You are on page 1of 81

Journal of Economic Literature

Vol. XLII (September 2004) pp. 691–751

Trade Costs
JAMES E. ANDERSON and Eric van Wincoop1

“… the report of my death was an exaggeration.” ~ Mark Twain, 1897

1. Introduction Trade costs are richly linked to economic


policy. Direct policy instruments (tariffs, the
T he death of distance is exaggerated.
Trade costs are large, even aside from
trade-policy barriers and even between
tariff equivalents of quotas and trade barri-
ers associated with the exchange-rate sys-
tem) are less important than other policies
apparently highly integrated economies.
(transport infrastructure investment, law
Despite many difficulties in measuring and
enforcement and related property-rights
inferring the height of trade costs and their
institutions, informational institutions, regu-
decomposition into economically useful
lation, language). (3) Trade costs have large
components, the outlines of a coherent pic-
welfare implications. For example,
ture emerge from recent developments in
Anderson and van Wincoop (2002) argue
data collection and especially in structural
that current policy-related costs are often
modeling of costs. Trade costs have econom-
worth more than 10 percent of national
ically sensible magnitudes and patterns
income. (4) Maurice Obstfeld and Kenneth
across countries and regions and across
Rogoff (2000) argue that all the major puz-
goods, suggesting useful hypotheses for
zles of international macroeconomics hang
deeper understanding. This survey is a
on trade costs. (5) Details of trade costs mat-
progress report. Much useful work remains
ter to economic geography. For example, the
to be done, so we make suggestions below.
home market effect hypothesis (big coun-
Trade Costs Matter. (1) They are large—a
tries produce more of goods with scale
170-percent total trade barrier is construct-
economies) hangs on differentiated goods
ed below as a representative rich country
with scale economies having greater trade
ad-valorem tax equivalent estimate. This
costs than homogeneous goods (Donald
includes all transport, border-related, and
Davis 1998). (6) The cross-commodity struc-
local distribution costs from foreign produc-
ture of policy barriers is important to welfare
er to final user in the domestic country. (2)
(e.g., Anderson 1994).
Broadly Defined. Trade costs, broadly
1
Anderson: Boston College and NBER. van Wincoop: defined, include all costs incurred in getting
University of Virginia and NBER. We are grateful to John
McMillan, two referees, and Jeff Bergstrand for excep- a good to a final user other than the margin-
tionally generous and detailed comments and sugges- al cost of producing the good itself: trans-
tions. We have also benefitted from many other portation costs (both freight costs and time
comments by colleagues too numerous to single out,
through e-mail and in presentations at conferences and at costs), policy barriers (tariffs and nontariff
university workshops. barriers), information costs, contract

691
692 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

enforcement costs, costs associated with the assumptions. We place gravity in a wide class
use of different currencies, legal and regula- of trade separable general equilibrium mod-
tory costs, and local distribution costs els. Trade separability obtains when the allo-
(wholesale and retail). Trade costs are cation of trade across countries is separable
reported in terms of their ad-valorem tax from the allocation of production and
equivalent. The 170-percent headline num- spending within countries. Gravity links the
ber breaks down into 55-percent local distri- cross-country general equilibrium trade
bution costs and 74-percent international allocation to the cross-country trade barri-
trade costs (1.7=1.55∗1.74-1). ers, all conditional on the observed con-
Both domestic and international trade sumption and production allocations.
costs are included because it is arbitrary to Inferences about trade costs therefore do
stop counting trade costs once goods cross a not depend on the general equilibrium
border. It is not even obvious when goods structure that lies beneath the observed
cross a border in the economic sense: Is it consumption and production allocations
when they arrive on the dock, leave the within countries.
dock, arrive at the importer? Appropriate aggregation of trade costs is a
Costs broadly defined and reported below key concern. Aggregation of some sort is
may include some rent. Exclusion of rent inevitable due both to the coarseness of
requires a markup theory and its application. observations of complex underlying phe-
Three Sources. We report on trade costs nomena and the desirability of simple meas-
from three broad sources. Direct measures ures of very high dimensional information.
of trade costs are discussed in section 2. We show how theory can be used to replace
Direct measures are remarkably sparse and common atheoretic aggregation methods
inaccurate. Two types of indirect measures with ideal aggregation. We also show how
complement the incomplete and inade- theory can shed light on aggregation bias
quate direct measures: inference from and what can be done to resolve it.
quantities (trade volumes), discussed in sec- Trade Costs Are Large and Variable.
tion 3, and inference from prices, discussed Mattel’s Barbie doll, discussed in Robert
in section 4. Feenstra (1998), illustrates large costs. The
Theory Looms Large. In our survey, theo- production costs for the doll are $1, while it
ry looms large. A theoretical approach is sells for about $10 in the United States. The
inevitable to infer the large portion of trade cost of transportation, marketing, wholesal-
costs that cannot be directly measured in the ing, and retailing have an ad-valorem tax
data. The literature on inference about trade equivalent of 900 percent.
barriers from final goods prices remains A rough estimate of the tax equivalent of
largely devoid of theory. We point to ways in “representative” trade costs for industrialized
which trade theory can be effectively used to countries is 170 percent. This number breaks
fill this gap and learn more about trade bar- down as follows: 21 percent transportation
riers from evidence on prices. Recent devel- costs, 44 percent border-related trade barri-
opments have bridged the gap between ers, and 55 percent retail and wholesale dis-
practice and theory in the inference of trade tribution costs (2.7=1.21∗1.44∗1.55). The
costs from trade flows. Readers who pause 21-percent transport cost includes both
with us on the bridge will produce better directly measured freight costs and a 9-per-
work in the future. cent tax equivalent of the time value of goods
The gravity model provides the main link in transit. Both are based on estimates for
between trade barriers and trade flows. U.S. data. The 44-percent border-related
Gravity is often taken to be rather atheoret- barrier is a combination of direct observation
ic or justified only under highly restrictive and inferred costs. Total international trade
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 693

costs are then about 74 percent policy (tariffs, quotas and the like) and
(0.74=1.21∗1.44-1). Representative retail costs imposed by the environment (trans-
and wholesale distribution costs are set at 55 portation, insurance against various haz-
percent, close to the average for industrial- ards, time costs). We review evidence on
ized countries. international policy barriers, transport
Direct evidence on border costs shows costs and wholesale and retail distribution
that tariff barriers are now low in most costs. We focus on current and recent trade
countries, on average (trade-weighted or costs in this survey; see the work of
arithmetic) less than 5 percent for rich Williamson and co-authors (e.g., Kevin
countries, and with a few exceptions are on O’Rourke and Jeffrey Williamson 1999) for
average between 10 percent and 20 percent historical evidence.
for developing countries. Our overall repre- An important theme is the many difficul-
sentative estimate of policy barriers for ties faced in obtaining accurate measures of
industrialized countries (including nontariff trade costs. Particularly egregious is the
barriers) is about 8 percent. Inferred bor- paucity of good data on policy barriers.2
der costs appear on average to dwarf the Transport-cost data is limited in part by its
effect of tariff and nontariff policy barriers. private nature. Many other trade costs, such
An extremely rough breakdown of the as those associated with information barriers
44-percent number reported above is as and contract enforcement, cannot be direct-
follows: an 8-percent policy barrier, a 7- ly measured at all. Better data on trade costs
percent language barrier, a 14-percent are feasible with institutional resources and
currency barrier (from the use of different would yield a high payoff.
currencies), a 6-percent information cost
2.1 Policy Barriers
barrier, and a 3-percent security barrier for
rich countries. 2.1.1 Measurement Problems and
Trade costs are also highly variable across Limitations
both goods and countries. Trade barriers in
How high are policy barriers to trade?
developing countries are higher than those
This seemingly simple question cannot usu-
reported above for industrialized countries.
ally be answered with accuracy for most
High value-to-weight goods are less penal-
goods in most countries at most dates. The
ized by transport costs. The value of timeli-
inaccuracy arises from three sources:
ness varies across goods, explaining modal
absence of data, data that are useful only in
choice. Poor institutions and poor infrastruc-
combination with other missing or fragmen-
ture penalize trade differentially across
tary data, and aggregation bias. Each of the
countries. Sectoral trade barriers appear to
difficulties is discussed further below.
vary inversely with elasticities of demand.
The key open3 (to the research communi-
Policy barriers, especially nontariff barriers
ty) source for panel data on policy barriers
(NTBs), also vary significantly across goods.
NTBs are highly concentrated: in many sec-
2
tors they are close to zero, but U.S. textiles The grossly incomplete and inaccurate information on
policy barriers available to researchers is a scandal and a
and apparel have 71 percent of products puzzle. It is natural to assume that trade policy is well-
covered, with tariff equivalents ranging from documented since theory and politics have emphasized it
5 percent to 33 percent. for hundreds of years.
3
UNCTAD sells the TRAINS data each year to com-
mercial customers who use it to provide current informa-
tion on trade costs to potential traders. It comes with a
2. Direct Evidence front end designed for convenience in pulling a maximum
of 200 lines of data while preventing a user from gaining
Direct evidence on trade costs comes in access to the whole database and using it to compete with
two major categories, costs imposed by UNCTAD’s potential sales to other customers.
694 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

to trade is the United Nations Conference comprehensive system for researchers, and
on Trade and Development’s Trade Analysis in principle provides public access.6 Its
& Information System, TRAINS. It contains World Integrated Trade System (WITS)
information on trade control measures (tar- software is coupled to TRAINS and to the
iff, para-tariff4 and nontariff measures) at World Trade Organization (WTO)
tariff line level for a maximum of 137 coun- Integrated Data Base and Consolidated
tries beginning in the late 1980s. TRAINS Tariff Schedules7 along with the UN
reports all data on bilateral tariffs, nontariff Statistical Division’s COMTRADE trade
barriers, and bilateral trade flows at the six- flow data. In principle it allows users to drill
digit level of the Harmonized System (HS) down and select data according to their own
product classification for roughly 5000 criteria, to track the complexities of trade
“products.” Countries use a finer product policy as finely as the primary inputs allow.8
classification when reporting tariffs to WITS has some other data handling and
UNCTAD. Thus, multiple tariff “lines” modeling functions as well.
underlie each six-digit aggregate. It is in National sources in combination with the
some cases possible to drill down to the above allow better measurement of a single
national tariff line level. Some organizations country’s trade policy. A series from the
have obtained the full TRAINS database Institute for International Economics pro-
(without the front end software) and pro- vides measures of a few national trade policies
vide access to a limited set of users inside
the organization.5
Table 1 gives a sense of the substantial
incompleteness of TRAINS. For each year 6
See http://wits.worldbank.org. At this writing, there
from 1989 to 2000, the table reports the are still technical glitches facing a user trying to gain
fraction of countries that report some lines access. WITS only runs in late model Windows machines,
users may need some IT support to install the software;
(though possibly a very limited number) for and a user must to pay fees to UNCTAD for use of COM-
tariffs, NTBs, and trade flows. Of 121 TRADE and TRAINS. Email queries are not answered, in
reporting countries in 1999, 43 percent our experience, without using friends at the Bank as inter-
mediaries.
report tariffs, 30 percent report NTBs, 55 7
The WTO Consolidated Tariff Schedule database lists
percent report trade flows, and 17.4 per- the Most Favored Nation (MFN) bound tariffs at the tar-
cent have data for all three. The other coun- iff line level. The bound tariffs are the upper limits under
the member countries’ WTO obligation for actual tariffs
tries report no data at all for any good. charged to member countries not associated with the
Coverage is not much better in other years. importer in a free trade agreement or a customs union,
Coverage is better for OECD countries— and often exceed the actual duties charged. The WTO’s
Integrated Data Base contains information on the applied
over 50 percent have tariff and NTB infor- rates at the national tariff line level. The data is closed to
mation recorded in 1999, with considerable researchers. The WTO periodically reports on individual
variability in coverage across the years. member-country trade policy with a published trade poli-
cy review based on its data.
The World Bank has very recently put 8
The World Bank Trade and Production database pro-
together from these elements the most duces from its resources a set of three- and four-digit
aggregates of trade, production, and tariff data. It is pub-
lished on the Bank website and presumably will be regu-
larly updated. The Trade and Production database covers
4
Para-tariff measures include customs surcharges such 67 developing and developed countries over the period
as import license fees, foreign exchange taxes, stamps, etc. 1976–99. Again, the description given misleadingly sug-
5
For example, Boston College has purchased disaggre- gests a useful panel; the actual data is full of missing obser-
gated tariff information from UNCTAD’s TRAINS data- vations due to the underlying limitations of TRAINS. The
base for the years 1988 through 2001, inclusive. We have sector disaggregation in the database follows the
data for 137 countries for at least one year, counting the International Standard Industrial Classification (ISIC) and
European Union as a single country, but far less than the is provided at the three-digit level (28 industries) for 67
maximum amount suggested by fourteen years times 137 countries and at the four-digit level (81 industries) for 24
countries. of these countries.
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 695

TABLE 1
PERCENTAGE OF COUNTRIES WITH DATA IN TRAINS

All Countries OECD Countries


Year Tariff NTB Trade All Tariff NTB Trade All
1989 0.8 1.7 1.7 0.8 0.0 0.0 5.6 0.0

1990 1.7 0.8 2.5 0.0 0.0 0.0 5.6 0.0

1991 6.6 5.8 11.6 0.8 11.1 16.7 27.8 0.0

1992 10.7 10.7 33.9 5.0 16.7 16.7 61.1 5.6

1993 30.6 23.1 35.5 13.2 83.3 72.2 72.2 50.0

1994 10.7 20.7 57.9 5.0 0.0 27.8 83.3 0.0

1995 33.1 17.4 63.6 14.0 50.0 22.2 83.3 22.2

1996 18.2 13.2 62.8 6.6 61.1 55.6 83.3 44.4

1997 29.8 15.7 58.7 8.3 27.8 11.1 83.3 11.1

1998 36.4 17.4 47.1 9.1 50.0 5.6 83.3 5.6

1999 43.0 29.8 55.4 17.4 55.6 50.0 83.3 38.9

2000 36.4 2.5 0.0 0.0 55.6 55.6 0.0 0.0

Notes: The data are from UNCTAD’s TRAINS database (Haveman Repackaging). The table reports the percentage
of all countries, based on total of 121 reporting countries, that have at least one type of data for one year available
through TRAINS. For OECD countries the percentages are based on 19 countries. “All” indicates that a country
has reported all three types of data for that year.

for single years.9 See also the WTO’s Trade and must be converted to ad valorem equiv-
Policy Reviews series. alents using price information that must be
Data limitations can make even the avail- matched up to the tariffs. Imperfections of
able trade-barrier information difficult to classification or other information introduce
interpret. TRAINS does not routinely report potential measurement error. TRAINS
ad-valorem equivalents of specific tariffs (on reports the percentage of underlying lines
quantities rather than values). Where specif- that have specific tariffs in order to provide
ic tariffs are prevalent, such as in agriculture some information about how widespread
in many countries, the omission of specific the measurement problem may be. The
tariffs is highly misleading. Many tariffs are World Bank’s trade-barrier database sub-
in the form of specific taxes (on quantity), stantially supplements TRAINS by supply-
ing missing specific tariff information. The
9
See Gary Hufbauer and Kimberly Ann Elliott (1994) match of the tariff line classifications with
on the United States; Patrick Messerlin (2001) on the the commodity classifications for trade flows
European Union; Yoko Sazanami, Shujiro Urate, and is imperfect as well, introducing measure-
Hiroki Kawai (1995) on Japan; Namdoo Kim (1996) on
South Korea; and Shuguang Zhang, Zhang Yansheng, and ment error when converting all data to the
Wan Zhongxin (1998) on China. Harmonized System.
696 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

Nontariff barriers (NTBs) are much more the restrictiveness of NTBs based on quota
problematic than tariff barriers. The World license prices where these are available.
Bank database unfortunately does not pro- Indirect methods of measuring the restric-
vide NTB data. A user must use TRAINS or tiveness of NTBs are important because of
more specialized databases directed at par- the paucity of direct measures. One method
ticular NTBs. The TRAINS database is to infer the restrictiveness of nontariff bar-
records the presence or absence of a nontar- riers through the comparison of prices. Some
iff barrier (NTB) on each six-digit line. Many important trade lines are well-suited for price
differing types of nontariff barriers are comparisons (homogeneous products sold on
recorded in TRAINS (a total of eighteen well-organized exchanges, for example), but
types). The NTB data requires concordance even here there are important issues with
between the differing NTB, tariffs, and domestic transport and intermediary margins
trade classification systems at the national and the location of wholesale markets rela-
level, converting to the common HS system. tive to import points of entry. Evidence from
Jon Haveman’s extensive work with price comparisons is discussed in section 4.
TRAINS has produced a usable NTB data- The restrictiveness of nontariff barriers can
base.10 Haveman follows what has become a also be inferred from trade quantities in the
customary grouping of NTBs into hard bar- context of a well-specified model of trade
riers (price and quantity measures), threat flows. Inference about nontariff barriers
measures (antidumping and countervailing from trade flows is discussed in section 3.
duty investigations and measures), and qual- Alan Deardorff and Robert Stern (1998) and
ity measures (standards, licensing require- Sam Laird and Alexander Yeats (1990) pro-
ments, etc.). A fourth category is embargoes vide other detailed discussions of inference
and prohibitions. A common use of the NTB about the restrictiveness of NTBs.
data is to construct a measure of the preva- Aggregation is an important problem in
lence of nontariff barriers, such as the per- the use and analysis of trade barriers. Tariffs
centage of HS lines in a given aggregate and NTBs comprise some 10,000 lines, with
that are covered by NTBs. Nontariff barrier large variation across the lines. The national
information in TRAINS is particularly customs authorities are the primary sources
prone to incompleteness and poor-quality of trade restrictions, and their classification
problems, so analysts seeking to study parti- systems do not match up internationally or
cular sectors such as the Multi-Fibre even intranationally, as between trade flows
Arrangement (MFA) will do better to access on the one hand and tariff and nontariff-
specialized databases such as the World barrier classes on the other hand. Matching
Bank’s MFA data.11 up the tariff, nontariff, and trade-flow data
No information about NTB restrictive- requires aggregation, guided by concor-
ness is provided in TRAINS, since measur- dances that are imperfect and necessarily
ing the restrictiveness of each type of generate measurement error. Moreover, for
nontariff barrier requires an economic many purposes of analysis, the comprehen-
model. In some important cases, individual sion of the analyst is overwhelmed by detail,
analysts have developed direct measures of and further aggregation is desirable.
Atheoretic indices such as arithmetic (equal-
10 ly weighted) and trade-weighted average tar-
See the Ultimate Trade Barrier Catalog at
http://www.eiit.org/Protection. iffs are commonly used, while
11
National tariff line information is also very problem- production-weighted averages sometimes
atic when analyzing nontariff barriers. For example, replace them. As for nontariff barriers, the
matching up reported trade flows with annual quotas
immediately runs into inconsistencies in reporting conven- binary indicator is aggregated into a nontar-
tions. iff barrier coverage ratio, the arithmetic or
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 697

trade-weighted percentage of component countries for 1999, based on TRAINS


sectors with nontariff barriers. data.14 The relatively small number of coun-
Ideal aggregation is proposed by James tries reflects reporting difficulties typical of
Anderson and Peter Neary (1996, 2003) TRAINS; some earlier years contain data for
based on the idea of a uniform tariff equiva- more countries. The reported numbers
lent of differentiated tariffs and NTBs. aggregate the thousands of individual tariff
Theoretically consistent aggregation lines in the underlying data. The table con-
depends on the purpose of the analysis, so firms that tariffs are low among most devel-
the analyst must specify tariff equivalence oped countries (under 5 percent), while
with reference to an objective that makes developing countries continue to have high-
sense for the task at hand. Anderson and er tariff barriers (mostly over 10 percent).
Neary develop and apply indices for the Dispersion across countries is wide: Hong
small-country case that are equivalent in Kong and Switzerland have 0 percent tariffs,
terms of welfare and in terms of distorted the United States has a 1.9 percent simple
aggregate trade volume,12 and show that average, and at the high end India has 30.1
atheoretic aggregation can significantly bias percent and Bangladesh 22.7 percent.
the measurement of trade restrictiveness.13 The variation of tariffs across goods is
The theme of appropriate aggregation in the quite large in all countries; typically only a
different setting of many countries in gener- few are large. Intuition suggests that the
al equilibrium plays a prominent role in our variation of tariffs adds to the welfare cost.
discussion of indirect measurement of trade Marginal deadweight loss is proportional to
costs, so we defer a full treatment to that the tariff, hence the cumulated dead weight
section. Ideal aggregation is informationally loss triangle varies with the square of the tar-
demanding, so for that reason and because iff. Coefficients of variation (the ratio of the
of their familiarity and availability in the standard deviation to the mean) of tariffs,
work of others, we report the standard trade- either arithmetic or trade-weighted, thus
weighted and arithmetic averages of tariffs sometimes supplement averages. Anderson
and of NTB coverage ratios below. and Neary (2003) report trade-weighted
coefficients of variation of tariffs for 25 coun-
2.1.2 Evidence on Policy Barriers
tries around the year 1990, ranging from
Tariffs. Trade-weighted and arithmetic 0.14 to 1.67, many being clustered around
average tariffs are reported in table 2 for fifty one. They show that a proper analysis quali-
fies the simple intuition considerably, with
12 welfare cost increasing in an appropriately
See also Anderson (1998) for equivalence in terms of
sector-specific factor income and its relationship to the weighted coefficient of variation.
commonly reported effective rate of protection. Bilateral variation of tariffs can also be
13
Anderson and Neary (2003) report results using a large. Preferential trade is mainly responsible
volume equivalent uniform tariff— replacement of the dif-
ferentiated tariff structure with a uniform tariff such that since insiders face a zero tariff while outsiders
the general equilibrium aggregate value of trade in distort- face the MFN tariff, but aggregation over
ed products (in terms of external prices) is held constant. goods induces further bilateral variation due
The ideal index is usually larger than the trade-weighted
average—an arithmetic average across countries in the to differing composition of trade across part-
study yields approximately 11 percent for the trade weight- ners. James Harrigan (1993) reports bilateral
ed average and 12 percent for the uniform volume equiv- production-weighted average tariffs in 28
alent, while the U.S. numbers in 1990 are 4 percent and
4.8 percent respectively. For purposes of comparison product categories for OECD countries for
between the initial tariffs and free trade, the two indexes
are quite highly correlated. For a smaller set of evaluations
14
of year-on-year changes, in contrast, Anderson and Neary Calculations were based on TRAINS annual data-
show that the ideal and trade-weighted average indexes are bases purchased by Boston College without the front-
uncorrelated. end software and assembled into panel data.
TABLE 2
SIMPLE AND TRADE-WEIGHTED TARIFF AVERAGES—1999

Country Simple TW
Average Average
Argentina 14.8 11.3
Australia 4.5 4.1
Bahamas 0.7 0.8
Bahrain 7.8 –
Bangladesh 22.7 21.8
Barbados 19.2 20.3
Belize 19.7 14.9
Bhutan 15.3 –
Bolivia 9.7 9.1
Brazil 15.5 12.3
Canada 4.5 1.3
Chile 10.0 10.0
Colombia 12.2 10.7
Costa Rica 6.5 4.0
Czech Republic 5.5 –
Dominica 18.5 15.8
Ecuador 13.8 11.1
European Union 3.4 2.7
Georgia 10.6 –
Grenada 18.9 15.7
Guyana 20.7 –
Honduras 7.5 7.8
Hong Kong 0.0 0.0
India 30.1 –
Indonesia 11.2 –
Jamaica 18.8 16.7
Japan 2.4 2.9
Korea 9.1 5.9
Mexico 17.5 6.6
Montserrat 18.0 –
New Zealand 2.4 3.0
Nicaragua 10.5 11.0
Paraguay 13.0 6.1
Peru 13.4 12.6
Philippines 9.7 –
Romania 15.9 8.3
Saudi Arabia 12.2 –
Singapore 0.0 0.0
Slovenia 9.8 11.4
South Africa 6.0 4.4
St. Kitts 18.7 –
St. Lucia 18.7 –
St. Vincent 18.3 –
Suriname 18.7 –
Switzerland 0.0 0.0
Taiwan 10.1 6.7
Trinidad 19.1 17.0
Uruguay 4.9 4.5
USA 2.9 1.9
Venezuela 12.4 13.0
Notes: The data are from UNCTAD’s TRAINS database (Haveman repackaging).
A “–” indicates that trade data for 1999 are unavailable in TRAINS.
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 699

1983. For Canada, the reported range of to NTB when broadly defined. These meas-
bilateral averages runs from 1.2 percent to 3.2 ures do not include withdrawn suits, which
percent and for Japan from 2.3 percent to 4.5 are presumptively restrictive since they facil-
percent. The United States has more modest itate collusion. Table 3 also shows wide vari-
differences, from 1.6 percent to 2.3 percent.15 ability over countries in the use of NTBs. The
Nontariff Barriers. Table 3 reports the broad definition with arithmetic averages has
prevalence of nontariff barriers for 34 coun- South Africa at 11.3 percent and Argentina at
tries in 1999 based on data from TRAINS and 71.8 percent.
Haveman’s work (rendering it more usable). The use of NTBs is concentrated in a few
The smaller number of countries available sectors in most economies. Table 4 reports
than for tariffs reflects previously noted limi- sectoral NTB coverage ratios for the United
tations of TRAINS. We report arithmetic and States, European Union, Japan, and Canada
trade-weighted NTB coverage ratios; the per- for 1999. NTBs are widely used by devel-
centage of tariff lines subject to NTBs. The oped countries in food products (for exam-
trade-weighted NTB coverage ratios general- ple, the trade-weighted NTB coverage of
ly exceed the arithmetic average NTB cover- agriculture, forestry and fishery products is
age ratios, often considerably so. For 74 percent for the United States and 24 per-
example, on the narrow definition (defined cent for the European Union), textiles/appar-
below), the U.S. arithmetic NTB coverage is el (71 percent for the United States and 42
1.5 percent, while the trade-weighted NTB percent for the European Union), wood and
coverage is 5.5 percent. This reflects the fact wood products (39 percent for the United
that NTBs tend to fall on important traded States and 26 percent for the European
goods such as textiles and apparel. Union) and in some other areas of manufac-
Narrow NTB coverage is basically price turing. The products involved are quite sig-
and quantity control measures and quality nificant in the trade of developing countries
control measures, while broad coverage is the but also somewhat significant in the trade of
narrow classification plus threat measures developed countries with each other.
related to antidumping. Threats are signifi- In comparison to tariffs, NTBs are con-
cant, since Robert Staiger and Frank Wolak centrated in a smaller number of sectors and
(1994) have shown that the threat of in those sectors they are much more restric-
antidumping impedes trade considerably (on tive. Deardorff and Stern (1998) survey most
average for the United States they find a sev- of what limited data is available on quota
enteen-percent reduction in trade due to an license prices. Table 5 (based on table 3.6 of
ongoing investigation). Narrow NTBs cover Deardorff and Stern 1998) gives estimates of
less than 10 percent of trade for the rich tax equivalents based on annual averages of
countries and modest amounts of trade in weekly Hong Kong MFA quota license
most except for Argentina and Brazil. Table 3 prices16 (which are themselves averages of
implies that antidumping is quite common.
For example, based on the TRAINS data, the 16
Where markets subject to quotas are thick and well-
United States in 1999 had 1.5 percent of tar- organized and behavior of all agents is competitive, quota
license prices provide the best evidence of tariff equiva-
iff lines subject to NTB when narrowly lents. Using license price data even under these assump-
defined but 27.2 percent of tariff lines subject tions forces the analyst to face the many dimensions on
which the quota is not equivalent to a tariff—daily price
quotes exhibit within-year variation with economically sig-
15 nificant patterns (seasonality, year-end jumps and drops)—
Harrigan’s data is available to the public. Huiwen Lai
and Daniel Trefler (2002) are notable for compiling three- such that no single index of them can generally be
digit bilateral tariffs for fourteen importers and 36 equivalent to a tariff. Nevertheless, average license prices
exporters for 1972, 1977, 1982, 1987, and 1992. They in combination with the substantial rent-retaining tariffs
emphasize the hard work involved and have not yet made found on most quota-constrained products provide a use-
the data public. ful measure of the restrictiveness of quotas.
TABLE 3
NON-TARIFF BARRIERS—1999

NTB ratio TW NTB ratio NTB ratio TW NTB ratio


Country (narrow) (narrow) (broad) (broad)
Algeria .001 .000 .183 .388
Argentina .260 .441 .718 .756
Australia .014 .006 .225 .351
Bahrain .009 – .045 –
Bhutan .041 – .045 –
Bolivia .014 .049 .179 .206
Brazil .108 .299 .440 .603
Canada .151 .039 .307 .198
Chile .029 .098 .331 .375
Colombia .049 .144 .544 .627
Czech Republic .001 – .117 –
Ecuador .065 .201 .278 .476
European Union .008 .041 .095 .106
Guatemala .000 .000 .348 .393
Hungary .013 .034 .231 .161
Indonesia .001 – .118 –
Lebanon .000 – .000 –
Lithuania .000 .000 .191 .196
Mexico .002 .000 .580 .533
Morocco .001 – .066 –
New Zealand .000 .004 .391 .479
Oman .006 .035 .134 .162
Paraguay .018 .108 .256 .385
Peru .021 .094 .377 .424
Poland .001 .050 .133 .235
Romania .001 .000 .207 .185
Saudi Arabia .014 – .156 –
Slovenia .030 .019 .393 .408
South Africa .000 .002 .113 .161
Taiwan .057 .074 .138 .207
Tunisia .000 .000 .317 .598
Uruguay .052 .098 .354 .470
USA .015 .055 .272 .389
Venezuela .131 .196 .382 .333

Notes: The data are from UNCTAD’s TRAINS database (Haveman repackaging). The “narrow’’ category includes,
quantity, price, quality and advance payment NTBs, but does not include threat measures such as antidumping
investigations and duties. The “broad’’ category includes quantity, price, quality, advance payment and threat
measures. The ratios are calculated based on six-digit HS categories.
A “–” indicates that trade data for 1999 are not available.
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 701

TABLE 4
NTB COVERAGE RATIOS BY SECTOR—1999

United States 1999 EU-12 1999 Japan 1996 Canada 1999


Narrow Broad Narrow Broad Narrow Broad Narrow Broad
NTB-ratio NTB-ratio NTB-ratio NTB-ratio NTB-ratio NTB-ratio NTB-ratio NTB-ratio

S TW S TW S TW S TW S TW S TW S TW S TW
ISIC Description
1 Agric., Forestry, Fish. .011 .052 .719 .743 .001 .001 .229 .241 .153 .227 .897 .962 .028 .022 .878 .938
2 Mining, Quarrying .000 .000 .018 .099 .001 .055 .001 .055 .028 .008 .193 .706 .000 .000 .027 .014
21 Coal Mining .000 .000 .000 .000 .004 .000 .004 .000 .000 .000 .667 1.000 .000 .000 .000 .000
22 Crude Petroleum .000 .000 .250 .105 .004 .067 .004 .067 .000 .000 1.000 1.000 .000 .000 .375 .019
23 Metal Ore Mining .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 .087 .000 .087 .000 .000 .000 .000 .000
29 Other Mining .000 .000 .000 .000 .001 .038 .001 .038 .014 .129 .120 .184 .000 .000 .000 .000
3 Manufacturing .015 .047 .245 .423 .007 .042 .083 .107 .044 .102 .322 .366 .171 .044 .261 .196
31 Food, Bev., Tobacco .072 .120 .644 .809 .004 .011 .489 .474 .185 .329 .925 .893 .185 .348 .456 .453
32 Textiles, Apparel .000 .002 .509 .708 .030 .255 .102 .420 .022 .050 .163 .120 .762 .681 .816 .784
33 Wood, Wood Prod. .000 .000 .459 .389 .000 .007 .197 .263 .000 .000 .098 .025 .016 .015 .262 .252
34 Paper, Paper Prod. .000 .000 .053 .023 .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 .133 .036 .000 .000 .000 .000
35 Chem., Petrol Prod. .036 .149 .114 .322 .003 .011 .032 .033 .048 .169 .635 .750 .013 .007 .047 .073
36 Non-Metal Min. Prod. .000 .006 .014 .029 .000 .016 .000 .043 .000 .000 .073 .160 .000 .000 .000 .000
37 Basic Metal Ind. .003 .044 .006 .044 .002 .010 .012 .016 .051 .086 .375 .139 .000 .000 .381 .362
38 Fab. Metal Prod. .002 .039 .166 .450 .000 .010 .005 .012 .032 .057 .095 .266 .000 .000 .048 .179
39 Other Manuf. .000 .002 .122 .199 .000 .017 .238 .222 .000 .000 .134 .112 .000 .000 .073 .012
Total All Products .015 .055 .272 .389 .008 .041 .095 .106 .055 .098 .369 .442 .151 .039 .307 .198

Notes: “S’’ indicates “simple’’ and “TW’’ indicates “trade-weighted.’’ Data are from UNCTAD’s TRAINS database
(Haveman repackaging). The “Narrow’’ category includes, quantity, price, quality and advance payment NTBs, but does
not include threat measures such as antidumping investigations and duties. The “Broad’’ category includes quantity,
price, quality, advance payment and threat measures. The ratios are calculated for two-digit ISIC categories based on
the six-digit HS classifications used by TRAINS, using HS to ISIC concordances published by the World Bank.

transactions within the week) for textiles and the license prices to form the full tax equiv-
apparel subject to quota between controlled alent. The table shows fairly high tax equiva-
exporters and the United States in 1991 and lents, especially in the largest trade
1993. The license prices imputed for other categories (23 percent for products of broad-
suppliers depend on arbitrage assumptions woven fabric mills, 33 percent for apparel
and especially on relative labor productivity made from purchased material). There is
assumptions which may not be met. The also high variability of license prices and tax
prices are expressed as ad-valorem tax equiv- equivalents across commodities (from 5 per-
alents using Hong Kong export prices for the cent to 23 percent for textiles, from 5 per-
underlying textile and apparel items, trade- cent to 33 percent for apparel). Earlier years
weighted across suppliers.17 We add the reveal higher tax equivalents.18 Thus there is
U.S. tariffs on the corresponding items to
18
Anderson and Neary (1994) report trade-weighted
average tax equivalents across the MFA commodity groups
17
Because the license prices are for transfer between for a set of exporters to the United States in the mid-
holders and users and are effectively subject to penalty for 1980’s. The Hong Kong average exceeded 19 percent in
the holder, the implied tariff equivalents are lower bounds each year and ranged to over 30 percent in some years,
to true measures of restrictiveness; this bias direction while tax equivalents (very likely biased upward) for other
probably also applies to the intertemporal averaging. countries were much larger, some over 100 percent.
702 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

TABLE 5
TARIFF EQUIVALENTS OF U.S. MFA QUOTAS, 1991 AND 1993 (PERCENT)

Sector 1991 1993


Rent Rent S TW Rent + %US
Tar Eq. Tar Eq. Tariff Tariff TW Tariff Imports
Textiles:
Broadwoven fabric mills 8.5 9.5 14.4 13.3 22.8 0.48
Narrow fabric mills 3.4 3.3 6.9 6.7 10.0 0.22
Yarn mills and textile finishing 5.1 3.1 10.0 8.5 11.6 0.06
Thread mills 4.6 2.2 9.5 11.8 14.0 0.01
Floor coverings 2.8 9.3 7.8 5.7 15.0 0.12
Felt and textile goods, n.e.c. 1.0 0.1 4.7 6.2 6.3 0.06
Lace and knit fabric goods 3.8 5.9 13.5 11.8 17.7 0.04
Coated fabrics, not rubberized 2.0 1.0 9.8 6.6 7.6 0.03
Tire cord and fabric 2.3 2.4 5.1 4.4 6.8 0.08
Cordage and twine 3.1 1.2 6.2 3.6 4.8 0.03
Nonwoven fabric 0.1 0.2 10.6 9.5 9.7 0.04
Apparel and fab. textile products:
Women’s hosiery, except socks 5.4 2.3
Hosiery, n.e.c. 3.5 2.4 14.9 15.3 17.7 0.04
App’l made from purchased mat’l 16.8 19.9 13.2 12.6 32.5 5.71
Curtains and draperies 5.9 12.1 11.9 12.1 24.2 0.01
House furnishings, n.e.c. 8.3 13.9 9.3 8.2 22.1 0.27
Textile bags 5.9 9.0 6.4 6.6 15.6 0.01
Canvas and related products 6.3 5.2 6.9 6.4 11.6 0.03
Pleating, stitching, ... embroidery 5.2 7.6 8.0 8.1 15.7 0.02
Fabricated textile products, n.e.c. 9.2 0.6 5.2 4.8 5.4 0.37
Luggage 2.6 10.4 12.1 10.8 21.2 0.28
Women’s handbags and purses 1.0 3.1 10.5 6.7 9.8 0.44

Notes: “S’’ indicates “simple’’ and “TW’’ indicates “trade-weighted.’’ Rent equivalents for U.S. imports from Hong
Kong were estimated on the basis of average weekly Hong Kong quota prices paid by brokers, using information
from International Business and Economic Research Corporation. For countries that do not allocate quota rights
in public auctions, export prices were estimated from Hong Kong export prices, with adjustments for differences
in labor costs and productivity. Sectors and their corresponding SIC classifications are detailed in USITC (1995)
Table D-1. Quota tariff equivalents are reproduced from Deardorff and Stern (1998), Table 3.6 (Source USITC
1993,1995). Tariff averages, trade-weighted tariff averages and U.S. import percentages are calculated using data
from the UNCTAD TRAINS dataset. SIC to HS concordances from the U.S. Census Bureau are used.

(i) substantial restrictiveness of MFA quotas and Canadian agriculture. Details are dis-
and (ii) very large differentials in quota pre- cussed in section 4.
mia across commodity lines and across Using a variety of methods, Messerlin
exporters. (2001) makes a notably ambitious attempt to
Price comparison measures confirm this assemble tariff equivalents of all trade policy
picture of the high and highly concentrated barriers for the European Union. He com-
nature of NTBs with data from the agricul- bines the NTB tariff equivalents with the
tural sector. European and Japanese agricul- MFN tariffs. For 1999 the tariff equivalent of
ture is even more highly protected than U.S. policy barriers were 5 percent for cereals,
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 703

64.8 percent for meat, 100.3 percent for dairy makes use of this source for the United
and 125 percent for sugar. In mining, the tar- States and several other countries. The most
iff equivalent was 71.3 percent. The com- widely available (many countries and years
bined arithmetic average protection rate was are covered) but least satisfactory average ad
31.7 percent in agriculture, 22.1 percent in valorem transport costs are the aggregate
textiles, 30.6 percent in apparel, and much bilateral c.i.f./f.o.b ratios produced by the
less in other industrial goods. The combined IMF from matching export data (reported
arithmetic average protection rate in industri- f.o.b.) to import data (reported c.i.f.).19 The
al goods was 7.7 percent. We use 7.7 percent IMF uses the UN’s COMTRADE database,
for our representative trade policy cost. supplemented in some cases with national
data sources. Hummels (2001a) points out
2.2 Transport Costs
that a high proportion of observations are
Direct transport costs include freight imputed; this and the compositional shifts in
charges and insurance which is customarily aggregate trade flows which occur over time
added to the freight charge. Indirect trans- lead him to conclude that “quality problems
port user costs include holding cost for the should disqualify these data from use as a
goods in transit, inventory cost due to measure of transportation costs in even
buffering the variability of delivery dates, semi-careful studies.”20
preparation costs associated with shipment
2.2.2 Evidence on Transport Costs
size (full container load vs. partial loads), and
the like. Indirect costs must be inferred. Hummels (2001a) shows the wide disper-
sion in freight rates over commodities and
2.2.1 Measurement Problems and
across countries in 1994. The all-commodi-
Limitations
ties trade-weighted average transport cost
There are three main sources of data for from national customs data ranges from 3.8
transport costs. The most direct is industry percent of the f.o.b. price for the United
or shipping firm information. Nuno Limao States to 13.3 percent for Paraguay. The all-
and Anthony Venables (2001) obtain quotes commodities arithmetic average ranges from
from shipping firms for a standard container 7.3 percent for Uruguay to 17.5 percent for
shipped from Baltimore to various destina- Brazil. The U.S. average is 10.7 percent.
tions. David Hummels (2001a) obtains Across commodities for the United States
indices of ocean shipping and air freight the range of trade-weighted averages is from
rates from trade journals which presumably less than 1 percent (for transport equip-
are averages of such quotes. Direct methods ment) to 27 percent for crude fertilizer. The
are best but not always feasible due to data arithmetic averages range from 5.7 percent
limitations and the very large size of the for machinery and transport equipment to
resulting datasets. 15.7 percent for mineral fuels.
Alternatively, there are two sources of Hummels (1999) considers variation over
information on average transport costs. time. The overall trade-weighted average
National customs data in some cases allow transport cost for the United States declined
fine detail. For example, the U.S. Census over the last thirty years, from 6 percent to 4
provides data on U.S. imports at the ten-digit
Harmonized System level by exporter coun- 19
See the Direction of Trade Statistics and the
try, mode of transport and entry port, by International Financial Statistics.
20
weight (where available) and valued at f.o.b. Nevertheless, because of their availability and the
and c.i.f. bases. Dividing the former value difficulty of obtaining better estimates for a wide range of
countries and years, apparently careful work such as
into the latter yields an ad-valorem estimate Harrigan (1993) and Scott Baier and Jeffrey Bergstrand
of bilateral transport cost. Hummels (2001a) (2001) uses the IMF data.
704 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

percent. Composition problems are acute Each day in travel is on average worth 0.8
because world trade in high-value-to-weight percent of the value of manufactured
manufactures has grown much faster than goods, equivalent to a 16-percent ad-val-
trade in low-value-to-weight primary prod- orem tariff for the average-length ocean
ucts. Hummels shows that air freight cost shipment. Shippers switch from ocean to air
has fallen dramatically, while ocean shipping in his mode choice model when the full
cost has risen (along with the shift to con- (shipping plus time) cost of ocean exceeds
tainerization, which improves the quality of that for air.22 The use of averages here
the shipping service). He also documents masks a lot of variation in the estimated
the wide dispersion in the rate of change of value of time across two-digit manufactur-
air-freight rates across country pairs over the ing sectors, and is subject to upward aggre-
past forty years. gation bias due to larger growth in trade
Notice that alongside tariffs and NTBs, where savings are greatest due to the sub-
transport costs look to be comparable in stitution effect. Infrastructure is likely to
average magnitude and in variability across have a considerable effect on the time costs
countries, commodities, and time. Transport of trade.
costs tend to be higher in bulky agricultural In 1998, half of U.S. shipments was by air
products where protection in OECD coun- and half by boat.23 Assigning one day to
tries is also high. Policy protection tends to shipment by air anywhere in the world, as
complement natural protection, amplifying Hummels does, and using the twenty-day
the variability of total trade costs. average for ocean shipping, leads to an
Limao and Venables (2001) emphasize the average 9-percent tax equivalent of time
dependence of trade costs on infrastructure. costs. Hummels argues that faster transport
They gather price quotes for shipment of a (shifting from shipping to air, and faster
standardized container from Baltimore to ships) has reduced the tax equivalent of
various points in the world. Infrastructure is time costs for the United States from 32
measured as an average of the density of the percent to 9 percent over the period
road network, the paved road network, the 1950–98.24
rail network, and the number of telephone We combine 9-percent time costs and
main lines per person. A deterioration of 10.7 percent U.S. average direct transport
infrastructure from the median to the 75th costs for our representative full transport
percentile of destinations raises transport cost of 21 percent (1.107∗1.09-1).
costs by 12 percent. The median landlocked
country has transport costs that are 55 per- 22
Linking port of entry for U.S. imports with the trav-
cent higher than the median coastal econo- el time to the exporter (a country-average of times to the
my.21 The infrastructure variables also have exporter’s ports), he creates a matrix of ocean shipping
explanatory power in predicting trade vol- times. Air freight is assumed to take one day for points
anywhere in the world.
ume. Inescapably, understanding trade costs 23
This ignores trucking and rail modes, which are
and their role in determining international important to trade with Canada and Mexico, the two
trade volumes must incorporate the internal largest trade partners of the United States.
24
The calculation is based on observing that U.S.
geography of countries and the associated imports, excluding Canada and Mexico, had 0-percent air
interior trade costs. shipment in 1950 and 50-percent air shipment in 1998.
As for indirect costs, Hummels (2001b) The average ocean shipment time was halved from forty
days to twenty days over the same time. The net effect is a
imputes a willingness-to-pay for saved time. saving of 29.5 days, equal to forty days for 1950 minus 10.5
days for 1998. The latter is equal to .5 times twenty days
for ocean shipping plus .5 times one day for air freight. For
manufacturing, at 0.8 per cent ad valorem per day for the
21
Limao and Venables also report similar results using value of time in shipping, the saving of 29.5 days is worth
the c.i.f./f.o.b. ratios of the IMF. a fall from 32 percent to 9 percent ad valorem.
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 705

TABLE 6
DISTRIBUTION MARGINS FOR HOUSEHOLD CONSUMPTION AND CAPITAL GOODS

Select Aus. Bel. Can. Ger. Ita. Jap. Net. UK US


Product Categories 95 90 90 93 92 95 90 90 92
Rice 1.239 1.237 1.867 1.423 1.549 1.335 1.434 1.511 1.435
Fresh, frozen beef 1.485 1.626 1.544 1.423 1.605 1.681 1.640 1.390 1.534
Beer 1.185 1.435 1.213 1.423 1.240 1.710 1.373 2.210 1.863
Cigarettes 1.191 1.133 1.505 1.423 1.240 1.398 1.230 1.129 1.582
Ladies’ clothing 1.858 1.845 1.826 2.039 1.562 2.295 1.855 2.005 2.159
Refrigerators, freezers 1.236 1.586 1.744 1.826 1.783 1.638 1.661 2.080 1.682
Passenger vehicles 1.585 1.198 1.227 1.374 1.457 1.760 1.247 1.216 1.203
Books 1.882 1.452 1.294 2.039 1.778 1.665 1.680 1.625 1.751
Office, data proc. mach. 1.715 1.072 1.035 1.153 1.603 1.389 1.217∗ 1.040 1.228
Electronic equip., etc. 1.715 1.080 1.198 1.160 1.576 1.432 1.224∗ 1.080 1.139
Simple Average
(125 categories) 1.574 1.420 1.571 1.535 1.577 1.703 1.502 1.562 1.681

Notes: The table is reproduced from Bradford and Lawrence, “Paying the Price: The Cost of Fragmented
International Markets”, Institute of International Economics, forthcoming (2003). Margins represent the ratio
of purchaser price to producer price. Margins data on capital goods are not available for the Netherlands, so an
average of the four European countries’ margins is used.

2.3 Wholesale and Retail Distribution Costs show that their input-output estimates of
U.S. distribution costs are roughly consis-
Wholesale and retail distribution costs tent with survey data from the U.S.
enter retail prices in each country. Since Department of Agriculture for agricultural
wholesale and retail costs vary widely by goods and from the 1992 Census of
country, this would appear to affect Wholesale and Retail Trade. For other G-7
exporters’ decisions. Local trade costs apply countries they report distribution costs in
to both imported and domestic goods, how- the range of 35–50 percent.
ever, so relative prices to buyers don’t Scott Bradford and Robert Lawrence
change and neither does the pattern of (2003) use the same input-output sources to
trade. Section 3 gives a formal argument. measure distribution costs for the United
Section 4 discusses the effect of distribution States and eight other industrialized coun-
margins on inference about international tries, but instead divide by the producer
trade costs from retail prices. price, consistent with the approach in this
Ariel Burstein, Joao Neves, and Sergio survey of reporting trade barriers in terms of
Rebelo (2003) construct domestic distribu- ad valorem tax equivalents. Table 6 reports
tion costs from national input-output data distribution costs for selected tradable
for tradable consumption goods (which household consumption goods and an arith-
correspond most closely to the goods for metic average for 125 goods. The averages
which narrowly defined trade costs are rel- range over countries from 42 percent in
evant). They report a weighted average of Belgium to 70 percent in Japan. Average
41.9 percent for the United States in 1992 U.S. distribution costs are 68 percent of pro-
as a fraction of the retail price. They also ducer prices. The range of distribution costs
706 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

is much larger across goods than across 3.1 Traditional Gravity


countries, for example running from 14 per-
Most estimated gravity equations take the
cent on electronic equipment to 216 percent
form
on ladies clothing in the United States.25 We
M
take 55 percent as our representative
domestic distribution cost, close to the trad-
xij = 1 yi + 2 yi + ∑
m =1
m ln( zijm) + ε ij (1)
able consumption goods average of OECD
where xij is the log of exports from i to j, yi
countries.
and yj are the log of GDP of the exporter
and importer, and zmij (m=1,…,M) is a set of
observables to which bilateral trade barri-
3. Inference of Trade Costs
ers are related. The disturbance term is ij.
from Trade Flows
A large recent literature developed estimat-
Trade costs can be inferred from an eco- ing this type of gravity equation after a sur-
nomic model linking trade flows to observ- prising finding by McCallum (1995) that
able variables and unobservable trade costs. the U.S.-Canada border has a big impact on
Inference has mainly used the gravity trade.27 McCallum estimated a version of
model.26 The economic theory of gravity is (1) for U.S. states and provinces with two z
developed here extensively, revealing new variables: bilateral distance and an indica-
properties that clarify procedures for good tor variable that is equal to one if the two
empirical work, reporting results, and doing regions are located in the same country and
sensible comparative statics. Our develop- equal to zero otherwise. He found that
ment embeds gravity within the classic con- trade between provinces is more than
cerns of trade economists with the twenty times trade between states and
equilibrium allocation of production and provinces after controlling for distance and
expenditure within nations. size. The subsequent literature has often
A variety of ad hoc trade cost functions added so-called remoteness variables,
have been used to relate the unobservable which are intended to capture the average
cost to observable variables. Plausibly, cost distance of countries or regions from their
falls with common language and customs, trading partners.
better information, better enforcement and Gravity equations can be derived from a
so forth. Many implementations impose variety of different theories. None lead to tra-
restrictions that seem implausible. Some ditional gravity, despite this literature’s use of
proxies may not be exogenous, such as references such as Anderson (1979) and
membership in a currency union or regional Deardorff (1998) to justify estimation of (1).28
trade agreement; their effects will not be
3.2 Theory-Based Gravity
uniform; functional form is often too simple
and so forth. Further economic theory is Gravity-like structure obtains in a wide
needed to identify the underlying structure class of models, those where the allocation
of trade costs. of trade across countries can be analyzed

25
We should warn that some of these distribution cost
27
estimates include rents in the form of monopolistic See Michael Anderson and Stephen Smith (1999a,b),
markups rather than actual costs incurred by the local dis- Natalie Chen (2002), Carolyn Evans (2003a,b,c), John
tribution sector. Although it would be desirable to take out Helliwell (1996, 1997, 1998), Helliwell and John
these rents, no data are available to do so. McCallum (1995), Helliwell and Genevieve Verdier
26
A subset of the gravity literature uses it to discrimi- (2001), Russell Hillberry (1998, 2002), Volker Nitsh
nate among theories of the determinants of trade. It is not (2000), Shang-Jin Wei (1996), and Holger Wolf (2000a,b).
28
very well-suited for this purpose, since many trade models For recent surveys of gravity theory, see Harrigan
will lead to gravity (Deardorff 1998). (2002), and Feenstra (2002, 2003).
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 707

separately from the allocation of production {Eik}.31 Bilateral trade is determined in con-
and consumption within countries.29 Let ditional general equilibrium whereby prod-
{Yik, Eik} be the value of production and uct markets for each good (each brand)
expenditure in country i for product class k. produced in each country clear conditional
A product class can be either a final or an on the allocations {Yik, Eik}. Inference about
intermediate good. A model is trade separa- trade costs is based on this conditional gen-
ble if the allocation of {Yik, Eik} for each coun- eral equilibrium. Comparative static analy-
try i is separable from the bilateral allocation sis, in contrast, requires consideration of
of trade across countries. the full general equilibrium. A change in
Trade separability obtains under the trade barriers, for example, will generally
assumption of separable preferences and affect the allocations {Yik, Eik}.
technology. Each product class has a distinct Two additional restrictions to the class of
natural aggregator of varieties of goods dis- trade separable models yield gravity. These
tinguished by country of origin. This are: the aggregator of varieties is identical
assumption allows the two-stage budgeting across countries and CES; and ad-valorem
needed to separate the allocation of expen- tax equivalents of trade costs do not depend
diture across product classes from the allo- on the quantity of trade. The CES form
cation of expenditure within a product class imposes homothetic preferences and the
across countries of origin.30 What exactly is homogeneity equivalent for intermediate
implied by product differentiation within a input demand. These assumptions simplify
product class will differ depending on the the demand equations and market clearing
product class and its myriad characteristics. equations. These two restrictions can be
For inputs of physically standardized prod- relaxed in various useful ways discussed
ucts (grains, petroleum, steel plate), differ- below. Our derivation provides much more
entiation may be on terms of delivery or context to Deardorff’s (1998) remark, “I sus-
subtle qualities that affect productivity while pect that just about any plausible model of
branded final goods suggest hedonic differ- trade would yield something very like the
entiation over varieties of clothing or per- gravity equation …”.
fume. Imposing some form of differentiation If Xijk is defined as exports from i to j in
is unavoidable if empirical trade models are product class k, the CES demand structure
to fit the bilateral trade data, as Armington implies (under the expositional simplifica-
noted long ago. tion of equal weights for each country of
The class of trade separable models origin)
yields bilateral trade without having to
1− k
make any assumptions about what specific  pk 
model accounts for the observed output X =  ijk 
k
ij Ekj (2)
structure {Yik} and expenditure allocations  Pj 

where k is the elasticity of substitution


29
The general equilibrium of trade in a many-country among brands, pijk is the price charged by i
world is enormously simplified by this natural assumption.
30
Explicitly, separability restricts the dual cost function for exports to j and Pjk is the CES price index:
c(p,w,y) where p is a vector of traded input prices and w is
a vector of non-traded primary input prices while y is the
level of output. The separability restriction is imposed in
c(p,w,y)=f[g(p),w,y] where g(p) is a homogenous of
31
degree one and concave function of p By Shephard’s Specifically, it does not matter what one assumes
Lemma, fg is the aggregate demand for the traded input about production functions, technology, the degree of
class while fg gp is the demand vector for the individual competition, or specialization patterns. The nature of pref-
products. A similar structure characterizes the assumption erences and technology that gives rise to the observed
of separability in final demand. expenditure allocations Eik also does not matter.
708 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

1/(1− k ) of trade barriers {tijk} and the entire set


 
P = ∑ ( pijk )1− k 
j
k
. (3) {Yik,Eik}. Trade flows therefore also depend
 i  on trade barriers and the set {Yik,Eik}.33
A wide variety of production and expen-
The assumption that trade costs are pro- diture models may lie behind {Ejk,Yik}. In
portional to trade implies that the price pijk particular, some of the E’s and Y’s may be
can be written as piktijk, where pik is the “sup- equal to zero. Previous derivations of gravi-
ply price” received by producers in country k ty have usually made much more restrictive
and tijk–1 is the ad-valorem tax equivalent of assumptions.34
trade costs, independent of volume. The main insight from the theory is that
If supply is monopolistic, the “supply bilateral trade depends on relative trade bar-
price” is the product of marginal production riers. The key variables ik and Pjk are out-
cost and the markup. So long as the markup ward and inward multilateral resistance,
is invariant over destinations,32 tijk contains respectively. They summarize the average
only trade costs. Otherwise the tax equiva- trade resistance between a country and its
lent must be interpreted to contain markups. trading partners in an ideal aggregation
With competitive supply, this issue does not sense, which we develop below. Basic
arise. Markups arising from monopoly demand theory suggests that the flow of good
power in the distribution sector itself are a i into j is increased (given 1) by high trade
more important issue with interpreting tijk–1 costs from other suppliers to j as captured by
as a cost. inward multilateral resistance Pjk. But, less
Imposing the market-clearing conditions obviously, high resistance to shipments from
i to its other markets, captured in outward
multilateral resistance ik, tips more trade
Yik = ∑ X ijk (4)
j
back into i’s market in j. Gravity gives these
insights an elegantly simple form in (5).
for all i and k yields gravity. Solve for the The trade cost tijk may include local distri-
supply prices pik from the market-clearing bution costs in the destination market, but
conditions and substitute the result in (2) those domestic costs do not affect trade flows.
and (3). This yields the system This rather surprising and important result
1− k follows from basic gravity theory. Suppose for
Ekj Yik  tijk  any goods class k that each destination j has
X =
k
  (5)
ij
Y k  Pjk ∏ ki  its own domestic margin mjk. If we multiply all
1− k
 tk  Ekj
(∏ ) k 1- k
i = ∑  ijk  (6) 33
Theoretical gravity equations in Anderson (1979),
j  Pj  Yk Jeffrey Bergstrand (1985, 1989, 1990) and Scott Baier and
Bergstrand (2001) look far more complicated than (5),
1− k with a large number of prices and price indices. Anderson
 tijk  Yik
= ∑ k 
k 1 k and van Wincoop (2003) show that all these prices can be
(P )
j (7) summarized by just two price indices, one for the
i  ∏i  Yk importer and one for the exporter, which are solved as a
function of trade barriers and total supply and demand in
where Yk is world output in sector k. The each location.
34
indices Pjk and ik can be solved as a function The first paper to formally derive a gravity equation
from a general equilibrium model with trade costs is
Anderson (1979), who assumes that every country pro-
duces a particular variety. Bergstrand (1989, 1990) and
32
With Cournot competition, the markup is invariant Baier and Bergstrand (2001) derive gravity equations in
over destinations in symmetric monopolistic competition. models with monopolistic competition, endogenizing vari-
Generally it is equal to 1/[1–1/(1–sij)] where sij is the mar- ety. Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) assume each coun-
ket share of i in j. try has an endowment of its good.
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 709

narrowly defined trade barriers tijk by domes- equal to E2k–Y2k. Gravity equation (5),
tic trade costs mjk in the destination market, it accounting for multilateral resistance,
is easily verified from (6)–(7) that the Pjk are indeed converges to this for the two-country
multiplied by mjk, the ik are unchanged, and case as k approaches infinity, assuming any
therefore trade flows are also unchanged. non-zero international trade barrier (and
The invariance of trade patterns to domes- normalizing domestic barriers to zero).
tic distribution costs that apply to all goods Since the bilateral trade flow in the condi-
has another important practical implication. tional general equilibrium does not depend
We can only identify relative costs with the on the magnitude of trade barriers, nothing
gravity model. One way to interpret an can be learned about trade barriers. More
inferred system of trade costs {tijk} is to pick generally, it is difficult to learn much about
some region i and normalize tiik=1. trade barriers from a gravity equation for
Essentially this procedure treats the trade sectors where the elasticity of substitution is
cost of i with itself as a pure local distribu- extremely high. The expressions tij1–k on
tion cost and divides all other trade costs by which trade flows (directly and through mul-
the local distribution cost in region i. tilateral resistance) depend are virtually zero
As in most gravity papers, Anderson and when k is very high as long as the trade bar-
van Wincoop (2003) consider a one-sector rier is positive (tijk1). Conditional on a trade
economy. They show that when consumers barrier being positive, the size of the trade
have CES preferences with common elas- barrier does not matter much to the pattern
ticity  among all goods, the gravity equa- of trade flows in the conditional general
tion can be written, omitting the equilibrium, hence we cannot learn much
superscripts k, as about their size.
1− Several authors have derived gravity equa-
YY  t  tions for homogeneous goods trade when
X ij = i j  ij  (8)
Yw  ∏ i Pj  trade is an aggregate of a variety of homoge-
neous goods. Deardorff (1998) derived a
gravity equation in the Heckscher Ohlin
Pj1− = ∑ i −1θ i tij1− ∀j (9)
i
model with complete specialization. This is
essentially a differentiated goods model
though, with each country producing a dif-
1i − = ∑ Pj −1θ j tij1− ,∀i. (10)
j
ferent brand. It does not mean much to say
that a good is homogeneous when there is
where Yi and Yj are levels of GDP, Yw is only one producer.
world GDP, and i is the income share of A real homogeneous goods model, with
country i. This is a special case of (5) with multiple producers of the same homoge-
expenditure equal to output because it is a neous good, is the Ricardian model of
one-sector economy (Ei=Yi). With symmetry Jonathan Eaton and Samual Kortum (2002).
of trade costs (tij=tji), i=Pi. Their model leads to a gravity equation for
A couple of comments are in order about an aggregate of homogeneous goods. It is
homogeneous goods trade. When we let the also a model with trade separability,
elasticity of substitution k in (5)–(7) go to although the rationale is somewhat different.
infinity, trade converges to that in a homoge- Production is Ricardian, with the cost of pro-
neous goods model. However, no informa- duction in country i in good k given by
tion about trade barriers can be inferred. As ci / z(k) where z(k) is the realization of tech-
an example, consider a two-country model nology in good k, an element in a continuum
with trade in a homogeneous good k. If of goods. Productivity is drawn from a
country 1 exports k to country 2, its export is Fréchet distribution. The distribution has
710 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

two parameters. The first is Ti, with higher Ti labor a fraction , gross output is 1/ times
meaning a higher average realization for value added. If we interpret Yi in (8) as
country i. The second is , with a larger value added, the gravity equation must be
value implying lower productivity differ- multiplied by 1/.
ences across countries. For a particular
3.3 The Trade Cost Function
good, users always buy from the cheapest
source. The price is the production cost The theoretical gravity model allows infer-
times the trade cost tij. Each good is pro- ence about unobservable trade costs by (i)
duced with both labor and a bundle of inter- linking trade costs to observable cost proxies
mediate goods that consists of the same CES and (ii) making an assumption about error
index of all final goods as the utility function terms which link observable trade flows to
over final goods. theoretically predicted values. Here we
Since there is a continuum of goods and focus on (i), the next section deals with (ii).
the setup is the same for all goods (same pro- For now we will focus on inference about
duction function, same productivity distribu- trade barriers from the aggregate gravity
tion, same trade cost), the fraction that equation (8). In a section about aggregation
country j spends on goods from i is equal to below we will return to the disaggregated
the probability for any particular good that j gravity equation (5).
sources from i. With the assumed Fréchet Bilateral trade barriers are assumed to
distribution this is equal to be a function of observables z ijm, commonly
loglinear:
X ij Ti (ci tij )−
=
M
. tij = ∏ ( zijm ) m
Ej ∑ i
Ti (ci tij )− m =1
(11)

The probability of shipment from country Normalizing such that z ijm=1 measures zero
i is lowered by the trade cost of getting the trade barriers associated with this variable,
good to country j, relative to the average (z ijm)m is equal to one plus the tax equivalent
trade cost of shipping from all other destina- of trade barriers associated with variable m.
tions, and lowered by a higher cost of labor. The list of observable arguments z ijm which
The same mathematical representation of have been used in the trade cost function in
the allocation of trade arises as with the CES the literature includes directly measured
structure of demand for goods differentiated trade costs, distance, adjacency, preferential
by place of origin. This equation is the same trade membership, common language, and a
as (2), with =1 and pi1– replaced by host of others. Gravity theory has used arbi-
Tici1–. The pi is essentially replaced by ci, trary assumptions regarding functional form
which can be solved in the same way from of the trade cost function, the list of vari-
the conditional general equilibrium. This ables, and regularity conditions.
gives rise to the same gravity equation as As an illustration of the functional form
before.35 problem, consider distance. By far the most
It is worth noting that gross output is now common assumption is that tij=dij . Gene
larger than net output due to the input of Grossman (1998) argues that a more reason-
intermediates. The output in the gravity able assumption is that τij=tij–1=dij since one
equation (8) is gross output. Since Eaton can think of τij as transport costs per dollar of
and Kortum assume that intermediates are a shipments. Hummels (2001a) estimates the
fraction 1– of the production cost ci, with in the second specification by using data on
ad-valorem freight rates and finds a value of
35
Eaton and Kortum only derive a gravity specification about 0.3. Limao and Venables (2001) esti-
for Xij /Xii. mate the first specification using c.i.f./f.o.b.
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 711

data and also find an estimate of of about the percentages of people in two countries
0.3. Although these numbers are the same, that can speak the same language. Another is
they are inconsistent with each other. If the the binary variable “open-circuit communica-
Grossman specification is correct with =0.3, tion,” which is one if two countries have the
one would expect a distance elasticity of tij of same official language or the same language
0.3τij/(1τij), evaluated at some average τ, is spoken by at least 20 percent of the popu-
which is much less than 0.3. Highly mislead- lations of both countries. The first variable
ing results for trade barrier estimates arise reflects that trade requires direct communi-
when the wrong functional form is adopted. cation, while the second variable is meant to
Eaton and Kortum (2002) generalize the capture an established network of translation.
treatment of distance with a flexible form Another example is distance. It is common to
which can approximate both of the preceding model distance as the Great Circle distance
specifications. They assume that there are dif- between capitals. Where these differ from
ferent trade barriers for six different distance commercial centers it is sometimes taken to
intervals. While implicitly they still assume a be superior to use distance between com-
particular functional form, in the form of a mercial centers. But then what of countries
step function, this spline approach is likely to with more than one commercial center, of
be more robust to specification error. interior infrastructure?36
Another functional form issue is that the Implausibly strong regularity (common
most common setup (11) is multiplicative in coefficients) conditions are often implicitly
the various cost factors. Hummels (2001a) imposed on the trade cost function. For
argues that an additive specification is more example, the effect of membership in a cus-
sensible. A multi-dimensional generalization toms union or a monetary union on trade
of the approach by Eaton and Kortum costs is often assumed to be uniform for all
(2002) may be applied, although there is a members. As for customs unions, a uniform
tradeoff between degrees of freedom and external tariff is indeed approximately the
generality of the specification. To the extent trade policy (though NTBs remain inherent-
that theory has something to say about the ly discriminatory), while free trade agree-
functional form, it is preferable to use this ments continue to have different national
information over econometric solutions that external tariffs and thus different effects. As
waste degrees of freedom. for monetary unions, the effect of switching
The second problem is which observables from national to common currencies is like-
to include. Empirical practice can improve ly to be quite different depending on the
with a more theoretical approach to the z’s. national currency. Similar objections can be
Especially for abstract trade barriers such as raised to a number of the other commonly
information costs, it is often unclear what used proxies zijm such as common language or
specific variables are meant to capture. Even adjacency dummies. NTBs present an acute
in the absence of a specific theory, it is useful form of this problem. The effect on trade
to ponder the relationship between trade barriers of NTBs in a country i will general-
barriers and observed variables. For example, ly vary across trading partners j, goods k, and
common empirical practice uses a language time t. Regression residuals reflect the
variable that is one if two countries speak the NTBs but also random error. To identify the
same language and zero otherwise. Jacques tariff equivalent of NTBs Harrigan (1993)
Melitz (2003) considers ways in which lan-
guage differences affect trade and develops 36
Some investigators (e.g., Bergstrand) measure bilat-
several variables that each capture different eral distance between ports, supplemented by twice the
land distance between ports and commercial centers,
aspects of communication. One such variable reflecting the rough difference in cost between water and
is “direct communication,” which depends on land shipment.
712 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

assumes, not very plausibly, that the import- which also gives an unbiased estimate of the
ing country’s NTB has the same trade dis- parameters λm, is to replace the inward and
placement effect for each exporter i that it outward multilateral resistance indices and
buys good k from. Trefler (1993) assumes production variables, yj–(1–σ)lnPj and
even less plausibly that U.S. NTBs have the yj–(1–σ)ln(Πi), with inward and outward
same trade-reducing effect for all goods k region-specific dummies. With symmetry, a
that it imports from the rest of the world. 37 single set of region-specific dummies suffice.
We sympathize with efforts to identify This approach is adopted by Anderson and
trade costs with simple forms of (11). Our van Wincoop (2003), Eaton and Kortum
criticism of the ad hoc functional form and (2002), Asier Minondo (2002), Andrew Rose
the regularity assumptions aims to stimulate and van Wincoop (2002), and Hummels
improvement in estimation and useful com- (2001a). Keith Head and Thierry Mayer
parative statics. Unpacking the reduced (2001) and Head and John Ries (2001) fol-
form to its plausible structural elements will low an estimation approach that is identical
aid both. to replacing multilateral resistance variables
with country dummies in the case where
3.4 Estimation of Trade Barriers
internal trade data Xii exist for all regions or
Given the trade cost function, the loga- countries. Assuming that zij=zji, it follows
rithmic form of the empirical gravity equa- from (12) that
tion becomes (dropping the constant term) 0.5
X X  M  (zm zm )0.5 
M
ln ii jj  = ∑
m ln ii mjj  . (13)
xij = yi + y j + ∑
m ln(zijm ) – (1 –  ) ln( i )  X ij X ji  m =1  zij 
m =1

– (1 −  ) ln(Pj ) + ε ij (12) The parameters λk can then be estimated


through a linear regression.
where xij=ln(Xij), yi=ln(Yi), and λm=(1–σ)γm, A third method is to use data for the price
xij and yi are observables, and εij is the error indices and estimate with OLS. This
term. requires data on price levels for a cross-sec-
The theoretical gravity equation can be tion regression or changes in price indices
estimated in three different ways.38 when there are at least two years of data.
Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) estimate The latter is the approach taken by
the structural equation with nonlinear least Bergstrand (1985, 1989, 1990), Baier and
squares after solving for the multilateral Bergstrand (2001), and Head and Mayer
resistance indices as a function of the (2000). As discussed in Baier and Berstrand
observables z ijm (bilateral distances and a (2001), it is often hard or impossible to
dummy variable for international borders) measure the theoretical price indices in the
and the parameters λm. Another approach, data. Price indices, such as the consumer
price index, also include nontradables and
are affected by local taxes and subsidies.
37
Both authors implicitly impose a further regularity Nominal rigidities also affect observed
condition. NTB coverage ratios for each good are the
explanatory variable, so all changes in this ratio are prices, and have a big impact on relative
assumed to be equally important. prices when combined with nominal
38
A potential fourth method is to infer all bilateral exchange rate fluctuations. Anderson and
trade barriers for a group of countries or regions from the
residuals of the bilateral trade flows from the prediction of van Wincoop (2003) also argue that certain
the frictionless gravity model. The information in this trade barriers, such as a home bias in prefer-
measure would be drowned in random error, however: ences, do not show up in prices. Similarly,
there is an unboundedly large confidence interval about
the point estimates because all degrees of freedom are Deardorff and Stern (1998) explain why cer-
used up. tain NTBs affect trade but not prices.
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 713

Feenstra (2003) sums it up by writing that the regressors. More careful consideration
“the myriad of costs … involved in making of measurement error is likely to be produc-
transactions across the border are probably tive. Some recent implementations recog-
not reflected in aggregate price indices …”. nize the panel nature of the data in
This does not mean that prices of individual constructing standard errors (all bilateral
tradable goods are entirely uninformative observations from i or into j may have com-
about trade costs. We turn to that topic in mon disturbance elements).40 Improved
section 4. econometric techniques based on careful
The tax equivalent of trade barriers consideration of the error structure are like-
between i and j associated with variable m is ly to pay off. Recent literature on spatial
estimated as econometrics (e.g. H. H. Kelejian and
Ingmar Prucha 1999) may be helpful.
(z )
m /(1– )
m
ij – 1 ≈ λm (zijm – 1) / (1 –  ). (14) The error term may also reflect unobserv-
able variables in the trade cost function
This shows that we need an estimate of σ (11). If the trade cost tij is multiplied by eij,
in order to obtain an estimate of trade barri- there is again an additive error term in the
ers. Assumptions about σ can make quite a empirical gravity equation (12). In this case
difference. For example, the estimated tax the structural estimation technique dis-
equivalent is approximately nine times larg- cussed above would have to be modified
er when using σ=2 instead of σ=10. since the multilateral resistance variables
Gravity can only measure trade barriers also depend on these error terms. But the
relative to some benchmark, as noted above. second estimation technique, replacing the
The literature tends to compare trade barri- multilateral resistance variables with region
ers between countries to barriers within or country-specific dummies, is still appro-
countries, or barriers between regions to priate. Eaton and Kortum (2002) introduce
barriers within regions. This is problematic the error term in this way and adopt the sec-
since different countries or regions have dif- ond estimation method.
ferent barriers for internal trade. The Non-orthogonality of the error term has
results will also depend on the measure of two sources, omitted variables and endo-
barriers within a region or country, such as geneity. If the error term reflects omitted
the treatment of distance within a country trade frictions which are correlated with the
or region. This is essentially an aggregation included z ijm variables, it causes estimation
problem since a country or region is itself an bias. Endogeneity problems arise in several
aggregate. Head and Mayer (2001), ways. Concerned that trade can affect out-
Helliwell and Verdier (2001), and Russell put, many papers use instrumental variables
Hillberry and David Hummels (2002a) for output Yi and Yj. The most common
show that the different measures of internal instruments are population or factor endow-
distance can make a big difference for the ments. 41 With coefficients on the y’s con-
results. strained to one, the natural implementation
The error term in the empirical gravity is to make the dependent variable size-
literature is usually taken to reflect meas- adjusted trade xij–yi–yj, as Anderson and van
urement error. Trade flow data are notori- Wincoop (2003) do. Endogeneity issues also
ously rife with measurement error,39 which arise when the proxies for trade costs are
is taken to justify a normally distributed
additive error term which is orthogonal to
40
See for example James Anderson and Douglas
Marcouiller (2002).
39 41
For example, mirror-image trade flow data do not See for example Evans (2003a), Harrigan (1993), and
match. Wei (1996).
714 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

endogenous. Examples are membership in resistance terms is equal to (1–σ)ln(b) plus


currency unions or free trade agreements. the bias
Section 3.7.2 below discusses how the liter- M–N
ature has addressed endogeneity in these (1 –  ) (lnPUS – lnPCA ) (16)
specific cases. N+M
where PUS and PCA are the multilateral resist-
3.5 Estimation Bias with Traditional
ance indices for, respectively, U.S. states and
Gravity Equations
Canadian provinces. PCAPUS because
The traditional gravity equation (1) omits Canada is smaller and provinces face border
the multilateral resistance terms of the theo- barriers with trade to all of the United States.
retically consistent model (12). In the The result is that for 1 the estimate of
absence of multilateral resistance the two (1–)ln(b) is biased upwards as long as
equations are the same, with βm=λm. In that MN. This result is intuitive. If, for example,
case (z ijm)β m/(1–) is an estimate of one plus the the only within-country trade in the sample is
tax equivalent of trade barriers associated between provinces, the average size-adjusted
with this variable. This interpretation of the within-country trade is very large. The reason
results from estimating (1) is generally incor- is that relative trade barriers within Canada
rect because the z ijm are correlated with the are lower than within the United States due
multilateral resistance indices, which are to larger multilateral resistance, so that size-
themselves a function of trade barriers. adjusted trade is larger between provinces
In order to better illustrate this point, con- than between states. This point was empha-
sider the following simplified environment. sized by Anderson and van Wincoop (2003).
There are two countries, the United States The example above emphasizes size, but
and Canada, with respectively N states and estimation bias holds more generally.
M provinces. The only trade barrier is a bor- Consider the role of distance. When tij=dij bδij,
der barrier between states and provinces the gravity equation becomes (4) with the
(ignore distance and other factors generating term (1–σ)ρln(dij) added. There are two
trade barriers). In that case tij=b ij, where b is types of bias when attempting to estimate
one plus the tariff equivalent of trade barri- the border barrier b in a traditional gravity
ers associated with the border, and δ ij is equation that omits multilateral resistance.
equal to zero when two regions are located First, the distance elasticity (1–σ)ρ is gener-
in the same country and equal to one other- ally incorrectly estimated since bilateral dis-
wise. The gravity equation is then (dropping tance is correlated with the multilateral
the constant term) distance terms that are left in the error term.
Second, even when (1–σ)ρ is estimated cor-
xij = yi + y j +(1 –  ) ln( b)ij – rectly, we still obtain the same bias as in (16).
(1 –  ) ln(Pi ) – (1 –  ) ln(Pj )+ ε ij . (15) The bias results as long as the multilateral
resistance terms PCA and PUS are different.
If we ignore multilateral resistance, the Differences arise due to size, but also due to
estimate of (1–σ)ln(b) is equal to the aver- geography. For example, Canadian
age within-country size adjusted trade provinces are located on the North
minus the average cross-country size- American periphery. As a result, their dis-
adjusted trade. When there are N observa- tances from main trading partners tend to be
tions of trade within the United States relatively large, so that PCAPUS. A
(between states) and M observations of McCallum type gravity equation with N=0
trade within Canada (between provinces), it would then imply a positive U.S.-Canada
is easy to check that the estimate of border barrier even when none existed. If
(1–σ)ln(b) when ignoring the multilateral the geographic size of Canada were much
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 715

smaller, so that trading distances between of directly observed trade costs. Hummels
provinces are much smaller, PCA would be estimates (18) for 1992 data on sectoral
smaller and the bias from estimating the imports of six countries from a large number
border barrier b with McCallum’s equation of other countries. Multilateral resistance
(N=0) would be smaller. Serge Coulombe terms are replaced by country dummies for
(2002) emphasizes the role of these topolog- each sector. The estimated elasticity rises
ical issues related to the special structure of from 4.79 for one-digit SITC data to 8.26 for
the regions.42 four-digit SITC data.
Head and Ries (2001) adopt a similar
3.6 The Elasticity of Substitution
method. They consider two countries, the
Estimates of trade costs from trade flows United States and Canada, and assume that
are very sensitive to assumptions about the the only trade barrier is a border-related bar-
elasticity of substitution , so a look at the rier, which varies across three-digit industry
evidence is worthwhile. Although many data from 1990 to 1995. They estimate
papers have estimated this elasticity from (–1)ln(bit), with bit equal to one plus the tar-
bilateral trade flow models, only a few have iff equivalent of the border barrier in indus-
used theory-based gravity. try i at time t.43 They then decompose the
One way to obtain an estimate of  is to border barrier into tariff and nontariff com-
use information from directly observed trade ponents, bit=(1+tarit)(1+NTBit). It is assumed
barriers. Harrigan (1993), Hummels (2001a), that ln(1+NTBit)=Kt+it, where Kt is a time
Head and Ries (2001), and Baier and dummy and it is a zero mean random distur-
Bergstrand (2001) all combine estimation of bance. By regressing the estimate of (1–)bit
theoretical gravity equations with informa- on a time dummy and ln(1+tarit) they obtain
tion about tariffs and/or transport costs. an estimate of both  and average nontariff
Hummels (2001a) assumes barriers across industries. This approach is
M similar to that in Hummels (2001a) in that it
tij = ( fij + tarij ) ∏ (zijm) m (17) uses evidence on observed trade barriers to
m =1 tie down the elasticity. Head and Ries obtain
where tarij is the tariff rate and fij is a freight an estimate of  of 11.4 when assuming that
factor, equal to one plus the tax equivalent NTBit is the same for all industries and 7.9
of freight costs. The gravity equation then when allowing for industry fixed effects.
becomes (dropping the constant term) Baier and Bergstrand (2001) estimate a
theoretical gravity equation where tariffs and
xij = yi + yi +(1 –  ) ln( fij + tarij ) transport costs are the only trade barriers.
(18) They use aggregate trade data for OECD
M
+∑(1-  ) m ln(zijm) –(1-  ) ln(Pi )–(1-  ) ln(Pj ). countries and focus on changes in trade
m =1 flows from the period 1958–60 to the period
The elasticity of substitution can now be 1986–88. Their point estimate of  is 6.4.
estimated through the coefficient on the log Harrigan (1993) implicitly models the
impact on full trade costs of directly observed
42
While we have focused the discussion on U.S.- trade costs as fij(1+tarij) and finds significantly
Canada, estimation bias when estimating the traditional different coefficients on lnfij and ln(1+tarij) in
gravity equation of course holds quite generally. Some the gravity regressions. His restricted regres-
authors have estimated both equations to allow for easy
comparison. For example, Rose and van Wincoop (2001) sions report most elasticity point estimates for
find that the estimated trade barriers associated with the
use of different currencies are much lower when estimating
43
the theoretical gravity equation. Minondo (2001) finds that In this setup the estimate is obtained as a simple ana-
the estimate of border barriers for European trade is much lytical function of the shares that both countries spend on
lower when estimating the theoretical gravity equation. their own goods.
716 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

28 sectors in the range from five to ten, with 3.7 The Size of International Trade Barriers
four above and one below.
An entirely different way to estimate  is In this section we report some results for
to simply estimate demand equations direct- international trade barriers, computed as the
ly, using data on prices. But in general one ratio of total trade barriers relative to domes-
estimates some combination of demand and tic trade barriers: tij/tii. We first present sum-
supply relationships, the classic simultaneity mary measures of all international trade
problem. Feenstra (1994) is nonetheless barriers and then discuss results which
able to obtain an estimate of the demand decompose border barriers into several like-
elasticity by using the fact that the second ly sources. All our calculations are based on
moments of demand and supply changes point estimates from gravity studies which
(their variances and covariance) have a lin- differ somewhat in their list of trade cost
ear relationship that depends on demand proxies, in the data used, and in the assump-
and supply elasticities. By assuming that tions used to construct standard errors.
supply elasticities are the same for all coun- 3.7.1 Summary Measures
tries, a cross-section of the second moments
allows for estimation of the elasticities. This Part of the empirical gravity literature
estimation method therefore requires panel reports the tax equivalent of summary meas-
data and is applied by Feenstra to U.S. ures of trade barriers, those associated with
imports from 1967 to 1987 from various distance and the presence of borders. Table
countries for six manufactured products. 7 presents the results of a number of studies.
The products are highly disaggregated, finer The table indicates whether results are
than eight-digit SITC. The estimated elas- based on the traditional gravity equation (1)
ticities range from three for typewriters to or the theory-based gravity equation (12). It
8.4 for TV receivers. also indicates whether numbers are based on
Eaton and Kortum (2002) adopt yet aggregate trade data or disaggregate (sec-
another entirely different approach to obtain toral) trade data. In the latter case table 7
an estimate of . From (8) it follows that reports the average trade barrier across sec-
tors. Column four reports the tax equivalent
xii − xij − yi + y j of trade barriers reported by the authors,
 −1 = . (19)
ln(tij ) − ln(tii ) + ln(Pi ) − ln(Pj ) with the corresponding elasticity  in brack-
ets. In order to make results more compara-
The numerator consists of observables. The ble across papers, the final three columns
denominator is approximated as follows. re-compute the trade barriers for elasticities
Using data on retail price levels for fifty of five, eight, and ten. These are representa-
manufactured products in nineteen coun- tive of the elasticities estimated in the litera-
tries, they approximate ln(Pj)–ln(Pi) as the ture. In some cases two numbers are shown,
arithmetic average of the log-price differen- with the lower number applying to countries
tials between j and i for all 50 goods. Using that share the same language and border.
the fact that log-price differentials between j The first three rows report results for total
and i are bounded above by ln(tij)–ln(tii), they international trade barriers. The results are
estimate ln(tij)–ln(tii) as the maximum of log- sensitive to the elasticity of substitution. For
price differentials between i and j. The example, the U.S.-Canada trade barrier
parameter θ=–1 can then be estimated as based on the Head and Ries (2001) study
the average of the ratio on the right hand side ranges from 35 percent for =10 to 97 per-
of (19). They find θ=8.28, so that =9.28. cent for =5. From now on we will focus the
Overall the literature leads us to conclude discussion on the intermediate value of =8.
that  is likely to be in the range of five to ten. In that case the findings by Head and Ries
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 717

TABLE 7
TARIFF EQUIVALENT OF TRADE COSTS

reported  5  8  10
method data
by authors
all trade barriers
Head and Ries (2001) new disaggr. 48 97 47 35
U.S.-Canada, 1990-1995 ( 7.9)
Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) new aggr 91 46 35
U.S.-Canada, 1993
Eaton and Kortum (2002) new aggr. 48–63 123–174 58–78 43–57
19 OECD countries, 1990 ( 9.28)
750-1500 miles apart
national border barriers
Wei (1996) trad. aggr. 5 26–76 14–38 11–29
19 OECD countries, 1982-1994 ( 20)
Evans (2003a) trad. disaggr. 45 45 30 23
8 OECD countries, 1990 ( 5)
Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) new aggr. 48 48 26 19
U.S.-Canada, 1993 ( 5)
Eaton and Kortum (2002) new aggr. 32–45 77–116 39–55 29–41
19 OECD countries, 1990 ( 9.28)
language barrier
Eaton and Kortum (2002) new aggr. 6 12 7 5
19 OECD countries, 1990 ( 9.28)
Hummels (1999) new disaggr. 11 12 8 6
160 countries, 1994 ( 6.3)
currency barrier
Rose and van Wincoop (2001) new aggr. 26 26 14 11
143 countries, 1980 and 1990 ( 5)

Notes: This table reports findings in the gravity literature on the tariff equivalent of a variety of factors that
increase trade barriers. The second column indicates whether estimates are based on the traditional gravity equa-
tion —“trad.’’— or the theory-based gravity equation —“new’’. The third column indicates whether estimation is
based on aggregate or disaggregate data. The numbers in the fourth column have been reported by the authors
for various elasticities of substitution s that are shown in brackets. For results based on disaggregated trade data,
the average trade barrier across sectors is reported (for Hummels (1999) only sectors with statistically significant
estimates are used). The numbers in the last three columns re-compute these results for alternative values of .
For results based on disaggregate data, the trade barriers are first re-computed for each sector and then averaged
(with the exception of Head and Ries (2001), who only report average trade barriers across all sectors). When two
numbers are reported, the lower number applies to countries that share a border and have a common language.

(2001) imply an average U.S.-Canada trade barrier for 1993, virtually the same as Head
barrier of 47 percent based on average and Ries (2001). This is calculated as the
results from 1990 to 1995. Based on trade-weighted average barrier for trade
Anderson and van Wincoop’s (2003) results, between states and provinces, divided by the
their estimated trade cost parameters with trade-weighted average barrier for trade
=8 imply a 46-percent U.S.-Canada trade within the United States and Canada. Eaton
718 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

and Kortum (2002) report results for nine- international trade barriers associated with
teen OECD countries for 1990. For coun- borders. For =8, the estimated U.S.-
tries that are 750–1500 miles apart the trade Canada border barrier from Anderson and
barrier is 58–78 percent. The lower 58 per- van Wincoop (2003) is 26 percent. With a
cent number, which applies to countries that total barrier of 46 percent, it implies a dis-
share a border and language, is not much tance related barrier of 16 percent
larger than the estimates of the U.S.-Canada (1.16=1.46/1.26). This is not much different
barrier. Summarizing, international trade than direct estimates of trade costs reported
barriers are in the range of 40–80 percent in section II: the total transport cost estimate
for a representative elasticity estimate. for the United States is 21 percent
Edward Balistreri and Russell Hillberry (1.21=1.107∗1.09, with 10.7-percent freight
(2002) argue that trade barrier estimates cost and 9-percent time cost). In our repre-
from these types of studies are implausibly sentative total trade cost calculation, we
large. Based on parameter estimates in assume all effects of distance are captured in
Anderson and van Wincoop (2003), they the transport cost number (Hummels reports
report on trade barriers for Alberta and partial success in testing this hypothesis with
Alabama relative to the barrier of trade with- his disaggregated data.)
in Maryland, which has the lowest trade bar- Although based on traditional gravity
rier. As an illustration, they report a trade equations, estimates of border barriers in
barrier between Alabama and Quebec of Wei (1996) and Evans (2003a) are not too far
1684 percent for =3 and 322 percent for off, respectively 14–38 percent and 30 per-
=5. These numbers are much larger than cent. Both apply to OECD countries. The
the 46 percent U.S.-Canada trade barrier results from Eaton and Kortum (2002) are a
reported above. There are several reasons bit higher, 39–55 percent. Eaton and Kortum
for this discrepancy. First, elasticities of do not actually report barriers associated
three and five are low relative to estimates in with national borders. The 39–55 percent
the literature reported above. If we set =8, barrier applies to trade costs of countries
the Alabama-Quebec barrier drops to 133 0–375 miles apart relative to domestic trade
percent relative to the Maryland barrier. costs. Since even for those countries the
Second, Balistreri and Hillberry report trade average distance is larger than within coun-
barriers relative to Maryland instead of rela- tries, it overstates a bit the barrier associated
tive to average domestic trade barriers as in with borders. But our own calculations based
the papers discussed above. They therefore on estimates from Anderson and van
also capture trade barriers within the United Wincoop (2003) indicate that this overstate-
States, which are known to be very large ment is only about 6 percent. Summarizing,
based on the direct evidence on distribution barriers associated with national borders are
costs reported in section 2. The trade barri- in the range of 25–50 percent for a represen-
er for Alabama-Quebec trade relative to tative elasticity estimate.44
within-U.S. trade is 61 percent. The latter is All the trade costs estimates reported above
still a bit above the 46-percent U.S.-Canada are based on point estimates. Standard errors
barrier reported above, since Alabama and tend to be quite small, though, as the empiri-
Quebec are farther apart than the average cal fit of gravity equations is generally very
state-province pair. strong. For example, a 95-percent confidence
International trade barriers can be decom-
posed into barriers associated with national
44
borders and barriers associated with geo- There is also a small literature that has documented
border barriers at the level of states within the United
graphic frictions such as distance. The next States. See Wolf (2000a,b), Hillberry and Hummels
set of rows in table 7 report the magnitude of (2002a), and Daniel Millimet and Thomas Osang (2001).
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 719

interval of U.S.-Canada border barriers based currency union trade three times as much.
on Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) is 23 The finding also applies to historical data.
percent–28 percent. Standard errors of trade Using data from the nineteenth and early
costs associated with distance are even smaller. twentieth centuries, Antoni Estevadeordal,
Brian Frantz, and Alan Taylor (2003) and
3.7.2 Decomposition of Border Barriers
Ernesto Lopez-Cordova and Christopher
It is of great interest to better understand Meissner (2003) document a big impact on
what blocks build these border barriers. We trade of belonging to the same commodity
saw in section 2 that policy barriers, in the regime, such as the gold standard. Rose
form of tariffs and NTBs, amount to no more (2004) considers the evidence from nineteen
than about 8 percent for OECD countries,45 studies on the effect of currency unions on
suggesting important additional barriers trade and concludes that the combined evi-
associated with national borders. Estimates dence from all studies suggests a doubling of
of five different types of trade frictions are trade if countries belong to a currency union.
associated with national borders. One problem with this evidence is that it
Language Barriers. Table 7 reports esti- is unclear why a currency union raises trade
mates from Eaton and Kortum (2002) and levels so much. There are small costs
Hummels (2001a) on language-related barri- involved in exchanging currencies. There is
ers. They both follow the common approach substantial consensus that the impact of
of introducing a dummy variable that is one exchange rate volatility on trade is very small
if two countries have a common language at best, with even the sign uncertain; hence
and zero otherwise. Results from both papers the volatility-suppressing effect of currency
imply a tax equivalent associated with speak- unions should not raise trade much.
ing different languages of about 7 percent Another potential problem is endogeneity.
when =8. Countries may join a currency union because
Currency Barriers. The use of different they have close trade relationships rather
currencies may pose a barrier to trade as than the other way around. The endogeneity
well. Rose and van Wincoop (2001) intro- problem is well-recognized in the literature.
duce a dummy variable that is equal to one Anecdotal evidence on this issue is mixed.
when two countries use the same currency Rose (2000) discusses anecdotal evidence
(are part of a currency union) and equal to suggesting that trade does not play an impor-
zero otherwise. Based on data for 143 coun- tant role in the decision to join a currency
tries, the estimated tariff equivalent associat- union, but Estevadeordal et.al. (2003) discuss
ed with using different currencies is 14 an example where it does appear to have mat-
percent when =8. tered. A second approach is to use instru-
While Rose and van Wincoop (2001) is the ments. Rose (2000) uses various instruments
only paper that computes the tariff equiva- associated with inflation and continues to find
lent of the reduction in trade barriers from that currency unions have a significant effect
joining a currency union, by now a large on trade. Alberto Alesina, Robert Barro, and
body of papers has documented a big posi- Silvana Tenreyro (2002) and Barro and
tive impact of currency unions on trade. Tenreyro (2002) also adopt an IV approach.
Rose (2000) estimates a traditional gravity Using a probit analysis, they first compute the
equation using data for 186 countries from probability that a country adopts each of four
1970 to 1990 and finds that countries in a potential anchor currencies.46 For any two
46
The probability depends on exogenous factors, such
45
Recall that Messerlin (2001) reports a 7.7 percent as various size-related measures, distance from the anchor
arithmetic average protection rate in industrial goods for currency country, and various dummy variables such as
the European Union. common language with the anchor currency country.
720 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

countries i and j, the probability of belonging However, their currency blocs have fixed
to the same currency union is then ∑ 4c =1 picpjc, exchange rate systems rather than a single
where pic is the probability that country i currency, so that it is not evidence about
adopts anchor currency c. This is used as an currency unions.
instrument for the currency union dummy. Information Barriers. Border costs associ-
They find that the impact of currency unions ated with information barriers are potential-
on trade remains large and significant. ly important. This is documented by several
Christian Broda and John Romalis (2003) authors. Richard Portes and Helene Rey
also adopt an instrumental variables tech- (2002) first estimate a traditional gravity
nique, but instead find that endogeneity is equation (1), regressing bilateral trade on
important. They argue that commodities GDPs, per capita GDPs, and distance. Then
trade should not be affected by currency they add two information variables: a size-
unions. If this is the case, commodities trade adjusted volume of telephone traffic and the
can be used as an instrument in a regression size-adjusted number of branches of the
of a currency union dummy on total trade. importing country’s banks located in the
The resulting error term of this regression is exporter’s country. Both coefficients are pos-
used as an instrument for currency unions in itive and highly significant. Moreover, the
a regression of manufacturing trade on a cur- coefficient on bilateral distance is reduced
rency union dummy. They find that the coef- from -0.55 to -0.23.
ficient on this currency union instrument is James Rauch and Vitor Trindade (2002)
small and insignificant. have conducted the most careful work so far.
Another approach to deal with endogene- They argue that information barriers to
ity uses time series evidence. If a country trade may be reduced when two countries
joins a currency union because of close trade have a substantial Chinese network, proxied
ties, then trade is already high when the as the product of the population percent-
country joins the currency union and does ages of Chinese ethnicity in the two coun-
not rise subsequent to that. Reuven Glick tries. They estimate a traditional gravity
and Andrew Rose (2002) examine data for equation for both “reference price” goods
200 countries from 1948 to 1997 and find and differentiated goods which do not have
that countries joining or exiting a currency reference prices.47 The trade-increasing
union during this period experienced effect of the Chinese network variable is
respectively a near-doubling or halving of larger for the differentiated goods than for
bilateral trade. In contrast, Albrecht Ritschl the reference price goods. The difference
and Nikolaus Wolf (2003) find evidence that between them may be taken to represent
endogeneity is important. After the Great the effects of information transfer using the
Depression, most countries went off the network, with the trade increasing effect of
gold standard and new regional currency networks on the reference price goods rep-
blocs were formed. Ritschl and Wolf find resenting the value of the network to infor-
that trade among members of these new mal contract enforcement. Pushing
currency blocs is two to three times as high inference based on their results to the limit,
as trade among countries that do not belong we calculate the information-cost-reducing
to the same currency bloc. But they show value of strong Chinese immigrant links
that trade among countries of these future (where both partners have a larger than 1
currency areas was already high in the percent Chinese population) to be worth as
1920s, a decade before the new currency
blocs were formed, and that the actual for- 47
For the reference price goods they also distinguish
mation of the currency areas did not raise between goods traded on organized exchanges and those
bilateral trade among their members. not so traded.
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 721

much as a 47-percent increase in trade.48 GDPs, distance, remoteness, and a border


Earlier work done on the effect of Chinese dummy. She finds that the coefficient on the
immigrant links on the bilateral trade of the border dummy does not drop once a variety
United States by Gould (1994) found larger of industry-specific variables related to the
effects, while Head and Ries (1998) found importance and difficulty of information
much more modest effects in the bilateral transfers are included (e.g. the frequency of
trade of Canada. technical service). More careful modeling of
With an elasticity of substitution of eight, the underlying information costs in future
these Chinese networks save an information work will probably be illuminating.
cost worth 6 percent. This may be both a Contracting Costs and Insecurity. The
lower bound and an upper bound to the tax costs of writing contracts and enforcing
equivalent of information barriers. It is a them or self-insuring the costs of default on
lower bound in that information barriers are unenforced contracts are all plausibly larger
likely to be important even if two countries across borders. 49 Evans (2001) provides evi-
have populations with the same ethnic back- dence that internal contracting costs within a
ground. It is an upper bound to the extent firm are much lower than external contract-
that one believes that other factors are ing costs. Specifically, the tax equivalent of
picked up. For example, the results are the trading costs of a foreign affiliate of a
largely driven by countries with very large U.S. multinational with unaffiliated U.S.
Chinese populations, such as Taiwan, Hong firms is on average 37 percent higher (for a
Kong, China, Singapore, and Malaysia. Since demand elasticity of five) than the trading
Rauch and Trindade estimate a traditional costs with its U.S. parent. She provides evi-
gravity equation, they may not properly con- dence that proprietary assets associated with
trol for the large distance of these countries transactions (e.g. the sale of a brand with a
from the United States and Europe. It is also good reputation or a good that is technolog-
possible that strong historical trade ties drive ically advanced) play an important role in
the results, as would be the case in trade this result. Since the goals of unaffiliated
models where history matters. Evidence by firms are different, there are greater risks
Evans (2003a) also suggest that the 6-per- involved in selling goods that involve sub-
cent information barrier is an overstatement. stantial proprietary assets, which would
She estimates a traditional gravity equation involve larger contracting costs.
for OECD bilateral trade flow data for Rauch and Trindade (2002) can be inter-
twelve industries, with trade dependent on preted to provide an inference about con-
tracting and enforcement cost. Networks
provide a kind of enforcement through sanc-
48
Table 9 of Rauch and Trindade (2002) reports the tions which substitutes for weak internation-
trade volume effect of changing the Chinese network vari- al enforcement of formal contracts. Their
able from zero to its sample mean value for two subsets of
trading partners, those with Chinese population shares finding of an 89 percent trade increasing
greater than 1 percent and those with Chinese population effect of networks for reference price goods
shares less than 1 percent. For the smaller share group, the is hard to interpret as information costs and
volume effects are modest—6.2 percent for the differenti-
ated products and somewhat smaller for the reference may be a result of contracting costs. But
priced products. For the subset of countries with larger since these goods presumably have high
Chinese population shares, the effect of switching on the elasticities of substitution, the tax equivalent
sample mean of the Chinese network variable is a 178 per-
cent rise in trade for differentiated goods, a 128 percent is likely small (3 percent when =20).
rise in trade in reference priced goods, and a 89 percent
rise in trade in goods on organized exchanges. We attrib-
ute the difference between the impact on differentiated
49
goods and goods traded in organized exchanges as a result See Anderson (2000) for a discussion of the literature
of information costs: 47 percent=100∗(2.78/1.89). on this topic.
722 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

Anderson and Marcouiller (2002) show sign. These insignificant results may be
that insecurity, associated both with contrac- explained by failure to control for the endo-
tual enforcement problems and with cor- geneity of NTBs suggested by political
ruption, lowers trade substantially. Using economy. Daniel Trefler (1993) shows that
survey data taken from businessmen by the the effect of NTBs on U.S. trade with the
World Economic Forum as an index of insti- rest of the world is increased in absolute
tutional quality and making institutional value by an order of magnitude when con-
quality (both contractual enforcement and trolling for the endogeneity of NTBs with
corruption) an argument of the trade cost instruments commonly used in the political
function, they implement a variant of the economy literature. In contrast, in a related
theoretically consistent gravity model.50 approach which uses a set of both rich and
They report the effect of raising the quality poor countries, Jong-Wha Lee and Phillip
of institutions from the Latin American Swagel (1997) jointly estimate an equation
average (for the seven Latin American coun- relating sectoral imports to trade barriers
tries in the sample—Argentina, Brazil, and an equation relating sectoral NTBs to
Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Peru, and various driving factors from political econo-
Venezuela) to the E.U. average. Combined my. Once appropriately controlling for
with their maximum likelihood point esti- industry and country dummies in the trade
mate of the elasticity of substitution equal to regression, they find no evidence that
eight, the implied tax equivalent of relative- NTBs affect trade flows. The difference
ly low quality institutions is 16 percent. between their results and Trefler’s may
Insecurity is therefore an important trade partly reflect differences across countries
barrier for developing countries. It plays less which are not controlled for, and partly the
of a role for industrialized countries on richer set of political economy variables
which trade barrier estimates in table 7 are which Trefler is able to deploy for the
based. An experiment based on their esti- United States alone.
mates that raises the U.S. security level to There is extensive evidence that free trade
that of Singapore, the highest in the data, agreements and customs unions increase
implies a tax equivalent of 3 percent for an trade and therefore reduce trade barriers
elasticity of eight. (e.g. Jeffrey Frankel, Ernesto Stein, and
Nontariff Policy Barriers. Harrigan Shang-Jin Wei 1998; Frankel and Wei 1997),
(1993), Head and Mayer (2000), and Chen but it is less clear what elements of these
(2002) consider the role of nontariff barri- trade agreements play a role (tariffs, NTBs,
ers in accounting for the impact of borders or regulatory issues). As noted above, all
on trade levels. The last two papers do not gravity model analyses of NTBs and regional
find evidence of a positive relationship trade agreements impose very strong and
between sectoral estimates of the impact of presumptively implausible regularity restric-
borders on trade and sectoral data for non- tions on the effect of nontariff barriers and
tariff barriers. Harrigan (1993) estimates customs-union membership upon trade vol-
the traditional gravity equation (1) for 1983 ume. Moreover, most of this evidence is
bilateral trade data for 28 industries among cross-section evidence, which raises causality
OECD countries and also finds that nontar- issues. Baier and Bergstrand (2003) control
iff barriers have little effect on trade, with for endogenous regional trade agreements
coefficients sometimes having the wrong and greatly increase the implied magnitude
of the membership effect. Time series evi-
50 dence, in contrast, suggests that free trade
They divide imports of j from i by U.S. imports from
i, which cancels the exporter price index. The importer rel- agreements are less important than in cross-
ative price index is approximated with a Törnqvist index. section findings. Although Helliwell (1998,
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 723

1999) estimates a substantial drop in the bor- 3.8.1 Ideal Aggregation


der effect for U.S.-Canada trade since the
1988 free trade agreement, Coulombe Anderson and Neary (2003) develop an
(2002) shows that the same downward trend ideal summary index of trade costs, defined
took place already before 1988 and applies as the uniform trade cost that leads to the
to the entire sample 1981–2000. Similarly, same aggregate trade level. The ideal index
Head and Mayer (2000) document a gradual idea can be applied to aggregation in sever-
drop in European border barriers from al dimensions, each providing answers to
1976 to 1995, with no significant drop after sensible questions. In the context of gravity
the implementation of the Single European models, it is natural to consider ideal aggre-
Act of 1986. gation over trading partners (e.g., aggregate
Summary. Assuming an 8-percent policy tijk over importers j for an export trade cost
related barrier (based on direct evidence index) and aggregation over commodities
from tariffs and NTBs), a 7-percent language (e.g., aggregate tijk over k for a given link
barrier, 14-percent currency barrier, a 6-per- from i to j).
cent information cost barrier, and a 3-per- Summary Trade Costs for Each Region.
cent security barrier, overall border barriers The multilateral indices {Pjk, jk} are elegant-
are 44 percent. This falls within the estimat- ly simple summary measures of trade costs
ed 25–50 percent range reported for OECD for a particular region j with all its trading
countries in table 7. The discussion above partners (including the region itself). Pjk is
qualifies these magnitudes as quite rough. an average import trade cost (including
imports from oneself) and  jk an average
3.8 Aggregation Issues
export trade cost (including exports to one-
The gravity equations (5)–(7) are the basis self). To see this, note that if, hypothetically,
for discussion of aggregation issues: the actual bilateral cost set {tijk} is replaced
1− k with {Pjk ik} the equilibrium price indices
Ek Y k  t k  themselves remain the same and aggregate
X = j k i  k ij k 
k
ij
Y  Pj  i  trade flows ∑iXijk and ∑jXijk also remain
unchanged.
1– k To illustrate, table 8 reports multilateral
 tk  Ekj resistance for U.S. states and Canadian
k 1– k
( )
i = ∑ j  ijk 
 Pj  Yk provinces based on Anderson and van
Wincoop (2003), assuming =8. In their
1– k model Pi=i, so the import and export
 tk  Yik trade cost measures are the same. We use
k 1– k
(Pi ) = ∑i  ijk  .
 j  Yk the approach of Balistreri and Hillberry
(2002) by normalizing trade costs within
There are two different aggregation issues. Maryland as zero and therefore dividing all
First, estimated trade costs at a disaggregate trade barriers by that of trade within
level overwhelm the comprehension of the Maryland. Note that Canadian provinces
analyst. Like others, we report atheoretic have systematically higher trade costs
averages in this survey, but an ideal summary because they face the border cost on much
index is desirable. Second, in practice gravity more of their trade with the U.S. states and
equations are estimated from aggregate data; because they are more distant from more
even sectoral data are not at the level of detail important sources of supply. Note also that
of reality. Aggregation bias results from esti- populous northeastern U.S. states and
mating trade costs with aggregate data when California face the lowest trade costs,
trade costs vary at the disaggregate level. explained by the geographic advantage of
TABLE 8
TRADE COST INDICES FOR U.S. AND CANADIAN REGIONS

Multilateral
resistance

Provinces
Alberta 1.65
British Columbia 1.55
Manitoba 1.65
New Brunswick 1.62
Newfoundland 1.74
Nova Scotia 1.63
Ontario 1.51
Prince Edward Island 1.67
Quebec 1.53
Saskatchewan 1.66
States
Alabama 1.39
Arizona 1.49
California 1.31
Florida 1.38
Georgia 1.37
Idaho 1.49
Illinois 1.35
Indiana 1.36
Kentucky 1.37
Louisiana 1.41
Maine 1.43
Maryland 1.31
Massachusetts 1.33
Michigan 1.37
Minnesota 1.42
Missouri 1.38
Montana 1.50
New Hampshire 1.39
New Jersey 1.33
New York 1.30
North Carolina 1.37
North Dakota 1.47
Ohio 1.35
Pennsylvania 1.33
Tennessee 1.38
Texas 1.41
Vermont 1.40
Virginia 1.35
Washington 1.43
Wisconsin 1.39
Rest of USA 1.50

Notes: This table reports multilateral resistance indices for U.S. states and Canadian provinces, based on data and
trade cost estimates from Anderson and van Wincoop (2003). The assumed elasticity of substitution is 8.
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 725

being close to a greater share of the output detailed data. To illustrate, again consider a
produced.51 simple example. Assume that there are two
Aggregating Across Trading Partners. equally sized countries (Y1=Y2) and K sec-
Since bilateral trade barriers vary across tors. Each country spends a fraction θk on
countries, a summary measure of interna- sector k, Eik=θkYi, and produces half of the
tional trade barriers is useful. A natural output in each sector. The only trade barrier
aggregator for inward or outward shipments is a border barrier between the two coun-
replaces all tij where i≠ j with a uniform tries that varies across industries: t12k=bk. This
inward or outward international trade barri- example again has the advantage of closed
er that leaves aggregate international trade form solutions for the multilateral resistance
unchanged. indices. It is easy to check that for each sec-
To illustrate this, consider a simple exam- tor Pk=k. When raised to be power 1–k
ple. There are N countries, with N an odd they are equal to (0.5+0.5bk1–k)0.5. In our
integer. Each produce a fraction 1/N of the example the uniform barrier b that leads to
output of industry k. The countries are even- the same aggregate trade between the two
ly spaced on a circle, with trade barriers countries can be solved from
between them proportional to their shortest
distance on the circle. There are no trade
K
(bk )1+ k K
b1+ k
barriers within countries. These simplifying ∑θ k
k =1
= ∑ kθ
1 – (bk )1− k k =1 1 – b1− k
. (21)
assumptions imply that inward and outward
summary barriers are the same and common Starting from a benchmark where all bar-
across countries, and that Pi=i=P. If bi is riers are equal to b̄ and all elasticities are
the trade barrier for two countries that are i equal to ¯, we now introduce variation in the
steps away from each other on the circle, it is barriers and elasticities such that the indus-
easily checked that the uniform internation- try size weighted averages
al trade cost index b that leads to the same
∑ ∑
N N
 bk and
k =1 k k =1 k
 k
level of international trade can be solved
from (dropping industry subscripts) remain constant at respectively b̄and ¯. The
function B(b,) b1-/(1+b1-) is decreasing

0.5 N– 0.5
bi1– and convex in b. Then Jensen’s Inequality
b1− = i =1
. (20)
0.5N – 0.5 implies that for a mean-preserving spread in
{bk}, b< b̄. Since the absolute effect on aggre-
Since b1– is convex in b, it follows that b is
gate trade is larger when reducing a trade
less than the average trade barrier. More
barrier than raising a trade barrier, the ideal
(omitted) algebra, based on the substitution
index gives relatively more weight to low
effect, shows that b is larger than the trade-
sectoral trade barriers. Variation in  given a
weighted average barrier. The ideal index
uniform b has no effect, from (21).
therefore lies in between the arithmetic
Simultaneous variation of {bk,k} requires
average and trade-weighted average barrier
us to consider covariation. Consider margin-
in this example.
al variation holding λ=var()/var(b) con-
Aggregating Across Goods. Aggregation
stant. We can use a second order Taylor
across goods is useful for summarizing
expansion of (21) to show the following:
b/(var(b))=–1+2λcorr(b,) (22)
51
A more subtle pattern may be discerned. Location
near a border should, all else equal, raise multilateral where 1 and 2 are two positive constants.
resistance since the border cannot matter as much for a If the elasticity is low exactly in sectors with
state located far from the boder where distance will natu-
rally impede trade. (This is observable only in states, since high barriers, the impact on aggregate trade
all Canadian provinces are on the border.) of these high barriers is reduced, leading to
726 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

Distance Elasticity of
Trade Costs (ρ)
0.6

0.5

0.4

0.3

0.2

0.1

0
0 2 4 6 8 10
Elasticity of Substitution (σ)

Figure 1. Elasticity of Substitution versus Distance Elasticity of Trade Costs

a smaller uniform barrier b. There is evi- barriers. Using 1990 OECD country data
dence that a negative correlation is realistic, for twelve industries, she estimates relative-
which reinforces the conclusion that the ly high values of b, with b the tariff equiva-
uniform b is lower than b̄.52 lent of border barriers, for industries with a
As an illustration, figure 1 graphs trade high degree of product differentiation (low
barriers against price elasticities for findings elasticity). This can only be the case if
based on table 4 in Hummels (2001a). industries with low elasticities tend to have
Hummels assumes tijk =dij k mijk, where dij is relatively high border barriers.53
distance and mijk stands for trade barriers Finally, there is also reason to believe
unrelated to distance. An increase in k that the industry size weighted average
b̄= ∑k =1 k bk is lower than a simple average
N
implies higher distance related trade barri-
ers. Figure 1 shows that sectors with a high trade barrier. Head and Ries (2001) point
distance elasticity k of trade costs tend to out that U.S.-Canada trade barriers tend to
have low elasticities of substitution, which is be low in relatively large sectors such as
consistent with corr(b,)<0. Similar conclu- motor vehicles. This will further reduce the
sions can be drawn for language and adja- uniform barrier below a simple average
cency as factors driving trade costs in barrier across industries. Hillberry (2002)
Hummels (2001a). Evans (2003a) provides shows that for U.S.-Canada trade, a simple
similar evidence for border related trade average border-related barrier across

52 53
Simulation with discrete changes confirms the result Chen (2002) finds that for European trade there is no
from (22): negative correlation increases b̄– b, positive cor- relationship between b and the Rauch and Trindade
relation can change its sign, and the magnitude of b̄– b can (2002) measure of product differentiation, again pointing to
be substantial. a negative relationship between b and  across industries.
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 727

industries is twice as large as an output X12


weighted average. ( bˆ )1− = 0.5 0.5
.
X X 22
11
The example shows that there are several
reasons to believe that an ideal index of trade Substitution of the theoretical expressions
barriers that aggregates over sectors will be for X11, X22 and X12 yields
lower than a simple average of sectoral trade
barriers. This suggests that arithmetic aver- (bˆ )1− K
bk1− k
age trade barriers reported in section 2, as
= ∑ 
1 + (bˆ )1− k =1 1 + b k
k 1−
. (25)
k
well as the numbers in table 7 based on stud-
ies from disaggregate data, overstate an ideal Together with (21) it follows that the esti-
index of trade barriers. How much they over- mate b̂ based on the aggregate gravity equa-
state the ideal index is unknown and is there- tion is equal to the ideal index b when all
fore an obvious area for future research. price elasticities are identical and we set  at
that level. Although the assumption of iden-
3.8.2 Estimation Bias and Aggregation
tical elasticities across sectors is not realistic,
Estimation based on aggregate data pre- this result nonetheless provides important
tends that there is only one border barrier b guidance. There is confusion in the litera-
and one elasticity  while international trade ture about whether one should use elastici-
barriers vary across goods. Consider aggre- ties based on aggregate data or disaggregate
gate estimation with multilateral resistance data when interpreting estimation results
indices replaced by country dummies. The based on aggregate data. It makes a big dif-
aggregate gravity equation can be written as ference because price elasticities based on
aggregate data are much smaller. The exam-
xij=i+j+(–1)ln(b) ij+ij (23) ple shows that the elasticity of substitution at
the more aggregate level, between sectors, is
where i and j are country-specific con-
entirely irrelevant. One should choose elas-
stants that depend on the multilateral resist-
ticities at a sufficiently disaggregated level at
ance variables, and ij is one if i=j and zero
which firms truly compete.
otherwise.
If the price elasticities differ across sectors,
First consider again the example above
then we need to choose  below the average
where the border barriers vary across coun-
across sectors in order for the estimate b̂ to
try pairs. With N countries, the OLS esti-
be equal to the uniform index b. If we
mate of ln(b1-) is
choose  to be equal to the average elastici-
1 1 N ty across sectors, then the estimate b̂ would
ln( bˆ 1− ) = ∑
N 2 − N i≠ j
x ij − ∑ xii
N i =1
be lower than the uniform barrier b. The
magnitude of this bias is unknown.
In the examples above the production and

0.5 N– 0.5
ln(bi1− ) spending structure—the set {Yik,Eik}—is
= i =1
. (24)
0.5N – 0.5 unrelated to trade barriers. In general though
the production and spending structure is
Together with (20) and the concavity of endogenous and depends on trade costs. This
the log-transformation, it follows that the can generate another important source of
estimated border barrier is larger than the aggregation bias, as discussed in Hillberry
ideal index if we know the elasticity . (2002) and Hillberry and Hummels (2002b).
Next consider the two-country example They consider models with an endogenous
with varying border barriers across indus- production structure, whereby either (i)
tries. In this case the OLS estimate of the trade barriers vary across both industries and
border barrier is: countries while the demand structure is the
728 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

same across countries, or (ii) trade barriers in the sectors with relatively low border
only vary across countries while the (inter- costs. Since all state-province pairs get equal
mediate) demand structure varies across weight in gravity equation estimation,
countries (due to varying gross output mix).54 Hillberry argues that estimates from aggre-
Hillberry (2002) considers case (i) in the gate gravity equations overstate the impact
context of a monopolistic competition model of border barriers on international trade. He
with endogenous entry of firms. Countries provides some evidence to confirm this, but
will tend to specialize in sectors in which because it is based on the traditional gravity
they have a comparative advantage reflected equation, omitted variable bias may explain
in trade costs. If for example trade costs take the finding.
the form tijk=τk+mij, then a country i that Hillberry and Hummels (2002) consider
faces relatively low trade barriers mij has case (ii) in which trade barriers are the same
comparative advantage in industries with across industries but the demand structure
relatively low industry-specific barriers τk.55 varies across countries because firms use dif-
This raises the level of trade among coun- ferent bundles of intermediate goods in pro-
tries with low bilateral trade barriers. Trade duction. In that case countries tend to
becomes more sensitive to trade barriers: specialize in industries in which demand is
trade barriers reduce trade both through a relatively high from trading partners with
standard substitution effect and because whom they have relatively low trade barri-
firms endogenously locate close to markets ers. This again raises the impact of trade bar-
with which they have low trade barriers. riers on aggregate trade flows, leading to an
Estimation based on aggregate data upward bias of trade cost estimates based on
attempts to attribute the reduction in trade aggregate data. For trade within and
as a result of trade costs solely to the stan- between U.S. states, Hillberry and
dard substitution effect. Estimated trade Hummels (2002b) regress the product of
barriers will therefore be too high. sectoral demand and supply, EjkYik, on dis-
Hillberry (2002) considers another exam- tance, adjacency, and a within-state dummy.
ple applied to U.S. states and Canadian They find that the co-location of production
provinces. He assumes that trade costs take and demand is mainly important at the very
the form tijk=mije ijτk, where mij is a barrier local level, within states or between adjacent
related to distance and ij is 0 if regions are states. They do not report results on the
located in the same country and 1 otherwise. extent to which trade barrier estimates based
τk is an industry-specific border barrier. This on aggregate data overstate the ideal index.
setup implies that regions located close to Papers by Kei-Mu Yi (2003a,b) are also
the border, which tend to trade a lot with the relevant in this context. These papers are
other country, have comparative advantage based on evidence of an important role of
vertical specialization in international trade,
as documented in Hummels, Jun Ishii, and
54
If neither (i) nor (ii) are satisfied, there is no aggre- Yi (2001). Vertical specialization is defined
gation bias. An example of this is the model by Eaton and as the use of imported intermediate goods in
Kortum (2002). All firms use the same CES bundle of all
intermediate goods as inputs and all consumers have the the production of goods that are exported. Yi
same preferences. The demand structure is therefore the (2003a) develops a two-country model (H
same across countries. Moreover, trade barriers are the and F) in which consumer goods are pro-
same for all industries. As discussed previously, their
model can be shown to lead to the standard aggregate duced in three stages. The first stage pro-
gravity equation (8). duces an intermediate good, which is used
55
If, on the other hand, trade barriers take a multi- in the second stage to produce another
plicative form tikj = τ k mij, the relative trade barrier in two dif-
ferent sectors is the same for all i, j and all countries will intermediate good. The final stage combines
have the same production structure. all intermediate goods from stage two to
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 729

produce a nontraded final consumption empirical magnitude of aggregation bias.


good. These stages can take place in differ- One obvious recommendation is to disaggre-
ent locations, leading to “back and forth” gate. There is no bias in the estimation of
trade. Yi (2003a) shows that trade barriers trade costs for given expenditure and pro-
now have a magnified effect on world trade, duction at the disaggregated level. But disag-
which helps account for the growth in world gregation can never be as fine as reality, so
trade over the past four decades. Yi (2003b) some degree of aggregation bias is inevitable.
argues that taking into account this magnifi-
3.9 Criticisms of the Gravity Approach
cation factor should reduce estimates of
trade barriers. The main criticisms against using gravity
Two factors magnify the impact of trade equations such as (8) and (5) to analyze trade
barriers on trade. First, there are fewer volumes and trade costs are these:
imports of vertically specialized goods by the 1. Estimates of the distance elasticity of
final goods sector. There is vertical special- trade costs are unrealistically high
ization when for example stage 1 is produced (Grossman 1998) and have not dropped
in H, which is shipped to F for stage-2 pro- over time in the face of globalization
duction, which is shipped to H for final (“the missing globalization puzzle”—
goods production. Stage 1 goods will then David Coe, Arvind Subramanian, and
have crossed borders twice, magnifying the Natalia Tumirisa 2002).
impact of border barriers.56 Second, a rise in 2. There are no import-competing sectors
trade barriers affects the production struc- or non-tradables sectors that only supply
ture in that it becomes more likely that the to the domestic market (Charles Engel
first two stages are produced in the same 2002).
country (thus eliminating vertical specializa- 3. One should allow the elasticity of substi-
tion). If stage 1 is produced in H, higher tution between domestic and foreign
trade barriers make it more attractive to pro- goods to be different from the elasticity
duce stage 2 in H as well. Both magnification of substitution among domestic goods
factors are again associated with aggregation (Engel 2002).
bias. Standard gravity equations still hold for 4. In contrast to the predictions of the
stage-2 sub-sectors that use the same pro- model, the substantial increase in U.S.-
duction function (source stage-1 products Canada trade during the 1990s was not
from the same country). accompanied by a big drop in intra-
While aggregation bias can theoretically provincial trade (Helliwell 2003).
arise in many ways, little is known about the 5. The model implies trade among all coun-
tries for each sector, while the reality is
dominated by zeros (Jon Haveman and
56
The critical aspect of the Yi model that leads to this Hummels 2004).
magnification effect is the asymmetry of production func-
tions. This can be seen most clearly in comparison to the 6. Estimated trade barriers are unrealisti-
model of Eaton and Kortum (2002). As discussed above, cally high (Balistreri and Hillberry 2002).
the Eaton and Kortum model leads to a standard gravity 7. Estimates of the gravity equation have
equation, so there is no magnification effect. In the Eaton
and Kortum model firms produce goods that are used both the unrealistic implication that consumer
as intermediate goods and final consumption goods. prices are much higher in Canada than in
Intermediate goods produced in one location are used as the United States (Balistreri and
inputs in the production of intermediate goods in another
location, which are used as intermediate inputs in another Hillberry 2002).
location, etc. Components will therefore have crossed bor- Criticisms of the empirical validity of
ders infinitely many times. But in contrast to Yi (2003a,b), gravity equations are implicitly (sometimes
the same bundle of intermediate goods is used for the pro-
duction of each good. This symmetry assumption regard- explicitly) criticisms of the assumptions of
ing production functions kills the magnification effect. theories underlying the gravity framework.
730 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

Below we will therefore discuss how these Apart from changing theoretical assump-
criticisms can be addressed by generalizing tions, to which we turn in a moment, there
assumptions of theories behind gravity are at least two possible explanations in the
equations (8) and (5). But before doing so, literature for this distance elasticity puzzle.
we will first discuss these criticisms in a bit First, the distance may proxy for much more
more detail. than trade costs. Portes and Rey (2002) find
The puzzle of unrealistically high distance that the distance elasticity halves to -0.23
elasticities was first raised by Grossman once information barriers are introduced
(1998). Grossman pointed out that a distance separately. A second explanation is offered
coefficient of -1.42 in McCallum’s gravity by Coe et al. (2002). They estimate the theo-
equation implies that regions that are 500 retical gravity equation (8) in levels rather
miles apart will trade 2.67 times more with than logs, which reduces the absolute value
each other than regions that are 1000 miles of the distance elasticity from -1.08 to -0.35
apart, which he considered implausibly large. for 2000 trade data. A possible explanation
The distance elasticity is much lower (-0.79 for their finding is that the absolute value of
with a reported standard error of 0.03) in the elasticity of trade with respect to distance
Anderson and van Wincoop (2003). This is falling in distance, as Eaton and Kortum
remains unreasonably large if distance is document. Cutting off the high-distance,
intended to capture transport costs. Grossman low-trade volume observations by using log-
(1998) reasoned as follows. First write tij=1+τij, arithmic data with exclusion of zeroes
where τij is the tax equivalent of transport excludes observations for which the elasticity
costs. Defining =τij /(1+τij), one can write the is low in absolute value, hence pushing
elasticity of bilateral trade with respect to dis- upward the estimated distance elasticity.
tance (holding constant multilateral resistance Apart from the level of the distance elas-
indices) as: ticity there is also the so-called “missing
(1-)ln(τij)/ln(dij). (4) globalization puzzle,” which is based on
findings in a large number of studies that
Transport costs are plausibly no more than the distance elasticity has not declined or
proportional to distance, so that the elastici- even risen over time (see survey of this lit-
ty ln(τij)/ln(dij) is less than one. Hummels erature in Coe et. al. 2002). This is often
(2001a) estimates it to be about 0.3.57 As dis- considered puzzling since transport costs
cussed in section 1, the tax equivalents for have declined over time. Coe et al. (2002)
transport costs for the United States are on find that when the gravity equation is esti-
average about 11 percent. With the elastici- mated in levels rather than logs, the dis-
ty  in the range of 5 to 10, the distance elas- tance elasticity has fallen over the last two
ticity can be expected to be in the range of decades, from -0.51 in 1980 to -0.35 in
-0.12 to -0.26. If we include time costs, the 2000. It is not clear, though, why estimation
tax equivalent of U.S. transport costs are on in levels would resolve this puzzle. For
average 21 percent. Even then the implied industrialized countries, Brun et al. (2002)
distance elasticity is below available esti- succeed in reversing a rising distance elas-
mates, in the range of -0.21 to -0.46 for  in ticity by including the cost of fuel in the
the interval [5,10]. trade cost function. A rise in the price of
57 fuel acts like a negative productivity shock
Grossman (1998) assumes a constant distance elastic-
ity of τ ij. However, the estimated trade-distance elasticities to transportation, so omitting the fuel cost
from the gravity equations that Grossman refers to assume variable in an era when it is rising will pro-
a constant distance elasticity of tij. If the Grossman specifi- duce rising distance elasticities. Fuel costs
cation is correct, it is possible that the high distance elas-
ticities obtained from gravity equation estimation are a both rose and fell in the period of their
result of specification error of tij. analysis, 1962–96, and it is not clear why the
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 731

omitted fuel-cost variable is associated with provinces, PUS and PCA be the respective mul-
rising distance elasticities in subperiods tilateral resistance variables for states and
when fuel costs are falling. Moreover, fuel provinces and b the border barrier. Then
costs should affect the trade cost of devel- trade between two provinces is equal to
oping countries symmetrically, so it is not YCA YCA 1
clear why this effect only works with rich 1− 1−
.
countries. The missing globalization puzzle Yw PCA PCA
may not be a real puzzle after all if one real- while trade between a province and state is
izes that since 1913 technology growth in equal to
shipping has been relatively slow in compar-
YUSYCA b1−
ison to the rest of the economy. Transport 1− 1−
.
costs may therefore have increased as a frac- Yw PUS PCA
tion of average marginal production costs. For observed tradables outputs YUS and
This point is emphasized in Estevadeordal YCA, the ratio of inter-provincial to state-
et. al. (2003). province trade does not depend on non-
The second criticism, raised by Engel tradables and the estimated border barrier
(2002), is that there are no import-compet- does not.
ing sectors or nontradables sectors that do In contrast, full general equilibrium com-
not export. Engel makes this comment on parative statics is affected by the presence of
Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) and nontradables. In the presence of nontrad-
argues that ignoring sectors that do not ables a rise in border barriers will shift
export can lead to an underestimation of resources to the nontradables sector, so that
border barriers. His reasoning is most clear- tradables output of Canadian provinces, YCA,
ly understood for nontradables. Assume that drops. Tradables output of U.S. states drops
as a result of a rise in border barriers there is much less. As a result inter-provincial trade
a shift in resources out of tradables into non- will rise less and state-province trade will
tradables. The nontradables are only sold drop more. For every 1-percent drop in inter-
locally within a region and not between national trade, the increase in interprovincial
regions. As a result, a given 10-percent drop trade will be lower.
in exports of provinces will lead to a smaller In short, the gravity equation and esti-
increase in trade with other provinces than mates of trade barriers are unaffected by
in the absence of nontradables. Engel argues non-tradables but comparative statics are.
that therefore a bigger border barrier is The same conclusion cannot be drawn for an
needed to account for the observed home import-competing sector. Many manufactur-
bias. Under trade separability, however, this ing firms do not export, a fact that cannot be
is not the case for the conditional general accommodated by the gravity equation (5).
equilibrium model upon which estimation is Below we will consider an extension of fixed
based. Nontradables do not affect the gravi- trade costs that modifies the gravity equation
ty equation for tradables, and trade barrier and allows for certain varieties to be only
estimates are therefore unaffected.58 supplied to the domestic market.
To better understand this seemingly para- The third criticism, also by Engel (2002),
doxical result, consider the gravity equation is that gravity theory does not allow the
(8). Let YUS and YCA be the tradables output elasticity of substitution between domestic
of respectively individual states and and foreign goods to be different from the
elasticity of substitution among domestic
58 goods. There is good reason to consider the
Under trade separability, nontradables do not affect
the marginal utility (or marginal productivity) of different case of a higher elasticity of substitution
types of tradable goods within a sector. among domestic goods, commonly assumed
732 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

in the “new open economy macro” litera- States and therefore be much bigger than in
ture. In the context of Eaton and Kortum Canada. There is no evidence of this in the
(2002) it is equivalent to the variation of data. With tradables defined as the sum of
productivity among regions within a country mining, agriculture, and manufacturing, its
being lower than among regions of different share in total output is about the same in the
countries, which is undoubtedly true. two countries.
Extensions of gravity in this direction are The criticism by Helliwell raises a more
discussed below. general point. An obvious direction for future
The fourth criticism is raised by Helliwell research would be to evaluate the validity of
(2003), based on a finding in another paper, theoretical gravity equations with respect to
Helliwell (1999). He documents that follow- their time series implications. This is espe-
ing the 1988 free trade agreement between cially useful since most estimation is based on
the United States and Canada, trade cross-section data. Baier and Bergstrand
between them rose rapidly while trade with- (2001) estimate a gravity equation with
in Canada (interprovincial trade) did not fall pooled data for two periods (1958–60 and
much. This stands in sharp contrast to the 1986–88) to understand what factors drive
finding by Anderson and van Wincoop the increase in world trade. However, their
(2003) that border barriers have increased use of price data is unlikely to properly cap-
interprovincial trade much more (factor 6) ture changes over time in multilateral resist-
than they reduced state-province trade ance indices. Estevadeordal et al. (2003)
(about 44 percent).59 estimate a gravity equation with pooled data
Helliwell (2003) criticizes the plausibility for three years (1913, 1928, and 1938). While
of the outcome from the comparative statics they include country-specific dummies to
exercise in Anderson and van Wincoop capture the multilateral resistance variables,
(2003). Comparative statics exercises the theory tells us that these will change over
depend on the entire general equilibrium. time. One should therefore include separate
This is therefore not necessarily a criticism country dummies for each year. In order to
of the gravity equation itself, which is based exploit the time series properties of the data
on a conditional general equilibrium. It may most effectively, it is even better to estimate
be that the modeling outside of the gravity gravity equations in their structural form.
structure, in particular the production struc- The fifth criticism, launched by Haveman
ture, is incorrect.60 This doesn’t affect the and Hummels (2004), is that gravity models
estimation of the trade cost parameters, imply that all countries purchase goods from
which only depends on the gravity structure. all suppliers. Using 1990 bilateral trade data
One possible explanation for the Helliwell among 173 countries for four-digit SITC cat-
puzzle is a nontradables sector, as discussed egories, Haveman and Hummels show that
above. But this would only work if trade bar- in 58 percent of cases importers buy from
riers lead to a significant shift out of trad- fewer than 10 percent of available suppliers.
ables into nontradables. Because of its much The Haveman and Hummels criticism is
larger size, the share of the tradables sector directed at models with complete specializa-
would not be much affected in the United tion. However, Eaton and Kortum (2002)
derived the same gravity equation in a model
59 without complete specialization. In that
Possibly related to the Helliwell evidence is the point
raised by W. Mark Brown (2003) that industries where model there are generally a limited number
border barriers have disappeared when comparing data on of suppliers, each of which sells to countries
interstate and state-province trade tend to still have much with whom they have relatively low trade
more interprovincial trade than interstate trade.
60
Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) adopt a simple barriers (in comparison to other suppliers).
endowment economy. Countries therefore buy goods from only
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 733

one supplier (the cheapest one), even 3.10 Extensions of the Gravity Approach
though many suppliers may exist. It can
therefore account for zero trade flows at a Simple extensions can meet criticisms
disaggregated level. At the aggregate level, and allow greater flexibility while retaining
since it is equivalent to the CES model, the the essential simplicity of the gravity model
Eaton and Kortum model cannot account (5)–(7). Three assumptions lead to gravity
for zero aggregate bilateral trade flows, (5): (i) trade separability, (ii) the aggregator
which are seen for trade among small of varieties is identical across countries and
regions (certain states and provinces) or CES, and (iii) ad-valorem tax equivalents
developing countries. Below we will also dis- of trade costs do not depend on the quan-
cuss an extension with fixed cost as an expla- tity of trade. A variety of extensions of (ii)
nation for zero trade flows. and (iii) are discussed below. With relax-
The sixth criticism, by Balistreri and ation of (i), two-stage budgeting is impossi-
Hillberry (2002), that estimated trade barri- ble. It is worthwhile to at least consider
ers are unrealistically high, has already been how estimates of trade barriers depend on
discussed above. The numbers would cer- this, but no work has yet been done in this
tainly be too high when they are interpreted direction.
as transport costs, as Balistreri and Hillberry Extensions of the CES Structure. Yuriy
do. In reality though, they reflect lots of trade Tchamourliysky (2002) considers non-
barriers that cannot be directly measured. It homothetic CES preferences. He modifies
is hard to dismiss estimates of large trade bar- a standard CES consumption index by
riers without direct evidence to refute this. It adding a constant i to consumption of
is quite possible though that various exten- goods from country i by every country’s
sions of existing gravity theory that we discuss consumers. He then derives a modified
below will eventually lead to a consensus of gravity equation and estimates i to be neg-
lower trade barriers than reported in table 7. ative, interpretable as a subsistence
The final criticism, by Balistreri and requirement. A subsistence requirement
Hillberry (2002), is that gravity equations makes trade flows less sensitive to trade
have unrealistic implications for price differ- barriers. Incorrectly assuming homothetic
ences. They argue that the Anderson and CES preferences would make consumption
van Wincoop (2003) results imply that the excessively sensitive to trade barriers and
consumer price index is 24 percent higher in the estimated trade barriers therefore too
Canada than in the United States (assuming high. Tchamourliysky (2002) focuses partic-
=5). As discussed above, we think the focus ularly on distance as a trade barrier and
on consumer prices indices in the data is a finds that allowing for non-homothetic pref-
misuse of the model. They include things erences reduces the impact of distance on
such as non-tradables, taxes and subsidies, trade barriers. This extension can potential-
and relative price fluctuations with exchange ly address several of the criticisms raised
rates due to nominal rigidities of prices. We above. First, by reducing estimates of trade
interpret multilateral resistance in the con- barriers, it addresses the concern by
text of gravity theory as an ideal index of Hillberry and Balistreri (2002) that estimat-
trade costs, and find the 24-percent greater ed trade barriers from theoretical gravity
trade cost index for Canada to be quite plau- equations are unrealistically high. Second, a
sible given the revealed trade-cost impact of lower distance elasticity of trade addresses
the border, Canada’s much smaller size, the the concern of Grossman (1998).
revealed trade-cost impact of distance, and The CES preference structure can also be
the greater distance of Canadian provinces generalized by assuming, using nested CES
from U.S. centers of activity. structures, that certain goods within a sector
734 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

are better substitutes than other goods. This trade costs from taste differences.62 Another
would for example allow domestic goods to promising route to distinguishing the two is
be closer substitutes for each other than to exploit time-series variation. Trade costs
domestic goods are with foreign goods, plausibly move over time while tastes pre-
addressing the criticism of Engel (2002). sumptively are stable.
How much this matters to trade costs is Evans (2003b) provides some evidence
unknown.61 suggesting that estimates of large border-
Differences in Preferences and Technol- related trade barriers are not a result of a
ogy. The gravity model assumes that prefer- home bias for domestic goods. Information
ences and technology are the same for all about the size of border-related barriers is
agents. This is a strong assumption and can usually obtained by comparing international
be relaxed in a number of directions. First, it trade to domestic trade within a gravity
is possible that consumers in different framework. Evans (2003b) estimates a tradi-
regions or countries have different prefer- tional gravity equation to find that, after con-
ences. For example, consumers may be trolling for size, distance and remoteness,
biased towards goods produced in their own domestic sales within non-U.S. OECD
country. Differences in preferences are, countries is 4.36 times imports from the
however, empirically indistinguishable from United States. But she finds that the home
trade costs. Consider the following utility bias is virtually identical when comparing
function for country j consumers: local sales in non-U.S. OECD countries of
 /( −1)
affiliates of U.S. multinationals to imports
  from the United States. This suggests that
 ∑ i
(1− )/
(cij /  ij )( −1)/  . (28)
 i  location—and not the nationality of the firm
that sells the goods—is critical.
Here cij is consumption of goods produced Demand can also be different when it
in country i by country j consumers. Utility comes from firms buying intermediate
generally differs across countries due to vari- goods. Assume that for a specific industry
ation in the ij. It is easily verified that in the the index of intermediates in the production
absence of trade barriers the gravity equa- function differs across firms. For example,
tion is the same as in (8) with tij replaced by let (28) represent the index of intermediates
ij. Under sufficiently strong restrictions on in the production functions of firms in coun-
taste differences, it is possible to distinguish try j. The same comment can now be made
as for heterogeneous preferences of con-
61
Consider, for example, data on trade flows for U.S. sumers. One cannot empirically distinguish
states and Canadian provinces. Assume a one-sector world. trade barriers tij and the parameters ij in
Let H be the elasticity of substitution between goods pro- production functions. If production func-
duced within a country and F the elasticity of substitution
between domestic and foreign goods. It is then easily ver- tions of firms tend to give more weight to
ified that the gravity equation (8) is modified as follows: intermediates that are produced in their own
YY t 1− H country, it will be indistinguishable from a
X ij = i j  – ij1– 1–
Yw Pj ,c Pj F  i H
F H
border barrier. One can therefore estimate
where Pj,c is the price index of goods imported by region j positive border barriers even if none exist.
from country c in which the exporting region i is located,
Pj is the overall price index of importer j and i is a price
62
index specific to exporter i. In general the estimated trade Bergstrand (1985) derives a gravity equation under a
barriers can now be different. The direction in which they different type of heterogeneity in preferences. Consumers
will change is not obvious though and will depend on the consider the elasticity of substitution among goods pro-
details. It is easy, for example, to show that the estimate of duced in foreign countries to be different from the elas-
the U.S.-Canada border barrier is the same as based on the ticity of substitution between home and foreign goods,
standard gravity equation (8) when this is the only trade where “home” and “foreign” varies with the location of the
barrier. consumer.
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 735

Fixed Costs of Trade. Bernard and Jensen importers.63 In that setup, it is possible that
(1997), Bernard and Wagner (1998) and firms only export to a limited number of
Roberts and Tybout (1997) all report sub- markets. The same would be the case if fixed
stantial evidence of fixed entry costs into costs are borne by exporters but vary across
foreign markets. They all show that having export markets. Based on data for Costa Rica
exported in the past significantly increases from 1986 to 1993, Klenow and Rodriguez-
the probability of a firm exporting today. Clare (1997) find that a drop in tariffs from
Introducing fixed costs can explain the 48.5 percent to 22.1 percent over this period
many zeros in bilateral trade data. Coe et al. led to an increase in the number of imported
(2002) and Evenett and Venables (2002) varieties of 30 percent for consumer goods
also document that the number of zeros has and 20 percent for intermediate goods.
substantially dropped over time. This sug- A simple generalization of (5)–(7) takes
gests that a reduction in fixed costs or into account fixed costs. Assume that as a
growth of income can play an important result of fixed costs in industry k country i
role in accounting for the growth of world exports to the limited set of countries Xik and
trade. Evenett and Venables (2002) find imports from the set Mik observed from the
that the removal of zeros accounts for one trade-flow data. When there are positive
third of developing countries’ export growth exports from i to j the generalized gravity
since 1970. equation becomes
Evans (2003c) attempts to recompute the 1− k
tax equivalent of proportional trade costs Ek Y k  t k 
for U.S. exports after controlling for fixed X = j k i  k ij k 
k
ij (29)
Y  Pj  i 
costs. She assumes that fixed trade costs are
1− k
borne by exporters. Once a firm has paid  tk  Ekj
the sunk cost, it can export to all foreign k 1− k
( )
i = ∑  ijk  (30)
markets. She finds that in 1992 only 25 per- jX ik  j 
P Yk
cent of all U.S. firms exported abroad. The 1− k
U.S. Census of Manufactures provides data  tk  Yik
k 1− k
(P ) = ∑  ijk  . (31)
for each industry on the proportion of U.S. j
i  Yk
iM kj 
output that is produced by firms that both
export and sell domestically. The output Yik This setup allows for the case where firms
of country i in industry k is then redefined in a country only sell to the domestic market
as the output of firms that sell in both (import-competing firms), sell to a limited set
domestic and foreign markets. Evans of foreign markets, or sell to all foreign mar-
(2003c) finds that estimates of proportional kets. On the importing side it allows for the
trade costs drop somewhat as a result of case where a country only purchases domes-
this. However, there are two problems with tic varieties, where it purchases a limited set
this approach. First, she estimates a tradi- of domestic and foreign varieties, and where
tional gravity equation. Second, one cannot it purchases all varieties from all countries. It
ignore firms that only supply varieties to can therefore address several of the criticisms
the domestic market. These are import- of gravity models discussed above. Note that
competing firms that affect the demand (29)–(31) give rise to zero trade flows inde-
from firms in the industry that supply goods pendently of fixed trade costs if either Ejk or
to both the domestic market and foreign Yik is equal to zero. These are unrestricted in
markets. conditional general equilibrium.
In contrast to Evans (2003c), Peter Klenow
and Andres Rodriguez-Clare (1997) develop 63
They use their model to compute welfare gains from
a model in which fixed costs are borne by trade liberalization.
736 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

We can either estimate the structural form country j is pj. The c.i.f. import price at the
or estimate the log-transformation with OLS port of entry is pjm, while the f.o.b. export
after replacing the multilateral resistance price is pix. The literature aims to extract
indices with importer and exporter dum- information about policy barriers by com-
mies. In the latter case the estimates for pro- paring either the “world” price pix or port of
portional trade barriers remain the same as entry import price pjm to the domestic whole-
before when only positive trade flows are sale price pj.
included in the regression. However, esti- There are both conceptual and data prob-
mates based on aggregate gravity equations lems associated with this method. The main
overstate proportional trade barriers since conceptual problem for our purposes is that
they aggregate zero and positive trade flows. the price comparison captures only a limited
We expect fixed costs to be a fruitful area for component of the overall trade barrier tij
further research.64 between two countries. It also does not
accurately capture NTBs, for which the
4. Evidence from Prices method is designed. Data problems take the
Prices provide another indirect source of form of measurement problems and limited
information about the magnitude of trade data coverage.
costs. Two separate literatures shed light on First consider the conceptual problems.
trade barriers using price data, a trade liter- In most reasonable models of economic
ature and a macro literature. The trade liter- activity, a large component of trade costs,
ature has focused on comparing import or often the most important component, is
“world” prices to domestic wholesale prices. borne by the exporter and then shifted onto
The aim is usually to estimate NTBs. The the importer. The c.i.f. import price includes
macro literature compares retail prices of not only the standard transport, insurance,
similar goods across countries. The macro and freight costs, but also the myriad of
literature is focused on issues such as the other costs borne by the exporter in order to
speed of convergence of prices across coun- bring the good to the foreign market. The
tries and the relationship between exchange price ratio pj /pjm therefore does not capture
rates and prices. We will only discuss what this portion of full trade cost. It only cap-
can be learnt about the magnitude of trade tures the trade costs directly borne by the
costs from this literature. Broader surveys importing country, those associated with pol-
can be found elsewhere.65 icy barriers in the form of tariffs and NTBs,
as well as more informal trade costs borne by
4.1 The Trade Literature the importing country, such as information,
It is useful to first introduce some nota- regulatory, and contract costs.
tion. Consider two countries, i and j, with i a Deardorff and Stern (1998), in their sur-
major exporter of a particular good and j an vey of the literature on the measurement of
importer. The wholesale price of the good in NTBs, explain why the price ratio pj /pjm does
not necessarily capture all trade costs associ-
64 ated with quotas and other NTBs. If for
Bergstrand (1985, 1989, 1990) and Baier and
Bergstrand (2001) model the cost of distributing, market- example the exporting firm has market
ing and tailoring a product to an export market as a CES power it may be able to extract the quota rev-
transformation function. Total output of a particular good enue for itself by raising the import price.66
is a CES function of the quantities of that good sold to var-
ious markets. It is not exactly clear though what the micro- Another possibility is that a quota licence is
foundations are for this transformation function. It leads to
additional price indices in the gravity equation.
65 66
See, for example, Kenneth Froot and Kenneth Michael Knetter (1997) provides evidence that
Rogoff (1995) and Pinelopi Koujianou Goldberg and German exporters charge substantially higher prices to
Michael Knetter (1997). Japan due to a variety of NTBs in Japan.
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 737

allocated directly to the final user of the to be very crude and yield very different
imported good. In that case no price com- results than survey data when both are avail-
parison will be able to capture it. Finally, vol- able. The comparison is often over very dis-
untary export restraints (VERs) allocate the similar goods.
quota to exporters who presumptively build Deardorff and Stern (1998) and Laird and
the value of their quota licenses into the Yeats (1990) both review studies that have
export price. The Multi-Fibre Arrangement estimated trade barriers based on price
is the most prominent example. comparisons. The overall conclusion one
The data problems besetting price com- reaches from the evidence is that trade bar-
parisons are twofold: limitations of coverage riers are very large in the agricultural sector.
and imperfections in the data which do exist. Table 9 reproduces from Deardorff and
As to limitations of coverage, perhaps the Stern a few price comparison measures in
main data problem, survey data on price agriculture in the United States for 1991 and
comparisons, is mostly limited to agricultur- 1993. Agricultural policy commonly starts
al products and, to a lesser extent, textiles with a price support fixed by the govern-
and clothing. Even within these categories ment, and uses quotas or variable levies (in
data are only available for certain countries the case of the European Union) to avoid
and years. As to imperfections of the data supporting farmers in the rest of the world.
that do exist, they can be categorized in Sugar is the most notorious example of large
three types. First, the wholesale price pj is distortions. In 1991 the sugar support price
not a port of entry price and therefore was equivalent to a 125-percent tariff, while
already contains some local distribution in some years the tariff equivalent has
costs. Second, the price pj is usually for a exceeded 300 percent. Protection for U.S.
domestic substitute of the import good or an dairy products is also very high. Canada also
index of imported and domestic goods. The protects its agricultural sector. Deardorff
analyst making price comparisons must con- and Stern report 1992 tariff equivalents of
front the issue of comparability of the goods. 165 percent in dairy products, 28 percent in
Even a physically homogeneous good (such chicken, and 29 percent in turkey. Other
as Number 2 Red wheat) has variations with countries have even more extreme agricul-
respect to terms of delivery. The price com- tural distortions—Japan is notorious for a
parison method is most convincing where domestic rice price over ten times the world
markets are thick and well organized. Third, price, with similar differentials for sugar in
there are timing problems, which are partic- some years.
ularly an issue when the import or world
4.2 The Macro Literature
price is denominated in another currency
and a correct exchange rate needs to be used The purchasing power parity literature
for price comparison. compares retail prices of individual goods or
The lack of availability of survey data on baskets of goods across countries. The main
prices has led some researchers to compute weakness of the literature to date is the
unit values (e.g. Sazanami et al. 1995). This absence of a theoretical foundation neces-
is only possible for categories of goods that sary to link evidence on relative prices across
are sufficiently broadly defined that domes- countries to trade barriers. We suggest vari-
tic production exists and for which sensible ous directions that trade theory can be
quantity units exist. The domestic price pj is employed to extract more information from
then computed by dividing the value of price data.
domestic production by the quantity of out- Papers that attempt to draw a link from
put, and similarly for imports. The approxi- relative prices to trade barriers commonly
mations resulting from this technique tend refer to an arbitrage equation of the type
738 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

TABLE 9
Price-Gap Measures by Sector, 1991 and 1993 (Percent)

Sector 1991 1993


Price-gap measures Quota Quota S TW Quota %US
Agricultural Sectora Tar. Eq. Tar. Eq. Tariff Tariff  TW Tar. Imports
Sugar 124.8 93.7 1.0 0.2 93.9 0.1296
Butter 26.9 20.8 8.8 8.7 29.5 0.0008
Cheese 35.4 37.4 10.6 11.2 48.6 0.0889
Dry/condensed milk prod. 60.3 60.3 13.2 13.2 73.5 0.0033
Cream 60.3 60.3 0.0 0.0 60.3 0.0008
Meat 6.5 5.0 1.3 4.0 9.0 0.4296
Cotton - 27.0 2.2 0.1 27.1 0.0001
Motor Vehiclesb - 0.4 2.2 1.7 2.1 9.5673
Maritime trans. (Jones Act)c 133.0 89.1

Notes:
a. The price comparisons for the agricultural products were as follows. Sugar calculated as the difference
between the U.S. price and the world price, inclusive of transport costs and import duties, expressed as a per-
centage of the world price; data from USDA, Sugar and Sweetener: Situation and Outlook Yearbook. Dairy prod-
ucts—based on domestic and world price data collected by the USDA for whole milk powder, butter and cheese;
for dry/condensed milk products and cream, the price gap for whole milk powder was used as a proxy. Meat —
based on the “market price support” portion of the producer subsidy equivalent (PSE) calculated by the OECD,
comparing Sioux Falls (U.S) cutter prices with New Zealand milk cow prices, and domestic and world prices of
Orleans/Texas “B” index cotton, including adjustments for transportation and marketing costs.
b. Motor vehicles based on an estimated 1.5 percent additional increase above the industrywide U.S. price
increase needed in Japanese autos to equate supply and demand in the presence of the auto import restraint;
weighted by the percent of Japanese auto imports to total whole imports.
c. Maritime transport calculated as the output-weighted average difference between the U.S. and world price for
shipping “wet” and “dry’’ cargo, the weighted differences are between the U.S. price for shipping Alaskan North
Slope crude petroleum to the U.S. west coast and to the U.S. gulf coast and the average world price for compara-
ble tanker shipments transported equal distances; a separate estimate from the literature was used for the tariff
equivalent for dry cargo. Additional estimates of the price gap attributed to the Jones Act can be found in White
(1988) and Francois et al. (1996, p.186).
Sources: USITC (1993, 1995). Quota tariff equivalents and the notes for price comparisons above are reproduced
from Deardorff and Stern, (1998), Table 3.6 (Source USITC 1993, 1995). Tariff averages, trade-weighted tariff aver-
ages and US product import percentages (except maritime transport) are calculated using data from the UNCTAD
TRAINS database (Haveman repackaging). SIC to HS concordances from the US Census Bureau are used.

1 pi vance in understanding the link between price


≤ ≤ tij (32) differentials and trade costs in most markets.
tij pj
Limitations on arbitrage pose a significant
with tij the cost of arbitraging a price differen- limitation to using (32). In many cases the
tial between i and j by a wholesaler. The rela- arbitrage costs of wholesalers are prohibi-
tive price is assumed to move freely between tive. Producers often obtain exclusive
the arbitrage points, also referred to as national marketing licences, which pre-
Heckscher’s (1916) commodity points. cludes arbitrage by wholesalers. Moreover,
Equation (32) is unfortunately of limited rele- as pointed out by Obstfeld and Rogoff
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 739

(2000), even small firms that do not have by a border than when they are located in
exclusive distribution rights can price dis- the same country. They argue that this may
criminate by dealing with a small number of be a result of trade barriers, as arbitrage
wholesalers with whom they have developed equation (32) suggests that larger relative
long-term relationships. Other factors, such price differences are possible if trade barri-
as warranties or small differences in prod- ers are larger. But Engel and Rogers (2001)
ucts due to regulatory constraints, also con- provide evidence that exchange-rate volatili-
tribute to limit the ability of wholesalers to ty may be the main explanation for the bor-
arbitrage price differences. Pinelopi der effect. In that study they use evidence
Koujianou Goldberg and Frank Verboven from cities in eleven European countries,
(2001) provide explicit evidence for the which allows them to compute the border
European car market showing that arbitrage effect after controlling for bilateral
activity by resellers is very limited even exchange-rate volatility. The coefficient on
though price differences are large. the border dummy drops from 2.85 to 0.21.
General equilibrium forces limiting price Maurice Obstfeld and Alan Taylor (1997)
variation pose an even greater limitation to is another example of a study that used price
using (32). Even though (32) holds in most index information. Their starting point is
models, the relative price cannot freely fluc- again (32). They estimate a threshold autore-
tuate in the range given by Heckscher’s gression (TAR) model67, whereby the log-
(1916) commodity points. Below we will price differential follows a random walk
show that arbitrage alone leads to a much inside a band [–c,c]. It can also exit the band
tighter condition. Assuming a specific trade and will then converge back to the band at a
model can tie down the relationship between rate to be estimated. Their estimates for c
relative prices and trade costs exactly. We tend to be rather small, on average about
will illustrate this point and examine the link 0.08 for the United States relative to other
between relative prices and trade costs below countries. Obstfeld and Taylor interpret
in the context of a version of the Ricardian them as estimates of trade barriers based on
model of Eaton and Kortum (2002). arbitrage equation (32).
While we will focus this survey on evi- Since theory tells us that relative prices
dence from price levels at a point in time, are not free to fluctuate in the range sug-
some studies have employed evidence on gested by (32), it is not a correct starting
changes in relative price over time to extract point for either time series evidence or evi-
information about trade costs motivated by dence about price levels at a point in time.
(32). We will first briefly review the time There are many factors that contribute to
series evidence. The remainder of this sec- time series variation in relative prices, such
tion discusses what can be learned from as changes in marginal costs, trade costs,
price levels at a point in time. taxes, markups, and exchange rates. It is
hard to see how information can be extract-
4.2.1 Time Series Evidence
ed about the level of trade costs from evi-
A well-known paper by Charles Engel and dence on changes in relative prices,
John Rogers (1996) computes the standard especially without the guidance of theory.
deviation of relative prices between
4.2.2 Extracting Information from Price
Canadian and U.S. cities for fourteen con-
Levels
sumption categories (such as alcoholic bev-
erages and men’s and boy’s apparel). They Recent survey evidence of price levels for
show that the standard deviation of relative individual goods in cities around the world
prices depends positively on distance and is
much higher when two cities are separated 67
See also Alan Taylor (2001) and references therein.
740 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

has led to a small but promising literature purchase the good from the same producer.
aimed at extracting information about trade If the producer is located in country m, the
costs. Since the approach that most authors relative price is equal to
have taken is rather atheoretical, we will first pi tim
discuss some theoretical background to = . (34)
interpret the findings from this literature. pj t jm
Some Theoretical Background. The price In this case the relative price is completely
paid by the final user of a good generally tied down by trade barriers. Analogous
contains four components: (i) the marginal points were made in Deardorff (1979) in the
cost of production, (ii) trade costs, (iii) vari- context of forward and spot currency trade
ous monopolistic markups over cost in the with transactions costs.
chain from producer to final user, and (iv) It also follows from (34) that trade costs do
subsidies and taxes. In order to shed light on not necessarily lead to price differentials. If
the relationship between trade costs and both i and j face the same trade barrier with
price differentials we will first abstract from m, their relative price is equal to one. On the
the last two price components. The key other hand, in the specific case where m is
force is a general equilibrium or multi-mar- one of the two countries, the relative price
ket version of arbitrage which constrains the captures exactly what we intend to measure.
behavior of relative prices. If m=j the relative price is tij /tjj, the trade
If country i buys a good from country m cost between i and j relative to the trade cost
the price in i will be pi=cmtmi, where cm is the within country j. A natural strategy would be
cost of production in m and tmi is one plus to identify the source country for each prod-
the tax equivalent of trade costs on ship- uct. The price in country i relative to the
ments from m to i. Country i will source source country is informative about interna-
from the producer m for which cmtmi is the tional relative to local trade barriers.
lowest. Arbitrage is done here not by con- Unfortunately survey data often do not tell
sumers or wholesalers, but by producers. If us which country produced the good. In
the price in market i is above cmtmi, it is prof- some cases the price is not even for a specif-
itable for the producer in country m to ic good, but an index of similar goods. We
undercut the existing price in country i. will return to these issues below.
Without imposing any specific model More can be learned about the relation-
structure, we can already say something ship between relative price differentials and
about the price in location i relative to the trade costs by adopting a specific trade
price in location j. Specifically, if it is optimal model with a specific economic geography.
for country i to source from country zi and This is useful for gaining perspective on the
country j from zj, then it must be the case atheoretical literature which looks at the geo-
that the price in i is no larger than if it had graphic dispersion of prices for evidence of
sourced from zj and the price in j is no larger trade costs. We simulate a model to generate
than if it had sourced from zi. These arbitrage distributions of prices and then relate them
constraints lead to the following inequalities to the trade cost parameters we impose.
For the trade model we will consider a
tizi pi tiz j variation of Eaton and Kortum (2002).
≤ ≤ . (33)
t jzi pj t jz j There are N countries that each have the
same size labor force. There are G goods,
The arbitrage equation (33) is generally with an elasticity of substitution  between
much tighter than the equation (32) com- them. Productivity z for each good in each
monly referred to in the literature. As an country is drawn from the Fréchet distribu-
example, consider the case where i and j tion with cumulative distribution function
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 741
–
e–z . The variance of z is inversely related to 5. standard deviation across both goods and
the parameter . countries of ln(pig )– ∑j ln(pjg )/N.
The countries are evenly spaced on a cir- Particularly the third and the fourth meas-
cle. The average trade cost for any pair of ures have been computed with the aim of
countries is proportional to their distance on measuring trade barriers. Bradford and
the circle. Trade costs vary across both goods Lawrence (2003) and Mario Crucini, Chris
and location pairs. This extends Eaton and Telmer, and Marios Zachariadis (2000) com-
Kortum, who assume that trade costs are pute variations of measure 3 and interpret it
identical across goods. The average trade respectively as a measure of “fragmentation”
cost of good g (across location pairs) is and “cost of arbitrage.” This measure may
2tav(g–1)/(G–1). Average trade costs there- both overstate and understate the trade-
fore vary across goods from 0 to 2tav. The weighted average trade barrier. If the cheap-
average trade cost (tax equivalent) across all est country is m, the price that i would pay to
goods and location pairs is tav. import from m is the price in m times the
Each country buys from the cheapest pro- trade cost tmgi. If the trade cost is high, it may
ducer, so that the price of good g in country i is be optimal to import from another country
with whom i has a lower trade barrier. In
pig = min(cgj tjig,..,cNg tNig ) (35)
that case the measure overstates actual trade
where cjg is the production cost of good g in costs. It may also be optimal to purchase
country j and tjig is one plus the tax equivalent from a domestic producer in i. In that case
of trade costs on shipments of good g from j the model tells us that the price difference
to i. When there is a continuum of goods, with the cheapest country m is equal to the
total labor demand will be the same across difference in production cost between i and
countries and wage rates will be equal. The m. The latter is smaller than the trade barri-
level of this common wage rate is irrelevant er between i and m (otherwise i would
for the price dispersion measures. We import from m) and may even be zero (if i is
approximate the continuum model by simu- itself the cheapest country).
lating the model for a large number of David Parsley and Shang-Jin Wei (2002)
goods, with G=3000. compute measure 4. They justify it based on
In simulations of the model, we compute the arbitrage equation (32). Assuming the
five different price dispersion measures that same trade barrier for all goods, and that the
have been reported in the literature. The relative prices between i and j are evenly dis-
measures can be location-specific, location persed in this no-arbitrage zone, there is
pair-specific or good-specific. The five meas- indeed a direct relationship between the
ures are: trade barrier between i and j and the stan-
1. location-specific: for given location i the dard deviation of these relative prices across
average of | pig – pjg |/(0.5pig+0.5pjg) across goods. But arbitrage equation (32) is not a
both goods and locations j; good starting point for relating price differ-
2. good-specific: average of | pig – pg |/pg ences to trade barriers. Two extreme exam-
across locations i, with pg the average ples make the point. First assume that trade
price of good g across locations; costs are so large that there is no trade. In
3. location-specific: expenditure weighted that case price differences are entirely driv-
average of (pig – plgow)/plgow across goods, en by differences in local production costs,
where plgow is the lowest price across coun- which in general bear no relationship to
tries of good g; trade costs. As a second example assume that
4. location pair-specific: the standard devi- i and j buy all goods from country m, with
ation of ln(pig ) – ln(pjg ) across goods for a whom they have the same trade barrier for
given location pair (i,j); each good. The price dispersion measure
742 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

TABLE 10
TRADE COSTS AND PRICE DISPERSION

parameters Price Dispersion Measure Trade Cost


N  θ trade cost 1 2 3 4 5 trade- ideal
average vary/ weighted index
same average
Trade Cost Only Source of Price Dispersion
(i) 10 4 5 100 vary 20 13 26 27 18 31 52
(ii) 10 4 5 200 vary 23 15 30 31 21 38 77
(iii) 10 1 5 100 vary 20 13 42 27 18 40 62
(iv) 10 1 5 200 vary 23 15 53 31 21 50 92
(v) 10 4 5 100 same 22 15 40 30 20 100 100
(vi) 10 4 3 100 vary 26 17 32 34 23 43 57
(vii) 10 4 8 100 vary 15 10 21 19 13 22 43
(viii) 20 4 5 100 vary 19 13 29 26 18 28 50
(ix) 20 4 5 200 vary 23 15 37 29 21 36 73
With Other Sources of Price Dispersion
(x) 20 4 5 0 vary 25 17 37 31 22 0 0
(xi) 20 4 5 100 vary 32 22 45 40 28 28 50
(xii) 20 4 5 200 vary 34 23 47 43 30 36 73
Data
(xiii) 32 21 40 44 24

Notes: This table reports the average of five price dispersion measures described in the text. All numbers are in
percentages. The model moments are based on the trade model described in the text, which is a variation of the
Eaton and Kortum (2002) model. Results are shown for a variety of parameter assumptions in the model. N
refers to the number of countries.  is the elasticity of substitution between goods. θ is the parameter from the
Fréchet distribution that is inversely related to productivity differences across countries. “vary/same’’ refers to
whether the trade barriers tijg vary across goods and countries as described in the text or are the same across al
goods and countries. Trade weighted average trade costs and the ideal index of trade costs are shown as well. The
latter is a common trade barrier across countries and goods that leads to the same overall expected trade level as
implied by the trade costs assumed in the model. The last row reports data moments that have been computed
by different authors. The samples are reported in Table 11.

will then be zero, even though trade costs international shipments tend to be limited to
may be very large. countries with whom the producer has a low
Table 10 provides some results of model trade barrier. Clusters of countries of vary-
simulations for various model parameters. ing sizes are formed, with one member of
Only average price dispersion measures are the cluster being the single source of pro-
reported (e.g. across location pairs or duction for all members of the cluster. The
goods). Apart from the assumed average ideal index always lies in between the arith-
trade cost, the table also reports the trade- metic average and trade-weighted average
weighted average and the ideal index. The barrier.
latter is the common international trade bar- Table 10 shows that even if trade barriers
rier (across goods and countries) that leads are the only source of price dispersion, it is
to the same aggregate international trade as hard to conclude much about the magnitude
implied by the assumed trade barriers. All of trade barriers from the average price dis-
reported numbers are in percentages. The persion measures. Rows (i)-(ix) show results
trade-weighted average trade cost is much for nine different parameterizations. All price
lower than the arithmetic average since dispersion measures are far below the ideal
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 743

Fourth Price
35 Panel A∗ Second Price
25 Panel B∗
Dispersion Dispersion
Measure 30 Measure 20

25 15

20 10

15 5

10 0
0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200
Average Trade Barrier For Location Pair Average Trade Barrier Class of Goods

Fourth Price
46 Panel C∗∗ Second Price Panel D∗∗
Dispersion 30
44
Dispersion
Measure Measure
42 27
40
24
38
36 21
34
32 18
30
15
0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200
Average Trade Barrier For Location Pair Average Trade Barrier Class of Goods

∗ Trade Costs Only Source of Price Dispersion ∗∗ Including Other Sources of Price Dispersion

Figure 2. Price Dispersion across Location Pairs and Goods

index. There is also no apparent relationship average or the ideal index. The reason is that
with the trade-weighted average index. If we we do not know the distribution of trade
lower the elasticity of substitution  from four costs across goods and location pairs.
to one, the trade-weighted average barrier While average price dispersion measures
rises but the price dispersion measures (other are not very informative about trade costs,
than the third) remain unchanged. If we the variation of price dispersion across loca-
remove the variation of trade barriers across tion pairs and goods is. This is illustrated in
locations and goods, the trade-weighted aver- panels A and B of figure 2 based on repre-
age barrier rises from 31 percent to 100 per- sentative simulations of the model. Panel A
cent but the price dispersion measures shows the fourth price dispersion measure
change very little. When we raise the number for each location pair as a function of the
of countries from ten to twenty, the trade- average trade cost for that location pair.
weighted average barrier drops, while the Price dispersion is clearly higher for location
third price dispersion measure rises. All price pairs that have higher average trade costs.
dispersion measures drop relative to the Panel B shows a similar result for goods
trade-weighted average barrier when the based on the second price dispersion meas-
average trade cost is increased or  is lowered. ure. Average price dispersion for a particular
Even if we knew the model and the good (across location pairs) depends on the
parameters of the model other than trade particular productivity draws for that good
costs, it would still be impossible to conclude from the Fréchet distribution and therefore
much about the magnitude of trade costs, has some randomness to it. Each point in the
whether the arithmetic or trade-weighted panel represents the average for ten goods.
744 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

It is clear that price dispersion tends to rise To illustrate the impact of these addition-
for goods with higher trade barriers. al sources of price dispersion, we multiply
These findings can be exploited empirical- the equilibrium prices by tig for good g in
ly. For example, one can specify a trade cost location i. This captures local taxes and dis-
function like (11), relating trade cost across tribution costs. One can make an argument
location pairs to distance and other observ- that it also captures ex-post markup variation
able characteristics that are associated with due to exchange rate volatility and price
trade barriers. One can similarly add good- rigidities, although introducing such features
specific characteristics to the trade cost would require a substantial modification of
function. The parameters of the trade cost the model. As an illustration we will assume
function can be estimated by using the vari- that ln(tig) has a standard deviation of 23 per-
ation of price dispersion across location pairs cent across goods and countries, including
and goods. We will return to this in the dis- country and good-specific components with
cussion of empirical evidence below. standard deviations of both 5 percent.
So far we have abstracted from the two Rows (x)–(xii) of table 10 show the average
other components of prices, associated with price dispersion moments which result from
taxes and markups. We have also abstracted introducing variation in ln(tig). It further
from differences in domestic trade costs illustrates that average price dispersion
across countries. Introducing domestic trade measures tell us very little about trade barri-
costs and taxes is relatively easy. The equilib- ers. For example, doubling the average trade
rium prices in the model above then need to barrier from 100 percent to 200 percent has
be multiplied by the ad-valorem tax equiva- remarkably little effect on the price disper-
lent of domestic trade costs and taxes. This sion measures. It is again the case that much
affects the price dispersion measures to the more can be learned from the variation in
extent that taxes and local trade costs vary price dispersion across location pairs and
across countries. goods. Panels C and D of figure 2 show that
Variable markups also affect price differ- across both location pairs and goods there
ences. Markups depend on factors such as remains a strong positive relationship
the price elasticity of demand and the mar- between price dispersion and trade costs,
ket share of an oligopolist. In practice one of even though it is somewhat clouded by the
the most important factors affecting additional sources of price dispersion.
markups is nominal exchange rate volatility Evidence from Survey Data. Various
combined with nominal price rigidities in authors have computed measures of price
the buyer’s currency. To the extent that dispersion, using survey data for disaggregat-
exporters set prices in the buyer’s currency, ed goods from the OECD, Eurostat, and the
the relative price for the same good across Economist Intelligence Unit. Table 11 lists
two countries will fluctuate one-for-one with the papers that have computed the five price
the exchange rate during the time that prices dispersion measures discussed above, as well
remain set. The profit margin of the exporter as the data samples. Average price disper-
will fluctuate accordingly.68 sion measures are listed in the last row of
both tables 10 and 11. While some papers
68
Essentially the same outcome occurs when the consider a much broader set of countries, for
exporter sets the price in its own currency, but domestic comparability we only report results for
distributors in the importing country (importers, whole-
salers, retailers) absorb the exchange rate fluctuations in industrialized countries (mostly European
their profit margins by setting the price fixed in the local countries).
currency. See Philippe Bacchetta and van Wincoop (2003) Table 10 shows that the average price dis-
for a model along this line, which shows that such price
setting behavior may be optimal for both exporters and persion numbers in the data are not too far
importers. from those in the model when other sources
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 745

TABLE 11
DATA SOURCES FOR PRICE DISPERSION MEASURES

Measure 1 Measure 2 Measure 3 Measure 4 Measure 5


author Bradford & Crucini Bradford & Parsley & Crucini &
Lawrence (2003) et.al (2001) Lawrence (2003) Wei (2002) Shintani (2002)
data source OECD survey Eurostat OECD survey Economist Economist
Intelligence Unit Intelligence Unit

countries 9 OECD 13 EC 9 OECD 11 EC 15 EC


goods 120 3545 120 95 270
(traded)
period 1990, 1999 1990 1990s 1990s 1990, 2000
average price 32 21 40 44 24
dispersion

Notes: the Table reports the papers and associated data sources that have computed the five price-dispersion
measures mentioned in the text. “Traded’’ refers to traded goods as an unknown subset of the total number of
goods listed.

of price dispersion are included. But since ln(pig)–ln(pjg) across goods, on various vari-
this can be said for an average trade barrier ables related to trade frictions. These include
in the model of 100 percent as well as for an distance, common language, exchange rate
average trade barrier of 200 percent, we volatility, membership of a currency union
cannot expect to learn much about trade and average tariff rate. Using data for four-
barriers from this. teen U.S. cities and cities in 69 other coun-
We saw that more can be learned by tries, they find that such regressions have a
exploiting the variation of price dispersion high adjusted R2 in the range of 0.7 to 0.8.
across location pairs and goods. Parsley and Parsley and Wei are particularly interested
Wei (2001, 2002) and Crucini et al. (2000) in an estimate of the reduction in the tariff
have related location pair-specific price dis- equivalent of trade barriers associated with
persion measures to observables associated currency unions. They find that the price
with trade barriers, while Crucini et al. dispersion measure is reduced by 3.2 per-
(2000, 2001) have related good-specific price cent for non-EMU country pairs with the
dispersion measures to various characteris- same currency and by 4.3 percent for EMU
tics of goods. These studies confirm that countries, relative to countries that do not
variation of price dispersion across location have a common currency. They transform
pairs and goods is related to variation in these into tax equivalents by using that a 1-
trade barriers across locations and goods. percent tariff reduction reduces the price
This is consistent with the results from the dispersion measure by 0.86 percent. The
model we discussed. The main weakness of reduction in the tax equivalent of trade bar-
the literature so far is that the empirical work riers is then 3.7 percent for non-EMU coun-
is not based on any particular trade model. tries in a currency union and 5 percent for
Parsley and Wei (2002) regress the loca- EMU countries. These are much lower esti-
tion pair-specific fourth price dispersion mates of international trade barriers than
measure, the standard deviation of those based on trade volume data in the
746 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

gravity literature. The important difference context of a trade model that incorporates all
though is that there is a theoretical founda- major sources of price differentials: interna-
tion for estimates based on gravity equa- tional trade costs, domestic trade costs, taxes
tions. Theory does not predict a simple and markups.
linear relationship between price dispersion Which theoretical approach to adopt
and trade barriers. depends on the nature of the survey data.
Parsley and Wei (2001) apply the same There are three different types of data. The
method to relative prices between Japanese first category gives us information about
and U.S. cities for 27 goods. They find that prices of a particular brand (particular make
price dispersion is positively related to dis- and model) in different locations and also
tance and the presence of a border between tells us the location of the producer of that
two cities. They also find that the impor- brand. An example of this is data on auto-
tance of the border has declined during their mobile prices for particular makes and mod-
1976–97 sample. Nominal exchange rate els. The second type of data also gives
volatility and shipping costs help account for detailed price information for a particular
the border effect, but do not explain the brand in various locations, but does not pro-
decline in the border effect over time. vide sufficient information that allows for
Crucini et al. (2000) run a regression of a identification of the producer of the brand.
different price dispersion measure on dis- An example of this is the Eurostat survey
tance and distance squared. Their price dis- data. The third type of price data is not for
persion measure for location pair (i,j) is particular brands, but for an average of rep-
∑ Gg =1(1/G)|pig – pjg|/pg. This is similar to the resentative brands in a sector. An example of
first price dispersion measure discussed this is the OECD survey data.69
above. Applying it to data for thirteen The first type of data is the most inform-
European countries from the mid-1980s, ative about trade costs, but detailed infor-
they find distance to be highly significant, mation of this type is quite rare. In the
with an R2 of 0.53. absence of local trade costs, markups and
Crucini et al. (2001) consider the relation- taxes, the trade barrier is revealed by the
ship between price dispersion and goods price relative to that in the producer’s coun-
characteristics. They do not particularly try. But of course local trade costs, markups
focus on trade costs, but one of their results and taxes are not zero and some modeling is
is closely related to trade costs. They find a still required to extract information about
negative relationship between good-specific trade barriers. A nice illustration is
price dispersion (measure 2 above) and the Goldberg and Verboven (2001), who devel-
level of trade for each good. The latter is op a model for the European car market.
defined as aggregate trade among the coun- They only consider one type of trade barri-
tries in the sample divided by aggregate out- er, quotas for Japanese cars, but their
put. Since more trade is associated with approach could be used more broadly to
lower trade barriers, this result is consistent estimate trade barriers. The price paid by
with a positive relationship between price consumers is equal to marginal cost times a
dispersion and trade barriers. wholesale price markup, times an exoge-
While the results from this literature do nous dealer markup, times the gross value
not yet reveal much about the magnitude of added tax rate, times trade costs associated
actual trade barriers, they suggest that with quotas. The marginal cost is defined to
exploiting the variation of price dispersion include the cost of local distribution and
across goods and location pairs is a natural
direction to go to learn about the size of 69
Bradford and Lawrence (2003) provide a description
trade barriers. This needs to be done in the of the aggregation procedures adopted by the OECD.
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 747

marketing in the destination market, which Theory implies that the equilibrium price
depends on the wage rate in the destination indices Pik for consumption category (or sec-
market. The markup charged by producers tor) k are an implicit function of aggregate
is endogenous and depends on both the demand and supply in every country and all
supply and demand side of the model. bilateral trade barriers. After adopting a spe-
Estimation of the parameters of the model, cific trade cost function, the equilibrium
together with data on taxes and exogenous price indices will depend on observables and
dealer markups, then yields an estimate of parameters of the trade cost function that
trade costs associated with quota. need to be estimated. If we interpret the
Next consider the second type of data, price data for consumption categories as the
where we do not know the location of the Pik, plus measurement error, the trade cost
producer. One can of course make an parameters can be estimated with nonlinear
informed guess about who the producer is. least squares.70
Otherwise we need a general equilibrium In applying this approach some other real-
model to tell us which country is the likely istic features need to be added. First, one
producer of a product. As an illustration, needs to allow for tax differences across
consider again the Eaton and Kortum (1992) countries and goods. Second, local trade
model. Production costs for each country are costs tii are probably better modeled as a
not known exactly, only the distribution from function of both local wages and internal dis-
which these costs are drawn. For each good tance. Direct information on local distribu-
in country i we know the probabilities that it tion costs may be used as well. Third, as
is sourced from various countries. The distri- discussed in section 3, introducing fixed costs
bution from which the set of relative prices makes it possible to capture the fact that
is drawn is therefore known and can be used brands from only a limited number of suppli-
to estimate trade barriers after assuming a ers are purchased by a country. Using infor-
specific trade cost function. For realism the mation about the set of suppliers to each
Eaton and Kortum model would need to be country will then make it possible to solve for
extended to allow for local distribution costs, the price indices Pik from (30) and ( 31).
taxes, and markups.
Finally consider the case where the price 5. Conclusion
data are not for individual brands, but for an
average of prices of various brands of a cate- Trade costs are large when broadly
gory of consumption. This may actually defined to include all costs involved in get-
make it easier to extract information about ting a good from producer to final user. Both
trade costs. In this case we can straightfor- international trade costs and local distribu-
wardly apply the gravity model without hav- tion costs are very large and together domi-
ing to make any specific assumptions about nate the marginal cost of production. Trade
the production structure. Simply equating costs also vary widely across countries. On
aggregate demand and aggregate supply, average, developing countries have signifi-
assuming a constant elasticity demand struc- cantly larger trade costs, by a factor of two
ture, yields (6) and (7): or more in some important categories.
1− k
Trade costs also vary widely across product
 tk  Ekj
( )
1− k lines, by factors of as much as ten or more.
 k
i = ∑ j  ijk 
 Pj  Yk
70
It is possible that the average price data are not rep-
1− k resentative of the various brands consumed and therefore
 tk 
(P ) Yik
1− k
= ∑i  ijk 
k not a good proxy for Pik. An alternative approach is to use
j . price data for individual brands from the second type of
 i  Yk data and aggregate those up to the price indices .
748 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

The patterns of variation make some eco- Policy,” Int. Econ. Rev. 44:2, pp. 627–49.
Anderson, James E. and Eric van Wincoop. 2002.
nomic sense, but we think more sense can “Borders, Trade and Welfare,” in Brookings Trade
still be extracted. Forum 2001. Susan Collins and Dani Rodrik, eds.
Better measurement of trade costs is high- Washington: Brookings Institution, pp. 207–44.
———. 2003. “Gravity with Gravitas: A Solution to
ly desirable. The quality of the existing the Border Puzzle,” Amer. Econ. Rev. 93:1, pp.
measures is low and can be improved. 170–92.
Direct measures of policy barriers are scan- Anderson, Michael A. and Stephen L.S. Smith. 1999a.
“Canadian Provinces in World Trade: Engagement
dalously difficult to find and to use, consid- and Detachment,” Can. J. Econ. 32:1. pp. 23–37.
ering the importance of trade policy in ———. 1999b. “Do National Borders Really Matter?
overall international policy making and to Canada-US Regional Trade Reconsidered,” Rev. Int.
Econ. 7:2. pp. 219–27.
potential welfare-improving changes. Bacchetta, Philippe and Eric van Wincoop. 2003. “Why
Transport-cost data could relatively easily be Do Consumer Prices React Less than Import Prices
improved greatly. Estimates based on the to Exchange Rates?” J. Europ. Econ. Assoc. forth-
coming.
structural gravity models can also be Baier, Scott L. and Jeffrey H. Bergstrand. 2001. “The
improved. Extensions of existing gravity Growth of World Trade: Tariffs, Transport Costs and
models, better treatment of aggregation and Income Similarity,” J. Int. Econ. 53:1, pp. 1–27.
———. 2003. “Endogenous Free Trade Agreements
endogeneity problems, and better estimates and the Gravity Equation,” Notre Dame U.
of substitution elasticities are all likely to Balistreri, Edward J. and Russell H. Hillberry. 2002.
improve our understanding of trade costs. “Trade Frictions and Welfare in the Gravity Model:
How Much of the Iceberg Melts?” work. pap., US
Our focus is on measuring the costs, only Int. Trade Commission.
glancingly with their explanation. Ultimately, Barro, Robert J. and Silvana Tenreyro. 2002.
the profession should proceed to explana- “Economic Effects of Currency Unions,” work. pap.
Harvard U.
tion. There is undoubtedly a rich relation- Bergstrand, Jeffrey H. 1985. “The Gravity Equation in
ship between domestic and international International Trade: Some Microeconomic
trade costs, market structure, and political Foundations and Empirical Evidence,” Rev. Econ.
Statist. 67:3. pp. 474–81.
economy. Some trade costs provide benefits, ———. 1989. “The Generalized Gravity Equation,
and it is likely that the pursuit of benefits Monopolistic Competition, and the Factor-
partly explains the costs. Proportions Theory in International Trade,” Rev.
Econ. Statist. 71:1. pp. 143–53.
———. 1990. “The Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson
Model, the Linder Hypothesis and the Determinants
REFERENCES
of Bilateral Intra-Industry Trade,” Econ. J. 100:403,
Alesina, Alberto; Robert J. Barro and Silvana Tenreyro. pp. 1216–29.
2002. “Optimum Currency Unions,” NBER Bernard, Andrew B. and J. Bradford Jensen. 2003.
Macroeconomics Annual 2002. “Why Some Firms Export,” Rev. Econ. Statist. forth-
Anderson, James E. 1979. “A Theoretical Foundation coming.
for the Gravity Equation,” Amer. Econ. Rev. 69:1. pp. Bernard, Andrew B. and Joachim Wagner. 2001.
106–16. “Export Entry and Exit by German Firms,”
———. 1994. “The Theory of Protection,” in Surveys Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 137:2. pp. 105–23.
in International Trade. David Greenaway and L. Bradford, Scott C. and Robert Z. Lawrence. 2003.
Alan Winters, eds. Oxford: Blackwell, pp. 107–38. “Paying the Price: The Cost of Fragmented
———. 1998. “Effective Protection Redux,” J. Int. International Markets,” Inst. Int. Econ.:Washington
Econ. 44:1, pp. 21–44. DC, forthcoming.
———. 2000. “Why Do Nations Trade (So Little)?” Broda, Christian and John Romalis. 2003. “Identifying
Pacific Econ. Rev. 5:2, pp. 115–34. the Relationship between Trade and Exchange Rate
Anderson, James E. and Douglas Marcouiller. 2002. Volatility,” work. pap., U. Chicago GSB.
“Insecurity and the Pattern of Trade: An Empirical Brown W. Mark. 2003. “Overcoming Distance,
Investigation,” Rev. Econ. Statist. 84:2, pp. 345–52. Overcoming Borders: Comparing North American
Anderson, James E. and J. Peter Neary. 1994. “The Regional Trade,” research pap. 8, Micro-Economic
Trade Restrictiveness of the Multi-Fibre Arrange- Analysis Division, Statistics Canada.
ment,” World Bank Econ. Rev. 8:2, pp. 171–89. Brown, W. Mark and William P. Anderson. 2002.
———. 1996. “A New Approach to Evaluating Trade “Spatial Markets and the Potential for Economic
Policy,” Rev. Econ. Stud. 63:1, pp. 107–25. Integration between Canadian and US Regions,”
———. 2003. “The Mercantilist Index of Trade Pap. Reg. Sci. 81:1, pp. 99–120.
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 749

Brun, Jean-Francois; Celine Carrere, Patrick ———. 2003b. “Home Bias in Trade: Location or
Guillaumont and Jaime de Melo. 2002. “Has Foreign-ness?” work. pap. 2001a, Board Gov. Fed.
Distance Died?” CEPR discus. pap. 3500. Reserve System.
Burstein, Ariel; Joao C. Neves and Sergio Rebelo. ———. 2003c. “Border Effects and the Availability of
2003. “Distribution Costs and Real Exchange Rate Domestic Products Abroad,” work. pap. Board Gov.
Dynamics During Exchange-Rate-Based Fed. Reserve System.
Stabilizations,” J. Monet. Econ. 50:6, pp. 1189–214. Evenett, Simon J. and Anthony Venables. 2002. “
Chen, Natalie A. 2002. “Intra-national versus Export Growth in Developing Countries: Market
International Trade in the European Union: Why Do Entry and Bilateral Trade Flows,” work pap.,
National Borders Matter?” CEPR Discus. Pap. 3402. London School Econ.
Coe, David T.; Arvind Subramanian and Natalia Feenstra, Robert C. 1994. “New Product Varieties and
Tamirisa. 2002. “The Missing Globalization Puzzle,” the Measurement of International Prices,” Amer.
work pap. IMF. Econ. Rev. 84:1. pp. 157–77.
Coulombe, Serge. 2002. “Border Effects and North ———. 1998. “Integration of Trade and
American Economic Integration,” work. pap. U. Disintegration of Production in the Global
Ottawa. Economy,” J. Econ. Perspect. 12:4, pp. 31–50.
Crucini, Mario J. and Mototsugu Shintani. 2002. ———. 2002. “The Gravity Equation in International
“Persistence in Law-of-One Price Deviations: Economics: Theory and Evidence,” Scot. J. Polit.
Evidence from Micro-Data,” work. pap. 02-W22, Econ. 49:5, pp. 491–506.
Vanderbilt U. ———. 2003. Advanced International Trade: Theory
Crucini, Mario J.; Chris I. Telmer and Marios and Evidence, Princeton: Princeton U. Press.
Zachariadis. 2000. “Dispersion in Real Exchange Frankel, Jeffrey, Ernesto Stein and Shang-jin Wei.
Rates,” work pap. Vanderbilt U. 1998. “Continental Trading Blocs: Are They Natural
———. 2001. “Understanding European Real or Supernatural?” in The Regionalization of the
Exchange Rates,” work pap. Vanderbilt U. World Economy. J.A. Frankel, ed. Chicago: U.
Davis, Donald. 1998. “The Home Market Effect, Trade Chicago Press, pp. 91–113.
and Industrial Structure,” Amer. Econ. Rev. 88:5, pp. Frankel, Jeffrey A. and Shang-Jin Wei. 1997. “ASEAN
1264–76. in a Regional Perspective,” in Macroeconomic Issues
Deardorff, Alan V. 1979. “One-Way Arbitrage and Its Facing ASEAN Countries. J. Hicklin, D. Robinson
Implications for the Foreign Exchange Markets,” J. and A. Singh, eds. Washington, DC: IMF.
Polit. Econ. 87:2, pp. 351–64. Froot, Kenneth and Kenneth Rogoff. 1995.
———. 1998. “Determinants of Bilateral Trade: Does “Perspectives on PPP and Long-Run Real Exchange
Gravity Work in a Neoclassical World?” in The Rates,” in Handbook of International Economics, vol.
Regionalization of the World Economy. J.A. Frankel, 3. Gene Grossman and Kenneth Rogoff, eds.
ed. Chicago: U. Chicago Press, pp. 7–32. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 1645–729.
Deardorff, Alan V. and Robert M. Stern. 1998. Ghosh, Atish and Holger C. Wolf. 1994. “Pricing in
Measurement of Nontariff Barriers. Ann Arbor: U. International Markets: Lessons from the
Michigan Press. Economist,” NBER work. pap. 4806.
Eaton, Jonathan and Samual Kortum. 2002. Glick, Reuven and Andrew K. Rose. 2002. “Does a
“Technology, Geography and Trade,” Econometrica Currency Union Affect Trade? Time Series
70:5, pp. 1741–79. Evidence,” Europ. Econ. Rev. 46:6, pp. 1125–51.
Engel, Charles. 2002. “Comment on Anderson and van Goldberg, Pinelopi Koujianou and Michael M. Knetter.
Wincoop” in Brookings Trade Forum 2001. Susan 1997. “Goods Prices and Exchange Rates: What
Collins and Dani Rodrik, eds. Washington: Have We Learned?” J. Econ. Lit. 35:3, pp. 1243–72.
Brookings Inst. Goldberg, Pinelopi Koujianou and Frank Verboven.
Engel, Charles and John H. Rogers 1996. ”How Wide 2001. “The Evolution of Price Dispersion in
Is the Border?” Amer. Econ. Rev. 86:5, pp. 1112–25. European Car Markets,” Rev. Econ. Stud. 68:4, pp.
———. 2000. “Relative Price Volatility: What Role 811–48.
Does the Border Play?” in Intranational Gould, David M. 1994. “Immigrant Links to the Home
Macroeconomics. Gregory Hess and Eric van Country: Empirical Implications for US Bilateral
Wincoop, eds. Cambridge: Cambridge U. Press, pp. Trade Flows,” Rev. Econ. Statist. 76:2, pp.302–16.
92–111. Grossman, Gene. 1998. “Comment on Deardorff,” in
.———. 2001. “Deviations from Purchasing Power The Regionalization of the World Economy. J.A.
Parity: Causes and Welfare Costs,” J. Int. Econ. 55:1, Frankel, ed. Chicago: U. Chicago Press, pp. 33–57.
pp. 29–57. Harrigan, James. 1993. “OECD Imports and Trade
Estevadeordal, Antoni; Brian Frantz and Alan M. Barriers in 1983,” J. Int. Econ. 34:1-2, pp. 91–111.
Taylor. 2003. “The Rise and Fall of World Trade, ———. 2002. “Specialization and the Volume of
1870–1939,” Quart. J. Econ. 68:2, pp. 359–408. Trade: Do the Data Obey the Laws?” in Handbook of
Evans, Carolyn L. 2001. “The Costs of Outsourcing,” International Trade. Kwan Choi and James
work. pap. 2001b. Board Gov. Fed. Reserve System. Harrigan, eds. London: Basil Blackwell.
———. 2003a. “The Economic Significance of Haveman, Jon and David Hummels. 2004. “Alternative
National Border Effects,” Amer. Econ. Rev. 93:4. pp. Hypotheses and the Volume of Trade: Evidence on the
1291–312. Extent of Specialization,” Can. J. Econ. forthcoming.
750 Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XLII (September 2004)

Head, Keith and Thierry Mayer. 2000. “Non-Europe: ———. 2001b. “Time as a Trade Barrier,” work pap.,
The Magnitude and Causes of Market Purdue U.
Fragmentation in the EU,” Weltwirtschaftliches Hummels, David; Jun Ishii and Kei-Mu Yi. 2001. “The
Archiv 136:2, pp. 284–314. Nature and Growth of Vertical Specialization in
———. 2001. “Illusory Border Effects: Distance World Trade,” J. Int. Econ. 54:1, pp. 75–96.
Mismeasurement Inflates Estimates of Home Bias in Kelejian, H.H. and Ingmar R. Prucha. 1999. “A
Trade,” work. pap. U. British Columbia. Generalized Moments Estimator for the
Head, Keith and John Ries. 1998. “Immigration and Autoregressive Parameter in a Spatial Model,” Int.
Trade Creation: Evidence from Canada,” Can. J. Econ. Rev. 40:2, pp. 509–33.
Econ. 31:1, pp. 47–62. Kim, Namdoo. 1996. Measuring the Costs of Visible
———. 2001. “Increasing Returns vs National Protection in Korea. Washington: Institute Int. Econ.
Product Differentiation as an Explanation for the Klenow, Peter J. and Andres Rodriguez-Clare. 1997.
Pattern of US-Canada Trade,” Amer. Econ. Rev. “Quantifying Variety Gains from Trade
91:4. pp. 858–76. Liberalization,” work. pap. Stanford U.
Heckscher, E.F. 1916. “Växelkursens Grundval vid Knetter, Michael. 1997.“Why Are Retail Prices in
Pappersmyntfot,” Ekonomisk Tidskrift 18:Oct. pp. Japan So High? Evidence from German Export
309–12. Prices,” Int. J. Ind. Organ. Aug., pp. 549–72.
Helliwell, John F. 1996. “Do National Boundaries Lai, Huiwen and Daniel Trefler. 2002. “The Gains from
Matter for Quebec’s Trade?” Can. J. Econ. 29:3, pp. Trade with Monopolistic Competition: Specification,
507–22. Estimation and Mis-specification,” NBER work.
———. 1997. “National Borders, Trade and pap. 9169.
Migration,” Pacific Econ. Rev. 2:3. pp. 165–85. Laird, Sam and Alexander Yeats. 1990. Quantitative
———. 1998. How Much Do National Borders Methods for Trade-Barrier Analysis. NY: NYU.
Matter? Washington DC: Brookings Inst. Press.
———. 1999. “Perspectives on North American Free Lee, Jong-Wha and Phillip Swagel. 1997. “Trade
Trade: Effects of the Canada-US Free Trade Barriers and Trade Flows Across Countries and
Agreement on Interprovincial Trade,” Industry Industries,” Rev. Econ. Statist. 19:3, pp. 372–82.
Canada Research Publications Program, pap.5. Limao, Nuno and Anthony J. Venables. 2001.
———. 2003. “Border Effects: Assessing Their “Infrastructure, Geographical Disadvantage,
Implications for Canadian Policy in a North Transport Costs and Trade,” World Bank Econ. Rev.
American Context,” work pap., U. British Columbia. 15:3, pp. 451–79.
Helliwell, John F. and Frank C. Lee. 1999. “Effects of Lopez-Cordova, Ernesto J. and Christopher M.
the Canada-United States Free Trade Agreement on Meissner. 2003. “Exchange Rate Regimes and
Interprovincial Trade,” Industry Canada Research International Trade: Evidence from the Classical
Publication Program, pap. 5. Gold Standard Era,” Amer. Econ. Rev. 93:1. pp.
Helliwell, John F. and John McCallum. 1995. “National 344–53.
Borders Still Matter for Trade,” Policy Options 16, McCallum, John. 1995. “National Borders Matter:
pp. 44–48. Canada-US Regional Trade Patterns,” Amer. Econ.
Helliwell, John F. and Genevieve Verdier. 2001. Rev. 85:3, pp. 615–23.
“Measuring Internal Trade Distances: A New Melitz, Jacques. 2003. “Language and Foreign Trade,”
Method Applied to Estimate Provincial Border work pap., U. Strathclyde.
Effects in Canada,” Can. J. Econ. 34:4. pp. 1024–41. Messerlin, Patrick. 2001. Measuring the Cost of
Hillberry, Russell. 1998. “Regional Trade and the Protection in Europe. Washington DC: Institute Int.
Medicine Line: The National Border Effect in US Econ.
Commodity Flow Data,” J. Borderlands Stud. 8:2, Millimet, Daniel L. and Thomas Osang. 2001. “Do
pp. 1–17. State Borders Matter for US Intranational Trade?
———. 2002. “Aggregation Bias, Compositional The Role of History and Internal Migration,” work
Change and the Border Effect,” Can. J. Econ. 35:3, pap., Southern Methodist U.
pp. 517–30. Minondo, Asier. 2002. “Borders and Trade in Europe:
Hillberry, Russell and David Hummels. 2002a. “Intra- A Fresh Analysis on the Extent of the Home-Bias
National Home Bias: Some Explanations,” NBER Effect,” work pap., U. Deusto-ESTE, San Sebastian.
work. pap. 9022, Rev. Econ. Statist. forthcoming. Nitsch, Volker. 2000. “National Borders and
———. 2002b. “Explaining Home Bias in International Trade: Evidence from the European
Consumption: The Role of Intermediate Input Union,” Can. J. Econ. 33:4. pp. 1091–105.
Trade,” work. pap. 9020, NBER Cambridge, MA. Obstfeld, Maurice and Kenneth Rogoff. 2000. “The
Hufbauer, Gary and Kimberly Ann Elliott. 1994. the Six Major Puzzles in International Macroeconomics.
Cost of Protection in the United States. Washington: Is There a Common Cause?” in NBER
Institute Int. Econ. Macroeconomics Annual 2000. B.S. Bernanke and
Hummels, David. 1999. “Have International K. Rogoff, eds. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp.
Transportation Costs Declined?” work pap., 339–90.
Purdue U. Obstfeld, Maurice and Alan M. Taylor. 1997.
———. 2001a. “Toward a Geography of Trade Costs,” “Nonlinear Aspects of Goods-Market Arbitrage and
work pap., Purdue U. Adjustment: Heckscher’s Commodity Points
Anderson and van Wincoop: Trade Costs 751

Revisited,” J. Japan. Int. Econ. 11:Dec. pp. 441–79. “National Money as a Barrier to Trade: The Real
O’Connel, Paul G.J. and Shang-Jin Wei. 2002. “The Case for Currency Union,” Amer. Econ. Rev. Pap.
Bigger They Are, the Harder They Fall: Retail Price Proceed. 91:2. pp. 386–90.
Differences across US Cities,” J. Int. Econ. 56:1, pp. Sazanami, Yoko, Shujiro Urate and Hiroki Kawai. 1995.
21–53. Measuring the Costs of Pretection in Japan.
O’Rourke, Kevin H. and Jeffrey G. Williamson. 1999. Washington: Institute Int. Econ.
Globalization and History: The Evolution of a Staiger, Robert W. and Frank A. Wolak. 1994.
Nineteenth Century Atlantic Economy. Cambridge: “Measuring Industry Specific Protection:
MIT Press. Antidumping in the United States,” Brookings Pap.
Parsley, David C. and Shang-Jin Wei. 2001. “Explaining Econ. Act.: Microecon. pp. 51–118.
the Border Effect: The Role of Exchange Rate Taylor, Alan M. 2001. “Potential Pitfalls for the
Variability, Shipping Costs and Geography,” J. Int. Purchasing-Power-Parity Puzzle? Sampling and
Econ. 55:1, pp. 87–105. Specification Biases in Mean-Reversion Tests of the
———. 2002. “Currency Arrangements and Goods Law of One Price,” Econometrica 69:2, pp. 473–98.
Market Integration: A Price Based Approach,” work Tchamourliyski, Yuriy. 2002. “Distance and Bilateral
pap. Vanderbilt U. Trade: The Role of Non-Homothetic Preferences,”
Portes, Richard and Helene Rey. 2002. “The work pap. Boston College.
Determinants of Cross-Border Equity Transaction Trefler, Daniel. 1993) “Trade Liberalization and the
Flows,” work pap., London Bus. School. Theory of Endogenous Protection: An Econometric
Rauch, James E. and Vitor Trindade. 2002. ”Ethnic Study of US Import Policy,” J. Polit. Econ. 101:1, pp.
Chinese Networks in International Trade,” Rev. 138–60.
Econ. Statist. 84:1, pp. 116–30. Wei, Shang-Jin. 1996. “Intra-national versus Inter-
Ritschl, Albrecht and Nikolaus Wolf. 2003. national Trade: How Stubborn Are Nations in Global
“Endogeneity of Currency Areas and Trade Blocs: Integration?” NBER work. pap. 5531, Cambridge,
Evidence from the Inter-War Period,” work pap., MA.
Humboldt U. Wolf, Holger. 2000a. “(Why) Do Borders Matter For
Roberts, Mark and James Tybout. 1997. ”The Decision Trade?” in Intranational Macroeconomics. G.D.
to Export in Colombia: An Empirical Model of Entry Hess and E. van Wincoop, eds. Cambridge:
with Sunk Costs,” Amer. Econ. Rev. 87:4, pp. 545–64. Cambridge U. Press, pp. 112–28.
Rose, Andrew K. 2000. “One Money, One Market: ————. 2000b. “Intranational Home Bias in Trade,”
Estimating the Effect of Common Currencies on Rev. Econ. Statist. 82:4. pp. 555–63.
Trade,” Econ. Pol. 30, pp. 7–45. Yi, Kei-Mu. 2003a. “Can Vertical Specialization Explain
———. 2004. “The Effect of Common Currencies on the Growth of World Trade?” J. Polit. Econ. 111:1.
International Trade: A Meta-Analysis,” in Monetary pp. 52–102.
Unions and Hard Pegs: Effects on Trade, Financial ————. 2003b. “A Simple Explanation for the
Development and Stability. Volbert Alexander, Border Effect,” work pap., Fed. Reserve Bank NY.
Jacques Melitz and George M. von Furstenberg, eds. Zhang Shuguang; Zhang Yansheng and Wan Zhongxin.
Oxford U. Press. 1998. Measuring the Costs of Protection in China.
Rose, Andrew K. and Eric van Wincoop. 2001. Washington DC: Institute Int. Econ.
This article has been cited by:

1. Joras Ferwerda, Mark Kattenberg, Han-Hsin Chang, Brigitte Unger, Loek Groot, Jacob A. Bikker.
2013. Gravity models of trade-based money laundering. Applied Economics 45:22, 3170-3182.
[CrossRef]
2. I. Sheldon, S. Khadka Mishra, D. Pick, S. R. Thompson. 2013. Exchange rate uncertainty and
US bilateral fresh fruit and fresh vegetable trade: an application of the gravity model. Applied
Economics 45:15, 2067-2082. [CrossRef]
3. Ignacio del Rosal. 2013. Delivery terms in international trade: some evidence for Spain. Applied
Economics Letters 20:6, 606-610. [CrossRef]
4. Richard Fabling, Arthur Grimes, Lynda Sanderson. 2013. Any port in a storm: Impacts of
new port infrastructure on exporter behaviour. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and
Transportation Review 49:1, 33-47. [CrossRef]
5. Mahmut Yasar, David Lisner, Roderick M. Rejesus. 2012. Bilateral trade impacts of temporary
foreign visitor policy. Review of World Economics 148:3, 501-521. [CrossRef]
6. Arijit Mukherjee, Kullapat Suetrong. 2012. Trade cost reduction and foreign direct investment.
Economic Modelling 29:5, 1938-1945. [CrossRef]
7. Xuan Wei, Suzanne Thornsbury. 2012. Firm level export decisions: The role of information cost.
Economics Letters 116:3, 487-490. [CrossRef]
8. Nelson Villoria. 2012. The effects of China's growth on the food prices and the food exports of
other developing countries. Agricultural Economics 43:5, 499-514. [CrossRef]
9. David Berger, Jon Faust, John H. Rogers, Kai Steverson. 2012. Border prices and retail prices.
Journal of International Economics 88:1, 62-73. [CrossRef]
10. Thomas J. Holmes, John J. Stevens. 2012. Exports, borders, distance, and plant size. Journal of
International Economics 88:1, 91-103. [CrossRef]
11. Dennis Novy. 2012. International Trade without CES: Estimating Translog Gravity. Journal of
International Economics . [CrossRef]
12. Frank Barry, Adele Bergin. 2012. Inward Investment and Irish Exports over the Recession and
Beyond. The World Economy no-no. [CrossRef]
13. Marco Fugazza, Alessandro Nicita. 2012. The Direct and Relative Effects of Preferential Market
Access. Journal of International Economics . [CrossRef]
14. David Chilosi, Tommy E. Murphy, Roman Studer, A. Co#kun Tunçer. 2012. Europe's Many
Integrations: Geography and Grain Markets, 1620–1913. Explorations in Economic History .
[CrossRef]
15. Xiaohua Bao, Larry D. Qiu. 2012. How Do Technical Barriers to Trade Influence Trade?. Review
of International Economics 20:4, 691-706. [CrossRef]
16. Shiro P. Armstrong. 2012. The Politics of Japan-China Trade and the Role of the World Trade
System. The World Economy 35:9, 1102-1120. [CrossRef]
17. Sergi Basco, Martí Mestieri. 2012. Heterogeneous trade costs and wage inequality: A model of
two globalizations. Journal of International Economics . [CrossRef]
18. Takumi Naito. 2012. Aid for trade, infrastructure, and growth. International Tax and Public
Finance . [CrossRef]
19. C. Arkolakis, M.-A. Muendler. 2012. Exporters and Their Products: A Collection of Empirical
Regularities. CESifo Economic Studies . [CrossRef]
20. Peter H. Egger, Andrea Lassmann. 2012. The language effect in international trade: A meta-
analysis. Economics Letters 116:2, 221-224. [CrossRef]
21. Peter H. Egger, Mario Larch. 2012. Tariff evasion effects in quantitative general equilibrium.
Economics Letters 116:2, 262-264. [CrossRef]
22. Pascal L. Ghazalian, Lota D. Tamini, Bruno Larue, Jean-Philippe Gervais. 2012. A gravity model
to account for vertical linkages between markets with an application to the cattle/beef sector. The
Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 21:4, 579-601. [CrossRef]
23. Kenji Fujiwara. 2012. Market integration, environmental policy, and transboundry pollution from
consumption. The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 21:4, 603-614.
[CrossRef]
24. BÉATRICE DEDINGER. 2012. The Franco-German trade puzzle: an analysis of the economic
consequences of the Franco-Prussian war1. The Economic History Review 65:3, 1029-1054.
[CrossRef]
25. Kristian Behrens, Cem Ertur, Wilfried Koch. 2012. ‘DUAL’ GRAVITY: USING SPATIAL
ECONOMETRICS TO CONTROL FOR MULTILATERAL RESISTANCE. Journal of Applied
Econometrics 27:5, 773-794. [CrossRef]
26. Miguel Gómez-Antonio, Bernard Fingleton. 2012. ANALYZING THE IMPACT OF PUBLIC
CAPITAL STOCK USING THE NEG WAGE EQUATION: A SPATIAL PANEL DATA
APPROACH. Journal of Regional Science 52:3, 486-502. [CrossRef]
27. Alberto Behar, Philip Manners, Benjamin D. Nelson. 2012. Exports and International Logistics*.
Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics no-no. [CrossRef]
28. José de Sousa, Thierry Mayer, Soledad Zignago. 2012. Market access in global and regional trade.
Regional Science and Urban Economics . [CrossRef]
29. Julian di Giovanni, Andrei A. Levchenko. 2012. Firm entry, trade, and welfare in Zipf's world.
Journal of International Economics . [CrossRef]
30. Ling Feng, Ching-Yi Lin. 2012. Financial shocks and exports. International Review of Economics
& Finance . [CrossRef]
31. Alberto Portugal-Perez, John S. Wilson. 2012. Export Performance and Trade Facilitation Reform:
Hard and Soft Infrastructure. World Development 40:7, 1295-1307. [CrossRef]
32. T. Mori. 2012. Increasing returns in transportation and the formation of hubs. Journal of Economic
Geography 12:4, 877-897. [CrossRef]
33. Marios Zachariadis. 2012. Immigration and international prices. Journal of International
Economics 87:2, 298-311. [CrossRef]
34. Yohei Okawa, Eric van Wincoop. 2012. Gravity in International Finance. Journal of International
Economics 87:2, 205-215. [CrossRef]
35. OZLEM INANC, MARIOS ZACHARIADIS. 2012. THE IMPORTANCE OF TRADE COSTS
IN DEVIATIONS FROM THE LAW-OF-ONE-PRICE: ESTIMATES BASED ON THE
DIRECTION OF TRADE. Economic Inquiry 50:3, 667-689. [CrossRef]
36. NATALIE CHEN, DENNIS NOVY. 2012. On the measurement of trade costs: direct vs. indirect
approaches to quantifying standards and technical regulations. World Trade Review 11:03,
401-414. [CrossRef]
37. Mariana Vijil, Laurent Wagner. 2012. Does Aid for Trade Enhance Export Performance?
Investigating the Infrastructure Channel. The World Economy 35:7, 838-868. [CrossRef]
38. José de Sousa. 2012. The currency union effect on trade is decreasing over time. Economics Letters
. [CrossRef]
39. Pascal L. Ghazalian. 2012. Home Bias in Primary Agricultural and Processed Food Trade:
Assessing the Effects of National Degree of Uncertainty Aversion. Journal of Agricultural
Economics 63:2, 265-290. [CrossRef]
40. Sugata Marjit, Biswajit Mandal. 2012. Domestic trading costs and pure theory of international
trade. International Journal of Economic Theory 8:2, 165-178. [CrossRef]
41. Giancarlo Corsetti, Philippe Martin, Paolo Pesenti. 2012. Varieties and the transfer problem.
Journal of International Economics . [CrossRef]
42. SHINTARO HAMANAKA, ROMANA DOMINGO. 2012. MEASURING LONG-TERM
COMMODITY-LEVEL TRADE COSTS: THE CASE OF ASIA. Journal of International
Commerce, Economics and Policy 03:02, 1250014. [CrossRef]
43. Sebastian Krautheim. 2012. Heterogeneous firms, exporter networks and the effect of distance on
international trade. Journal of International Economics 87:1, 27-35. [CrossRef]
44. Takumi Naito. 2012. A Ricardian model of trade and growth with endogenous trade status. Journal
of International Economics 87:1, 80-88. [CrossRef]
45. Matthias Busse, Ruth Hoekstra, Jens Königer. 2012. The Impact of Aid for Trade Facilitation on
the Costs of Trading. Kyklos 65:2, 143-163. [CrossRef]
46. Christoph Fischer. 2012. Price convergence in the EMU? Evidence from micro data. European
Economic Review 56:4, 757-776. [CrossRef]
47. Gordon H. Hanson. 2012. The Rise of Middle Kingdoms: Emerging Economies in Global Trade.
Journal of Economic Perspectives 26:2, 41-64. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
48. Jonathan Eaton, , Samuel Kortum. 2012. Putting Ricardo to Work. Journal of Economic
Perspectives 26:2, 65-90. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
49. Yongwan Chun, Hyun Kim, Changjoo Kim. 2012. Modeling interregional commodity flows with
incorporating network autocorrelation in spatial interaction models: An application of the US
interstate commodity flows. Computers, Environment and Urban Systems . [CrossRef]
50. Zhigang Li, Xiaohua Yu, Yinchu Zeng, Rainer Holst. 2012. Estimating transport costs and trade
barriers in China: Direct evidence from Chinese agricultural traders. China Economic Review .
[CrossRef]
51. Jeffrey H. Bergstrand, Peter Egger, Mario Larch. 2012. Gravity Redux: Estimation of gravity-
equation coefficients, elasticities of substitution, and general equilibrium comparative statics under
asymmetric bilateral trade costs. Journal of International Economics . [CrossRef]
52. Serge Shikher. 2012. International production, technology diffusion, and trade. The Journal of
International Trade & Economic Development 1-44. [CrossRef]
53. Kevin K Boeh, Paul W Beamish. 2012. Travel time and the liability of distance in foreign
direct investment: Location choice and entry mode. Journal of International Business Studies .
[CrossRef]
54. Hsiu-Ling Wu, Chien-Hsun Chen, Li-Ting Chen. 2012. Determinants of Foreign Trade in China's
Textile Industry. The International Trade Journal 26:2, 112-138. [CrossRef]
55. Guo-xue WEI, Ji-kun HUANG, Jun YANG. 2012. Honey Safety Standards and Its Impacts on
China's Honey Export. Journal of Integrative Agriculture 11:4, 684-693. [CrossRef]
56. SERGE SHIKHER. 2012. DETERMINANTS OF TRADE AND SPECIALIZATION IN THE
ORGANISATION FOR ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT COUNTRIES.
Economic Inquiry no-no. [CrossRef]
57. Andrea Finicelli, Patrizio Pagano, Massimo Sbracia. 2012. Ricardian selection. Journal of
International Economics . [CrossRef]
58. Michele Fratianni, Francesco Marchionne. 2012. Trade Costs and Economic Development.
Economic Geography no-no. [CrossRef]
59. C. C. Coughlin, D. Novy. 2012. Is the International Border Effect Larger than the Domestic Border
Effect? Evidence from US Trade. CESifo Economic Studies . [CrossRef]
60. Serge Shikher. 2012. Putting industries into the Eaton–Kortum model. The Journal of International
Trade & Economic Development 1-31. [CrossRef]
61. Costas Arkolakis, , Arnaud Costinot, , Andrés Rodríguez-Clare. 2012. New Trade Models, Same
Old Gains?. American Economic Review 102:1, 94-130. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with
links]
62. Peter H. Egger, Maximilian von Ehrlich, Douglas R. Nelson. 2012. Migration and Trade. The
World Economy 35:2, 216-241. [CrossRef]
63. Simone Juhasz Silva, Douglas Nelson. 2012. Does Aid Cause Trade? Evidence from an
Asymmetric Gravity Model. The World Economy no-no. [CrossRef]
64. Patricia Sourdin, Richard Pomfret. 2012. Measuring International Trade Costs. The World
Economy no-no. [CrossRef]
65. Gabriel J. Felbermayr, Farid Toubal. 2012. Revisiting the Trade-Migration Nexus: Evidence from
New OECD Data. World Development . [CrossRef]
66. Warren H. Hausman, Hau L. Lee, Uma Subramanian. 2012. The Impact of Logistics Performance
on Trade. Production and Operations Management n/a-n/a. [CrossRef]
67. DENNIS NOVY. 2012. GRAVITY REDUX: MEASURING INTERNATIONAL TRADE
COSTS WITH PANEL DATA. Economic Inquiry no-no. [CrossRef]
68. Céline Carrère, Jaime de Melo, John Wilson. 2012. THE DISTANCE PUZZLE AND LOW-
INCOME COUNTRIES: AN UPDATE. Journal of Economic Surveys no-no. [CrossRef]
69. Laura Márquez-Ramos, Inmaculada Martínez-Zarzoso, Celestino Suárez-Burguet. 2012. Trade
Policy versus Trade Facilitation: An Application Using "Good Old" OLS. Economics: The Open-
Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal . [CrossRef]
70. Matthias Helble, Catherine L. Mann, John S. Wilson. 2011. Aid-for-trade facilitation. Review of
World Economics . [CrossRef]
71. P. Egger, T. Seidel. 2011. Tax competition, trade liberalization, and imperfect labour markets.
Oxford Economic Papers 63:4, 722-739. [CrossRef]
72. NIKOLAUS WOLF, MAX-STEPHAN SCHULZE, HANS-CHRISTIAN HEINEMEYER. 2011.
On the Economic Consequences of the Peace: Trade and Borders After Versailles. The Journal of
Economic History 71:04, 915-949. [CrossRef]
73. Gregory Corcos, Massimo Del Gatto, Giordano Mion, Gianmarco I.P. Ottaviano. 2011.
Productivity and Firm Selection: Quantifying the ‘New’ Gains from Trade*. The Economic
Journal no-no. [CrossRef]
74. Prabir De. 2011. Why is trade at borders a costly affair in South Asia? An empirical investigation.
Contemporary South Asia 19:4, 441-464. [CrossRef]
75. Ivan T. Kandilov, Thomas Grennes. 2011. The determinants of service offshoring: Does distance
matter?. Japan and the World Economy . [CrossRef]
76. Pedro Albarran, Raquel Carrasco, Adelheid Holl. 2011. Domestic transport infrastructure and
firms’ export market participation. Small Business Economics . [CrossRef]
77. J. H. Grant, K. A. Boys. 2011. Agricultural Trade and the GATT/WTO: Does Membership Make
a Difference?. American Journal of Agricultural Economics . [CrossRef]
78. M. Crozet, K. Head, T. Mayer. 2011. Quality Sorting and Trade: Firm-level Evidence for French
Wine. The Review of Economic Studies . [CrossRef]
79. Oliver Holtemöller, Götz Zeddies. 2011. Has the Euro increased international price elasticities?.
Empirica . [CrossRef]
80. Gerrit Faber, Michiel Gerritse. 2011. Foreign determinants of local institutions: Spatial dependence
and openness. European Journal of Political Economy . [CrossRef]
81. Andrew J. Nelson, Edmund J. Zolnik. 2011. Regional Effects of Trade on Income. Regional Studies
1-16. [CrossRef]
82. Miguel Fuentes, Pablo Ibarrarán. 2011. Firm dynamics and real exchange rate fluctuations:
Does trade openness matter? Evidence from Mexico's manufacturing sector. The Journal of
International Trade & Economic Development 1-61. [CrossRef]
83. Jean-Baptiste Chesneau, Elisabeth Net, Staffan Berg. 2011. A transport tool to evaluate
sustainability impacts of transport processes within the Forest Wood Chain. European Journal of
Forest Research . [CrossRef]
84. Lota Tamini, Pascal Ghazalian, Jean-Philippe Gervais, Bruno Larue. 2011. Trade Liberalization
in Primary and Processed Agricultural Products: Should Developing Countries Favour Tariff or
Domestic Support Reductions?. International Economic Journal 1-23. [CrossRef]
85. Steven Yamarik, Sucharita Ghosh. 2011. Is natural openness or trade policy good for the
environment?. Environment and Development Economics 1-28. [CrossRef]
86. Michael A. Clemens. 2011. Economics and Emigration: Trillion-Dollar Bills on the Sidewalk?.
Journal of Economic Perspectives 25:3, 83-106. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
87. P. Antras, A. Costinot. 2011. Intermediated Trade. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 126:3,
1319-1374. [CrossRef]
88. Rahul Giri. 2011. Local costs of distribution, international trade costs and micro evidence on the
law of one price. Journal of International Economics . [CrossRef]
89. Hakan Yilmazkuday. 2011. Understanding interstate trade patterns. Journal of International
Economics . [CrossRef]
90. Benjamin Bridgman. 2011. The rise of vertical specialization trade. Journal of International
Economics . [CrossRef]
91. Huasheng Song, Jacques-François Thisse, Xiwei Zhu. 2011. Urbanization and/or Rural
Industrialization in China. Regional Science and Urban Economics . [CrossRef]
92. GIOVANNI FEDERICO. 2011. How much do we know about market integration in Europe?1.
The Economic History Review no-no. [CrossRef]
93. A. B. Bernard, S. J. Redding, P. K. Schott. 2011. Multiproduct Firms and Trade Liberalization.
The Quarterly Journal of Economics . [CrossRef]
94. Raú l Serrano, Vicente Pinilla. 2011. The long-run decline in the share of agricultural and food
products in international trade: a gravity equation approach to its causes. Applied Economics 1-12.
[CrossRef]
95. Douglas H. Brooks, Benno Ferrarini. 2011. Asia’s Melting Trade Costs. The World Economy 34:7,
1138-1147. [CrossRef]
96. Natalie Chen, Dennis Novy. 2011. Gravity, trade integration, and heterogeneity across industries.
Journal of International Economics . [CrossRef]
97. J. Scott Davis, Kevin X.D. Huang. 2011. International real business cycles with endogenous
markup variability. Journal of International Economics . [CrossRef]
98. Patrik Gustavsson Tingvall, Andreas Poldahl. 2011. Determinants of Firm R&D: The Role of
Relationship-Specific Interactions for R&D Spillovers. Journal of Industry, Competition and
Trade . [CrossRef]
99. Philip Sauré. 2011. Bounded Love of Variety and Patterns of Trade. Open Economies Review .
[CrossRef]
100. Iván Arribas, Francisco Pérez, Emili Tortosa-Ausina. 2011. A New Interpretation of the Distance
Puzzle Based on Geographic Neutrality. Economic Geography no-no. [CrossRef]
101. Richard Kneller, Mauro Pisu. 2011. Barriers to Exporting: What are They and Who do They Matter
to?. The World Economy 34:6, 893-930. [CrossRef]
102. Noel Gaston, Douglas R. Nelson. 2011. BRIDGING TRADE THEORY AND LABOUR
ECONOMETRICS: THE EFFECTS OF INTERNATIONAL MIGRATION*. Journal of
Economic Surveys no-no. [CrossRef]
103. Nobuaki Yamashita. 2011. Production sharing and trade flows: A comparative analysis of Japan
and the US. Journal of Asian Economics . [CrossRef]
104. Efthymios G Pavlidis, Ivan Paya, David A Peel. 2011. Real Exchange Rates and Time-Varying
Trade Costs. Journal of International Money and Finance . [CrossRef]
105. Bernard Hoekman, Alessandro Nicita. 2011. Trade Policy, Trade Costs, and Developing Country
Trade. World Development . [CrossRef]
106. Olivier Parent, James P. LeSage. 2011. DETERMINANTS OF KNOWLEDGE PRODUCTION
AND THEIR EFFECTS ON REGIONAL ECONOMIC GROWTH. Journal of Regional Science
no-no. [CrossRef]
107. Chung-Yi Tse. 2011. THE SPATIAL ORIGIN OF COMMERCE*. International Economic
Review 52:2, 349-377. [CrossRef]
108. Peter Egger, David Greenaway, Tobias Seidel. 2011. Rigid labour markets with trade and capital
mobility: theory and evidence. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique
44:2, 509-540. [CrossRef]
109. Gianluca Cafiso. 2011. Rose effect versus border effect: the Euro's impact on trade. Applied
Economics 43:13, 1691-1702. [CrossRef]
110. Valentina Raimondi, Alessandro Olper. 2011. Trade Elasticity, Gravity and Trade Liberalisation:
Evidence from the Food Industry. Journal of Agricultural Economics no-no. [CrossRef]
111. E. Chevassus-Lozza, K. Latouche. 2011. Firms, markets and trade costs: access of French exporters
to European agri-food markets. European Review of Agricultural Economics . [CrossRef]
112. Gabriel Felbermayr, Julien Prat. 2011. PRODUCT MARKET REGULATION, FIRM
SELECTION, AND UNEMPLOYMENT. Journal of the European Economic Association 9:2,
278-317. [CrossRef]
113. GIOVANNI FEDERICO. 2011. When did European markets integrate?. European Review of
Economic History 15:01, 93-126. [CrossRef]
114. Francesca Sanna-Randaccio, Roberta Sestini. 2011. Foreign Direct Investment and Environmental
Policy: Have Location Factors Been Neglected?. Asia-Pacific Journal of Accounting & Economics
18:1, 45-60. [CrossRef]
115. Imran Ullah Khan, Kaliappa Kalirajan. 2011. The impact of trade costs on exports: An empirical
modeling#. Economic Modelling . [CrossRef]
116. Pierre-Philippe Combes. 2011. The empirics of economic geography: how to draw policy
implications?. Review of World Economics . [CrossRef]
117. Marcela Sabaté, Carmen Fillat, Ana Belén Gracia. 2011. The peripheral protectionist backlash in
the First Globalization: Spain (1870-1913). Revista de Historia Económica / Journal of Iberian
and Latin American Economic History 29:01, 95-121. [CrossRef]
118. Wim Naudé, Marianne Matthee. 2011. The impact of transport costs on new venture
internationalisation. Journal of International Entrepreneurship 9:1, 62-89. [CrossRef]
119. A.K.M. Mahbub Morshed. 2011. Border effects in the variability of rice price in the Indian
subcontinent: Results from a natural experiment. Journal of Asian Economics . [CrossRef]
120. Edward J. Balistreri, Russell H. Hillberry, Thomas F. Rutherford. 2011. Structural estimation
and solution of international trade models with heterogeneous firms. Journal of International
Economics 83:2, 95-108. [CrossRef]
121. David S. Jacks, Christopher M. Meissner, Dennis Novy. 2011. Trade booms, trade busts, and trade
costs. Journal of International Economics 83:2, 185-201. [CrossRef]
122. Serge Shikher. 2011. Capital, technology, and specialization in the neoclassical model. Journal of
International Economics 83:2, 229-242. [CrossRef]
123. Donald R. Davis, James Harrigan. 2011. Good jobs, bad jobs, and trade liberalization. Journal of
International Economics . [CrossRef]
124. Gabriel J. Felbermayr, Benjamin Jung. 2011. Sorting It Out: Technical Barriers to Trade and
Industry Productivity. Open Economies Review 22:1, 93-117. [CrossRef]
125. Christian Volpe Martincus, Jeronimo Carballo, Andres Gallo. 2011. The impact of export
promotion institutions on trade: is it the intensive or the extensive margin?. Applied Economics
Letters 18:2, 127-132. [CrossRef]
126. Pedro Cavalcanti Ferreira, Alberto Trejos. 2011. Gains from trade and measured total factor
productivity. Review of Economic Dynamics . [CrossRef]
127. Kenji Fujiwara. 2011. Market Integration and Competition in Environmental and Trade Policies.
Environmental and Resource Economics . [CrossRef]
128. Majid Ghorbani. 2011. Immigrant effect in melting pot and multicultural societies: a comparison
between the USA and Canada. Journal of Asia Business Studies 5:1, 23-41. [CrossRef]
129. Xiaoyun Liu, Xian Xin. 2011. Why Has China's Trade Grown So Fast? A Demand-Side
Perspective. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 47:1, 90-100. [CrossRef]
130. T. Kemeny. 2011. Are international technology gaps growing or shrinking in the age of
globalization?. Journal of Economic Geography 11:1, 1-35. [CrossRef]
131. Byron S. Gangnes, Alyson C. Ma, Ari Van Assche. 2011. China's exports in a world of increasing
oil prices. Multinational Business Review 19:2, 133-151. [CrossRef]
132. Gordon Hanson, Chong Xiang. 2011. Trade barriers and trade flows with product heterogeneity:
An application to US motion picture exports. Journal of International Economics 83:1, 14-26.
[CrossRef]
133. Ivan Kandilov, Xiaoyong Zheng. 2011. The impact of entry costs on export market participation
in agriculture. Agricultural Economics no-no. [CrossRef]
134. Marilyne Huchet-Bourdon, Angela Cheptea. 2011. Informal barriers and agricultural trade: does
monetary integration matter?. Agricultural Economics no-no. [CrossRef]
135. Richard Friberg, Robert W. Paterson, Andrew D. Richardson. 2011. Why is there a Home Bias?
A Case Study of Wine. Journal of Wine Economics 6:01, 37-66. [CrossRef]
136. James E. Anderson, , Yoto V. Yotov. 2010. The Changing Incidence of Geography. American
Economic Review 100:5, 2157-2186. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
137. Michael E. Waugh. 2010. International Trade and Income Differences. American Economic
Review 100:5, 2093-2124. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
138. George Alessandria, , Joseph P. Kaboski, , Virgiliu Midrigan. 2010. Inventories, Lumpy Trade,
and Large Devaluations. American Economic Review 100:5, 2304-2339. [Abstract] [View PDF
article] [PDF with links]
139. Jeffrey J. Reimer, Sang M. Kang. 2010. Estimation of trade and domestic distortions: an application
to world agriculture. Journal of Productivity Analysis 34:3, 257-265. [CrossRef]
140. Jan Havenga. 2010. LOGISTICS COSTS IN SOUTH AFRICA - THE CASE FOR
MACROECONOMIC MEASUREMENT. South African Journal of Economics 78:4, 460-476.
[CrossRef]
141. Barry Eichengreen, Douglas A. Irwin. 2010. The Slide to Protectionism in the Great Depression:
Who Succumbed and Why?. The Journal of Economic History 70:04, 871-897. [CrossRef]
142. Olly Norojono, David Roland-Holst, Guntur Sugiyarto. 2010. Macroeconomic Effects of
Road Corridor Investment in Kazakhstan. Transportation Research Record: Journal of the
Transportation Research Board 2162:-1, 90-97. [CrossRef]
143. Richard Pomfret, Patricia Sourdin. 2010. Why do trade costs vary?. Review of World Economics
146:4, 709-730. [CrossRef]
144. Andrei A Levchenko, Logan T Lewis, Linda L Tesar. 2010. The Collapse of International Trade
during the 2008–09 Crisis: In Search of the Smoking Gun. IMF Economic Review 58:2, 214-253.
[CrossRef]
145. L. D. Tamini, J.-P. Gervais, B. Larue. 2010. Trade liberalisation effects on agricultural goods
at different processing stages. European Review of Agricultural Economics 37:4, 453-477.
[CrossRef]
146. Alberto Portugal-Perez, José-Daniel Reyes, John S. Wilson. 2010. Beyond the Information
Technology Agreement: Harmonisation of Standards and Trade in Electronics. The World
Economy 33:12, 1870-1897. [CrossRef]
147. Francesco Aiello, Paola Cardamone, Maria Rosaria Agostino. 2010. Evaluating the impact of
nonreciprocal trade preferences using gravity models. Applied Economics 42:29, 3745-3760.
[CrossRef]
148. Marcus Sundberg. 2010. Optimal fragmentation in monopolistically competitive industries. The
Annals of Regional Science . [CrossRef]
149. Martina Lawless. 2010. Deconstructing gravity: trade costs and extensive and intensive margins.
Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 43:4, 1149-1172. [CrossRef]
150. David S Jacks, Krishna Pendakur. 2010. Global Trade and the Maritime Transport Revolution.
Review of Economics and Statistics 92:4, 745-755. [CrossRef]
151. Davin Chor. 2010. Unpacking sources of comparative advantage: A quantitative approach. Journal
of International Economics 82:2, 152-167. [CrossRef]
152. Nicolas Sauter. 2010. Talking trade: language barriers in intra-Canadian commerce. Empirical
Economics . [CrossRef]
153. Ivan T. Kandilov, Thomas Grennes. 2010. The determinants of service exports from Central and
Eastern Europe. Economics of Transition 18:4, 763-794. [CrossRef]
154. Peter Egger, Douglas Nelson. 2010. How Bad Is Antidumping? Evidence from Panel Data. Review
of Economics and Statistics 110823094915005. [CrossRef]
155. R. S. Grossman, C. M. Meissner. 2010. International aspects of the Great Depression and the crisis
of 2007: similarities, differences, and lessons. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 26:3, 318-338.
[CrossRef]
156. Guillaume Daudin. 2010. Domestic Trade and Market Size in Late-Eighteenth-Century France.
The Journal of Economic History 70:03, 716-743. [CrossRef]
157. J. Korinek, P. Sourdin. 2010. Clarifying Trade Costs: Maritime Transport and Its Effect on
Agricultural Trade. Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy 32:3, 417-435. [CrossRef]
158. Joseph Francois, , Bernard Hoekman. 2010. Services Trade and Policy. Journal of Economic
Literature 48:3, 642-692. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
159. James E. Anderson. 2010. The Gravity Model. Annual Review of Economics 3:1,
110301095653089. [CrossRef]
160. Maarten Bosker, Harry Garretsen. 2010. Trade costs in empirical New Economic Geography.
Papers in Regional Science 89:3, 485-511. [CrossRef]
161. Uluc Aysun. 2010. Testing for Balance Sheet Effects in Emerging Markets: A Non-Crisis Setting*.
International Finance 13:2, 223-256. [CrossRef]
162. Arne Melchior. 2010. Globalisation and the provinces of China: the role of domestic versus
international trade integration. Journal of Chinese Economic and Business Studies 8:3, 227-252.
[CrossRef]
163. Johannes Bröcker, Artem Korzhenevych, Carsten Schürmann. 2010. Assessing spatial equity
and efficiency impacts of transport infrastructure projects. Transportation Research Part B:
Methodological 44:7, 795-811. [CrossRef]
164. Guy Michaels, , Xiaojia Zhi. 2010. Freedom Fries. American Economic Journal: Applied
Economics 2:3, 256-281. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
165. J. Chami Batista, G. B. da Silveira Filho. 2010. Trade Costs and Deviations from the Law of One
Price. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 92:4, 1011-1023. [CrossRef]
166. KICHUN KANG. 2010. OVERSEAS NETWORK OF EXPORT PROMOTION AGENCY AND
EXPORT PERFORMANCE: THE KOREAN CASE. Contemporary Economic Policy no-no.
[CrossRef]
167. Christian Volpe Martincus, Jerónimo Carballo. 2010. Beyond the average effects: The
distributional impacts of export promotion programs in developing countries#. Journal of
Development Economics 92:2, 201-214. [CrossRef]
168. Denis Medvedev. 2010. Preferential trade agreements and their role in world trade. Review of
World Economics 146:2, 199-222. [CrossRef]
169. Alberto Behar, Phil Manners. 2010. Distance to Growing Markets and Sub-Saharan African
Exports*. African Development Review 22:2, 316-330. [CrossRef]
170. P. Buys, U. Deichmann, D. Wheeler. 2010. Road Network Upgrading and Overland Trade
Expansion in Sub-Saharan Africa. Journal of African Economies 19:3, 399-432. [CrossRef]
171. Dennis Novy. 2010. Trade Costs and the Open Macroeconomy. Scandinavian Journal of
Economics no-no. [CrossRef]
172. Akie Iriyama, Yong Li, Ravi Madhavan. 2010. Spiky globalization of venture capital investments:
the influence of prior human networks. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal 4:2, 128-145.
[CrossRef]
173. Ye Hu, Xin Wang. 2010. Country-of-Origin Premiums for Retailers in International Trades:
Evidence from eBay's International Markets. Journal of Retailing 86:2, 200-207. [CrossRef]
174. Erhan Demirel, Jos van Ommeren, Piet Rietveld. 2010. A matching model for the backhaul
problem#. Transportation Research Part B: Methodological 44:4, 549-561. [CrossRef]
175. ALBERTO SALVO. 2010. Sequential Cross-border Mergers in Models of Oligopoly. Economica
77:306, 352-383. [CrossRef]
176. Christian Volpe Martincus, Antoni Estevadeordal, Andrés Gallo, Jessica Luna. 2010. Information
barriers, export promotion institutions, and the extensive margin of trade. Review of World
Economics 146:1, 91-111. [CrossRef]
177. Maria Bas, Ivan Ledezma. 2010. Trade integration and within-plant productivity evolution in
Chile. Review of World Economics 146:1, 113-146. [CrossRef]
178. RICHARD POMFRET, PATRICIA SOURDIN. 2010. TRADE FACILITATION AND THE
MEASUREMENT OF TRADE COSTS. Journal of International Commerce, Economics and
Policy 01:01, 145-163. [CrossRef]
179. Laura Márquez-Ramos, Inmaculada Martínez-Zarzoso, Eva Pérez-García, Gordon Wilmsmeier.
2010. “Special Issue on Latin-American Research” Maritime Networks, Services Structure and
Maritime Trade. Networks and Spatial Economics . [CrossRef]
180. Kei-Mu Yi. 2010. Can Multistage Production Explain the Home Bias in Trade?. American
Economic Review 100:1, 364-393. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
181. Corey Lang. 2010. Heterogeneous transport costs and spatial sorting in a model of New Economic
Geography*. Papers in Regional Science 89:1, 191-202. [CrossRef]
182. Mathias Hoffmann, Oliver Holtemöller. 2010. Transmission of Nominal Exchange Rate Changes
to Export Prices and Trade Flows and Implications for Exchange Rate Policy. Scandinavian
Journal of Economics 112:1, 127-161. [CrossRef]
183. Karl Morasch, Martin Bandulet. 2010. Sharing the Market or Getting Closer for a Fight? Strategic
Reaction to Reduced Trade Costs. Open Economies Review . [CrossRef]
184. Jacques-François Thisse. 2010. TOWARD A UNIFIED THEORY OF ECONOMIC
GEOGRAPHY AND URBAN ECONOMICS. Journal of Regional Science 50:1, 281-296.
[CrossRef]
185. Matthieu Crozet, Pamina Koenig. 2010. Structural gravity equations with intensive and
extensive margins. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 43:1, 41-62.
[CrossRef]
186. Zahoor Haq, Karl Meilke. 2010. Do the BRICs and Emerging Markets Differ in their Agrifood
Imports?. Journal of Agricultural Economics 61:1, 1-14. [CrossRef]
187. Rolf J. Langhammer. 2010. Unordnung in der internationalen Handelsordnung: Befunde, Gründe,
Auswirkungen und Therapien. Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik 11:1, 75-98. [CrossRef]
188. Christopher Balding. 2010. Joining the World Trade Organization: What is the Impact?. Review
of International Economics 18:1, 193-206. [CrossRef]
189. Michael Storper. 2010. AGGLOMERATION, TRADE, AND SPATIAL DEVELOPMENT:
BRINGING DYNAMICS BACK IN. Journal of Regional Science 50:1, 313-342. [CrossRef]
190. Reuven Glick, Alan M Taylor. 2010. Collateral Damage: Trade Disruption and the Economic
Impact of War. Review of Economics and Statistics 92:1, 102-127. [CrossRef]
191. Gordon Wilmsmeier, Inmaculada Martinez-Zarzoso. 2010. Determinants of maritime transport
costs - a panel data analysis for Latin American trade. Transportation Planning and Technology
33:1, 105-121. [CrossRef]
192. Joseph F. Francois, Will MartinChapter 13 Ex Ante Assessment of the Welfare Impacts of Trade
Reforms with Numerical Models 7, 379-434. [CrossRef]
193. T.Huw Edwards. 2010. Globalisation as a ‘Good Times’ Phenomenon: A Search-Based
Explanation. Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal . [CrossRef]
194. Štefan Bojnec, Imre Ferto. 2010. Internet and international food industry trade. Industrial
Management & Data Systems 110:5, 744-761. [CrossRef]
195. Sylvia Heuchemer, Stefanie Kleimeier, Harald Sander. 2009. The Determinants of Cross-Border
Lending in the Euro Zone. Comparative Economic Studies 51:4, 467-499. [CrossRef]
196. Richard G. Harris, Peter E. Robertson. 2009. Dynamic Gains and Market Access Insurance:
Another Look at the AustraliaâUS Free Trade Agreement. Australian Economic Review 42:4,
435-452. [CrossRef]
197. W. Czubala, B. Shepherd, J. S. Wilson. 2009. Help or Hindrance? The Impact of Harmonised
Standards on African Exports. Journal of African Economies 18:5, 711-744. [CrossRef]
198. M. Hashem Pesaran, Ron Smith, Takashi Yamagata, Lyudmyla Hvozdyk. 2009. Pairwise Tests of
Purchasing Power Parity. Econometric Reviews 28:6, 495-521. [CrossRef]
199. Adeel Malik, Jonathan R.W. Temple. 2009. The geography of output volatility#. Journal of
Development Economics 90:2, 163-178. [CrossRef]
200. Paul R. Bergin, Reuven Glick. 2009. Endogenous tradability and some macroeconomic
implications. Journal of Monetary Economics 56:8, 1086-1095. [CrossRef]
201. James E. Anderson. 2009. Does trade foster contract enforcement?. Economic Theory 41:1,
105-130. [CrossRef]
202. Yang-Ming Chang, Philip G. Gayle. 2009. Exports versus FDI: do firms use FDI as a mechanism
to smooth demand volatility?. Review of World Economics 145:3, 447-467. [CrossRef]
203. Volker Nitsch. 2009. Terrorismus und internationaler Handel: Probleme und Ergebnisse
empirischer Untersuchungen. Vierteljahrshefte zur Wirtschaftsforschung 78:4, 41-50. [CrossRef]
204. Nelson Villoria. 2009. China's Growth and the Agricultural Exports of Sub-Saharan Southern
Africa. European Journal of Development Research 21:4, 531-550. [CrossRef]
205. Kuang-Hann Chou, Chien-Hsun Chen, Chao-Cheng Mai. 2009. A Geospatial Analysis of China's
Exports, 1991-2008. Eurasian Geography and Economics 50:5, 532-546. [CrossRef]
206. N. Crafts. 2009. Transport infrastructure investment: implications for growth and productivity.
Oxford Review of Economic Policy 25:3, 327-343. [CrossRef]
207. Zahoor Haq, Karl Meilke. 2009. The Role of Income in Trading-Differentiated Agri-Food
Products: The Case of Canada, the United States, and Selected EU Countries. Canadian Journal
of Agricultural Economics/Revue canadienne d'agroeconomie 57:3, 343-363. [CrossRef]
208. Anthony J. Venables. 2009. Rethinking Economic Growth in a Globalizing World: An Economic
Geography Lens. African Development Review 21:2, 331-351. [CrossRef]
209. Thomas Gries, Wim Naudé, Marianne Matthee. 2009. THE OPTIMAL DISTANCE TO PORT
FOR EXPORTING FIRMS. Journal of Regional Science 49:3, 513-528. [CrossRef]
210. Eckhard Janeba. 2009. Exports, unemployment, and the welfare state. Canadian Journal of
Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 42:3, 930-955. [CrossRef]
211. Julian di Giovanni, Andrei A Levchenko. 2009. Trade Openness and Volatility. Review of
Economics and Statistics 91:3, 558-585. [CrossRef]
212. MAURICE J. G. BUN, FRANC J. G. M. KLAASSEN, G. K. RANDOLPH TAN. 2009. FREE
TRADE AREAS AND INTRA-REGIONAL TRADE: THE CASE OF ASEAN. The Singapore
Economic Review 54:03, 319-334. [CrossRef]
213. Christian Volpe Martincus, Antoni Estevadeordal. 2009. Trade policy and specialization in
developing countries. Review of World Economics 145:2, 251-275. [CrossRef]
214. Vincent Vicard. 2009. On trade creation and regional trade agreements: does depth matter?. Review
of World Economics 145:2, 167-187. [CrossRef]
215. ALBERTO PORTUGAL-PEREZ, JOHN S. WILSON. 2009. Why trade facilitation matters to
Africa. World Trade Review 8:03, 379. [CrossRef]
216. Joseph Francois, Julia Woerz. 2009. Non-linear panel estimation of import quotas: The evolution of
quota premiums under the ATC#. Journal of International Economics 78:2, 181-191. [CrossRef]
217. Edward N Wolff. 2009. Using Energy Resources to Diversify the Economy: Agricultural Price
Distortions in Kazakhstan. Comparative Economic Studies 51:2, 181-212. [CrossRef]
218. Alexandre Gohin, Fabienne Féménia. 2009. Estimating Price Elasticities of Food Trade Functions:
How Relevant is the CES-based Gravity Approach?. Journal of Agricultural Economics 60:2,
253-272. [CrossRef]
219. Boriss Siliverstovs, Dieter Schumacher. 2009. Estimating gravity equations: to log or not to log?.
Empirical Economics 36:3, 645-669. [CrossRef]
220. Thomas L. Vollrath, Mark J. Gehlhar, Charles B. Hallahan. 2009. Bilateral Import Protection,
Free Trade Agreements, and Other Factors Influencing Trade Flows in Agriculture and Clothing.
Journal of Agricultural Economics 60:2, 298-317. [CrossRef]
221. Alessandro Olper, Valentina Raimondi. 2009. Patterns and Determinants of International Trade
Costs in the Food Industry. Journal of Agricultural Economics 60:2, 273-297. [CrossRef]
222. Martijn Burger, Frank van Oort, Gert-Jan Linders. 2009. On the Specification of the Gravity
Model of Trade: Zeros, Excess Zeros and Zero-inflated Estimation. Spatial Economic Analysis
4:2, 167-190. [CrossRef]
223. Marion Jansen, Roberta Piermartini. 2009. Temporary Migration and Bilateral Trade Flows. World
Economy 32:5, 735-753. [CrossRef]
224. Vasco Leite, Sofia B. S. D. Castro, João Correia-da-Silva. 2009. The core periphery model with
asymmetric inter-regional and intra-regional trade costs. Portuguese Economic Journal 8:1, 37-44.
[CrossRef]
225. Matthias Helble, Ben Shepherd, John S. Wilson. 2009. Transparency and Regional Integration in
the Asia Pacific. World Economy 32:3, 479-508. [CrossRef]
226. Steven Brakman, Harry Garretsen. 2009. Trade and Geography: Paul Krugman and the 2008 Nobel
Prize for Economics. Spatial Economic Analysis 4:1, 5-23. [CrossRef]
227. N COEURDACIER. 2009. Do trade costs in goods market lead to home bias in equities?. Journal
of International Economics 77:1, 86-100. [CrossRef]
228. S BAIER, J BERGSTRAND. 2009. Estimating the effects of free trade agreements on international
trade flows using matching econometrics. Journal of International Economics 77:1, 63-76.
[CrossRef]
229. Ali Hortaçsu, , F. Asís Martínez-Jerez, , Jason Douglas. 2009. The Geography of Trade in
Online Transactions: Evidence from eBay and MercadoLibre. American Economic Journal:
Microeconomics 1:1, 53-74. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
230. Yuriy Gorodnichenko, , Linda L. Tesar. 2009. Border Effect or Country Effect? Seattle May Not
Be so Far from Vancouver After All. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 1:1, 219-241.
[Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
231. Gianmarco I.P. Ottaviano, Daria Taglioni, Filippo di Mauro. 2009. The euro and the
competitiveness of European firms. Economic Policy 24:57, 5-53. [CrossRef]
232. Aihie Osarenkhoe. 2009. An integrated framework for understanding the driving forces behind
non-sequential process of internationalisation among firms. Business Process Management
Journal 15:2, 286-316. [CrossRef]
233. James P. LeSage, R. Kelley Pace. 2008. SPATIAL ECONOMETRIC MODELING OF ORIGIN-
DESTINATION FLOWS*. Journal of Regional Science 48:5, 941-967. [CrossRef]
234. Arjan M. Lejour, Peter M. Smith. 2008. International Trade in Services—Editorial Introduction.
Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade 8:3-4, 169-180. [CrossRef]
235. C. Emlinger, F. Jacquet, E. C. Lozza. 2008. Tariffs and other trade costs: assessing obstacles
to Mediterranean countries' access to EU-15 fruit and vegetable markets. European Review of
Agricultural Economics 35:4, 409-438. [CrossRef]
236. Christian Broda, , Nuno Limão, , David E. Weinstein. 2008. Optimal Tariffs and Market Power:
The Evidence. American Economic Review 98:5, 2032-2065. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF
with links]
237. Andrew Atkeson, , Ariel Burstein. 2008. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International
Relative Prices. American Economic Review 98:5, 1998-2031. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF
with links]
238. G.-J. M. Linders, M. J. Burger, F. G. van Oort. 2008. A rather empty world: the many faces
of distance and the persistent resistance to international trade. Cambridge Journal of Regions,
Economy and Society 1:3, 439-458. [CrossRef]
239. S. Brakman, C. van Marrewijk. 2008. It's a big world after all: on the economic impact of location
and distance. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society 1:3, 411-437. [CrossRef]
240. Fukunari Kimura. 2008. Demystify Protectionism: The WTO Trade Policy Review of Japan. World
Economy 31:11, 1383-1392. [CrossRef]
241. T. Huw Edwards. 2008. Implicit trade Costs and European single market enlargement. Applied
Economics 40:20, 2601-2613. [CrossRef]
242. Belaid Rettab, Azzeddine Azzam. 2008. Re-export Intensity and Trade Costs: Port Facilities and
Services. Maritime Economics &#38; Logistics 10:3, 229-242. [CrossRef]
243. Salvador Gil, Rafael Llorca, J. Antonio Martínez-Serrano. 2008. Assessing the Enlargement and
Deepening of the European Union. World Economy 31:9, 1253-1272. [CrossRef]
244. Xian Xin, Xiuqing Wang. 2008. Was China's Inflation in 2004 Led by an Agricultural Price Rise.
Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics/Revue canadienne d'agroeconomie 56:3, 353-364.
[CrossRef]
245. Alessandro Olper, Valentina Raimondi. 2008. Explaining National Border Effects in the QUAD
Food Trade. Journal of Agricultural Economics 59:3, 436-462. [CrossRef]
246. Thomas Chaney. 2008. Distorted Gravity: The Intensive and Extensive Margins of International
Trade. American Economic Review 98:4, 1707-1721. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with
links]
247. Guido G. Porto. 2008. Agro-Manufactured Export Prices, Wages and Unemployment. American
Journal of Agricultural Economics 90:3, 748-764. [CrossRef]
248. Hildegunn Kyvik Nordås. 2008. Vertical Specialisation and its Determinants. Journal of
Development Studies 44:7, 1037-1055. [CrossRef]
249. PHILIPPE MARTIN, THIERRY MAYER, MATHIAS THOENIG. 2008. Make Trade Not War?.
Review of Economic Studies 75:3, 865-900. [CrossRef]
250. Hyun-Hoon Lee, Chung Mo Koo, Euijeong Park. 2008. Are Exports of China, Japan and Korea
Diverted in the Major Regional Trading Blocs?. World Economy 31:7, 841-860. [CrossRef]
251. M BERTHELON, C FREUND. 2008. On the conservation of distance in international trade#.
Journal of International Economics 75:2, 310-320. [CrossRef]
252. Peter Egger. 2008. On the role of distance for outward FDI. The Annals of Regional Science 42:2,
375-389. [CrossRef]
253. ESTER FAIA, TOMMASO MONACELLI. 2008. Optimal Monetary Policy in a Small Open
Economy with Home Bias. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 40:4, 721-750. [CrossRef]
254. Elhanan Helpman, Marc Melitz, Yona Rubinstein. 2008. Estimating Trade Flows: Trading Partners
and Trading Volumes *. Quarterly Journal of Economics 123:2, 441-487. [CrossRef]
255. Peter Egger. 2008. On the Role of Distance for Bilateral Trade. The World Economy 31:5, 653-662.
[CrossRef]
256. Richard Kneller, Mauro Pisu, Zhihong Yu. 2008. Overseas business costs and firm export
performance. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 41:2, 639-669.
[CrossRef]
257. Oliver Lorz, Matthias Wrede. 2008. Standardization of intermediate goods and international trade.
Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 41:2, 517-536. [CrossRef]
258. David S. Jacks, , Christopher M. Meissner, , Dennis Novy. 2008. Trade Costs, 1870–2000.
American Economic Review 98:2, 529-534. [Citation] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
259. Philippe Martin, Thierry Mayer, Mathias Thoenig. 2008. Civil Wars and International Trade.
Journal of the European Economic Association 6:2-3, 541-550. [CrossRef]
260. Scott L. Baier, Jeffrey H. Bergstrand, Peter Egger, Patrick A. McLaughlin. 2008. Do Economic
Integration Agreements Actually Work? Issues in Understanding the Causes and Consequences of
the Growth of Regionalism. The World Economy 31:4, 461-497. [CrossRef]
261. GIANCARLO CORSETTI, LUCA DEDOLA, SYLVAIN LEDUC. 2008. International Risk
Sharing and the Transmission of Productivity Shocks. Review of Economic Studies 75:2, 443-473.
[CrossRef]
262. Eric Toulemonde. 2008. Multinationals: Too Many or Too Few?— The Proximity–concentration
Trade-off. Open Economies Review 19:2, 203-219. [CrossRef]
263. Doireann Fitzgerald. 2008. Can trade costs explain why exchange rate volatility does not feed into
consumer prices?#. Journal of Monetary Economics 55:3, 606-628. [CrossRef]
264. Kanda Naknoi. 2008. Real exchange rate fluctuations, endogenous tradability and exchange rate
regimes#. Journal of Monetary Economics 55:3, 645-663. [CrossRef]
265. Daniel J. Henderson, Daniel L. Millimet. 2008. Is gravity linear?. Journal of Applied Econometrics
23:2, 137-172. [CrossRef]
266. Salvador Gil, Rafael Llorca, José A. Martínez Serrano. 2008. Measuring the impact of regional
export promotion: The Spanish case. Papers in Regional Science 87:1, 139-146. [CrossRef]
267. Gordon Wilmsmeier, Jan Hoffmann. 2008. Liner Shipping Connectivity and Port Infrastructure
as Determinants of Freight Rates in the Caribbean. Maritime Economics &#38; Logistics 10:1-2,
130-151. [CrossRef]
268. Gilles Duranton, Michael Storper. 2008. Rising trade costs? Agglomeration and trade with
endogenous transaction costs. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique
41:1, 292-319. [CrossRef]
269. Gianpaolo Rossini, Paolo Zanghieri. 2008. What Drives Price Differentials of Consumables in
Europe? Size? Affluence? Or Both?. Open Economies Review 19:1, 121-134. [CrossRef]
270. Wolfram Berger. 2008. Monetary Policy Rules for a Small Open Economy. Economic Notes 37:1,
1-30. [CrossRef]
271. Anne-Célia Disdier, Keith Head. 2008. The Puzzling Persistence of the Distance Effect on Bilateral
Trade. Review of Economics and Statistics 90:1, 37-48. [CrossRef]
272. James E. Anderson. 2008. Economic Integration and the Civilising Commerce Hypothesis. World
Economy 31:1, 141-157. [CrossRef]
273. Jeffrey H. Bergstrand, Antoni Estevadeordal, Simon J. Evenett. 2008. Introduction - The
Sequencing of Regional Economic Integration. World Economy 31:1, 1-4. [CrossRef]
274. Emanuel Ornelas, John L. Turner. 2008. Trade liberalization, outsourcing, and the hold-up
problem#. Journal of International Economics 74:1, 225-241. [CrossRef]
275. Christian Daude, Marcel Fratzscher. 2008. The pecking order of cross-border investment#. Journal
of International Economics 74:1, 94-119. [CrossRef]
276. Q DO, A LEVCHENKO. 2007. Comparative advantage, demand for external finance, and
financial development#. Journal of Financial Economics 86:3, 796-834. [CrossRef]
277. Andrew Yuen, Anming Zhang. 2007. Strategic Trade and Transport Policies with Congestible
Facilities. Asia-Pacific Journal of Accounting & Economics 14:3, 235-257. [CrossRef]
278. Slavi T. Slavov. 2007. Innocent or Not-so-innocent Bystanders: Evidence from the Gravity Model
of International Trade About the Effects of UN Sanctions on Neighbour Countries. The World
Economy 30:11, 1701-1725. [CrossRef]
279. Gianpaolo Rossini. 2007. Pitfalls in Private and Social Incentives of Vertical Cross-border
Integration and Disintegration. Review of International Economics 15:5, 932-947. [CrossRef]
280. Zsolt Becsi and Sajal Lahiri. 2007. Bilateral war in a multilateral world: carrots and sticks
for conflict resolution. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 40:4,
1168-1187. [CrossRef]
281. Jeffrey H. Bergstrand, Peter Egger. 2007. A knowledge-and-physical-capital model of
international trade flows, foreign direct investment, and multinational enterprises. Journal of
International Economics 73:2, 278-308. [CrossRef]
282. V MIDRIGAN. 2007. International price dispersion in state-dependent pricing models#. Journal
of Monetary Economics 54:8, 2231-2250. [CrossRef]
283. Scott L. Baier, Jeffrey H. Bergstrand, Erika Vidal. 2007. Free Trade Agreements In the Americas:
Are the Trade Effects Larger than Anticipated?. The World Economy 30:9, 1347-1377. [CrossRef]
284. CHRISTOPHER ADAM, DAVID COBHAM. 2007. EXCHANGE RATE REGIMES AND
TRADE. The Manchester School 75:s1, 44-63. [CrossRef]
285. G CORSETTI, P MARTIN, P PESENTI. 2007. Productivity, terms of trade and the ‘home market
effect’#. Journal of International Economics 73:1, 99-127. [CrossRef]
286. P BERGIN, R GLICK. 2007. Tradability, productivity, and international economic integration.
Journal of International Economics 73:1, 128-151. [CrossRef]
287. Badi H. Baltagi, Peter Egger, Michael Pfaffermayr. 2007. Estimating models of complex FDI: Are
there third-country effects?. Journal of Econometrics 140:1, 260-281. [CrossRef]
288. Fernando Alvarez, Robert E. Lucas, Jr.. 2007. General equilibrium analysis of the Eaton–Kortum
model of international trade#. Journal of Monetary Economics 54:6, 1726-1768. [CrossRef]
289. Maurice J. G. Bun, Franc J. G. M. Klaassen. 2007. The Euro Effect on Trade is not as Large as
Commonly Thought. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 69:4, 473-496. [CrossRef]
290. Hans Christian Heinemeyer. 2007. The treatment effect of borders on trade. The great war and the
disintegration of Central Europe. Cliometrica 1:3, 177-210. [CrossRef]
291. DANIEL LEDERMAN, ÇAGLAR ÖZDEN. 2007. GEOPOLITICAL INTERESTS AND
PREFERENTIAL ACCESS TO U.S. MARKETS. Economics & Politics 19:2, 235-258.
[CrossRef]
292. E BALISTRERI, R HILLBERRY. 2007. Structural estimation and the border puzzle. Journal of
International Economics 72:2, 451-463. [CrossRef]
293. Richard Pomfret. 2007. Is Regionalism an Increasing Feature of the World Economy?. The World
Economy 30:6, 923-947. [CrossRef]
294. Priya Ranjan, Justin L. Tobias. 2007. Bayesian inference for the gravity model. Journal of Applied
Econometrics 22:4, 817-838. [CrossRef]
295. Kazunobu Hayakawa. 2007. Measuring Barriers to International Division of Labor in East Asia.
Asian Economic Journal 21:2, 139-153. [CrossRef]
296. Arjan Lejour, Jan-Willem de Paiva Verheijden. 2007. The Tradability of Services within Canada
and the European Union. The Service Industries Journal 27:4, 389-409. [CrossRef]
297. David T Coe, Arvind Subramanian, Natalia T Tamirisa. 2007. The Missing Globalization Puzzle:
Evidence of the Declining Importance of Distance. IMF Staff Papers 54:1, 34-58. [CrossRef]
298. Laura Alfaro, Eliza Hammel. 2007. Capital flows and capital goods#. Journal of International
Economics 72:1, 128-150. [CrossRef]
299. Chong Xiang. 2007. Diversification cones, trade costs and factor market linkages#. Journal of
International Economics 71:2, 448-466. [CrossRef]
300. A AVIAT, N COEURDACIER. 2007. The geography of trade in goods and asset holdings. Journal
of International Economics 71:1, 22-51. [CrossRef]
301. S TENREYRO. 2007. On the trade impact of nominal exchange rate volatility. Journal of
Development Economics 82:2, 485-508. [CrossRef]
302. Edward E. Leamer. 2007. A Flat World, a Level Playing Field, a Small World After All, or None of
the Above? A Review of Thomas L. Friedman's The World is Flat. Journal of Economic Literature
45:1, 83-126. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
303. Pinelopi Koujianou Goldberg, Nina Pavcnik. 2007. Distributional Effects of Globalization in
Developing Countries. Journal of Economic Literature 45:1, 39-82. [Abstract] [View PDF article]
[PDF with links]
304. Serge Coulombe. 2007. Globalization and Regional Disparity: A Canadian Case Study. Regional
Studies 41:1, 1-17. [CrossRef]
305. Juha Tervala. 2007. Technology Shocks and Employment in Open Economies. Economics: The
Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal . [CrossRef]
306. Cindy Duc, Clotilde Granger, Jean-Marc Siroën. 2007. Commerce et préférences. Revue
économique 58:5, 1055. [CrossRef]
307. ANDREW B. BERNARD, STEPHEN J. REDDING, PETER K. SCHOTT. 2007. Comparative
Advantage and Heterogeneous Firms. Review of Economic Studies 74:1, 31-66. [CrossRef]
308. KIMINORI MATSUYAMA. 2007. Beyond Icebergs: Towards a Theory of Biased Globalization.
Review of Economic Studies 74:1, 237-253. [CrossRef]
309. Asier Minondo. 2007. The disappearance of the border barrier in some European Union countries'
bilateral trade. Applied Economics 39:1, 119-124. [CrossRef]
310. Thomas L. Vollrath, Charles B. Hallahan, Mark J. Gehlhar. 2006. Consumer Demand and Cost
Factors Shape the Global Trade Network in Commodity and Manufactured Foods. Canadian
Journal of Agricultural Economics/Revue canadienne d'agroeconomie 54:4, 497-511. [CrossRef]
311. M KLEIN, J SHAMBAUGH. 2006. Fixed exchange rates and trade. Journal of International
Economics 70:2, 359-383. [CrossRef]
312. B BLUM, A GOLDFARB. 2006. Does the internet defy the law of gravity?. Journal of
International Economics 70:2, 384-405. [CrossRef]
313. Philippe Martin, Hélène Rey. 2006. Globalization and Emerging Markets: With or Without Crash?.
American Economic Review 96:5, 1631-1651. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
314. Chengyan Yue, John Beghin, Helen H. Jensen. 2006. Tariff Equivalent of Technical Barriers to
Trade with Imperfect Substitution and Trade Costs. American Journal of Agricultural Economics
88:4, 947-960. [CrossRef]
315. Carsten Herrmann-Pillath. 2006. The true story of wine and cloth, or: building blocks of an
evolutionary political economy of international trade. Journal of Evolutionary Economics 16:4,
383-417. [CrossRef]
316. Chris Milner. 2006. Making NAMA Work: Supporting Adjustment and Development. The World
Economy 29:10, 1409-1422. [CrossRef]
317. R FRIBERG, M GANSLANDT. 2006. An empirical assessment of the welfare effects of reciprocal
dumping. Journal of International Economics 70:1, 1-24. [CrossRef]
318. Elhanan Helpman. 2006. Trade, FDI, and the Organization of Firms. Journal of Economic
Literature 44:3, 589-630. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
319. Kristian Behrens. 2006. Do changes in transport costs and tariffs shape the space-economy in the
same way?. Papers in Regional Science 85:3, 379-399. [CrossRef]
320. Scott C. Bradford, Paul L. E. Grieco, Gary Clyde Hufbauer. 2006. The Payoff to America from
Globalisation. The World Economy 29:7, 893-916. [CrossRef]
321. Armando José Garcia Pires. 2006. Estimating Krugman’s Economic Geography Model for the
Spanish Regions. Spanish Economic Review 8:2, 83-112. [CrossRef]
322. Peter Egger, Thomas Url. 2006. Public Export Credit Guarantees and Foreign Trade Structure:
Evidence from Austria. The World Economy 29:4, 399-418. [CrossRef]
323. D MADDISON. 2006. Environmental Kuznets curves: A spatial econometric approach. Journal
of Environmental Economics and Management 51:2, 218-230. [CrossRef]
324. J HARRIGAN, A VENABLES. 2006. Timeliness and agglomeration#. Journal of Urban
Economics 59:2, 300-316. [CrossRef]
325. Edward J. Balistreri, Russell H. Hillberry. 2006. Trade frictions and welfare in the gravity model:
how much of the iceberg melts?. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'<html_ent
glyph="@eacute;" ascii="e"/>conomique 39:1, 247-265. [CrossRef]
326. Nicolas Péridy. 2006. La nouvelle politique de voisinage de l'Union européenne. Revue
économique 57:4, 727. [CrossRef]
327. Richard PomfretChapter 3 Regional Trade Agreements 12, 39-54. [CrossRef]
328. Gordon Wilmsmeier, Jan Hoffmann, Ricardo J. Sanchez. 2006. The Impact of Port Characteristics
on International Maritime Transport Costs. Research in Transportation Economics 16, 117-140.
[CrossRef]
329. Esteban Rossi-Hansberg. 2005. A Spatial Theory of Trade. American Economic Review 95:5,
1464-1491. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
330. Lionel Fontagne, Thierry Mayer, Soledad Zignago. 2005. Trade in the Triad: how easy is
the access to large markets?. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'<html_ent
glyph="@eacute;" ascii="e"/>conomique 38:4, 1401-1430. [CrossRef]
331. Alan V. Deardorff. 2005. How Robust is Comparative Advantage?. Review of International
Economics 13:5, 1004-1016. [CrossRef]
332. V TRINDADE. 2005. The big push, industrialization and international trade: The role of exports.
Journal of Development Economics 78:1, 22-48. [CrossRef]
333. G CORSETTI, L DEDOLA. 2005. A macroeconomic model of international price discrimination.
Journal of International Economics 67:1, 129-155. [CrossRef]
334. Masahisa Fujita, Tomoya Mori. 2005. Frontiers of the New Economic Geography*. Papers in
Regional Science 84:3, 377-405. [CrossRef]
335. Michel Beine, Serge Coulombe. 2005. One Market, One Money: Evidence from Canada-United
States Economic Integration. The World Economy 28:7, 985-1003. [CrossRef]
336. G PORTO. 2005. Informal export barriers and poverty. Journal of International Economics 66:2,
447-470. [CrossRef]
337. John McMillanQuantifying Creative Destruction: Entrepreneurship and Productivity in New
Zealand 9, 189-210. [CrossRef]
338. Antoine Bouët, Lionel Fontagné, El Mouhoub Mouhoud. 2005. Introduction. Revue économique
56:6, 1173. [CrossRef]
339. John McMillan. 2004. Quantifying creative destruction: Entrepreneurship and productivity in New
Zealand. New Zealand Economic Papers 38:2, 153-173. [CrossRef]
340. Alan M. Taylor , Mark P. Taylor . 2004. The Purchasing Power Parity Debate. Journal of Economic
Perspectives 18:4, 135-158. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
341. Anne T. CoughlanMarketing Channel Strategy . [CrossRef]

You might also like