures the gains from exchange but not the
rium. This follows from a simple argument technical productivity gains. In the general
by contraction. If, for example, ng > n =n5 case, it is impossible to say which of the two
+ n f, then Xh> Xs (even ignoring output second-best trade regimes dominates.
from f ) whict contradicts the result that Restrictions implying commodity price
Xg = Xf < Xs Thus n_ (n equalization from input trade only are used,
The proof that nS ? (ng, ngf) is in turn all but not needed to prove the superiority of
that we need to prove that the second term free-input trade to autarky. p( X) in the
in (44) is non-positive. Except for the terms- derivation of the reaction curves could refer
of-trade effect (the third term in (44)), both only to domestic price and demand. A spe-
countries are assured of gains at the input- cific factor in X that is unequal between
trade equilibrium relative to the goods-trade countries could be added to prevent the
equilibrium and one must prefer the former. equalization of r from implying the equal-
Note also if we add the inequality in (44) to ization of p. The reaction curve analysis and
the corresponding one for f (identical homo- the expansion of n over autarky levels will
thetic utility makes this meaningful), the continue to go through. The revealed-prefer-
terms-of-trade effects cancel. The world con- ence analysis culminating in (29) will need
sumption bundle at the service-trade equilib- modification for the additional factor but the
rium is preferred to that in goods-trade equi- same result on X-sector expansion and gains
librium. from trade will emerge. Unlike the case of
goods trade only, free trade in the special-
III. Robustness of the Results ized inputs in these circumstances cannot
result in disadvantaging the distorted sector
A few comments on the robustness of the such that there is an inefficient contraction
results may be in order before closing. None of output. The assumption that there are
of the results relies on the fact that the constant returns in X for fixed n is similarly
number of specialized inputs exceeds the unimportant in this respect.
number of goods in the relevant sector. The
X sector could be composed of many goods IV. Summary
with the total number exceeding the number
of inputs n. The result that free-input trade The purpose of this paper is to develop
is preferred to free trade in goods only for and analyze a model of trade in which trade

This content downloaded from 128.252.67.66 on Fri, 27 Nov 2015 02:48:41 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL. 79 NO. I MARKUSEN: TRADE IN PRODUCER SER VICES 95

occurs in differentiated or specialized inter- REFERENCES


mediate products produced with increasing
returns. I suggest that increasing returns Dixit, AvinashandStiglitz,Joseph,"Monopolis-
characterize both capital-intensive interme- tic Competition and Optimum Product
diate manufactures and knowledge-intensive Diversity," American Economic Review,
producer services. Many of these inputs are June 1977, 67, 297-308.
differentiated and complementary to domes- Ethier, Wilfred, "Internationally Decreasing
tic inputs. Costs and World Trade," Journal of Inter-
As in the case of Ethier (1982), the model national Economics, February 1979, 9,
adapts the Avinash Dixit-Joseph Stiglitz 1-24.
(1977) characterization of differentiated ___ "National and International Re-
goods to differentiated inputs. These inputs turns to Scale in the Modem Theory of
are produced with increasing returns and so International Trade," American Economic
differentiation is limited by the extent of the Review, June 1982, 72, 389-405.
market, and increases with international Helpman,Elhanan,and Krugman,Paul, Increas-
trade in specialized inputs or services. ing Returns, Imperfect Markets, and Inter-
Permitting trade only in final goods is an national Trade,Cambridge:MIT Press,1985.
imperfect and inferior substitute for per- Markusen, James R., " Production, Trade
mitting trade in specialized services in two and Migration with Differentiated, Skilled
well-defined senses. (a) Free trade in Workers," Canadian Journal of Economics,
inputs/services is Pareto-superior to autarky August 1988, 21, 492-506.
while free trade in goods only may not be. _ and Melvin,James R., "Trade,Factor
(b) Free trade in inputs/services is superior Prices, and the Gains from Trade with
to free trade in goods from the point of view Increasing Returns to Scale," Canadian
of the world as a whole, although not neces- Journal of Economics, August 1981, 14,
sarily the point of view of each individual 450-69.
country. . (1984a) "The Gains from Trade
These results have special relevance to Theorem with Increasing Returns to
current discussions about the liberalization Scale," in Henryk Kierzkowski, ed.,
of trade in services, particularly trade in Monopolistic Competitionand International
producer services. I suggest that these ser- Trade, London: Oxford University Press,
vices are very likely to have the complemen- 1984, 10-33.
tarity property found in the model. Because , (1984b) The Theory of International
of the need to move people and/or establish Trade and Its Canadian Applications, To-
a foreign presence, trade in producer services ronto: Butterworths, 1984.
tends to fall under restrictions imposed by Romer, Paul M., "Growth Based on Increas-
immigration and foreign investment laws. In ing Returns Due to Specialization," Amer-
most countries, these laws tend to be signif- ican Economic Review, May 1987, 77,
icantly more restrictive than barriers to trade 56-62.
in goods. Combining this generalization with Sanyal, Kalyan,K. and Jones, RonaldW., "The
the welfare results of the previous section Theory of Trade in Middle Products,"
suggests the possibility of significant gains American Economic Review, March 1982,
from liberalized trade in producer services. 72, 16-31.

This content downloaded from 128.252.67.66 on Fri, 27 Nov 2015 02:48:41 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like