You are on page 1of 11

Progress report

Progress in Human Geography


2019, Vol. 43(5) 948–958
Geographies of production I: ª The Author(s) 2018
Article reuse guidelines:

Global production and uneven sagepub.com/journals-permissions


DOI: 10.1177/0309132518760095
journals.sagepub.com/home/phg
development

Marion Werner
SUNY-Buffalo, New York, USA

Abstract
Serial crises in the global economy have spurred renewed debate over contemporary transformations in
geographies of uneven development. Global production network (GPN) studies have not been inured to this
trend; indeed, in both geography and development sociology, a variety of approaches have emerged to grasp
the multi-scaled, relational process of uneven development through the lens of global production. This
progress report parses three of these: firm-centric scholarship that increasingly incorporates disinvestment
and devaluation as an empirical ‘dark side’ to global production network participation; Marxist approaches
that explore the evolving relationship between global inequality and global production; and neo-Marxist
studies of regional conjunctures that highlight the constraints, contingencies and colonial legacies shaping
uneven development in both long-standing and new ways. While their epistemological differences and
normative assumptions are mostly incommensurable, more dialogue across these positions is nonetheless
warranted if scholars are to grasp the vicissitudes upending received patterns of uneven development and
portending uncertain futures.

Keywords
conjunctural analysis, disarticulations, global commodity chains, global production networks, uneven
development

I Introduction investigate the value, power and embeddedness


of transactionally linked but geographically dis-
Uneven development is back on the agenda of
persed production arrangements. The geogra-
economic geography after several decades of
relative neglect. Since the 1990s, the sub-field phy framework was developed in conversation
has been primarily animated by its explorations with development sociology’s research program
of ‘the nodal, the near and the networked’, tak- on global commodity chains and, later, global
ing the field’s focus on ‘the sociospatial, the value chains. A detailed discussion of the dif-
systemic and the structural’ as a largely taken- ferences between these heuristics can be found
for-granted platform for the cultivation of vari- elsewhere (e.g. Bair, 2009). Suffice it to say that
ous heterodox concepts and conversations
(Peck, 2016: 307). Among the most prevalent
Corresponding author:
of the latter is the global production network Marion Werner, Department of Geography, SUNY-Buffalo,
(GPN) framework, associated with the Buffalo, NY 14260, USA.
Manchester-Singapore school. GPN scholars Email: wernerm@buffalo.edu
Werner 949

geographers have sought to foreground more (e.g. Callinicos and Rosenberg, 2008; Kiely,
robust territorial and non-firm dimensions that 2012; Rosenberg, 2010; Desai, 2015), and
were given short shrift by their sociology coun- development studies (e.g. Makki, 2015). Not
terparts. Despite differences in emphasis, how- surprisingly then, uneven development is also
ever, GPN and global value chain studies both being take up more significantly in the analysis
train their analytical gaze on the advantages that of production networks beyond the initial cri-
accrue to firms and regions that leverage their tiques. As I discuss in more detail below, a
participation in transnational supply chains to growing number of studies in sociology and
access higher value niches in the production geography pay increasing attention to the
structure; this is what the literature calls eco- dynamics of uneven development, suggesting
nomic upgrading (focusing on firms) or strate- a reformulation of the hitherto dominant
gic coupling (with an eye to regions). Jennifer assumption of felicitous inclusion, and an ana-
Bair and I have summarized this predilection for lytical centering of workers, firms, and regions
exploring the largely beneficial effects of link- that remain trapped in low-value positions or
ing supplier firms and regions to contracting excluded by heightened competition. How do
chains coordinated by multinational corpora- we make sense of this emerging trend in the
tions as an ‘inclusionary bias’ (Bair, 2011): this study of global production and how do we parse
bias clouds our understanding of the extent and the differences among the diverse range of
significance of the reproduction of low-value contributions?
positions as well as the constitutive exclusions In the rest of this report, I examine three
of firms, regions and workers that remain part approaches to uneven development in the global
and parcel of network formation and restructur- production network literature in economic
ing. To address this weakness, Bair and Werner geography and cognate fields. The first, ‘main-
(2011), Bair et al. (2013), and McGrath (2017) stream’ position examines uneven development
have developed the notion of ‘disarticulations’ as a contingent empirical outcome – a ‘dark
to signal the re-working of the GPN framework side’ – of the process of global market integra-
to center on uneven development. These authors tion. The second and third positions that I
frame global production networks as both tem- review share a broadly Marxist or neo-Marxist
porarily stabilized outcomes of inherited pat- orientation, including a theoretical commitment
terns of uneven development and contributors to formulate uneven development in dialectical
to their ongoing formulation, especially as firms terms and an embrace of a dynamic, integrated,
and firm networks reorganize to adjust to vari- but nonetheless structured global economy. The
ous pressures. second position – global production networks as
Current calls in the discipline to focus on new conduits of unequal value distribution – theo-
geographies of uneven development have rizes the mechanisms through which global pro-
emerged from multiple corners beyond GPN duction arrangements reproduce global
studies, of course. They have been spurred, or inequality. The third position – global produc-
at least emboldened, by serial crises in the glo- tion ‘without guarantees’ – adopts Gramscian
bal economy and a concomitant surge in related and/or feminist frameworks to historicize sub-
debates in the social sciences, including geogra- national regional experiences of global produc-
phical political economy (e.g. Sheppard, 2016; tion network incorporation. All three positions
Hudson, 2016; Peck, 2016; Dunford and Liu, offer rich accounts of actually existing pro-
2017), urban and regional studies (Hadjimicha- cesses of restructuring of the global economy,
lis, 2011; Hadjimichalis and Hudson, 2013; albeit differing significantly in their theoretical
Phelps et al., 2018), international relations commitments and normative assumptions.
950 Progress in Human Geography 43(5)

Despite these differences, more dialogue across time. Extending the timescale allows the
these positions is warranted if we are to leverage authors to account better for variation not only
the relatively powerful perspective that produc- in the traditional remit of GPN studies (i.e.
tion network studies afford to grasp the vicissi- ‘inclusion’, or how regions initially link to
tudes upending received patterns of uneven GPNs), but also in how these modes of linkage
development and portending uncertain futures. can shape outcomes, including negative ones
such as heightened intra-regional inequality and
lock-in to low-value, dependent positions in
II Exploring the ‘dark side’ of global networks (see also Coe and Hess, 2011).
production Coe and Yeung’s revision forms part of a
In their recent book, Coe and Yeung seek to broader effort within mainstream GPN and cog-
transform GPN from a heuristic, explanatory nate studies in sociology to address the dark side
framework to a dynamic theory (dubbed GPN of participation in global supply chains. Sociol-
2.0) that will ‘enhance the ability of GPN think- ogists, for example, have developed a parallel
ing to contribute to explanations of patterns of dimension to economic upgrading that they call
uneven territorial development in the global social upgrading, which examines how the
economy’ (2015: 22). Keeping with a firm- changes in what a firm does or the process of
centric focus, the authors identify firm-level doing it affects the rights and entitlements of
organizational strategies (e.g. intra-firm coordi- workers (Barrientos et al., 2011). This shift
nation versus inter-firm control) as the proxi- towards including worker-based dimensions is
mate dependent variable of what they call informed in part by large-scale transformations
competitive dynamics (e.g. financial discipline of supply chains in the last decade that have
and downward cost pressures). Their principal made supplier participation generally more
goal is to determine how the interaction complex and ultimately more restrictive (Ger-
between competitive dynamics and firm-level effi, 2014). In studying how suppliers are adapt-
strategies leads to given outcomes for ‘strategic ing and learning under these highly competitive
coupling’, a term that signals the prospects for conditions, a number of empirical studies con-
regions plugged into GPNs via goods or ser- clude that economic upgrading, which secures
vices suppliers to improve their economic con- suppliers’ continued participation in a restruc-
dition. In thinking about uneven development, tured production network, often does not trans-
the shift from a static equilibrium view of the late into better outcomes for workers.
firm-GPN nexus to what the authors call ‘value Increasing evidence suggests that shifts to more
capture trajectories’ is moderately useful if one technologically-intensive export production is
accepts the overall premise. ‘Trajectories’ refer associated with reductions in the proportion of
to the wide range of methods that firms employ female workers (e.g. Barrientos, 2014; Kucera
to ‘capture’ more or less value (as surplus above and Tajani, 2014; Greenstein and Anderson,
costs and normal profits, see below) over time. 2017), for example. As firms respond to
Built into this notion of trajectories are the vag- pressures to undertake more complex functions,
aries of growth and decline, indicative of a wide processes or higher value products, and to meet
range of possible outcomes of a firm’s partici- intensified cost-capability pressures (that is, to do
pation in global production networks. Coe and more for less), they adjust by creating more fine-
Yeung scale up these trajectories to sub-national grained stratifications among their workforces,
regions to identify three modes of strategic cou- between permanent and temporary employment
pling and, drawing on evolutionary economic in garment manufacturing (Plank et al., 2012;
geography, to emphasize territorial change over Rossi, 2013) or between permanent and
Werner 951

seasonal workers in export horticulture (Alford from higher value functions and more auton-
et al., 2017). As I have discussed at length omy in the network affect the possibilities for
elsewhere (Werner, 2016a), studies of dark other regions or firms to occupy the same posi-
sides of economic upgrading and strategic tionality? Or, the converse: do firms or regions
coupling can offer an empirically-grounded locked in to ‘low-value’ (i.e. highly competi-
perspective on new geographies of uneven tive) functions make it possible for other firms
development if read with an eye to them. or regions to be linked in more ‘value adding’
ways?
III Global production networks In this section, I turn to literature on global
production that places macro-scale geographies
as conduits of unequal value of uneven development at the center of its
distribution inquiry. Much of this work emerges out of, or
Firm-centered approaches to global production in close conversation with, the world-systems
– and the dark sides that they might reveal – tradition. World-systems scholars Hopkins and
nonetheless suffer from key limitations that hin- Wallerstein (1977, 1986) coined the term ‘com-
der the analytical project of understanding modity chain’ to disrupt nation-centered
long-standing and emerging geographies of accounts of development and, in particular,
uneven development through the study of glo- modernization theory and its attendant ideas of
bal production. Uneven development framed as sequentialist stages of development. Instead,
a ‘dark side’ generally presumes that these they proposed the study of linked sets of activ-
arrangements are outcomes of firms or firms ities – from inputs to production and consump-
in regional contexts. Leaving to one side other tion – organized transnationally. In this
limitations that follow from firm-centrism (e.g. tradition, returns are created (and destroyed)
limited attention to labor, the state and geopo- and distributed via these chains or networks.
litics), the principal problem with this approach The value characteristics of the economic activ-
for my purposes here is a failure to engage with ities that make up the chain are not static, more-
macro-scale questions of global inequality. Coe over (Arrighi and Drangel, 1986). They stem
and Yeung, for example, reject hierarchy in the from capitalist strategies, supported by states, to
global economy even as they acknowledge that distance themselves from highly competitive
structural inequality exists (2015: 179). In so functions – thus accruing above average profits
doing, the possibility to marshal the rich from (semi)monopolized ones – through orga-
empirics and analysis of GPNs into a dynamic, nizational (e.g. outsourcing), technological (e.g.
spatiotemporal understanding of a globally innovation) and, with the support of states, legal
integrated and dynamically structured global (e.g. intellectual property rights, trade regula-
economy is lost. Mainstream production net- tions) strategies. The main point is that core and
work studies tend to dismiss macro- peripheral positions in the world-system con-
geographies of uneven development out of hand centrate core-like and peripheral-like functions.
as a form of rigid structuralism that necessarily These attributes do not correspond to particular
reduces actors and places to their functions in activities (e.g. assembly or resource extraction),
the global hierarchy. As a result, the main- but instead reflect the degree of monopolization
stream scholarship pays little heed to the ways of the activity and thus the possibility to earn
that structural hierarchy conditions the possibi- above-average returns. Arrighi and Drangel’s
lities for firms and regions. Empirical questions classic work (1986) identified a resulting
that are sidelined as a result include, for exam- tri-modal hierarchy to the global economy
ple, how might regions or firms that benefit (core, semi-periphery, and periphery) as a
952 Progress in Human Geography 43(5)

relatively stable, if dynamically configured, auto and garment commodity chains and finds
structure. In an early dialogue with geography, that participation in these chains increases
Peter Taylor (1988) offered a ‘supportive note’ polarization within the world-system, albeit not
to this approach by demonstrating that the tri- in the same way. He argues that stratification in
modal distribution was even more robust if one the global economy linked to production net-
used finer-grained spatial units (i.e., using a work participation thus requires sector-specific
subnational rather than a national areal base). analysis. The question of the actual morphology
Obviously, this ground is well-worn, but I of global hierarchy is again being hotly debated
repeat it here because a new generation of com- in the world-systems tradition and extending
modity chain studies seeks to recuperate the from it. Karataşli (2017), squarely in that tradi-
basic project in order to grasp the reproduction tion, has recently extended the Arrighi and
of spatial hierarchy in today’s global economy Drangel contribution to posit a contemporary
via the study of production networks (Bair, ‘quadri-modal’ distribution. Collections by
2005, 2009, 2014). Bond and Garcia (2015) and Wallerstein et al.
Let me briefly highlight a few key contribu- (2015) consider this question directly in the con-
tions. Much of this literature seeks to marshal text of the rise of the so-called BRICS. And
the study of global production to better under- Hudson (2016) has offered the provocation of
stand observed patterns of global inequality. a ‘new’ New International Division of Labor,
Despite the championing of network extension reflecting similar upheavals in the structure of
to new places and actors and subsequent the global economy.
‘upgrading’ in the mainstream literature, At the heart of Marxist debates over the
dynamic but durable inequalities persist. Thus, world-systems approach has long been the onto-
the aspirational, catch-up type underpinnings of logical status of value posited as a form of
the mainstream literature are discarded for a Schumpeterian rent (i.e. above-average profits
more sobering look at how production network due to monopoly over a relatively scarce asset)
restructuring relates to the reproduction of glo- in the latter, in contrast to Marx’s original
bal income inequality. In an early contribution, notion of surplus value, which reflects relations
Arrighi et al. (2003) demonstrated that the con- of production between capital and labor. The
vergence in industrialization in the late 20th distinction reveals both theoretical commit-
century had not yielded an attendant conver- ments and empirical emphasis. Neil Smith and
gence in incomes; instead, the relative value David Harvey both sided with the orthodox
of manufacturing had decreased as core regions position in early work on uneven development;
had benefited from more monopolized activities Smith (2008 [1984]: 289), in particular, dis-
(such as R&D) and accumulated resources, missed world-systems theory for its position
especially financial and political ones, that had on value. Beyond the particularities of the value
shielded these areas, relative to others, from the definition (see Arrighi, 2007, for an excellent
destructive phase of capitalist restructuring. synthesis), however, what has unified Marxist
Brewer (2011) extends these basic insights to global production studies within and beyond the
critique the clear disconnect between the notion world-systems tradition is an understanding of
of generalizable upgrading and durable sys- the global economy – and the states and produc-
temic patterns of inequality, parsing the com- tion networks that constitute it – as a (variously)
plex debates on income polarization and complex totality. Thus, for Starosta, in perhaps
connecting these to commodity chain studies. the most orthodox proposal, the forms of pro-
Mahutga (2014) uses trade data to compare the duction networks are expressions of the unfold-
positional power of countries in the well-studied ing of the law of value wherein all capitals are,
Werner 953

in principle, subject to the general rate of profit: Campling, 2018; see also Seabrooke and
deviation from that rate – in the form of either Wigan, 2017; Bassens and Van Meeteren,
export suppliers, national industries, or multi- 2015). World cities scholars are also uncovering
national corporations – is not explained by how financial nodes and the producer services
monopoly control (or lack thereof), but rather that concentrate within them contribute to the
place-specific social relations that permit capi- unequal transfer of value. Parnreiter, for exam-
tals (i.e. firms) to survive at a lower rate of profit ple, looks at the direct role of law firms in this
(such as non-market subsidies to social repro- process via intellectual property rights claims
duction) (Starosta, 2010; Fitzsimons and Star- and labor regulation arbitrage (2017; see also
osta, 2017; see also Purcell et al., 2016). Selwyn Brown et al., 2010). Although sharing similar
(2015) offers a mixed approach that hinges objects of analysis with the mainstream GPN
Schumpeterian rents to class relations: after all, literature here (cf. Coe et al., 2014), these
the impetus to innovate and the possibility to latter studies insist that the specifics of finan-
implement such changes is determined in some cial, fiscal, or extra-economic forms of appro-
part by the power of the working class. Building priation and dispossession are understood
on the insights of agrarian and world-systems within the context of global hierarchy as a con-
scholar Farshad Araghi (2003), Selwyn argues crete abstraction.
that the goal of production network analysis
should be to understand how ‘the form and
intensity of the exploitation of labour in differ-
IV Global production ‘without
ent parts of the globe, and the systems of devel- guarantees’
opment that are based upon them, are There are of course significant dangers to
dialectically inter-related’ (2015: 258). macro-scale analyses of uneven development.
As McGrath has recently reminded the read- An immediate drawback of global inequality
ers of Progress, following in the tradition of chains can be their reliance on income inequal-
Elson’s (1979) classic intervention, the concep- ity as a measure (and attendant data problems
tualization of macro-scale geographies of plus the invisibility of unpaid labor and other
inequality benefit from a critical, heterodox, measures of well-being). Beyond the empirics,
politically-attuned approach to the question of scholarship on uneven development must avoid
value (McGrath, 2017). Towards such an endea- the pitfalls of ‘encompassing comparison’, an
vor, Werner (2016a), Argent (2017), McGrath approach that presumes that the ‘whole’ or total-
(2017) and Ouma (2015) have brought ques- ity governs its parts (McMichael, 1990). If we
tions of value transfer, dispossession and appro- understand global hierarchy to be a complex
priation more centrally into the geography totality, the latter must not be mistaken for a
literature on production networks. Recent work totalizing account wherein the multiple, partic-
by Quentin and Campling adds an additional ular arrangements of capitalist accumulation are
valence to this effort by exploring what they call reduced to their parts in the system. Nor should
‘global inequality chains’ that reflect the inter- this critique, however, be grounds for dismissal
action between global production networks, on of totality altogether in favor of unprincipled
the one hand, and ‘global wealth chains’, on the appeals to geographic polycentricity and hetero-
other. The latter refers to the increasingly com- geneous causality as is so often the case in the
plex mechanisms marshaled by global corpora- mainstream literature. We can instead seize
tions to capture surplus by avoiding tax upon open non-teleological understandings of
liabilities using strategies of offshore incorpora- dialectical relations (Hart, 2016) wherein ‘total-
tion and transfer pricing (Quentin and ity is a conceptual procedure, rather than an
954 Progress in Human Geography 43(5)

empirical or conceptual premise . . . in which the outcomes in overdetermined ways. In particu-


whole is discovered through the analysis of the lar, domestic firms adjust to global pressures
mutual conditioning parts’ (McMichael, 1990: through large-scale layoffs, while marshaling a
391; see also Friedman, 2016). particular regional culture tied to small-scale
In this final section, then, I focus on studies of export tobacco in order to minimize class con-
global production that contribute to our under- flicts. There are important differences with the
standing of uneven development as a complex Eastern European case, but also some fascinat-
totality through the study of regional conjunc- ing similarities: in particular, the emergence of
tures. Variously inspired by Gramsci, Hall, and South–South subcontracting networks between
Massey, this work sees ‘the region’ as a process, the Dominican Republic and Haiti that serve a
‘a product of interrelations . . . constituted similar function to the East–East networks
through interactions’ (Massey, 1999: 2), as an described by Pickles and Smith.
indeterminate multiplicity made through and in The region as ‘conjuncture’ offers consider-
turn remaking social relations at multiple scales. able promise for reconstructing the complex
The most explicit attempts to redefine the global totality of uneven development. This approach
production literature through this lens in geo- is often mobilized in the interdisciplinary tradi-
graphy include Pickles and Smith (with multiple tion of agrarian studies, a tradition that has long
co-authors) (2015) and Werner (2016a). In their served as a sympathetic but critical fellow tra-
study of the post-Soviet apparel economy, veler of the world-systems project (see e.g.
Pickles and Smith discuss the divergent out- Mintz, 1977; cf. Coronil, 1996). Agrarian stud-
comes of transforming textile and garment firms ies has much to offer the study of production
in post-Soviet states, formerly state-protected network restructuring in the Global South since
industries, into export platforms for the Eur- the debates over agrarian change have long
opean Union (EU) market. Combined with EU wrestled with the constitutive complexities of
accession and sectoral trade liberalization, the transition (from the [in]famous ‘articulation of
authors trace related processes of firm restruc- modes of production’ debates onward) and dis-
turing and geographical shifts in the context of posed of any Eurocentric attachment to the
serial crises. The result is neither a uniform race inevitability of expanded wage relations. Gill
to the bottom nor robust and generalized Hart’s Disabling Globalization (2002), which
upgrading (indeed the term does not contem- grounded itself in studies of agrarian change
plate the initial ‘downgrading’ of state- to understand divergent but related outcomes
sponsored industry), but rather significant var- of Taiwanese FDI in the South African garment
iegation, including novel East–East geographies industry, is an excellent example of this
of uneven development as Slovak garment firms approach, foreshadowing a number of the
sub-contract ‘unskilled’ work to Ukrainian sub- insights in Pickles and Smith. Tania Li’s
contractors. Articulation, rather than evolution, (2014) book on the articulation of forest dwell-
signals the contested and contingent, yet also ers into the global cacao chain offers a recent
structured and conditioned, outcomes of this sustained engagement with conjunctural
process. The parallels with my research on approaches to agrarian change. Her revisit eth-
restructuring and regional disinvestment in the nography highlights a recurring theme in South-
Dominican garment industry are striking east Asian studies of export commodity
despite the distinct contexts. My work traces production: small suppliers (be they peasants
how the legacies of colonialism – or what I call or swidden agriculturalists, indigenous or
coloniality (following the work of Anibal Qui- migrant) may accede to capitalist relations of
jano and Silvia Federici) – shape contemporary labor and property even in the absence of
Werner 955

corporate-driven or state-driven dispossession to develop stronger dialogue with those who


(see also Hall, 2012). study the seemingly interminable tide of disin-
Conjunctural analysis of global production vestment, and associated social malaise, that
feels particularly urgent in the current period. continues to grip rustbelts 40 years on from the
As Gramsci wrote (of his place and time but introduction of the ‘first’ New International
easily applied to ours), the ruling class has ‘lost Division of Labor (e.g. Smith, 2015; Smith and
its consensus’; it dominates but no longer leads. Winders, 2017).
‘The crisis consists,’ he continued, ‘precisely in
the fact that the old is dying and the new cannot
be born; in this interregnum, a great variety of
V Conclusion
morbid symptoms appear’ (1971: 275–6). The
dogged insistence that the globalization of pro- My intention in this report has not been to offer
duction would be a rising tide that lifts all boats a comprehensive review of the literature, but
has proven to be patently false; instead some rather to parse different approaches to under-
boats are lifted while others sink (and, if I may, standing the multi-scaled, relational process of
rising tides as a positive metaphor seems par- uneven development through the lens of global
ticularly ill-suited to the anthropo/capitalo- production. Global production ‘without guaran-
cene). What conjunctural analysis offers in tees’ – a conjunctural analysis that historicizes
this context is an attention to cultural forma- regional change and centers questions of social
tions and an attendant openness to political out- relations without presuming what these will
comes, not as unbridled contingency but rather look like – offers a useful corrective to macro-
as a mix of both conditioned and indeterminate scale approaches, but neither should the latter be
forces. The study of outcomes will only be rejected. Moreover, the boundaries between all
strengthened if we turn our lens as much to the three approaches sketched out here – the (still
new geographies of restructuring in the Global relatively heterodox) mainstream literature, and
South as to the legacies of serial disinvestment Marxist and neo-Marxist approaches – are not
in the historically peripheralized regions of the hard and fast. Clear epistemological differences
Global North. I am not suggesting that the same remain; and while we are well served by recog-
studies incorporate all of these moving parts, nizing that these different approaches, and the
but rather, expanding upon Ramamurthy’s distinct priorities that they reflect, are incom-
(2004) call for a feminist commodity chain mensurable, they are also not zero sum. In the
analysis, that we continue to trouble the false best scenario of engaged pluralism (Barnes and
binary that global production networks link Sheppard, 2010), much can be learned by navi-
producers in the Global South to consumers in gating between these approaches, and holding
the Global North. For Ramamurthy, and many them in productive tension, if we are to gain a
others, this has meant interrogating the subjec- handle on the relatively fast-moving, rapidly
tivities of Global South workers in and beyond transforming geographies of uneven develop-
capitalist production as they experience ment in our time.
‘adverse incorporation’ (Phillips, 2011) and
iterative or permanent exclusion (recent work
includes, e.g., Dutta, 2016; Prentice, 2016; Acknowledgements
Sum, 2017; Gago, 2017). Future work might I am grateful to Jim Glassman and Jenn Bair for
take these insights from the Global South and reading a draft of this essay and to Christian Berndt
trouble the class- and gender-based assump- for his patience and support. The usual disclaimers
tions of the ‘consuming’ Global North in order apply.
956 Progress in Human Geography 43(5)

Declaration of conflicting interests Barnes TJ and Sheppard E (2010) ‘Nothing includes every-
The author(s) declared no potential conflicts of inter- thing’: Towards engaged pluralism in anglophone eco-
est with respect to the research, authorship, and/or nomic geography. Progress in Human Geography 34:
publication of this article. 193–214.
Barrientos S (2014) Gendered global production networks:
Funding Analysis of cocoa-chocolate sourcing. Regional
Studies 48: 791–801.
The author(s) disclosed receipt of the following
Barrientos S, Gereffi G and Rossi A (2011) Economic and
financial support for the research, authorship, and/
social upgrading in global production networks: A new
or publication of this article: This report arises from
paradigm for a changing world. International Labour
research funded by the Regional Studies Association
Review 150: 319–340.
(#70677).
Bassens D and Van Meeteren M (2015) World cities under
References conditions of financialized globalization. Progress in
Human Geography 39: 752–775.
Alford M, Barrientos S and Visser M (2017) Multi-scalar
Bond P and Garcia A (2015) BRICS: An Anti-Capitalist
labour agency in global production networks: Contesta-
Critique. London: Pluto Press.
tion and crisis in the South African fruit sector. Devel-
Brewer B (2011) Global commodity chains and world
opment and Change 48: 721–745.
income inequalities: The missing link of inequality and
Araghi F (2003) Food regimes and the production of value:
the ‘upgrading’ paradox. Journal of World-Systems
Some methodological issues. The Journal of Peasant
Research 17: 308–327.
Studies 30: 41–70.
Brown E, Derudder B, Parnreiter C, Pelupessy W, Taylor
Argent N (2017) Rural geography I: Resource peripheries
PJ and Witlox F (2010) World city networks and global
and the creation of new global commodity chains.
commodity chains: Towards a world-systems integra-
Progress in Human Geography 41: 803–812.
tion. Global Networks 10: 12–34.
Arrighi G (2007) Adam Smith in Beijing: Lineages of the
Callinicos A and Rosenberg J (2008) Uneven and com-
Twenty-First Century. London and New York: Verso.
Arrighi G and Drangel J (1986) The stratification of the bined development: The social-relational substratum
world-economy: An exploration of the semiperipheral of ‘the international’? An exchange of letters. Cam-
zone. Review X: 9–74. bridge Review of International Affairs 22: 89–105.
Arrighi G, Silver BJ and Brewer BD (2003) Industrial Coe NM and Hess M (2011) Local and regional develop-
convergence and the persistence of the North–South ment: A global production network approach. In: Pike
divide. Studies in Comparative International Develop- A, Rodrı́guez-Pose A and Tomaney J (eds) Handbook
ment 38: 3–31. of Local and Regional Development. London: Routle-
Bair J (2005) Global capitalism and commodity chains: dge, 128–138.
Looking back, going forward. Competition & Change Coe NM and Yeung HW-C (2015) Global Production Net-
9: 153–180. works: Theorizing Economic Development in an Inter-
Bair J (2009) Global commodity chains: Genealogy and connected World. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
review. In: Bair J (ed.) Frontiers of Commodity Chain Coe NM, Lai KPY and Wójcik D (2014) Integrating
Research. Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1–34. finance into global production networks. Regional
Bair J (2014) Editors’ introduction: Commodity chains in Studies 48: 761–777.
and of the world system. Journal of World-Systems Coronil F (1996) Beyond occidentalism: Toward nonim-
Research 20: 1–10. perial geohistorical categories. Cultural Anthropology
Bair J and Werner M (2011) Commodity chains and the uneven 11: 51–87.
geographies of global capitalism: A disarticulations per- Desai R (ed.) (2015) Theoretical Engagements in Geopo-
spective. Environment and Planning A 43: 988–997. litical Economy. Bingley: Emerald Group.
Bair J, Berndt C, Boeckler M and Werner M (2013) Dis/ Dunford M and Liu W (2017) Uneven and combined
articulating producers, markets and regions: New direc- development. Regional Studies 51: 69–85.
tions in critical studies of commodity chains. Environ- Dutta M (2016) The Nokia SEZ story: Economy of
ment and Planning A 45: 2544–2552. disappearances. Economic & Political Weekly 51.
Werner 957

Available at: http://www.epw.in/journal/2016/51/ Hudson R (2016) Rising powers and the drivers of uneven
special-articles/nokia-sez-story.html (accessed 5 global development. Area Development and Policy 1:
February 2018). 279–294.
Elson D (1979) The value theory of labour. In: Elson D (ed.) Karataşli ŞS (2017) The capitalist world-economy in the
Value: The Representation of Labour in Capitalism. longue dure´e. Sociology of Development 3: 163–196.
London: CSE, 115–180. Kiely R (2012) Spatial hierarchy and/or contemporary
Fitzsimons AL and Starosta G (2017) Global capital, geopolitics: What can and can’t uneven and combined
uneven development and national difference: Critical development explain? Cambridge Review of Interna-
reflections on the specificity of accumulation in Latin tional Affairs 25: 231–248.
America. Capital & Class. DOI: 10.1177/ Kucera D and Tejani S (2014) Feminization, defeminiza-
0309816817692126. tion, and structural change in manufacturing. World
Friedmann H (2016) Commentary: Food regime analysis Development 64: 569–582.
and agrarian questions: Widening the conversation. The Li T (2014) Land’s End: Capitalist Relations on an Indi-
Journal of Peasant Studies 43: 671–692. genous Frontier. Durham: Duke University Press.
Gago V (2017) Neoliberalism from Below: Popular Prag- Mahutga M (2014) Global production networks and inter-
matics and Baroque Economics. Durham: Duke Uni- national inequality: Making a case for a meso-level turn
versity Press. in macro-comparative sociology. Journal of World-
Gereffi G (2014) Global value chains in a post-Washington Systems Research 20: 11–37.
consensus world. Review of International Political Makki F (2015) Reframing development theory: The sig-
Economy 21: 9–37. nificance of the idea of uneven and combined develop-
Gramsci A (1971) Selections from the Prison Notebooks of ment. Theory and Society 44: 471–497.
Antonio Gramsci. New York: International Publishers. Massey D (1999) Philosophy and politics of spatiality:
Greenstein J and Anderson B (2017) Premature deindus- Some considerations (The Hettner Lecture in Human
trialization and the defeminization of labor. Journal of Geography). Geographische Zeitschrift 1–12.
Economic Issues 51: 446–457. McGrath S (2017) Dis/articulations and the interrogation
Hadjimichalis C (2011) Uneven geographical develop- of development in GPN research. Progress in Human
ment and socio-spatial justice and solidarity: European Geography. DOI: 10.1177/0309132517700981.
regions after the 2009 financial crisis. European Urban McMichael P (1990) Incorporating comparison within a
and Regional Studies 18: 254–274. world-historical perspective: An alternative compara-
Hadjimichalis C and Hudson R (2013) Contemporary cri- tive method. American Historical Review 55: 385–397.
sis across Europe and the crisis of regional develop- Mintz S (1977) The so-called world system: Local initiative
ment theories. Regional Studies 48: 208–218. and local response. Dialectical Anthropology 2: 253–267.
Hall D (2012) Rethinking primitive accumulation: Theo- Ouma S (2015) Assembling Export Markets: The Making
retical tensions and rural Southeast Asian complexities. and Unmaking of Global Food Connections in West
Antipode 44: 1188–1208. Africa. Oxford: John Wiley & Sons.
Hart G (2002) Disabling Globalization: Places of Power in Parnreiter C (2017) Global cities and the geographical
Post-Apartheid South Africa. Berkeley: University of transfer of value. Urban Studies. DOI: 10.1177/
California Press. 0042098017722739.
Hart G (2016) Relational comparison revisited: Peck J (2016) Macroeconomic geographies. Area Devel-
Marxist postcolonial geographies in practice. opment and Policy 1: 305–322.
Progress in Human Geography. DOI: 10.1177/ Phelps NA, Atienza M and Arias M (2018) An invitation to
0309132516681388. the dark side of economic geography. Environment and
Hopkins TK and Wallerstein I (1977) Patterns of develop- Planning A. DOI: 10.1177/0308518X17739007.
ment of the modern world-system. Review (Fernand Phillips N (2011) Informality, global production networks
Braudel Center) 1: 111–145. and the dynamics of ‘adverse incorporation’. Global
Hopkins TK and Wallerstein I (1986) Commodity chains Networks 11: 380–397.
in the world-economy prior to 1800. Review (Fernand Pickles J, Smith A, Begg R, Bucek M, Roukova P and
Braudel Center) 10: 157–170. Pástor R (2015) Articulations of Capital: Global
958 Progress in Human Geography 43(5)

Production Networks and Regional Transformations. Sheppard E (2016) Limits to Globalization: The Disruptive
Oxford: John Wiley & Sons. Geographies of Capitalist Development. Oxford:
Plank L, Rossi A and Staritz C (2012) Workers and social Oxford University Press.
upgrading in ‘fast fashion’: The case of the apparel Smith BE (2015) Another place is possible? Labor geo-
industry in Morocco and Romania. Working Paper, graphy, spatial dispossession, and gendered resistance
Austrian Foundation for Development Research in central Appalachia. Annals of the Association of
(ÖFSE). American Geographers 103: 567–582.
Prentice R (2016) Microenterprise development, industrial Smith BE and Winders J (2017) Intervention: The Trump
labour, and the seductions of precarity. Critique of effect? Whiteness, masculinity, and working-class
Anthropology. DOI: 10.1177/0308275X17694944. lives. Antipode Online. Available at: https://antipode
Purcell TF, Fernández N and Martı́nez E (2016) The foundation.org/2017/08/08/the-trump-effect/ (accessed
uneven geographical development of cacao commodity 10 January 2018).
chains in Ecuador: From differential to monopoly Smith N (2008 [1984]) Uneven Development: Nature,
ground-rent. Working Paper, El Centro Nacional de Capital and the Production of Space. Athens: Univer-
Estrategia para el Derecho al Territorio (CENEDET). sity of Georgia Press.
Quentin D and Campling L (2018) Global inequality chains: Starosta G (2010) Global commodity chains and the Marx-
Integrating mechanisms of value distribution into analy- ian law of value. Antipode 42: 433–465.
ses of global production. Global Networks 18: 33–56. Sum N-L (2017) The making of subaltern subjects: Embo-
Ramamurthy P (2004) Why is buying a ‘Madras’ cotton diment, contradictory consciousness, and re-
shirt a political act? A feminist commodity chain anal- hegemonization of the Diaosi in China. Globalizations
ysis. Feminist Studies 30: 734–769. 14: 298–312.
Rosenberg J (2010) Basic problems in the theory of uneven Taylor PJ (1988) Alternative geography: A supportive note
and combined development. Part II: Unevenness and on Arrighi and Drangel. Review (Fernand Braudel
political multiplicity. Cambridge Review of Interna- Center): 569–579.
tional Affairs 23: 165–189. Wallerstein I, Chase-Dunn C and Suter C (2015) Over-
Rossi A (2013) Does economic upgrading lead to social coming Global Inequalities. London: Paradigm
upgrading in global production networks? Evidence Publishers.
from Morocco. World Development 46: 223–233. Werner M (2016a) Global Displacements: The Making of
Seabrooke L and Wigan D (2017) The governance of glo- Uneven Development in the Caribbean. Oxford: John
bal wealth chains. Review of International Political Wiley & Sons.
Economy 24: 1–29. Werner M (2016b) Global production networks and
Selwyn B (2015) Commodity chains, creative destruction uneven development: Exploring geographies of deva-
and global inequality: A class analysis. Journal of Eco- luation, disinvestment and exclusion. Geography Com-
nomic Geography 15: 253–274. pass 10: 457–469.

You might also like