You are on page 1of 12

Singapore Management University

Institutional Knowledge at Singapore Management University

Research Collection School Of Economics School of Economics

11-1997

Government Policies and Private Housing Prices in Singapore


Sock Yong PHANG
Singapore Management University, syphang@smu.edu.sg

Wing-Keung WONG
Hong Kong Baptist University

Follow this and additional works at: https://ink.library.smu.edu.sg/soe_research

Part of the Asian Studies Commons, Economics Commons, and the Real Estate Commons

Citation
PHANG, Sock Yong and WONG, Wing-Keung. Government Policies and Private Housing Prices in
Singapore. (1997). Urban Studies. 34, (11), 1819-1830. Research Collection School Of Economics.
Available at: https://ink.library.smu.edu.sg/soe_research/118

This Journal Article is brought to you for free and open access by the School of Economics at Institutional
Knowledge at Singapore Management University. It has been accepted for inclusion in Research Collection School
Of Economics by an authorized administrator of Institutional Knowledge at Singapore Management University. For
more information, please email library@smu.edu.sg.
Urban Studies, Vol. 34, No. 11, 1819± 1829, 1997

Published in Urban Studies, Volume 34, Issue 11, November 1997, Pages 1819-1829.
http://doi.org/10.1080/0042098975268

Government Policies and Private Housing Prices in


Singapore

Sock-Yong Phang and Wing-Keung Wong


[Paper ® rst received, April 1996; in ® nal form March 1997]

Summary. Regression models are used to show that interest rates, income growth rates and the
supply of housing have not played a statistically signi® cant role in the determination of private
housing prices in Singapore between 1975 and 1994. Instead, private housing prices in Singapore
were highly correlated with the prices for public-sector-built housing. Moreover, the timing of
government policies relating to the use of compulsory savings for private housing ® nance
purposes, the liberalisation of rules on public housing ownership criterion as well as for housing
® nance had a signi® cant impact on private housing prices.

1. Introduction
Singapore is a small densely populated island or simple trend-line extrapolations. Only
city state with a population of 3.6 million and where housing markets are essentially free of
a land area of 648 sq km. Singapore’ s per government controls and intervention can
capita GNP in 1995 was S$34 500 or approx- studies be made by the simple application of
imately US$24 500 (where S$1 5 US$0.71). partial equilibrium or real estate cycle analy-
For the decade between 1986 and 1995, ses. In Singapore, as well as many other
prices of private housing in Singapore rose nations of the world, housing markets are
unabatedly at an average rate of 18 per cent characterised by the co-existence of a freely
per year (in nominal terms). Over the same priced part of the market with a part that is
period, nominal per capita GNP increased at subject to varying degrees and forms of
an average annual rate of 10 per cent, while government intervention and regulation. The
in¯ ation as measured by the consumer price Singapore housing market has an especially
index averaged only 2 per cent per annum. complex institutional structure with its large
Escalating property prices became a major regulated public housing sub-sectors.
issue of public concern, and resulted in the Part 2 of this paper contains an overview
convening of a high-level, government- of the Singapore housing market which is
appointed Cost Review Committee in 1993 dominated by the public housing sector. The
and again in 1996 (Cost Review Committee, Housing and Development Board (HDB) and
1993, 1996). the Central Provident Fund (CPF), two im-
Private housing prices in Singapore cannot portant institutions in the housing market, are
be easily analysed by recourse either to described. Prices in the private housing sec-
analysis of private-sector supply and demand tor are affected by the standard determinants

Sock-Yong Phang and Wing-Keung Wong are in the Department of Economics, National University of Singapore, Kent Ridge,
Singapore 119260, Republic of Singapore. Fax: (65) 775-2646. E-mail Sock-Yong Phang: ecspsy@nus.sg.

0042-0980/ 97/111819-11 $7.00 Ó1997 The Editors of Urban Studies


1820 SOCK-YONG PHANG AND WING-KEUNG WONG

of supply and demand as well as by many by members of parliament take care of gen-
government policies. In the public housing eral estate maintenance for a monthly fee.
sector, the HDB decides prices and supply of The home-ownership rate in Singapore is
new units and excess demand has spillover therefore in the region of 90 per centÐ one of
effects on the HDB resale sector and the the highest rates in the world. Besides HDB
private housing sector. Prices set by the HDB policy, this high rate is also attributed to
for its new ¯ ats also serve as a guide for Singapore’ s unique housing ® nance arrange-
properties in the other sectors. Policies on ment known as the Central Provident Fund
HDB resale ¯ ats, Central Provident Fund (CPF) (see Asher, 1991, 1996). The fund is
housing ® nance terms and conditions, and essentially a fully funded, pay-as-you-go so-
the release of state land for development are cial security scheme which requires manda-
but a few of the several ways through which tory contributions by both employers and
the government affects prices in the private employees of a certain percentage of the
sector. Part 3 reviews key government poli- employees’ monthly contractual wage to his/
cies that are likely to have an effect on her account in the fund. The contribution
private residential property prices. rates peaked at 25 per cent of wages for both
The objective of this paper is to develop employers and employees from 1984±86.
an understanding of how various policies Contribution rates are currently 20 per cent
have affected private residential property of wages for both employees and employers.
prices during the past two decades. Part 4 of The scheme covers about two-thirds of the
the paper contains a time-series analysis of work-force and CPF balances at the end of
private housing prices in Singapore for the 1995 were S$66 bn or 56 per cent of GDP.
period 1975±94. Besides the conventional CPF contributions are exempt from income
factors of income growth, interest rates and tax and balances earn interest which are also
private-sector supply, we consider two sup- tax-deductible. The interest rate is based on
ply-side policy variables: public housing the average of 1-year ® xed deposit and
prices and public housing supply. In ad- month-end savings rates of the `Big Four’
dition, the effects on housing prices of liber- Singapore banks, subject to a minimum rate
alisation in housing ® nance regulations in of 2.5 per cent.
1981 and 1993, and deregulation measures These fairly substantial forced savings
for resale public housing in 1989 and 1991 may be withdrawn at age 55 or earlier for
are estimated using dummy variables. various approved purposes. Between 1968
and 1981, they could only be withdrawn for
purposes of downpayment, stamp duties,
2. The Singapore Housing Market
mortgage and interest payments incurred for
Singapore’ s housing market is skewed to- the purchase of public-sector-built housing.
wards the public sector. In 1995, 86 per cent In 1981, the scheme was extended to allow
of the 3.6 million population in Singapore for withdrawals for mortgage payments for
resided in public housing (see Yearbook of the purchase of private housing. During the
Statistics Singapore, 1995). Of the 700 060 past decade, rules governing the use of CPF
units of public housing, 90 per cent were savings have been gradually liberalised to
owner-occupied units while the other 10 per allow for withdrawals for medical and edu-
cent of the public housing stock comprised cation expenses, insurance and investments
rental units. Owner-occupied public housing, in various ® nancial assets (Phang, 1992,
an anomaly in most other countries, is hous- pp. 74±83).
ing built by the Housing and Development Public housing rents and prices of new
Board (HDB)1 and sold on 99-year leases to units are subsidised by the government.
eligible households who are subject to resale While a brand new 5-room HDB ¯ at cost
and other regulations imposed by the housing between S$160 000 and S$260 000 (depend-
authority. Designated town councils chaired ing on location) in 1995, a comparable resale
PRIVATE HOUSING PRICES IN SINGAPORE 1821

HDB ¯ at would cost double the amount. units to be completed. In contrast to the
Subsidies to the HDB are in the form of chronic disequilibrium evident in the market
loans (at below market rates of interest) and for new ¯ ats, prices in the resale market are
grants ® nanced from the government’ s bud- determined largely by market forces but are
get, and more importantly, land made avail- also in¯ uenced by prices for new HDB ¯ ats
able to the HDB at prices below market and HDB credit and valuation policies for
value. About four-® fths of the land in Singa- resale ¯ ats (see section 4).
pore belongs to the state. 2 Table 1 shows the structure of the housing
The HDB also provides mortgage market as at the end of 1995. Of a total of
® nancing to its ¯ at-buyers. The loan quantum 830 000 units of housing, 84 per cent had
is either 80 or 90 per cent (depending on loan been built by the public sector. Clearly
scheme) of the price for the new ¯ at and the government interventions in the regulated
maximum repayment period is 25 years. The public housing sector have spillover effects
HDB mortgage interest rate is pegged at 0.1 on the private housing sector. Thus, any
per cent above the CPF interest rate, which is meaningful discussion of the private housing
below the housing mortgage interest rates of market cannot ignore the public housing sec-
commercial banks. This represents another tor. This is a key premise underlying this
subsidy for the purchaser of an HDB ¯ at. paper.
Public housing supply is allocated based
on `® rst-come-® rst-served’ waiting lists as
well as various eligibility conditions. About
140 000 households are presently on the Table 1. Structure of Singapore’ s housing market
waiting list for new HDB ¯ ats and the wait- (end-1995)
ing time is about 5 years. An applicant who
Type of housing Number of units
satis® es the eligibility conditions is entitled
to apply to the HDB to purchase a ¯ at twice. HDB housing
Half the households on the present waiting 1-room 25 930
list are second-time applicants. Eligibility 2-room 35 165
conditions (which have been relaxed over 3-room 241 085
4-room 236 798
time as the housing programme expanded) 5-room 111 664
include citizenship status, non-ownership of Executive 44 100
other residential properties, minimum house- HUDCa 5 318
hold size of two, and having household in- Total 700 060
comes below the ceiling set by the HDB. The
present monthly income ceilings are S$800 Private residential units
for rental ¯ ats (mainly 1- to 3-room units), Non-landed
S$1200 for 3-room ¯ ats, S$8000 for 4- Apartment 34 402
Condominum 34 908
and 5-room ¯ ats, S$10 000 for executive
condominiums, and S$12 000 for multi-tier Landed
Terrace house 31 316
families. Semi-detached bungalow 18 286
An authorised resale market for HDB ¯ ats Detached bungalow 10 194
has existed since 1971 and is subject to the
Total 129 106
regulations laid down by the HDB. The seller
must satisfy a minimum occupancy period of a
This refers to middle-income public housing
5 years if the ¯ at was purchased at a sub- built initially by the Housing and Urban Develop-
sidised price from the HDB. The minimum ment Company between 1973 and 1982. The
occupancy period is 30 months if the ¯ at had functions of the HUDC were taken over by the HDB
in 1982.
been purchased in the resale market. A resale Sources: Yearbook of Statistics Singapore, 1995;
unit differs from a new unit in that the buyer and Urban Redevelopment Authority, Real Estate
does not have to be on a waiting list for new Series: Stock and Occupancy, 4th Quarter, 1995.
1822 SOCK-YONG PHANG AND WING-KEUNG WONG

3. Government Policies and Regulations example, the household monthly income


ceiling to purchase a 5-room ¯ at was S$1500
Government policies that affect housing
in 1975, but it has been increased over the
prices in Singapore are wide-ranging and
years to the present S$8000 (Phang, 1992,
varied. Policies that have an impact on pri-
p. 85). Only citizens, non-owners of any
vate housing prices include policies concern-
other residential property, and households
ing public housing, the supply of state land
with a minimum size of two persons could
for private housing developments, as well as
purchase new or resale HDB ¯ ats before
rules governing the use of Central Provident
1989. In 1989, the income ceiling restriction
Fund savings. How these numerous policies
was removed for HDB resale ¯ ats; the public
affect private housing prices are discussed in
housing resale market was opened to perma-
this section.
nent residents and private property owners
who had to owner-occupy their HDB proper-
Public Housing Policies ties; HDB ¯ at-owners who could not own
any other residential properties before, could
Pricing and supply of new HDB ¯ ats. Prices also invest in private-sector-built dwellings.
of new HDB ¯ ats are regulated and are at In 1991, single citizens above the age of 35
substantially below market rates. Prices vary were allowed to purchase HDB 3-room or
with ¯ at size, design, location, storey height, smaller resale ¯ ats in estates outside the cen-
orientation and housing market conditions. tral area for owner-occupancy.
The stock of HDB ¯ ats is another policy
variable which is determined by new con- Credit policies relating to resale HDB ¯ ats.
struction and the demolition of older units. The HDB also provides loans to buyers of
The number of dwellings under HDB man- resale HDB ¯ ats. Loan ® nancing prior to
agement was 552 000 in 1985, 624 000 in 1993 was based on 80 per cent of 1984 HDB
1990 and 700 000 in 1995. new ¯ at prices. The failure to adjust the loan
Weibull (1983) has built a simple model of quantum for HDB resale ¯ ats for a decade
a housing market with two sectors with char- affected the demand for these ¯ ats. In 1993,
acteristics similar to the Singapore housing the HDB moved its mortgage ® nancing terms
market. In one of these sectors, prices are closer to market practice by granting loan
free and housing is traded competitively; in ® nancing of up to 80 per cent of current
the other sector, prices are ® xed by regu- valuation or the declared resale price of the
lation and excess demands are dissipated by ¯ at, whichever is lower (see section 4).
means of trade frictions which cause
spillovers to the unregulated sector. Using State Land Sales for Private Housing Devel-
Weibull’ s model, we obtain the following opments
comparative statics: when the regulated
price (regulated stock) of dwellings is in- The government, through its sale of sites
creased, prices in the private sector increase programme, makes available state land (via
(decrease), and queue times in the regulated auction or tender) to the private sector for the
sector are reduced. development of 99-year leasehold dwellings
(Phang, 1996). The few major private-sector
developers in Singapore also possess their
Changes in eligibility criteria for public own (limited compared with the state’ s) land
housing. Eligibility criteria for public hous- banks of freehold or 999-year leasehold
ing purchase were extremely restrictive in properties.
the 1960s and 1970s due to the severe hous-
ing shortage. As the public housing pro-
Central Provident Fund Policies
gramme expanded and the basic shelter
needs of the majority were met, the eligi- Between 1968 and 1981, CPF savings and
bility criteria were made less stringent. For future contributions could only be used for
PRIVATE HOUSING PRICES IN SINGAPORE 1823

downpayment and mortgage payments re- queues. While these are also features of the
lated to the purchase of public-sector-built Singapore housing market, the Singapore
dwellings. In 1981, the Approved Residential market has the further complexity that it is
Properties Scheme was implemented which frequently subjected to policy interventions
extended the use of CPF savings to the pur- that result in structural changes with their
chase of private residential property. The consequent effects on housing prices.
objective of this scheme extended beyond In this part of the paper, a time-series
home-ownership as the dwelling purchased econometric model is used to study the
could be used for rental as well as owner-oc- effects of these interventions on private
cupation. CPF members were allowed to use housing prices. The model uses the private
90 per cent of their CPF balances and residential property price index (RPPI) series
monthly contributions to redeem one housing from the ® rst quarter of 1975 to the fourth
loan or to buy one residential property at any quarter of 1994 (a total of 80 periods).
one time. Withdrawals, however, were not The RPPI excludes HDB properties and is
allowed to exceed 80 per cent of the valu- the weighted average of current prices of
ation price of the property, which either had ® ve types of property (see Table 1) in ® ve
to be on freehold land or have a remaining planning districts. The weight assigned to
lease of at least 75 years. Upon the sale of each group is the percentage share of the
the property, the amount of CPF savings value of property transactions in the base
withdrawn under the scheme had to be re- year 1990. 3
turned, together with interest, to the mem- The variables included in the study are:4
ber’ s account, and a 3-year lapse was
necessary before the savings could be with- (1) economic growthÐ measured by the
drawn again. quarterly growth rate of real Gross Dom-
The above numerous restrictions accompa- estic Product (GDP);
nying the scheme were gradually lifted over (2) nominal interest rateÐ measured by the
the next one and a half decades: in 1984 (the quarterly average of prime lending rates
3-year lapse condition was removed); in (PLR);
1985 (100 per cent instead of 90 per cent of (3) quarterly private-sector supply of com-
savings); in 1988 (100 per cent instead of 80 pleted residential units (PRSUPPLY)Ð
per cent of valuation price of property); in this is partly market-driven and partly
1989, 1992 (remaining lease of at least 60 dependent on the volume of government
years instead of 75 years) and in 1993. The land sales in previous periods;
more signi® cant changes in CPF polices oc- (4) HDB supply of new unitsÐ this is cap-
curring in 1989 and 1993 will be elaborated tured in the variable TSUPPLY which is
upon in the next section. the total supply of completed residential
units in any quarter; and
(5) HDBPRICEÐ the average price for new
HDB 5-room ¯ ats in thousands of Singa-
4. Empirical Findings on the Effects of
pore dollars; HDBPRICE is determined
Government Policies on Housing Prices
by the HDB.
There exists a large international literature on
house-price determination and modelling. Part 4.1 describes the correlation between
DiPasquale and Wheaton (1996) analyse US RPPI and each of the above variables on
housing markets which are essentially free of RPPI. Part 4.2 is a regression model which
government controls and intervention (see estimates the overall effect of these variables
chs 8±10 for a review of the US literature). on RPPI. Part 4.3 looks at the interaction
Anas and Cho (1988) is an example of a between price and supply over time by
study that explicitly incorporates regulated analysing the correlation between lag values
sub-markets with rationed dwellings and of price and supply.
1824 SOCK-YONG PHANG AND WING-KEUNG WONG

Many discrete changes in housing policies from October 1993, it would allow with-
occurred over the 20-year period. In particu- drawals of CPF savings to be used to
lar, we would like to estimate the effects on meet interest payments on mortgage
RPPI of the following policies implemented loans for resale HDB and private hous-
in 1981, 1989, 1991 and 1993: ing purchases. Before this, members
were allowed to withdraw only up to 100
(1) June 1981Ð The Approved Residential per cent of the value of the property at
Properties Scheme (ARPS). In March the time of purchase.
1981, it was announced that with effect
In Part 4.4, we estimate the effects of the
from June 1981, under the ARPS, CPF
above policies on private residential property
compulsory savings that previously
price RPPI using a regression model with
could only be used for the purchase and
dummy variables.
® nancing of public housing could now
be used for private housing purchases.
(2) August/September 1989Ð HDB owner- 4.1 Correlation Coef® cients
ship criterion liberalisation. The income
Table 2 shows the correlation coef® cients of
ceiling restriction was removed for HDB
RPPI with variables t (t is the time-trend
resale ¯ ats. Owners of HDB ¯ ats pur-
variable where the ® rst quarter of 1975 is
chased from the resale market were al-
represented by 1, the second quarter of 1975
lowed to use their CPF savings to
by 2, and so on), PLR, GDP, PRSUPPLY,
purchase private residential properties
TSUPPLY and HDBPRICE. The results
for investment purposes (i.e. to earn
show that private housing prices are
rental income). Permanent residents of
signi® cantly positively correlated with time t,
Singapore and owners of private residen-
and prices of new 5-room HDB ¯ ats
tial properties were allowed to use their
HDBPRICE, but are signi® cantly negatively
CPF savings to purchase HDB resale
correlated with interest rates PLR and total
¯ ats for owner-occupancy. Before this
supply of housing units TSUPPLY. RPPI is
change in policy, the eligibility criteria
positively but not signi® cantly correlated
for resale HDB ¯ ats were similar to
with GDP growth rates.
those for new subsidised HDB ¯ ats, and
HDB-dwellers were not allowed to own
any other residential property. 4.2 Regression Model 1
(3) October 1991Ð The Single Singapore
To study the overall effect of these variables
Citizen Scheme. Single citizens (bache-
on RPPI, we use a multiple regression model
lors/spinsters) above the age of 35 were
with random error terms that follow a ® rst-
allowed to purchase HDB 3-room or
order autoregressive process:
smaller resale ¯ ats in estates outside the
central area for owner-occupancy. RPPIt 5 b0 1 b1t 1 b2 PLRt 1 b3 GDPt 1 b4
(4) 1993Ð HDB resale ¯ at credit policy and
PRSUPPLYt 1 b5 TSUPPLYt 1 b6
CPF liberalisation. In April 1993, sub-
sidised mortgage loans provided by the HDBPRICE t 1 et
HDB for purchase of resale ¯ ats were
increased to 80 per cent of the market
et 5 r et 2 1 1 ut
value or resale price, whichever is lower. where, r is a parameter such that u r u , 1; ut
Previously, the mortgage loan provided are independent N(0,s 2).
by HDB to a buyer of a resale ¯ at was The results of the multiple regression
based on up to 80 per cent of HDB’ s analysis are shown in Table 3. We note that
1984 sale price for a comparable new ¯ at there is no serious multicollinearity problem
(the posted price). In March 1993, the among the independent variables. Table 3
CPF Board announced that with effect shows that t, interest rates PLR, and
PRIVATE HOUSING PRICES IN SINGAPORE 1825

Table 2. Correlation analysis: Pearson correlation coef® cients (sample size 5 80)
Prob . u Ru under H0: Rh0 5 0

t PLR GDP PRSUPPLY TSUPPLY HDBPRICE

RPPI 0.85846 2 0.26969 0.15825 0.46906 2 0.24787 0.96681


0.0001 0.0156 0.1609 0.0001 0.0266 0.0001

Table 3. Regression model 1

Variable b value Standard error t ratio

Intercept 2 26.9020372 7.7438 2 3.474


t 0.3830944 0.1536 2.495
PLR 1.9981912 0.6390 3.127
GDP 0.5265946 0.3451 1.526
PRSUPPLY 0.0008158 0.0010 0.782
TSUPPLY 2 0.0001560 0.0002 2 0.932
HDBPRICE 0.0008810 0.0001 14.923
rà 0.7968865 0.0712 11.193
R2 0.9196

HDBPRICE have signi® cant positive effects residential units (TSUPPLY) in period t will
on RPPI; GDP, PRSUPPLY, TSUPPLY are result in a fall in RPPI for up to t 1 12
insigni® cant in explaining RPPI; t and quarters (3 years).
HDBPRICE are signi® cantly positively cor-
related to RPPI individually as well as mar-
ginally in the regression model. However, 4.4 Demand-side Intervention Policies
the individual effect of PLR on RPPI is Dummy variables are used to estimate the
negative (refer to Table 2) but the marginal effects on RPPI of policies implemented in
effect is positive in the regression model (see 1981, 1989, 1991 and 1993. They are de® ned
Table 3). in the following manner:
D81 5 1 for periods after the fourth quar-
4.3 Interactions between Prices and Supply ter of 1980.
To analyse further the relationship between D81 5 0 OTHERWISE.
supply and prices, the cross-correlation D89 5 1 for periods after the second quar-
coef® cients between lag values of RPPI and ter of 1989.
PRSUPPLY and between RPPI and TSUP- D89 5 0 OTHERWISE.
PLY are estimated. The results are shown in D91 5 1 for periods after the third quarter
Table 4 and suggest that TSUPPLY is of 1991.
signi® cantly negatively correlated to RPPI up D91 5 0 OTHERWISE.
to 12 quarters (3 years) into the future. How- D93 5 1 for periods after the ® rst quarter
ever, PRSUPPLY is signi® cantly positively of 1993.
correlated to RPPI up to a lag of 10 quarters D93 5 0 OTHERWISE.
(2.5 years). From these ® ndings, one may and
conclude that, ceteris paribus, an increase in
the RPPI in period t will result in an increase S81 5 D81 * (t 2 25)
in private-sector supply of completed units S89 5 D89 * (t 2 59)
(PRSUPPLY) for up to t 1 10 quarters (2.5 S91 5 D91 * (t 2 68)
years), while an increase in total supply of S93 5 D93 * (t 2 73)
1826

Table 4. Cross-correlation between supply and price

Cross-correlation between RPPIt and TSUPPLY(t-L)


1±12 2 0.28 2 0.30 2 0.34 2 0.32 2 0.32 2 0.32 2 0.32 2 0.31 2 0.32 2 0.30 2 0.27 2 0.26
Standard error 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.12 0.12 0.12 0.12 0.12 0.12 0.12 0.12
13±24 2 0.21 2 0.17 2 0.14 2 0.14 2 0.11 2 0.08 2 0.03 2 0.00 0.01 0.06 0.13 0.16
Standard error 0.12 0.12 0.12 0.13 0.13 0.13 0.13 0.13 0.13 0.13 0.13 0.13

Cross-correlation between PRSUPPLYt and RPPI(t 2 L)


1±12 0.43 0.39 0.36 0.33 0.31 0.32 0.31 0.30 0.28 0.25 0.22 0.20
Standard error 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.11 0.12 0.12 0.12 0.12 0.12 0.12 0.12 0.12
13±24 0.18 0.16 0.11 0.09 0.08 0.06 0.01 2 0.02 2 0.04 2 0.07 2 0.11 2 0.13
Standard error 0.12 0.12 0.12 0.13 0.13 0.13 0.13 0.13 0.13 0.13 0.13 0.13
SOCK-YONG PHANG AND WING-KEUNG WONG
PRIVATE HOUSING PRICES IN SINGAPORE 1827

where, 25 is the smallest value of t such that off over time. The coef® cient of S81
D81 5 1, 59 is the smallest value of t such is 2 1.07 which is smaller in magnitude
that D89 5 1, and so on. than the coef® cient of t which is 1.21.
We obtain the following piecewise re- This implies that the rate of housing
gression model with random error terms that price increase remained positive after the
follow a ® rst-order autoregressive process: announcement (and subsequent im-
RPPIt 5 b0 1 b1 t 1 b2 D81t 1 b3 D89t 1 b4 plementation) of the ARPS, although its
effect on RPPI dampened off over time.
D91t 1 b5 D93t 1 b6 S81t 1 b7 (2) The coef® cient of D89 is positive but not
S89t 1 br 8 S91t 1 b9 S93t 1 signi® cant, while that of S89 is
signi® cantly positive. This implies that
b10 PLRt 1 b11 GDPt 1 b12 the 1989 HDB ownership criterion liber-
PRSUPPLYt 1 b13 TSUPPLYt 1 et alisation policy did not result in a
signi® cant initial rise in private housing
et 5 r et 2 1 1 ut prices but did increase their growth rate
where, r is a parameter such that u r u , 1; ut signi® cantly thereafter.
are independent N(0,s 2). (3) The coef® cients of both D91 and S91 are
The estimates of the above model are pre- not signi® cant. This leads us to conclude
sented in Table 5. In this model, we have that the 1991 Single Citizen Scheme did
dropped the variable HDBPRICE as it domi- not have a signi® cant effect on private
nates the total variation of RPPI. From the housing prices.
results in Table 5, we infer the following: (4) The estimate of b9, the coef® cient of
(1) The large coef® cient for D81 implies S93, is the largest of the slope dummy
that the 1981 ARPS policy resulted in a coef® cients (b9 5 12.7). This result im-
large initial increase in private housing plies that the 1993 policies (or other
prices when the policy was ® rst an- events occurring in 1993) caused a steep
nounced. However, the negative increase in private housing prices. The
coef® cient for S81 suggests that, while fact that the estimate of the coef® cient of
the initial effect was large, it dampened D93 is small (and not signi® cant) implies

Table 5. Regression model 2

Variable b value Standard error t ratio

Intercept 8.8528573 6.7377 1.314


t 1.2058629 0.3404 3.542
D81 30.2054974 4.4425 6.799
D89 8.2197063 4.9274 1.668
D91 0.6234105 5.6940 0.109
D93 1.0948393 6.0831 0.180
S81 2 1.0679206 0.5257 2 2.032
S89 2.8478511 1.1996 2.374
S91 1.2685777 2.2367 0.567
S93 12.7007308 2.2938 5.537
PLR 0.3288408 0.8602 0.382
GDP 0.4419669 0.3193 1.384
PRSUPPLY 0.0006525 0.0013 0.506
TSUPPLY 2 0.0000885 0.0002 2 0.473
rà 0.5636353 0.1025 5.501
R2 0.9710
1828 SOCK-YONG PHANG AND WING-KEUNG WONG

that events occurring in the second quar- cies (such as changes in the prices for public
ter of 1993 did not cause a signi® cant housing, supply of private and public hous-
initial jump in private housing prices, but ing, liberalisation of public housing regula-
did result in a signi® cant increase in the tions and housing ® nance regulations) are
subsequent rate of growth of RPPI. crucial to prevent excessive instability in pri-
vate housing prices. Well-timed housing-re-
The above results also suggest that nominal lated policies may even be used to dampen
interest rate PLR, private housing supply the residential property cycle. These ® ndings
PRSUPPLY and GDP growth rate are posi- have important implications for residential
tively related to private housing prices, while property price management and therefore
the total supply of completed residential macroeconomic management in Singapore.
units TSUPPLY is negatively related to
RPPI. However, all four conventional vari-
ables are insigni® cant in explaining RPPI. Notes
`Insigni® cance’ refers to the insigni® cant 1. See Wong and Yeh (1985) for an informative
marginal contribution of PLR, GDP, PRSUP- review of public housing policies between
PLY and TSUPPLY in explaining RPPI. 1960 and 1985. Since 1982, public housing
previously built by other public-sector agen-
cies such as the Jurong Town Corporation
and the Housing and Urban Development
5. Conclusion Company have come under the management
The above results show that the conventional of the HDB. See Phang (1992) for the effects
of housing policies on housing, location and
factors which affect private housing prices in commute decisions.
other countries (see for example DiPasquale 2. This has come about because of the appli-
and Wheaton, 1996), such as interest rates, cation of the Land Acquisition Act of 1966
income growth rates and supply of housing, which has allowed the government to acquire
appear to have played a statistically less land from private landowners at prices
pegged below market values for broadly
signi® cant role in the determination of pri- de® ned public purposes which include any
vate housing prices in Singapore. public, residential, industrial or commercial
Private housing prices in Singapore are purposes. See Phang (1996) for the effect of
highly correlated with the prices for public this land policy on the economic develop-
housing that are set by the Housing and ment of Singapore.
3. This price series is compiled by the Urban
Development Board. Moreover, the timing of Redevelopment Authority and is not quality-
policies relating to: controlled (Urban Redevelopment Authority,
1995). It is, however, the only series avail-
(1) the use of compulsory CPF savings for able for analysis.
private housing ® nance purposes in 4. There is a case for using personal income
1981; rather than GDP as an explanatory variable,
(2) the liberalisation of rules on public hous- and also a case for including measures of
ing ownership criterion in 1989; and income distribution and wealth, given that
the private housing market caters for the
(3) the change in maximum HDB loan upper echelons of Singapore society. Ideally,
amount allowable for the ® nancing of demographic variables such as the number of
HDB resale ¯ ats and the use of compul- households, should also be included in the
sory CPF savings for housing mortgage explanatory variables. However, quarterly
interest payments in 1993; or data for the above-mentioned variables do
not exist.
(4) other events occurring simultaneously
during the respective periods;
References
appears to have had a signi® cant impact on
ANAS, A. and CHO, J. R. (1988) A dynamic, policy
private housing prices. oriented model of the regulated housing mar-
The above ® ndings suggest that the co-or- ket: the Swedish prototype, Regional Science
dination and timing of housing-related poli- and Urban Economics, 18, pp. 201±231.
PRIVATE HOUSING PRICES IN SINGAPORE 1829

ASHER, M. (1991) Social Adequacy and Equity of PHANG, S.- Y. (1992) Housing Markets and Urban
the Social Security Arrangements in Singapore. Transportation: Economic Theory, Economet-
Singapore: Times Academic Press. rics, and Policy Analysis for Singapore. Singa-
ASHER, M. (1996) Compulsory savings in Singa- pore: McGraw Hill.
pore: an alternative to the welfare state, in: E. PHANG, S.-Y. (1996) Economic development and
BUTLER , M. ASHER and K. BORDEN Singapore the distribution of land rents in Singapore: a
vs Chile: Competing Models for Welfare Re- Georgist implementation, The American Jour-
form, pp. 12±22. London: Adam Smith Insti- nal of Economics and Sociology, 55, pp. 489±
tute.
501.
COST REVIEW COMMITTEE (1993, 1996) Report of
The Straits Times (various dates) Singapore: Sin-
the Cost Review Committee. Singapore: Minis-
try of Trade and Industry. gapore Press Holdings.
DEPARTMENT OF STATISTICS (various years) URBAN REDEVELOPMENT AUTHORITY (various
Yearbook of Statistics. Singapore. dates) Real Estate Statistics Series. Singapore.
DIPASQUALE, D. and WHEATON , W. C. (1996) WEIBULL, J. W. (1993) A dynamic model of trade
Urban Economics and Real Estate Markets. frictions and disequilibrium in the housing mar-
Englewoods Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. ket, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 85,
HOUSING AND DEVELOPMENT BOARD (various pp. 373±392.
years) Annual Report. Singapore. WONG , A. and YEH, S. (1985) Housing a Nation.
NETER, J., WASSERMAN, W. and KUTNER , M. Singapore: Housing and Development Board.
(1989) Applied Linear Regression Models.
Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin.

You might also like