You are on page 1of 14

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/262124464

Unorganised and Organised Manufacturing in India: Potential for


Employment Generating Growth

Article in Economic and Political Weekly · January 2004


DOI: 10.2307/4415652

CITATIONS READS
69 4,018

2 authors:

Uma Rani Jeemol Unni


International Labour Organization Ahmedabad University
82 PUBLICATIONS 1,540 CITATIONS 79 PUBLICATIONS 1,320 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Innovation and Entrepreneurship Research (sub themes - Gender, Social, User Innovation and entrepreneurship) View project

Informal Economy View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Jeemol Unni on 24 June 2020.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Unorganised and Organised
Manufacturing in India
Potential for Employment Generating Growth
This paper analyses the impact of economic reforms on the organised
and unorganised manufacturing sectors. It also seeks an explanation for the growth trends
observed by looking at specific trade and industrial policies. The analysis indicates that
economic reform policies had a differential impact on various industry groups. In
particular, the growth in the automobile industry and the infrastructure sector helped the
growth of the manufacturing industry, especially in the unorganised segment
and the generation of quality employment.
UMA RANI, JEEMOL UNNI

T
he Planning Commission’s special group on employment manufacturing continued till 2001, by looking at the growth
generating growth has noted that “even if the organised rates of value added and employment. We also seek an
sector grew at 20 per cent per annum and the private explanation for the growth trends observed by looking at
organised sector at 30 per cent per annum, their contribution to specific trade and industrial policies introduced in the sectors.
total employment would increase hardly by 1.5 to 2.0 per cent The second section analyses in detail certain specific sectors and
of the total over the Tenth Plan” [Planning Commission 2002]. sub-sectors within them, which had a high growth in the late
Hence, in order to increase employment, the unorganised 1990s, to understand what led to this growth. We explore the
sector has to be specially targeted. The idea is not new, as it employment-generating potential of this growth throughout
was earlier envisaged in the Second Plan, which “aimed at the analysis.
expanding employment opportunities of which the bulk was
to be provided by the unorganised sector” [Banerjee 1988: 78]. Growth in Manufacturing Sector
This was expected to improve productivity, bring about
greater equality and alleviate poverty. However, this was not In the initial years of planning, the thrust was to develop the
realised due to the multiplicity of forms of production manufacturing base by setting up heavy industry, towards which
organisation and the variety of enterprises in this sector, which the organised manufacturing sector was mainly producing basic
was beyond the analytical framework of planning in India intermediate goods and machinery. The 1980s saw a clear departure
[Banerjee 1988]. Hence, most policies were geared towards from this strategy with partial liberalisation, as consumer goods
organised sector income and employment growth. The economic became the dominant industry. The introduction of economic
reforms initiated in 1991 were also meant to reverse the poor reforms in the 1990s led to growth of the consumer durables
growth performance. It was expected that rapid and sustained industry and export-dependent growth. Both these strategies
growth of output and employment would reduce poverty made growth more volatile since demand for consumer durables
[Chaudhuri 2002]. is income-elastic and export growth is based on international
In an earlier paper, we had observed that the growth of value- demand [Unni 2003]. In this section, we discuss the growth in
added, employment and capital in the organised manufacturing the organised and unorganised manufacturing sector during the
sector in the country as a whole had surged in the initial years partial liberalisation and liberalisation periods. To see the impact
after the introduction of reforms. Growth in the unorganised of liberalisation, we divide the entire period from 1984 to 2001
sector, however, was observed to have peaked in the initial phase into three sub-periods: the partial liberalisation period from
of partial liberalisation (1984-90), and tapered off in the 1984-85 to 1989-90; liberalisation of the early 1990s, 1989-90
reforms period (1989-95) [Unni et al 2001]. High growth in the to 1994-95; and liberalisation of the late 1990s from 1994-95
organised sector was expected as these units were better to 2000-01. The cut-off points are largely based on the availability
equipped to deal with competitive conditions arising out of of data on unorganised manufacturing sector (See Appendix for
economic reforms. details on data). The first period captures partial liberalisation
There exists a vast literature on the impact of economic quite precisely. The second period begins a year before reforms
reforms on mainly the organised manufacturing sector. There were introduced in 1991. The initial two years after the reforms
are not many studies that systematically analyse the impact of were introduced were years of adjustment before the economy
economic reforms on the unorganised sector. This paper tries actually started picking up. The year 1994-95 was actually one
to fill this gap by analysing the impact of economic reforms of the peak years, and we expect to capture the impact of reforms.
on the organised and unorganised manufacturing sectors. We The third period covers both the period of rapid growth and
take forward our earlier analysis to see if the rapid growth recession (which began around 1996-97), with the continuation
of organised manufacturing compared with unorganised of reforms.

4568 Economic and Political Weekly October 9, 2004


Late 1980s, 1984-85 to 1989-90 the two fastest growing industries were chemicals and chemical
products, and rubber and plastic products, other than machinery
Partial liberalisation of the economy actually started in the mid- and equipment, and medical, precision and optical instruments,
1980s, after the Rajiv Gandhi government came to power and watches and clocks (Table 3). The reason for high growth in value
“delicensed several industries; increased the ceiling of invest- added in chemicals and chemical products in both sectors was
ment for big business houses; relaxed rules for importation of argued to be due to the exceptionally high effective rates of
foreign technology; replaced quantitative trade restrictions with protection that the industry enjoyed, especially for synthetic
tariffs, and lowered tariff barriers overall, reduced marginal tax fibres, soaps, cosmetics and glycerine, pesticides, and inorganic
rates on personal and corporate income and simplified tax rules; heavy chemicals [Kelkar and Kumar 1990; Nouroz 2001]. The
and, finally, announced that public sector reforms was necessary” preference given for the chemicals sector showed very clearly
[Varshney 2001: 241]. Import of capital goods against replen- that there was a bias in the policy in the 1980s.
ishment licences was granted to small-scale industries and non- As the protection afforded to the domestic industry declined
small-scale industries [Das 2003]. There was also easing of with the reduction in tariffs for most capital goods, it adversely
licensing restrictions, particularly with respect to expansion and affected the unorganised sector. In the organised sector, while
diversification within the same product group, broad banding we observed a slowdown4 in growth, the unorganised sector had
[Kathuria 1995]. The 1980s saw changes in the external and a negative value added for electrical machinery, fabricated metal
industrial sector in matters pertaining to licensing for scale and products, office, accounting and computing machinery, motor
technology as well as quantitative restrictions on imports and vehicles, and transport equipment (Table 3). The short-term effect
tariff rates [Das 2003]. of the worsening of effective protection rates for this sector could
However, due to political pressure, the government did not have been the pressure on capacity utilisation and profitability
allow “across-the-board cuts in excise duties, and it was forced of these enterprises.
to make tariffs on capital goods higher” [Varshney 2001: 244]. Despite the high growth in industrial output, employment grew
Though the system began to be administered more liberally in very slowly in the organised sector (0.65 per cent) and was
the 1980s, with import licences being much more freely given, negative in the unorganised sector (-0.95 per cent) (Table 1). The
it remained restrictive and also highly discretionary [Ahluwalia
2001]. During this period, the pace of reforms was slow and it Table 1: Growth Rates and Shares in Value Added,
focused on dismantling internal controls and increased the flex- Employment and Fixed Capital in Manufacturing Sector
ibility of operation of domestic capital. The attempts to foster Growth Rates
domestic competition through delicensing of domestic industries, Organised Unorganised
1984-85 1989-90 1994-95 1984-85 1989-90 1994-95
while continuing with non-tariff measures to protect them from to to to to to to
foreign competition, probably helped a recovery and acceleration 1989-90 1994-95 1999-2000 1989-90 1994-95 2000-01
in manufacturing activity during the 1980s.
Value Added 7.20 8.25 6.94 0.99 -0.99 6.92
During the partial liberalisation period of 1984-90, value added (8.42)
in the organised sector grew at 7.2 per cent, with growth of capital Organic 7.82 7.19 3.46 0.47 -3.00 5.86
at 6 per cent and employment at 0.65 per cent (Table 1). The (8.41)
Inorganic 6.90 8.74 8.33 2.09 2.54 8.43
organic1 industries that registered high growth in value added Employment 0.65 2.13 0.70 -0.95 -1.73 2.16
during this period were food and beverages, tobacco products, (3.80)
wearing apparel, and paper and paper products. Among the Organic 0.90 1.97 0.55 -2.59 -2.35 2.47
inorganic2 industries, intermediate goods like chemicals and (4.72)
Inorganic 0.40 2.29 0.85 4.04 -0.26 1.44
chemical products, coke and refined petroleum, rubber and plastic Fixed Capital 5.99 13.56 12.09 -20.41 5.25 6.39
products, and other non-metallic mineral products, and consumer (7.60)
goods like office accounting machinery, radio, television and Organic 4.28 15.37 11.38 -23.39 3.72 5.84
communications, medical, precision and optical instruments, (7.81)
Inorganic 6.56 12.96 12.34 -12.62 7.96 7.24
watches and clocks had a high growth in value added (Table 2).
The import policy of the 1980s included a number of capital Shares
Organised Unorganised
goods3 in the open general licence (OGL) category. Some of 1984- 1989- 1994- 1999- 1984- 1989- 1994- 2000-
the intermediate goods, like metal products and organic heavy 85 90 95 2000 85 90 95 01
chemicals were also included in the OGL. This effectively brought
Value Added
down the protection afforded to domestic producers [Kelkar and Organic 31.69 32.70 31.02 26.06 68.52 66.75 60.34 56.6
Kumar 1990 Nouroz 2001]. As a result, there was a slowdown Inorganic 68.31 67.30 68.98 73.94 31.48 33.25 39.66 43.4
in value added growth in most of these industries, and transport Employment
Organic 49.93 50.54 50.14 49.77 78.17 72.02 69.83 71.12
equipment registered a negative growth (Table 2). With import
Inorganic 50.07 49.46 49.86 50.22 21.83 28.03 30.17 28.88
liberalisation, intermediate and consumer goods became the Fixed Capital
prime movers of growth during the 1980s, and metal-based and Organic 25.96 23.83 26.09 25.17 77.35 66.90 61.73 59.72
machinery industries, which had provided the momentum for Inorganic 74.04 76.17 73.91 74.83 22.65 33.40 38.27 40.28
industrial growth in the economy, grew at a much slower rate Note: Figures in parentheses include tailoring establishments. To make the
[Kelkar and Kumar 1990]. overall growth rate comparable with the earlier periods, we have
In the unorganised sector, the manufactured output grew very excluded tailoring establishments from wearing apparel.
Source: NSSO (1989), NSSO (1994a), NSSO (1994b), NSSO (1998a), NSSO
slowly at nearly 1 per cent, compared with the organised sector (1998b), NSSO (1998c), NSSO (2002a), NSSO (2002b), NSSO (2002c).
during 1984-90, with a negative growth of capital and employ- CSO (1985a), CSO (1985b), CSO (1985c), CSO (1990a), CSO (1990b),
ment (Table 1). As in the organised sector, even in this sector, CSO (1990c), CSO (1995a), CSO (1995b), CSO (2002).

Economic and Political Weekly October 9, 2004 4569


slow growth in employment in the organised manufacturing intensity was not accompanied by an increase in capital produc-
sector was termed as the period of ‘jobless’ growth [Nagaraj tivity (Table 5). This industry, while being skill intensive, was
2000]. In the organised sector, employment growth was com- not labour absorbing, as the employment output elasticity for this
paratively higher in organic than in inorganic industries. Except industry group was 0.20 (Table 4).
for wearing apparel, tobacco products, and leather there was The growth in the consumer goods industries, which was
hardly any growth of employment in the organic industries. facilitated by the macroeconomic policies during this period
Chemical industries, which had a high growth of value added (effective rate of protection for consumer goods remained high),
did not generate similar employment growth. Employment growth also reflected the modernisation of consumption, as a large
was observed only in radio, television and communication, medical, number of consumer products embodied modern technological
precision and optical instruments, watches and clocks, and rubber characteristics. There was a reliance on imported kits for most
products, among inorganic industries (Table 2). of these goods, which probably led to low generation of employ-
In the unorganised sector, employment in the organic industries ment [Kelkar and Kumar 1990]. The other reason could have
had a negative growth (-2.6 per cent), while inorganic industries been the change in labour laws in the early 1980s, making labour
saw a positive growth of 4 per cent. Wearing apparel, textiles, adjustment in the organised sector more difficult, which might
food products and leather had a high negative growth in em- have led to inappropriate technology choice and slowdown in
ployment among the organic industries. Among inorganic indus- machinery industries in this period as the effective rates of
tries, employment grew in all industries except basic metals, protection declined. These industries, it was argued, were rela-
fabricated metal products and office accounting and computing tively more employment generating and also offered greater
machinery (Table 3). technological flexibility in terms of factor proportions, which
The employment output elasticity for the organised sector was could be changed to some extent in response to relative factor
0.09 during this period and it was negative for the unorganised prices [Kelkar and Kumar 1990]. Despite the slowdown, fab-
sector (-0.96) (Table 4). The low absorption of labour in the ricated metal and electrical machinery industry had an employ-
organised sector was argued to be due to inappropriate technology ment elasticity of 0.54 and 0.65 in the organised sector (Table 4).
choice or product composition [Mohan 1996]. It was argued that The negative employment growth in the unorganised sector
chemicals, petrochemicals and related activity are process indus- was largely due to the textile policy of 1984, which led to the
tries with vast potential for automation and application of elec- closure of textile mills, affecting employment in both large and
tronic process control equipment [Kelkar and Kumar 1990] and small industries. Secondly, the massive growth of capital-inten-
that labour productivity was the highest in these industries in sive chemical and related industries had less scope for
the organised sector, but not so in the unorganised sector. However, ancillarisation and subcontracting, unlike the machinery indus-
the high labour productivity seems to be due to substitution of tries, which had both forward and backward linkages. Thirdly,
capital for labour in this industry, as the increase in capital the consumer goods industry, which grew in the organised sector

Table 2: Growth Rates in Value Added, Employment and Fixed Capital


in Organised Manufacturing by Two-Digit Industry Group
Industry Groups Value Added Employment Fixed Capital
1984-85 to 1989-90 to 1994-95 to 1984-85 to 1989-90 to 1994-95 to 1984-85 to 1989-90 to 1994-95 to
1989-90 1994-95 1999-2000 1989-90 1994-95 1999-2000 1989-90 1994-95 1999-2000

1405 Cotton ginning 6.65 -6.36 11.84 3.06 -0.93 2.66 -2.47 7.76 17.23
15 Food products 10.52 5.82 4.31 1.79 2.30 1.65 9.46 12.58 12.16
16 Tobacco products 7.66 7.18 7.72 8.25 2.10 -1.86 13.40 12.39 13.89
17 Textiles 5.91 6.41 2.86 -2.41 -0.34 0.21 3.70 14.75 13.29
18 Wearing apparel 20.19 26.97 2.20 11.15 17.30 3.73 16.92 32.78 10.80
19 Leather products 5.18 11.05 6.26 6.49 3.79 1.68 7.14 17.66 9.19
20 Wood products 2.10 -3.84 -5.11 -0.73 -0.17 -4.81 7.80 6.25 4.93
21 Paper products 9.32 3.56 -0.88 0.36 3.57 1.75 -4.05 21.87 3.74
22 Publishing, printing 1.32 10.85 3.19 -2.75 2.66 -6.43 -1.23 12.57 16.61
Organic 7.82 7.19 3.46 0.90 1.97 0.55 4.28 15.37 11.38
23 Coke, petroleum 25.07 9.19 -1.41 4.06 5.46 -0.01 4.02 10.57 20.25
24 Chemical products 9.10 9.35 10.72 1.80 3.37 3.11 10.28 12.36 12.81
25 Rubber products 8.64 7.54 12.00 4.87 5.14 3.11 13.90 14.39 13.91
26 Other non-metallic minerals 8.27 4.38 11.92 1.14 0.41 0.32 13.51 9.21 18.15
27 Basic metals 5.20 10.02 7.22 -2.51 1.34 -0.03 1.56 16.98 6.00
28 Fabricated metals 4.67 6.93 10.83 2.52 2.07 3.74 8.20 17.43 9.07
29 Machinery and equipments 1.75 5.13 6.37 -0.69 0.86 -0.09 4.75 7.62 10.82
30 Office, accounting and
computing machinery 7.98 10.67 -12.29 -4.23 -1.57 -6.12 10.44 7.70 -3.67
31 Electrical machinery 3.51 9.71 5.31 2.28 2.53 -0.81 6.33 22.25 42.31
32 Radio, television and
communication equipment 17.93 13.18 3.56 6.73 2.91 -3.05 20.21 -22.4 42.31
33 Medical, precision and optical
instruments, watches and clocks 11.25 9.04 13.18 4.14 3.02 3.32 12.86 11.89 2.07
34 Motor vehicles 5.25 9.11 11.30 1.89 3.50 4.31 7.79 10.91 27.70
35 Other transport equipments -1.38 7.31 6.66 -4.27 2.01 -10.08 -0.75 2.96 7.97
36 Other manufacturing -1.68 22.16 19.57 1.33 8.44 9.83 1.89 21.17 16.17
Inorganic 6.90 8.74 8.33 0.40 2.29 0.85 6.56 12.96 12.34
All 7.20 8.25 6.94 0.65 2.13 0.70 5.99 13.56 12.09

Source: CSO (1985a), CSO (1985b), CSO(1985c), CSO (1990a), CSO (1990b), CSO (1990c), CSO (1995a), CSO (1995b), CSO (2002).

4570 Economic and Political Weekly October 9, 2004


with the easing of import liberalisation, probably did not spill automatic approval of foreign collaboration agreements in 34
over to the unorganised sector, as most of these goods were priority industries subject to certain guidelines, and foreign firms
imported and assembled in large factories. could hold up to 51 per cent equity in these industries, if their
During this period, capital-intensity grew at 5 per cent with a requirement for capital imports was financed through foreign
growth in capital productivity of 1.2 per cent and labour pro- equity [Kathuria 1995]. This change in policy allowed firms to
ductivity at 6.5 per cent in the organised sector (Table 5). The enter into joint ventures with multinational enterprises (MNEs)
rise in capital-intensity with capital productivity remaining un- more freely, import technology from MNEs, import capital goods
changed or rising meant that the production efficiency had and expand capacities and introduce new products without
improved and it might have led to technological upgradation obtaining an industrial licence. The liberalisation measure also
[Ghose 1994]. However, at the two-digit industry group, it was made technology transfer easier as firms could import technology
observed that in most of the modern industries there was a rise in against royalty and lumpsum payments. Liberalisation of foreign
capital intensity, with a substantial decline in capital productivity, direct investment was expected to facilitate the formation of
which meant that there was merely substitution of capital for alliances for technology transfer and international marketing. The
labour (Table 5), and no technological upgradation. The slowdown reforms reduced dependence on sub-optimal domestic inputs and
in employment growth could be attributed to this strategy of technology by allowing freer imports of raw materials, interme-
capital deepening by firms in the organised sector. In the diate goods and capital goods [Siddharthan and Lal 2003]. To
unorganised sector, the growth of capital intensity was negative, encourage private initiative, tax policies were also rationalised.
and capital productivity grew at 21.4 per cent and labour producti- During this period, no reforms were undertaken in areas related
vity grew at 2 per cent (Table 6). The negative capital intensity to privatisation of public sector enterprises and labour laws.
could be due to the closure of textile mills or closure of inefficient All these policies together led to growth in value added of 8.3
units, bringing down both capital investment and employment, per cent with an employment growth of 2.1 per cent and fixed
and allowing the remaining units to operate productively. It is also capital growth of 13.6 per cent in the organised sector during
possible that with the decline in protection to domestic producers, 1989-95 (Table 1). There was also a remarkable turnaround, with
many of the units might have found it difficult to operate. exports growing by 20 per cent in 1993-94. According to
Chandrasekhar and Ghosh (2002) the growth in manufacturing
Early 1990s, 1989-90 to 1994-95 output in this period was a result of “pent-up demand for a host
of import-intensive goods, which because of liberalisation could
The current account imbalance of the early 1990s, which led be serviced through domestic assembly or production using
to the liberalisation of the economy, was argued to be due to imported inputs and components” (p 60). Across the industry
the import liberalisation policies of the mid-1980s, as it stimu- groups, wearing apparel and leather products had a high value
lated faster import growth [Chandrasekhar and Ghosh 2002]. The added among organic industries. Among inorganic industries,
reforms of the new policy regime abolished investment licensing growth was observed in consumer durable industries like radio,
and simplified rules to facilitate private investment. Exclusive television and communications; medical, precision and optical
monopoly of the public sector over a number of industries was instruments, watches and clocks, furniture and other manufac-
abandoned. This policy allowed domestic private investors to turing, office accounting and computing machinery, chemical
invest in capacity and production in a wide range of industries, industries, motor vehicles and metal based industries (Table 2).
including heavy industries and automobiles, which were earlier Undoubtedly, during this period, the consumer goods industry
reserved for public sector [Chandrasekhar and Ghosh 2002]. The dominated the manufacturing sector and the continued growth
new industrial policy abolished the system of licensing for all was also due to domestic protection and high levels of tariff
but 18 industries, which were reduced to 15 by 1993 [Kathuria [Nouroz 2001]. It was argued that the industrial base of the
1993]. For small-scale industries, investment limit in plant and economy had become shallower as more than half the growth
machinery was increased from Rs 2 to Rs 5 lakh. was accounted for by consumer goods [Chaudhuri, 2002].
This period brought about a more comprehensive trade Despite the steep reduction in tariffs in the metal-based and
liberalisation, which encompassed abolition of non-tariff barri- machinery industry by 1994-95, these industries had a compara-
ers, reduction of peak tariff rates and dispersion along with tively better growth than in the earlier period. This growth in
devaluation of the rupee [Das 2003]. Imports were further value added was largely due to growth in fixed capital, as capacity
liberalised, whereby the domestic industry could access capital expansion and import of technology became easier. However,
goods, intermediates and raw materials. Tariff barriers and the consumer goods industry continued to grow as the tariff levels
quantitative restrictions on foreign trade were sharply reduced. were high. The protection for consumer goods while liberalising
Average tariff was brought down from 123 per cent in 1987-88 other imports was widely criticised as illogical because it dis-
to 58 per cent in 1994-95 [Nouroz 2001], and quantitative torted resource allocation in favour of highly protected consumer
restrictions on trade were lifted, except for consumer goods and goods industries and away from basic and capital goods which
agricultural commodities [Varshney 2001: 234]. The dismantling were strategically important [Ahluwalia 2001: 47].
of quantitative restrictions occurred in the first two years, when In the unorganised sector, growth in value added was negative
import licensing was virtually abolished for imports of industrial (-0.99 per cent) accompanied by a negative growth of employ-
raw materials, intermediates, components and capital goods. ment (-1.7 per cent) and positive growth of fixed capital (5.3
However, restrictions on imports of consumer goods continued, per cent) (Table 1). Among the organic industries, only wearing
which provided “substantial and open-ended protection for all apparel and leather products had a positive growth, while in the
industrial consumer goods” [Ahluwalia 2001]. inorganic industries positive growth was observed in rubber and
Foreign portfolio institutions were given entry and rules for plastic products, non-metallic mineral products, fabricated metal
foreign direct investment were liberalised. The policy allowed products, office, accounting and computing machinery and other

Economic and Political Weekly October 9, 2004 4571


manufacturing industries (Table 3). While, the metal-based and declining and growth of the middle and small-sized units
machinery industry in the organised sector recovered despite the [Uchikawa 2003]. Goldar (2000) also observed an increase in
decline in protection, the unorganised sector was affected quite employment, but he argued that this was not in large establish-
badly. Except for fabricated metals, all the other metal-based and ments, but in small and medium-sized factories. The growth in
machinery industry had negative growth. Though the fixed capital employment in organised industries was observed in wearing
in these industries increased as a result of incentives given to apparel, rubber and plastic and other manufacturing industries
the small-scale industry, it did not help in improving value added (Table 2). However, employment growth in the unorganised
growth, which continued to be negative. One consequence for sector was negative (-1.7 per cent) (Table 1), and across industry
the manufacturing industry with the policy change was argued groups positive employment growth was observed only in food
to be “displacement of existing domestic production either directly products, wearing apparel, rubber and plastic products, basic
by imports or indirectly by new products assembled domestically metals; fabricated metal products, office, accounting and com-
from imported inputs” [Chandrasekhar and Ghosh 2002: 56]. puting machinery, motor vehicles and other manufacturing
This could be one of the reasons for the growth of the organised (Table 3). All other industries had negative employment growth.
sector and the lack of it in the unorganised sector. In the organised sector, though employment growth was much
Contrary to expectations, with the opening up of the economy, higher compared with the earlier period, it was not commensurate
employment grew at 2.1 per cent in the organised sector, and with the growth in value added. The employment output elasticity
growth was much higher in the inorganic industries (2.3 per cent) improved from 0.09 in the earlier period to 0.26 (Table 4). At
(Table 1). The absence of massive labour dislocations following the two-digit industry group, the industries that, generated
the liberalisation of the economy, as expected, was because the employment were wearing apparel, paper products, coke, petro-
government postponed reforms that might have strong negative leum and rubber products. The unorganised sector had a negative
effects on employment [Zagha 2001]. In the initial three years, employment output elasticity of 1.76. The industries that gen-
1992-93 to 1994-95, after the reforms were introduced, employ- erated employment in the unorganised sector were wearing apparel,
ment grew at 4 per cent per annum in the organised sector.5 The rubber products, fabricated metals, office accounting and com-
acceleration in employment growth, especially in the capital puting machinery, motor vehicles and other manufacturing
goods industry in the organised sector, was due to the expansion (Table 4). A sharp growth in capital intensity in both the organised
in output and investment boom in response to industrial deregu- and unorganised sector was observed. The positive growth in
lation and trade policy reforms [Forbes 2002; Goldar 2000]. capital intensity was not accompanied by a rise in capital pro-
The organised manufacturing sector also saw reorganisation ductivity in both sectors, which again implied a substitution of
in terms of size, with the very large units (above 1,000 workers) capital for labour, without any technological upgradation
Table 3: Growth Rates in Employment, Value Added and Fixed Capital in Unorganised
Manufacturing by Two-Digit Industry Group
Industry Groups Value Added Employment Fixed Capital
1984-85 to 1989-90 to 1994-95 to 1984-85 to 1989-90 to 1994-95 to 1984-85 to 1989-90 to 1994-95 to
1989-90 94-95 2000- 01 1989-90 1994-95 2000-01 1989-90 1994-95 2000-01

1405 Cotton ginning 3.85 -20.83 -1.53 -16.08 -4.33 -11.93 -31.48 -2.42 -1.34
15 Food products 0.33 -1.52 6.52 -3.65 0.79 1.69 -12.98 -0.80 6.39
16 Tobacco products 7.24 -4.30 5.03 12.89 -8.80 7.73 ** ** 5.68
17 Textiles 3.50 -2.88 6.26 -5.63 -2.43 -0.16 -19.92 5.62 4.28
18 Wearing apparel* -29.52 6.24 14.40 -41.34 1.52 14.44 -76.13 23.61 7.90
19 Leather products -16.50 8.24 1.71 -6.94 -1.65 -2.65 -38.60 2.23 6.83
20 Wood products 6.12 -7.31 1.20 7.53 -3.08 2.36 -24.41 2.53 5.27
21 Paper products 7.64 -3.95 10.91 10.21 -1.13 5.73 11.45 9.85 4.58
22 Publishing, printing 12.25 -6.04 5.97 12.60 -2.16 3.99 4.58 1.39 9.16
Organic* 0.47 -3.00 5.86 -2.59 -2.35 2.47 -23.39 3.72 5.84
23 Coke, petroleum -4.33 -6.73 0.16 3.11 -10.76 0.45 -27.81 3.56 8.41
24 Chemical product 10.83 -12.94 8.29 9.62 -9.39 7.63 -4.37 3.20 7.49
25 Rubber products 15.69 4.79 0.83 12.18 4.77 1.45 11.35 19.64 -4.52
26 Other non-metallic minerals 6.15 1.34 13.43 2.03 -1.81 2.69 -17.30 0.55 13.93
27 Basic metals 2.10 -3.82 7.02 -1.58 1.84 1.16 2.62 4.40 10.80
28 Fabricated metals -6.25 4.83 8.37 -0.31 2.38 4.27 -20.15 9.29 6.19
29 Machinery and equipments 11.21 -10.67 12.31 6.69 -2.55 7.56 -2.28 6.26 8.95
30 Office, accounting and
Computing machinery -1.60 19.91 -53.12 -12.41 5.91 -30.76 -33.82 -17.18 -40.98
31 Electrical machinery – – 21.72 9.10 -6.30 18.63 -2.13 2.62 14.37
32 Radio, television and
communication equipment 2.23 -0.44 10.76 9.25 -1.52 4.77 -4.41 0.63 5.92
33 Medical, precision and optical
Instruments, watches and clocks 26.31 -7.01 -1.31 7.76 -0.39 -4.36 -3.91 17.97 -6.91
34 Motor vehicles -26.93 -1.84 16.54 8.38 3.00 9.40 -0.80 13.74 19.81
35 Other transport equipments -22.86 -3.10 3.43 5.25 -6.87 -0.45 -3.51 8.26 10.46
36 Other manufacturing 10.66 5.38 4.99 5.80 1.35 -3.44 -14.92 8.72 5.49
Inorganic 2.09 2.54 8.43 4.04 -0.26 1.44 -12.62 7.96 7.24
All* 0.99 -0.99 6.92 -0.95 -1.73 2.16 -20.41 5.25 6.39

Note: ‘-’ Implies that the growth rates could not be computed as the gross value added for electrical machinery and related goods were negative.
‘*’ Implies that tailoring establishments are excluded from wearing apparel, to make the data comparable with the earlier periods.
‘**’ Implies that the growth rates could not be computed as the fixed capital for tobacco products was negative.
Source: NSSO (1989), NSSO (1994a), NSSO (1994b), NSSO (1998a), NSSO (1998b), NSSO (1998c), NSSO (2002a), NSSO (2002b), NSSO (2002c).

4572 Economic and Political Weekly October 9, 2004


(Tables 5 and 6). This was true across all the industry groups slowed down in this period to 6.9 per cent, along with employ-
at the two-digit level in both the sectors. ment (0.7 per cent) and capital (12.1 per cent) (Table 1).
Chandrasekhar and Ghosh (2002), commenting on the recession
Late 1990s, 1994-95 to 2000-01 in the organised manufacturing industry since mid-1996, observed
that “liberalisation per se is not enough to ensure high rates of
In this period, the reforms were gradually extended to other growth of investment and productive activity, and that other
sectors. Tariffs were further reduced for most goods, and con- strategies may be necessary to encourage” (p 23). Vaidyanathan
sumer goods were also included in 1997, and tariffs were to be (1995) also pointed out that though the policy regime changed
reduced in a phased manner over a period of six years [Ahluwalia under reforms, which deregulated and got rid of bureaucratic
2001]. By 1997-98, the average tariff rate came down to 41 per controls, the responsibility for the necessary reform was left to
cent from 58 per cent [Nouroz 2001]. Public sector reforms the states. The requirements for licences, permits and inspections
started in 1996 with “‘disinvestments’ involving sale of a portion at the state and local level continued to be onerous, as the
of the government equity in public sector enterprises while enterprises faced difficulties in procuring land, electricity and
retaining majority control with the government” [Ahluwalia water connections. Secondly, there was a credit squeeze in 1996,
2001: 62]. In 1998, seven years after reforms were introduced, based on the quality of credit, which also seemed to have dis-
the government finally announced its intention to push through suaded industrial producers from plans to expand their pro-
privatisation of public firms [Varshney 2001]. Labour law was duction and import technology [Desai 2002]. A credit policy
amended, allowing firms with more than 100 workers to restruc- based more on changes in interest rates would have been more
ture their companies and lay off labour in the process. responsive to market conditions. Instead, the credit squeeze
The other important policy that was introduced was the de- choked funds to industry and perhaps resulted in the prolonged
reservation of 15 small-scale industries in 1997-98, allowing larger recession.
firms to enter and compete. Investment ceiling in plant and In the organised sector, among organic industries positive
machinery was enhanced from Rs 60 lakh to Rs 3 crore and for the growth was registered in all areas except wood, and paper and
tiny sector it was raised from Rs 5 lakh to Rs 25 lakh in 1996-97. paper products. Positive growth in value added was observed
Composite loan limit for SSI units increased to Rs 2 lakh from in all inorganic industries except coke, refined petroleum, and
Rs 50,000. The export promotion capital goods (EPCG) scheme office accounting and computing machinery. The value added
at zero duty was extended to the small-scale engineering industry. continued to grow in chemical and rubber products, other non-
Further, the ceiling for working capital was doubled for small- metallic mineral products, fabricated metals, machinery and
scale units from Rs 2 to Rs 4 crore. Small-scale industry units equipments, medical, precision and optical instruments,
were exempted from excise duty (Economic Survey, various years). watches and clocks, and motor vehicles in 1994-2000 (Table 2).
The earlier period, which had a high growth rate in value added In most of these industry groups fixed capital also increased
in the organised sector was led by an import-led boom, and it during this period.
Table 4: Employment Elasticity With Respect to Output in the Organised
and Unorganised Manufacturing by Two-Digit Industry Groups
Industry Groups Organised Unorganised
1984-85 1989-90 to 1994-95 to 1984-85 to 1989-90 to 1994-95
to 1989-90 1994-95 1999-2000 1989-90 1994-95 to 2000-01

1405 Cotton ginning 0.46 -0.15 0.23 -4.17 -0.21 -7.78


15 Food products 0.17 0.40 0.38 -11.12 0.52 0.26
16 Tobacco products 1.08 0.29 -0.24 1.78 -2.04 1.54
17 Textiles -0.41 -0.05 0.07 -1.61 -0.84 -0.03
18 Wearing apparel* 0.55 0.64 1.70 -1.40 0.24 1.00
19 Leather products 1.25 0.34 0.27 -0.42 -0.20 -1.55
20 Wood products -0.35 -0.05 -0.94 1.23 -0.42 1.98
21 Paper products 0.04 1.00 1.98 1.34 -0.29 0.53
22 Publishing, printing -2.09 0.25 -2.01 1.03 -0.36 0.67
Organic 0.12 0.27 0.16 -5.53 -0.78 0.56
23 Coke, petroleum 0.16 0.60 -0.01 0.72 -1.60 2.83
24 Chemical product 0.20 0.36 0.29 0.89 -0.73 0.92
25 Rubber products 0.56 0.68 0.26 0.78 1.00 1.76
26 Other non-metallic minerals 0.14 0.09 0.03 0.33 -1.35 0.20
27 Basic metals -0.48 0.13 -0.00 -0.75 0.48 0.17
28 Fabricated metals 0.54 0.30 0.35 -0.05 0.49 0.51
29 Machinery and equipments -0.40 0.17 -0.01 0.60 -0.24 0.61
30 Office, accounting and computing machinery -0.53 -0.15 -0.50 -7.78 0.30 -0.58
31 Electrical machinery 0.65 0.26 -0.15 - - 0.86
32 Radio, television and communication equipment 0.38 0.22 -0.86 4.15 -3.45 0.44
33 Medical, precision and optical Instruments, watches and clocks 0.37 0.34 0.25 0.30 -0.06 -3.34
34 Motor vehicles 0.36 0.38 0.38 0.31 1.63 0.57
35 Other transport equipments 3.11 0.28 -1.51 0.23 -2.22 -0.13
36 Other manufacturing -0.79 0.38 0.50 0.54 0.25 -0.69
Inorganic 0.06 0.26 0.10 1.94 -0.10 0.17
All* 0.09 0.26 0.10 -0.96 -1.76 0.31

Note: ‘-’ implies that the growth rates could not be computed as the gross value added for electrical machinery and related goods were negative.
‘*’ implies that tailoring establishments are excluded from wearing apparel, to make the data comparable with the earlier periods
Source: Same as Table 1.

Economic and Political Weekly October 9, 2004 4573


The value added grew rapidly in the unorganised manufactur- among the organic industries. In inorganic industries, employ-
ing sector (6.9 per cent) compared with a negative growth in the ment grew only in fabricated metal products, medical, precision
earlier periods, employment growth of 2.1 per cent and fixed and optical instruments, watches and clocks, and motor vehicles
capital growth of 6.4 per cent (Table 1). This could mean that (Table 2). Employment elasticity in the organised sector declined
with the reforms, some of the growth-oriented industry in the to 0.10 during this period. Wearing apparel and paper products
organised sector has spilled over to the unorganised sector. in the organic industry were the only groups that had a high
Secondly, with the enhancement of investment ceiling for plant employment elasticity and also elasticity greater than in the
and machinery for small-scale industries from Rs 60 lakh to Rs 3 unorganised sector (Table 4).
crore, and other concessions accorded to this sector, the firms In the unorganised sector, employment grew at 2.1 per cent
might have gone in for better technology or technological after registering a negative growth in the earlier two periods
upgradation,which helped to improve output. Thirdly, with (Table 1). The unorganised sector, which has a larger presence
liberalisation and dereservation of small-scale industries the in the organic industries, registered a higher growth of employ-
forces of competition are unleashed and there is reorganisation ment in all the groups except leather and textiles. In the inorganic
or restructuring of the unorganised sector, which might have also industries, employment grew in chemicals and chemical prod-
led to improved output. ucts, other non-metallic mineral products, fabricated metal prod-
In the unorganised sector, positive growth in value added was ucts, machinery and equipment, electrical machinery, and motor
observed in all the industries except for office accounting and vehicles (Table 3). In all these industries, though employment
computing machinery, medical precision and optical instruments generation was not commensurate to the growth in value added,
and watches and clocks. A high growth in value added was the quality of employment measured in terms of labour produc-
observed in wearing apparel, chemical products, other non- tivity was quite high. Employment elasticity in the unorganised
metallic mineral products, basic metals, fabricated metals, sector was 0.45 during this period. Employment elasticity close
machinery and equipment, electrical machinery, and motor vehicles to or greater than one was observed in tobacco products, wearing
(Table 3). There was an increase in fixed capital growth in all apparel, wood products, coke petroleum, chemical products,
these industries except fabricated metals. The high growth in the rubber products and electrical machinery industries (Table 4).
unorganised sector could also be due to the subcontracting Capital intensity grew at a similar rate as in the earlier period
arrangements with firms within and outside the country. in the organised sector along with increasing labour productivity
Organised sector employment grew by only 0.7 per cent during and declining capital productivity. This was true for most of the
this period (Table 1). This could be due to the public sector industry groups in this sector. In the unorganised sector, the
reforms, which were introduced during this period, and also due capital intensity continued to grow at a slower pace and this was
to the general slowdown of the economy. Positive employment accompanied by an increase in capital productivity, and labour
growth was observed in food products and beverages, wearing productivity also increased during this period (Tables 5 and 6).
apparel, fur products, leather, and paper and paper products, This could mean that in the unorganised sector there was

Table 5: Growth Rates in Partial Productivity in Organised Manufacturing Sector by Two-Digit Industry Group
Industry Groups Labour Productivity Capital Productivity Capital Intensity
1984-85 to 1989-90 to 1994-95 to 1984-85 to 1989-90 to 1994-95 to 1984-85 to 1989-90 to 1994-95 to
1989-90 1994-95 1999-2000 1989-90 1994-95 1999-2000 1989-90 1994-95 1999-2000

1405 Cotton ginning 3.59 -5.43 9.18 9.12 -14.12 -5.39 -5.53 8.68 14.57
15 Food products 8.74 3.52 2.66 1.06 -6.77 -7.85 7.68 10.29 10.51
16 Tobacco products -0.58 5.08 9.58 -5.73 -5.21 -6.17 5.15 10.29 15.74
17 Textiles 8.33 6.75 2.65 2.22 -8.34 -10.43 6.11 15.10 13.08
18 Wearing apparel 9.04 9.67 -1.53 3.26 -5.80 -8.60 5.78 15.47 7.07
19 Leather products -1.32 7.25 4.57 -1.96 -6.61 -2.93 0.64 13.86 7.51
20 Wood products 2.83 -3.67 -0.30 -5.69 -10.09 -10.04 8.52 6.42 9.74
21 Paper products 8.96 -0.01 -2.63 13.37 -18.31 -4.62 -4.41 18.30 1.99
22 Publishing, printing 4.07 8.19 9.63 2.55 -1.72 -13.42 1.52 9.91 23.04
Organic 6.93 5.22 2.90 3.54 -8.18 -7.92 3.38 13.40 10.82
23 Coke, petroleum 21.01 3.73 -1.40 21.05 -1.38 -21.66 -0.04 5.11 20.26
24 Chemical products 7.31 5.98 7.61 -1.18 -3.01 -2.09 8.49 8.99 9.70
25 Rubber products 3.77 2.40 8.89 -5.26 -6.84 -1.91 9.03 9.25 10.80
26 Other non-metallic minerals 7.13 3.97 11.60 -5.24 -4.83 -6.23 12.38 8.80 17.83
27 Basic metals 7.71 8.67 7.25 3.64 -6.96 1.22 4.07 15.64 6.03
28 Fabricated metals 2.15 4.86 7.09 -3.53 -10.49 1.76 5.68 15.36 5.33
29 Machinery and equipments 2.44 4.28 6.47 -2.99 -2.48 -4.45 5.44 6.76 10.91
30 Office, accounting
and computing machinery 12.21 12.24 -6.17 -2.46 2.97 -8.62 14.67 9.27 2.45
31 Electrical machinery 1.23 7.17 6.12 -2.82 -12.55 -0.17 4.05 19.72 6.29
32 Radio, television and
communication equipment 11.20 10.27 6.62 -2.28 35.60 -38.75 13.48 -25.3 45.37
33 Medical, precision and optical
Instruments, watches and clocks 7.10 6.01 9.87 -1.62 -2.85 11.12 8.72 8.86 -1.25
34 Motor vehicles 3.36 5.61 6.99 -2.55 -1.79 -16.39 5.90 7.40 23.38
35 Other transport equipments 2.90 5.30 16.75 -0.63 4.35 -1.30 3.52 0.95 18.05
36 Other manufacturing -3.02 13.72 9.74 -3.57 0.99 3.40 0.56 12.73 6.34
Inorganic 6.50 6.45 7.48 0.34 -4.22 -4.01 6.15 10.66 11.49
All 6.55 6.11 6.24 1.21 -5.31 -5.16 5.34 11.43 11.39

Source: Same as Table 2.

4574 Economic and Political Weekly October 9, 2004


technological upgradation taking place during this period. This however, had a high growth in the unorganised sector in both
technological upgradation was taking place in paper products value added and employment (Table 7).
with increase in labour productivity among the organic industries. The industry group manufacture of motor vehicles (341)
Among the inorganic industries, the growth of labour produc- maintained a high value added growth throughout the 1990s, but
tivity was accompanied by some sort of technological upgradation the growth in employment declined (-4.8 per cent) during the
in radio, television and communications, machinery and equip- late 1990s in the organised sector. In the unorganised sector,
ments and fabricated metals industries. both value added and employment registered negative growth
By the end of the 1990s, the growth in value added and throughout the 1990s (Table 7). The removal of licences for
employment in the organised sector slowed down, while the motor vehicles brought about 17 new ventures, 16 of which
growth in value added and employment in the unorganised sector were for the manufacture of cars, according to a Ficci estimate
showed a recovery. In the initial phase of liberalisation, consumer [Shourie 2003].
goods grew under protection. Growth slowed down later when The liberalisation policy allowed import of capital goods and
protection for this industry was phased out. The opposite was automotive components under open general licence, but re-
true of metal-based and machinery industries, which slowed stricted import of cars and automotive vehicles in semi-knocked
down during the partial liberalisation phase with reduction in down (SKD) condition. Car manufacturing units were issued
tariffs but began to grow with the opening up of the economy. licences to import components in complete knocked down (CKD)
The early 1990s had a higher growth in employment but it was or SKD form only on executing a memorandum of understand-
not commensurate with the growth in value added in the organised ing6 (MoU), which was signed by 11 companies [GoI 2002].
sector. The unorganised sector had a negative employment This policy might have helped the manufacture in the motor
growth. The reforms of the late 1990s did not generate any employ- vehicles industry to grow in the 1990s in the organised sector.
ment in the organised sector, but the unorganised sector saw an The removal of restrictions also allowed a number of multi-
increase in value added and employment, with better quality of nationals and large companies to manufacture cars and supply
employment. In certain specific industries in the unorganised sector, it to other countries. For example, in the small car business, Maruti
employment elasticity was equal to or more than one, but the became the preferred supplier under the Suzuki brand for Europe.
employment generating potential was quite low in other industries. Suzuki has also decided to make India its manufacturing, export
and research hub outside Japan. Hyundai Motors India got its
Sector-Based Impact of Reforms first outsourcing contract in 1999 and started exporting cars to
Indonesia, Algeria, Morocco, Columbia, Nepal, Sri Lanka and
The earlier analysis indicated that the economic reform policies Bangladesh [Pande 2003]. Ford India is the sole manufacturing
had a differential impact on various industry groups. In this and supply base for Ikon cars and components exported to
section we analyse in detail some of these industries at the sub- Mexico, China and Africa [Shourie 2003]. Liberalisation policies
sector level. seem to have helped India become the preferred destination for
many countries to take advantage of low costs and high-quality
Motor Vehicles services, in engineering and software.
As companies started to establish their automobile industry in
This sector was heavily regulated and dominated by a few India, this had a positive impact on the manufacture of parts and
players before reforms were introduced. The liberalisation policy accessories for motor vehicles and their engines (343), which
of 1992-93 allowed import of motor vehicle parts through special had a high growth in value added in both the organised and
import licence. The motorcar was delicenced in 1993-94. Excise unorganised sector. High growth in both sectors was due to the
duty on automobiles was reduced from 55 to 40 per cent and structure of the automobile industry, which was hierarchical and
there was also reduction in excise and customs duties on various ‘system supply’ of integrated components and sub-systems is in
components and spare parts in 1993-94. These policies allowed practice, where individual small components were supplied to
a number of global firms like Ford, General Motors, Daewoo, the system integrators instead of the vehicle manufacturers directly.
Hyundai, Mercedes Benz, Peugeot and Honda to enter the Indian In this process, the unorganised sector manufacturing smaller
market [Zagha 2001]. The automobile industry seems to have individual components became tier-2 and tier-3 suppliers, to the
emerged as a fiercely competitive industry with the opening up tier-1 company, which was the system integrator. The larger
of the economy. companies, including most multinational companies, were being
The motor vehicles industry had a high growth in the 1990s transformed into tier-1 companies, which purchase from tiers 2
in both the organised and unorganised sector. In the organised and 3, and sell to the auto manufacturers or original equipment
sector, employment and value added grew at 4.3 and 11.3 per manufacturers. This kind of system allowed both small and
cent during 1994-2000 (Table 2), while in the unorganised sector large firms to grow.
both employment (9.4 per cent) and value added (16.5 per cent) India is gaining global recognition for auto component manu-
registered a very high growth during 1994-2001 (Table 3). In facturing and is the preferred base as it offers the best mix of
this industry, the sub-sector, manufacture of motor vehicles (341) low cost and high quality engineering skills. According to a Ficci
had a high growth in the organised sector, while manufacture estimate, 15 of the world’s major automobile manufacturers are
of parts and accessories for motor vehicles and their engines (343) now obtaining components from Indian firms [Shourie 2003].
had a comparatively high value added growth in both the organised There is an increasing pressure on global tier-1 suppliers and
and unorganised sector. Manufacture of bodies (coach work) for original equipment manufacturers in US and Europe to reduce
motor vehicles and manufacture of trailers and semi-trailers (342) costs by 3-5 per cent.7 This is not possible unless they outsource
had a negative growth in both value added and employment in components from low-cost countries like India. An increasing
the organised sector during the late 1990s. This industry group number of foreign manufacturers are making their Indian firms

Economic and Political Weekly October 9, 2004 4575


the sourcing base.8 Hyundai has decided to make its Indian plant sector, employment elasticity was closer to one. The industry
the exclusive sourcing base for the Santro. Most of the large and group insulated wire and cable (313) had a high growth in both
medium-sized companies in the automotive segment have made value added and employment in the unorganised sector, while
exports a focus area and are concentrating on systems and processes it had a declining growth in the organised sector (Table 7). Though
in their companies accordingly (Auto parts exports to grow by this industry group had a high employment elasticity of 1.75 in
35 per cent ACMA, The Economic Times, April 2003). the unorganised sector, labour productivity was declining. The
The growth of the automobile industry has had a positive impact growth in this industry group could be due to the increased
on the unorganised sector’s auto components and parts industries, demand for optical fibre cables for telecom infrastructure.
where both value added and employment grew, with improved Machinery and Equipment: Value added growth in this industry
quality of employment, measured by growth of labour produc- group grew during the late 1990s, 1994-2000-01, in both the
tivity. The employment elasticity in both organised and unorganised organised and unorganised sectors. Employment, however, had
sectors was quite high and similar. The growth of the automobile a negative growth in the organised and positive growth in the
industry has also helped the consumer durables industry to be unorganised sector (Tables 2 and 3). At the three-digit level,
more prominent in the 1990s than in the earlier decade. The general purpose machinery (291) and domestic appliances (293)
expansion of this industry has also spilled over to other manu- had a very high growth in value added and employment in both
facturing industries like electric equipments in electrical machi- the organised and unorganised sectors. The growth in general
nery; forging in fabricated metal products and metal casting in purpose machinery could be due to increased demand for lifting
basic metals, where we observed tremendous growth. and handling equipments (2,915) or earth moving equipments
Electrical machinery: The value added growth in this industry needed in the construction sector. Some of the general purpose
group declined in the organised sector at the two-digit level, with machinery, like compressors are also exported, which has helped
negative employment growth during 1994-2000 (Table 2). In the this industry group to grow. The employment potential in both
unorganised sector employment and value added had a very high these industry groups in the unorganised sector was quite high,
growth of 19 and 22 per cent during 1994-2001 (Table 3). as their employment elasticity to output was closer to one, while
However, at the three-digit level, we found that accumulators, only general purpose machinery had employment elasticity closer
cells and batteries (314) and other electric equipments (319) had to one in the organised sector. The growth of domestic appliances
a very high growth in value added in both the organised and (293) could be largely due to increased demand for home
unorganised sectors (Table 7). It is possible that both these appliances in the country and also due to increased exports to
industry groups manufacture and supply intermediate goods for Sri Lanka, Bangladesh, Mexico, Ivory Coast and Dubai
the automotive industry, which is growing. In the unorganised [Chandramouli 2003].

Table 6: Growth Rates in Partial Productivity in Unorganised Manufacturing Sector by Two-Digit Industry Group
Industry groups Labour Productivity Capital Productivity Capital-Intensity
1984-85 to 1989-90 to 1994-95to 1984-85 to 1989-90 to 1994-95 to 1984-85 to 1989-90 to 1994-95 to
1989-90 1994-95 2000-01 1989-90 1994-95 2000-01 1989-90 1994-95 2000-01

1405 Cotton ginning 19.93 -16.49 10.40 35.33 -18.41 -0.19 -15.40 1.92 10.58
15 Food products 3.98 -2.30 4.83 13.31 -0.72 0.13 -9.33 -1.58 4.70
16 Tobacco products -5.65 4.49 -2.70 ** ** -0.65 ** ** -2.05
17 Textiles 9.13 -0.45 6.42 23.42 -8.50 1.98 -14.29 8.05 4.43
18 Wearing apparel* 11.82 4.72 -0.05 46.61 -17.37 -6.55 -34.79 22.09 6.50
19 Leather products -9.56 9.89 4.36 22.10 6.01 -5.12 -31.67 3.88 9.49
20 Wood products -1.40 -4.23 -1.17 30.54 -9.84 -4.07 -31.94 5.61 2.90
21 Paper products -2.57 -2.83 5.18 -3.80 -13.81 6.33 1.23 10.98 -1.15
22 Publishing, printing -0.36 -3.89 1.98 7.67 -7.44 -3.19 -8.02 3.55 5.17
Organic 3.06 -0.65 3.69 23.86 -6.72 0.60 -20.80 6.07 3.09
23 Coke, petroleum -7.44 4.03 -0.29 23.48 -10.29 -8.25 -30.92 14.32 7.96
24 Chemical product 1.21 -3.55 0.66 15.20 -16.14 0.80 -13.99 12.59 -0.14
25 Rubber products 3.52 0.03 -0.63 4.34 -14.85 5.35 -0.83 14.87 -5.98
26 Other non-metallic minerals 4.12 3.15 10.74 23.45 0.79 -0.50 -19.33 2.36 11.24
27 Basic metals 3.69 -5.66 5.86 -0.52 -8.22 -3.79 4.21 2.55 9.64
28 Fabricated metals -5.94 2.45 4.10 13.90 -4.46 2.18 -19.84 6.91 1.92
29 Machinery and equipments 4.53 -8.12 4.75 13.50 -16.93 3.35 -8.97 8.81 1.40
30 Office, accounting and computing
machinery 10.82 14.00 -22.36 32.22 37.10 -44.22 -21.40 -23.1 21.86
31 Electrical machinery - - 3.09 - - 7.35 -11.23 8.92 -4.27
32 Radio, television and communication
equipment -7.02 1.08 5.99 6.64 -1.07 4.84 -13.66 2.15 1.15
33 Medical, precision and optical
instruments, watches and clocks 18.54 -6.62 3.06 30.22 -24.98 5.60 -11.67 18.36 -2.54
34 Motor vehicles -35.31 -4.84 7.14 -26.1 -15.5 -3.27 -9.18 10.74 10.41
35 Other transport equipments -28.11 3.77 3.87 -19.35 -11.36 -7.03 -8.76 15.13 10.91
36 Other manufacturing 4.86 4.03 8.43 25.58 -3.34 -0.49 -20.72 7.37 8.92
Inorganic -1.95 2.80 6.99 14.71 -5.42 1.19 -16.67 8.22 5.81
All* 1.94 0.75 4.76 21.39 -6.24 4.23 -19.44 6.98 0.53

Note: ‘-’ implies that the growth rates could not be computed as the gross value added for electrical machinery and related goods were negative.
‘*’ implies that tailoring establishments are excluded from wearing apparel, to make the data comparable with earlier periods.
‘**’ implies that the growth rates could not be computed as the fixed capital for tobacco products was negative.
Source: Same as Table 3.

4576 Economic and Political Weekly October 9, 2004


Table 7: Growth Rates in Employment and Value Added in Organised and Unorganised Manufacturing Sector
by Three Digit Industry Groups
Industry Groups Organised Unorganised Employment Elasticity
Value Added Employment Value Added Employment Organised Unorganised
1989-90 1994-95 1989-90 1994-95 1989-90 1994-95 1989-90 1994-95 1989-90 1994-95 1989-90 1994-95
to to to to to to to to to to to to
1994-95 1999-2000 1994-95 1999-2000 1994-95 2000-01 1994-95 2000-01 1994-95 1999-2000 1994-95 2000-01

15 Food products
151 Meat, fish, fruits, vegetables 9.8 1.7 2.2 0.3 4.2 4.3 -3.0 8.2 0.22 0.18 -0.71 1.89
152 Dairy products -5.2 13.8 4.6 2.7 7.9 6.2 8.7 5.1 0.89 0.19 1.10 0.81
153 Grain mill 13.0 7.0 2.1 4.9 -4.0 8.3 -2.6 5.4 0.16 0.70 -0.66 0.65
154 Other food 3.8 2.4 -0.9 7.8 -1.7 12.1 0.9 0.9 -0.23 3.21 -0.53 0.07
155 Beverages 8.5 14.1 3.4 2.1 -3.3 14.3 9.3 3.0 0.40 0.14 2.81 0.21
16 Tobacco products 7.2 7.7 2.1 -1.9 -4.3 5.0 -8.8 7.7 0.29 -0.24 -2.04 1.54
17 Textiles
171 Spinning, weaving, finishing 6.0 1.5 -0.8 -0.6 -5.7 4.3 -4.9 -0.6 -0.13 -0.43 -0.86 -0.14
172 Other textiles 8.9 16.9 2.8 11.9 3.2 10.1 1.4 0.2 0.31 0.70 0.44 0.01
173 Knitted and crocheted 10.3 16.3 10.7 4.7 5.1 3.6 -17.5 6.4 1.03 0.28 -3.42 1.77
18 Wearing apparel
181 Wearing apparel 27.0 2.3 17.3 3.8 6.2 14.9 0.7 15.2 0.64 1.64 0.10 1.19
182 Fur products 22.0 -14.4 12.7 -2.6 7.9 23.6 2.2 -2.2 0.57 -0.18 0.28 -0.09
19 Leather products
191 Tanning and dressing 6.8 -1.2 0.3 -5.0 6.2 32.3 0.7 38.7 0.04 4.26 0.41 0.27
192 Footwear 15.6 10.8 7.1 6.1 7.9 23.6 2.2 -2.2 0.45 0.56 0.43 -5.51
20 Wood except furniture
201 Saw milling -12.1 4.6 -2.6 -27.0 7.3 -7.9 5.0 -3.4 -0.21 -5.91 0.68 -0.42
202 Products of wood -1.9 -4.2 0.7 -3.0 -10.6 3.5 -4.3 2.7 0.40 -0.71 -0.41 0.77
21 Wood products -5.1 7.8 -0.2 -4.8 -7.3 1.2 -3.1 2.4 -0.03 -0.62 -0.42 2.00
22 Paper products -0.9 -4.1 3.6 1.8 -3.9 10.9 -1.1 5.7 4.00 0.43 -0.28 0.52
23 Coke, petroleum
231 Coke oven prod 12.3 -1.1 4.0 -4.6 -10.0 5.4 -13.0 6.0 0.32 -4.26 -1.29 1.12
232 Refined petroleum 9.0 -1.4 7.0 3.6 -5.1 -9.2 -1.6 -21.3 0.77 2.48 -0.30 -2.31
24 Chemical and chemical products
241 Basic chemicals 12.3 10.2 3.4 1.3 -20.9 9.2 10.5 -5.7 0.27 0.12 0.50 -0.62
242 Other chemicals 7.9 13.3 3.2 5.9 -21.2 8.8 -12.9 9.5 0.40 0.44 -0.60 1.07
243 Man made fibres 2.4 -0.3 10.8 -5.3 -30.8 12.6 -31.7 4.1 4.48 -15.43 -1.03 0.32
25 Rubber and plastic products
251 Rubber products 10.5 6.9 4.0 2.6 3.9 -7.1 6.0 -1.0 0.38 0.37 1.55 -0.14
252 Plastic products 9.6 14.4 6.8 6.7 5.6 4.0 5.5 3.1 0.71 0.46 0.99 0.77
26 Other non-metallic mineral products
261 Glass products -0.3 7.8 -1.1 -1.2 -15.9 8.7 -16.1 0.7 -3.64 -0.15 -1.01 0.08
262 Other non-metals 5.0 12.3 0.7 0.5 2.6 13.6 -1.0 2.8 0.13 0.04 -0.39 0.20
27 Basic metals
271 Basic iron, steel 11.8 5.2 1.6 -1.0 -6.5 0.3 -12.8 -0.3 0.13 -0.19 -1.96 -1.18
272 Non-ferrous metal 5.5 13.9 -8.8 16.5 -2.1 9.3 13.2 1.7 -1.58 1.18 6.34 0.18
273 Casting metals 3.3 9.8 -0.5 0.4 -17.5 14.4 -6.2 0.6 -0.13 0.04 -0.35 0.04
28 Fabricated metal products
281 Structural metal 12.3 24.2 3.4 14.0 5.0 24.1 2.1 21.2 0.27 0.58 0.41 0.87
289 Other fabricated metal
products nec 5.7 5.2 1.7 -0.8 4.0 4.1 0.4 1.8 0.28 -0.15 0.09 0.43
29 Machinery and equipment, nec
291 General purpose machinery 5.0 15.5 1.5 12.6 -20.9 26.4 -11.7 25.0 0.30 0.81 -0.55 0.94
292 Special purpose machinery 5.0 -1.0 0.4 -8.7 -1.6 7.6 0.9 3.9 0.07 -8.35 0.55 0.51
293 Domestic appliances 13.4 17.9 4.7 10.0 -31.6 8.7 -15.0 6.8 0.34 0.55 -0.47 0.78
30 Office accounting and
computing machinery 10.7 -12.3 -1.6 -6.1 19.9 -53.1 5.9 -30.8 -0.15 -0.49 0.30 -0.58
31 Electrical machinery
311+312 Electric motor, generators,
transformers, etc 9.6 1.4 3.8 -3.5 - 14.4 -13.1 18.4 0.39 -2.59 - 1.27
313 Insulated wire and cables 13.1 7.5 0.9 2.9 -6.2 3.7 -15.1 6.5 0.07 0.38 -2.45 1.75
314 Accumulators, cells and
batteries 4.8 12.4 3.3 2.9 4.1 9.8 6.3 5.3 0.69 0.23 1.53 0.54
315 Electric lamps 9.0 12.5 1.8 -1.8 -24.5 11.0 -5.1 6.8 0.19 -0.14 -0.21 0.62
319 Other electrical equipments 4.6 18.8 -5.9 12.8 19.7 44.9 10.6 40.4 -1.28 0.67 0.53 0.90
32 Radio, television and communication
321 Electronic tubes 7.5 25.8 8.0 5.0 9.8 -4.9 25.8 4.9 1.06 0.19 2.63 1.00
322 Television and radio
transmitters 5.4 -0.9 4.0 -12.3 -38.3 52.3 -26.4 28.4 0.74 13.64 -0.68 0.54
323 Television and radio receivers 21.7 -1.7 -2.0 0.4 6.0 -6.1 1.8 -7.5 -0.09 0.26 0.30 -1.22
33 Medical, precision, optical instruments, watches and clocks
331 Medical and precision
instruments 14.0 15.3 5.4 4.5 -25.3 10.4 -15.0 10.6 0.38 0.29 -0.59 1.01
332 Optical instruments 24.9 15.9 51.3 7.3 27.8 -10.9 8.0 -10.0 2.06 0.45 0.29 -0.91
333 Watches and clocks 0.8 -0.2 -0.9 0.0 -26.2 -25.0 4.3 -26.2 -1.22 0.04 0.29 -1.05
34 Motor vehicles
341 Motor vehicles 11.3 11.7 1.3 -4.8 -6.2 -47.6 -9.9 -45.0 0.11 -0.40 -1.58 -0.94
342 Coach work 6.8 -47.3 5.8 -28.1 -14.1 15.0 4.0 9.5 0.84 -0.59 0.28 0.63
343 Parts and access 12.1 61.1 3.6 47.1 21.6 24.0 11.6 16.1 0.29 0.77 0.53 0.67
35 Other transport equipments
351 Ships and boats 15.5 3.8 -0.2 -0.7 -27.1 32.1 -36.1 23.1 -0.01 -0.18 -1.32 0.72
352 Railways -8.1 -13.7 2.7 -35.0 -17.7 0.9 -24.5 6.0 0.33 -2.56 -1.38 6.42
353 Spacecraft 14.1 20.5 4.7 -8.6 - 15.8 -34.4 19.7 0.33 -0.41 - 1.24
359 Transport nec 16.8 9.1 1.3 3.2 -1.0 1.1 -4.6 -2.4 0.08 0.35 -4.67 -2.19
36. Other manufacturing
361 Furniture 30.0 16.6 4.7 6.9 1.4 4.7 -7.5 -4.0 0.15 0.41 -5.30 -0.84
369 Manufacturing nec
(Jewellery, sports, music) 20.6 20.2 9.6 10.6 7.1 5.1 5.4 -3.3 0.46 0.52 0.76 -0.64

Source: Same as Table 1.

Economic and Political Weekly October 9, 2004 4577


Fabricated metal products: This industry group had a high growth throughout the 1990s in the organised sector and the value
growth in value added and employment in both the organised added in the unorganised sector grew in the late 1990s (Tables 2
and unorganised sector during the 1990s (Tables 2 and 3). At and 3). The growth of India’s pharmaceuticals industry has come
the three-digit level this industry group includes structural metal to be feared as much as the infotech industry [Shourie 2003].
products (281) and other fabricated metal products (289). The At the three-digit level, other chemicals (242) had a high value
manufacture of structural metal products (281) had a high value added growth in both the organised and unorganised sector in
added and employment growth in both the organised and the late 1990s (Table 7). This could be due to certain policy
unorganised sectors, with employment elasticity closer to one changes for drugs and pharmaceuticals. Industrial licensing for
in the unorganised sector (Table 7). The growth of this sector all bulk drugs and their formulations and intermediates was
was largely due to the construction boom that the economy abolished in 1994-95, except for five identified bulk drugs
experienced in the 1990s [Unni 2003]. The rapid expansion of reserved for the public sector, drugs involving the use of recom-
infrastructure had actually triggered off construction activities, binant DNA technology and specific cell/tissue targeted formu-
which had in turn fuelled demand for many key sectors of the lations. Automatic approval of foreign investment up to 51 per
economy such as cement, steel, paints and chemicals, earthmoving cent and foreign technology agreements were permitted for all
equipment and machinery, apart from structural metal products. bulk drugs and formulations, except for those produced by the
The other fabricated metal products (289) maintained its value use of recombinant technology. India is among the top five
added growth in both the organised and unorganised sectors but manufacturers of bulk drugs [Shourie 2003]. This apart, this
the growth was not employment generating. The growth could group also includes soaps, detergents and cosmetics, the demand
be due to increased demand for some fabricated metal products for which is growing, which has proved advantageous for both
in the automobile industry. Forging has a huge demand in this the organised and unorganised sectors, which cater to different
sector. Bharat Forge has the world’s largest single-location forging sections of the economy. In this industry group, the unorganised
facility and it supplies to auto manufacturers like Toyota, Honda, sector had an employment elasticity of 1.07 in the late 1990s,
Volvo, Cummins, Daimler Chrysler. This industry was chosen which was much higher than in the earlier periods. Employment
as a supplier of small forging parts for Toyota’s global trans- generation in the organised sector was quite low.
mission parts’ sourcing hub in Bangalore [Shourie 2003]. The sub-sector analysis clearly shows that growth in the metal-
Basic metals: This industry group at the two-digit level had a based and machinery industry is largely due to the growth in the
declining value added growth in the organised sector and increas- automobile industry and that of the infrastructure sector. The
ing growth in the unorganised sector in the late 1990s (Tables 2 growth of these industries would continue as long as the economy
and 3). At the three-digit level non-ferrous metals (272) and enjoys the low-cost advantage and the infrastructure development
casting metals (273) had a high value added growth in both the takes place. Once the Indian economy ceases to be a low income
organised and unorganised sectors in the late 1990s (Table 7). destination, a number of Indian manufacturing industries and
The growth in metal casting was largely due to increase in demand multinational companies would move their production base to
for iron castings, which is an essential component of the auto- other countries affecting the industrial output. At the moment
mobile industry. A number of multinational car companies were India can only seize this opportunity and improve its technologi-
hiring more vendors for iron castings to be outsourced to their cal base, and the quality of employment thereby even in the
locations abroad [Athale 2003]. The increase in demand for non- unorganised sector. The analysis also showed that with the
ferrous metals could largely be due to the growth of the infrastruc- automobile and construction industry growing, certain sub-sec-
ture sector. The declining growth in basic iron and steel industry tors within the industry groups had a potential for generating
(271) was somewhat surprising, given an increasing demand for quality employment.
galvanised and colour coated steel from the west Asia, Iran and
China. This apart, with the growth of infrastructure and construc- Conclusion
tion activities in the economy, one would expect an increase in
domestic demand for steel, which would have led to the growth The opening up of the economy helped the organised manu-
of this industry. In the unorganised sector none of these groups facturing sector to grow for more than a decade, before slowing
were employment generating, while non-ferrous metals in the down. Initial reforms promoted the consumer goods industry,
organised sector had an employment generating potential. along with certain basic and intermediate goods, through pro-
Other non-metallic products: This industry group at the two-digit tection and import liberalisation. The metal-based and machinery
level had a high value added growth in the late 1990s in both industry slowed down in the phase of partial liberalisation, as
the organised and unorganised sectors (Tables 2 and 3). Both they faced fierce competition due to tariff reduction. The growth
glass products (261) and other non-metallic mineral products was not employment generating in this sector as capital-intensive
(262) had a high growth in value added in the late 1990s (Table 7). chemical and consumer goods industries were promoted. How-
The demand for other non-metallic mineral products, such as ever, after reforms were introduced with firms allowed to expand
ceramic products, cement, and sanitaryware, are increasing in the their capacities and import of technology, there was a turnaround
housing and infrastructure sector, which might have led to the in the metal-based and machinery industries as they started to
growth of this sector. The growth in value added was not employ- grow by the mid-1990; some of these industries also upgraded
ment generating in both the organised and unorganised sectors. their technology. This apart, some policies like restriction on
Chemicals and Chemical Products: This industry was heavily import of second-hand goods of all kinds would also have helped
protected with high tariff rates till 1994-95 [Nouroz 2001]. The these industries to grow. The protection accorded to the consumer
government policies of the 1980s were biased towards chemicals goods industries helped them grow in the early 1990s, but with
and chemical products, which allowed this industry to grow. At the withdrawal of tariffs some of the industries were affected.
the two-digit level this industry maintained a high value added Growth in the early 1990s had employment generating potential

4578 Economic and Political Weekly October 9, 2004


in some consumer goods industries but this potential tapered off for each year relates to all enterprises in the unorganised sector,
in the late 1990s. Machinery and metal-based industries did not that is, own account manufacturing enterprises (OAME), non-
have labour absorption capacity during the reforms period in the directory manufacturing enterprises (NDME) and directory
organised sector. manufacturing enterprises (DME) in rural and urban areas. For
Initial reform policies affected the unorganised sector adversely the organised sector, data for the same four years were obtained
and employment growth was negative. The decline in employ- from the Annual Survey of Industries. The 56th round data,
ment was observed across all industries, especially in the textile 2000-01 of the unorganised manufacturing sector survey and the
industry. The reforms of the early 1990s did not help the 1999-2000 data of the organised sector was based on the National
unorganised sector to grow, and employment continued to be Industrial Classification (NIC), 1998 while the earlier rounds
negative during this period. However, after the promotional used the NIC-1987.
policies towards small-scale industries of expanding their capaci- For this analysis we have made the data comparable at the
ties and raising their investment limits, the unorganised segment 2-digit level using the NIC-1998 for all the years. The NIC 1998
surged forward in the 1990s. The growth also generated employ- excludes industry group repair of goods from the manufacturing
ment in most of the industries. The metal-based and machinery sector and cotton ginning has been excluded from cotton textiles
industry, which suffered badly after initial reforms, also picked and included in the agricultural sector. We have excluded the
up in the unorganised sector in the late 1990s. Though the repair of goods from the manufacturing sector, but maintained
employment generating potential in these industries was low, the cotton ginning under a separate category. The NIC 1998 includes
quality of employment improved. tailoring establishments (964-NIC 1987) in wearing apparel,
The growth of the metal-based and machinery industry since which was earlier included in personal services.
the beginning of the 1990s seemed to be intriguing. The sub- Wearing apparel: The latest unorganised manufacturing sector
sector analysis showed that the delicensing of the automobile survey, 2000-01 included all tailoring establishments in the
industry resulted in the entry of a number of global multinational manufacture of wearing apparel (NIC 1998 code 18) category.
companies. India became a preferred destination not only for its To make the data comparable with the earlier rounds we have
low costs but also for its high-quality engineering and software excluded tailoring establishments from wearing apparel in 2000-01
services, as firms try to compete to maintain their market share. for the unorganised sector.
This also helped the development of the auto component manufac- The proportion of tailoring establishments to the total wearing
turing base not only for the organised but also the unorganised apparel and tailoring establishments was computed separately for
sector. The unorganised sector growth in the motor vehicles rural, urban and total from the employment-unemployment round,
industry is largely due to their being tier-2 and tier-3 auto NSS 1993-94. We assume that all tailoring establishments are in
component suppliers to large companies. The development of the unorganised sector. The wearing apparel segment in 1993-94
the automobile industry also triggered growth in other manufac- is split into the organised and unorganised sectors using the pro-
turing industries, like electric equipments in the electrical portion of the same from the unorganised manufacturing sector
machinery sector, forging in fabricated metal products and metal survey, 1994-95 and the Annual Survey of Industries (organised)
casting in basic metals. This seems to have benefited the un- of the same year. The proportion of tailoring establishments to
organised sector, which enjoyed high growth during the late 1990s. the total unorganised segment of the wearing apparel and tailoring
The infrastructure sector also contributed to the growth of the establishment is then obtained. This proportion separately for
metal-based and machinery industry in the 1990s, as emphasis rural and urban, is applied to both the OAME and NDME to
on this sector in the globalised era gained importance. The rapid estimate the wearing apparel segment alone in 2000-01.
expansion of infrastructure has triggered off construction acti- To estimate the value added for wearing apparel, we have
vities, which in turn fuelled demand for many key sectors of the multiplied the estimated number of workers in wearing apparel
economy such as cement, steel, paints and chemicals, earthmoving to labour productivity of wearing apparel, which includes
equipment and machinery. The 1990s saw a number of projects tailoring establishments. To estimate the fixed capital for wearing
like the nationwide National Highway Development Programme, apparel, we have multiplied the estimated number of workers
the golden quadrilateral project, telecom infrastructure, water in wearing apparel to the capital productivity of wearing apparel,
supply, sanitation, and irrigation projects, which led to increased which includes tailoring establishments.
demand for these products. There was an increased demand for Deflators: We have used the implicit deflators of gross domestic
private urban housing in the 1990s, with a number of concessions product at 1993-94 prices of the respective organised and
and incentives being provided under different schemes, which unorganised manufacturing at the two-digit industry group to
also led to the construction boom. These developments also deflate the gross value added in the two sectors. The total fixed
helped the unorganised sector to grow, especially in employ- assets was deflated by the gross fixed capital formation at 1993-94
ment. The growth in these sectors generated quality employment in prices for both the organised and unorganised manufacturing
the unorganised sector. The sub-sector analysis thus showed that sector at the two-digit level. -29
in the liberalised era two sectors, automobile and the construction
industry, have actually helped the growth of the manufacturing Address for correspondence:
industry, especially the unorganised segment. gidrad1@sancharnet.in
jeemol@gidr.ac.in
Appendix
Notes
Data on the unorganised sector for India are obtained from
1 Organic industries include the traditional industries, cotton ginning, food
the follow-up surveys of the National Sample Survey Organisation products, tobacco products, textiles, wearing apparel, leather products,
for the years 1984-85, 1989-90, 1994-95 and 2000-01. The data wood products, paper products and publishing, printing.

Economic and Political Weekly October 9, 2004 4579


2 Inorganic industries include the modern industries, coke, petroleum, Desai, Ashok, V (2002): ‘A Decade of Economic Reforms’ in Uma Kapila
chemical products, rubber products, other non-metals, basic metals, and Raj Kapila (eds), A Decade of Economic Reforms in India: The
fabricated metals, machinery and equipment, office, accounting, electrical Past, The Present, The Future, Academic Foundation, New Delhi.
machinery, radio, television, medical, precision, motor vehicles, other Forbes, Naushad (2002): ‘Doing Business in India: What Has Liberalisation
transport and other manufacturing industries. Changed?’ in Anne O Krueger (ed), Economic Policy Reforms and the
3 These goods included tractors and other agricultural machinery; food and Indian Economy, Oxford University Press, New Delhi.
textile industrial machinery; industrial machinery (except food and textile); Ghose, A K (1994): ‘Employment in Organised Manufacturing in India’
other non-electrical machinery; communication equipment; electronic Indian Journal of Labour Economics, 37(2): 143-162.
equipment and television; ships and boats; rail equipment; motor vehicles; Ghosh, Jayati (1999): ‘Liberalisation Debates’ in Terence J Byres (ed), The
and motor cycles and scooters. Indian Economy: Major Debates Since Independence, Oxford University
4 For growth rates in the earlier period please refer to Unni et al, (2001). Press, New Delhi.
5 Computed from Annual Survey of Industries. GoI (2002): Sector Specific Policy, Auto Policy, Government of India,
6 The MoU included, to establish actual production of cars and not merely New Delhi.
assemble vehicles; to bring in a minimum foreign equity of US $ million Goldar, B N (2000): ‘Employment Growth in Organised Manufacturing in
if a joint venture involved majority foreign equity ownership; to indigenise India’ Economic and Political Weekly, 35(14): 1191-95.
components up to a minimum of 50 per cent in the third and 70 per cent Kathuria, Sanjay (1995): ‘Competitiveness of Indian Industry’ in Dilip
in the fifth year or earlier from the date of clearance of the first lot of Mookherjee (ed), Indian Industry: Policies and Performance, Oxford
imports. Thereafter the MoU and import licence would abate; to neutralise University Press, Delhi.
foreign exchange outgo on imports (cif) by export of cars, auto components, Kelkar, Vijay and Rajiv Kumar (1990): ‘Industrial Growth in the Eighties:
etc, (fob). This obligation was to commence from the third year of start Emerging Policy Issues’, Economic and Political Weekly, 25(4):
of production and to be fulfilled during the duration of the MoU. From 209-225.
the fourth year imports were to be regulated in relation to the exports Mohan, Rakesh (1996): ‘Urbanisation in India’ in Josef Gugler (ed), The
made in the previous year. Urban Transformation of the Developing World, Oxford University
7 Global tier-I suppliers like Visteon, Mico Bosch, Cummins and Delphi Press, New York.
are emerging as the largest exporters of auto components from the country. Nagaraj, R (2000): ‘Organised Manufacturing Employment’ Economic and
Large domestic companies like Bharat Forge, Ricoh Industries, Motherson Political Weekly, 35(38): 3445-48.
Sumi Systems, Sundaram Fasteners and Hi-Tech Gears are also supplying Nouroz, H (2001): Protection in Indian Manufacturing: An Empirical Study,
components to companies in North America and Western Europe (Kant, K Macmillan India, New Delhi.
(2003), ‘Auto Part Exports to Rise over 100 Per Cent to $ 2 bn in 2 Years’, NSSO (1989): NSS 40th Round (July 1984-June 1985); No 363/1, Tables
The Economic Times, May 20). with Notes on Survey of Unorganised Manufacture: Non-Directory
8 Dailmer Chrysler India (DCIL) has firmed up a base of 25 auto components Establishments and Own Account Enterprises, Part I, Part II (Volume 1
and ancillary manufacturers that supply these products to Dailmer Chrysler and 2), Department of Statistics, Government of India, New Delhi.
AG (DCAG) globally. DCIL began with sourcing for local content in 1997. – (1994a): NSS 45th Round (July 1989-June 1990); No.396/2, Tables with
However, catering to only its Indian division provided limited opportunities. Notes on Survey of Unorganised Manufacture: Non-Directory
Hence it quickly moved to global outsourcing. Today, 28 Indian companies Establishments and Own Account Enterprises, Part-I (All India).
export to DCAG. The vendor base developed in India by DCIL caters to – (1994b): NSS 45th Round (July 1989-June 1990); No 396/2, Tables with
DCAGs three basic business groups, the Mercedes Benz passenger car plants Notes on Survey of Unorganised Manufacture: Non-Directory Establish-
in Germany, Chrysler in North America and the commercial vehicle (CV) ments and Own Account Enterprises, Part-II (States), Volume 1 and 2.
division, comprising Mercedes Benz CVs in Europe and Freightliner and – (1998a): NSS 51st Round (July 1994-June 1995); No 433 (51/2.2/1)
Sterling Tricks in the US (Athale (2003)) The Economic Times, May 21). Unorganised Manufacturing Sector in India: Its Size, Employment and
Some key Estimates, – Directory Establishments and Own Account
References Enterprises.
– (1998b): NSS 51st Round (July 1994-June 1995); No 434 (51/2.2/2)
Ahluwalia, M S (2001): ‘India’s Economic Reforms: An Appraisal’ in Jeffery Unorganised Manufacturing Sector in India: Salient Features.
Sachs, Ashutosh Varshney and Nirupam Bajpai (eds), India in the Era – (1998c): NSS 51st Round (July 1994-June 1995); No 435 (51/2.2/3) Assets
of Economic Reforms, Oxford University Press, New Delhi. and Borrowings of the Unorganised Manufacturing Sector in India.
Athale, G A (2003): ‘Dailmer Chrysler Grabs 8 per cent of Auto Part Exports’, – (2002a): NSS 56th Round (July 2000-June 2001); No 478 (56/2.2/2)
The Economic Times, May 21. Unorganised Manufacturing Sector in India: Characteristics of
Banerjee, N (1988): ‘The Unorganised Sector and the Planner’ in Amiya Enterprises, Ministry of Statistics and Programme Implementation.
Kumar Bagchi (ed), Economy, Society and Polity: Essays in the Political – (2002b): NSS 56th Round (July 2000-June 2001); No 479 (56/2.2/3)
Economy of Indian Planning, Oxford University Press, Calcutta. Unorganised Manufacturing Sector in India: Employment, Assets and
Chandramouli, A (2003): ‘L G Electronics Targets Rs 5500 Cr Topline’, Borrowings.
The Economic Times, October 01. – (2002c): NSS 56th Round (July 2000-June 2001); No 480 (56/2.2/4)
Chandrasekhar, C P and Jayati Ghosh (2002): The Market that Failed: A Unorganised Manufacturing Sector in India: Input, Output and Value
Decade of Liberal Economic Reforms in India, LeftWord Books, Added.
New Delhi. Pande, V (2003): ‘Figuring it Out’, The Economic Times, May 13.
Chaudhuri, Sudip (2002): ‘Economic Reforms and Industrial Structure in Planning Commission (2002): Employment Generating Growth: Special
India’, Economic and Political Weekly, 37 (2): 155-62. Group in Targeting Ten Million Employment Opportunities Per Year,
CSO, (1985a): Directory Manufacturing Establishments Survey 1984-85, Government of India, New Delhi.
Summary Results for Central Sample, Department of Statistics, Ministry Shourie, A (2003): ‘Before the Whining Drowns it out Listen to the New
of Planning, Government of India, New Delhi. India’, The Indian Express, August 15.
– (1985b): Annual Survey of Industries 1984-85, Summary Results for Siddharthan, N S and K Lal (2003): ‘Liberalisation and Growth of Firms
Factory Sector by State and Industry, Department of Statistics, Ministry in India’, Economic and Political Weekly, 38(20): 1983.
of Planning and Programme Implementation. Uchikawa, S (2003): ‘Employment in the Manufacturing Organised Sector in
– (1985c) Supplement to Annual Survey of Industries 1984-85, Summary India: The Rise of Medium Scale Units’ in Shuji Uchikawa (ed), Labour Market
Results for Factory Sector by State and Industry. and Institutions in India: 1990s and Beyond, Manohar, New Delhi.
– (1990a): Directory Manufacturing Establishments Survey 1989-90, Unni, Jeemol (2003): ‘Economic Reforms and Labour Markets in India:
Summary Results for Central Sample. Organised and Unorganised Sectors’ in Shuji Uchikawa (ed), Labour
– (1990b): Annual Survey of Industries 1989-90, Summary Results for Market and Institutions in India: 1990s and Beyond, Manohar, New Delhi.
Factory Sector by State and Industry. Unni, Jeemol, N Lalitha and Uma Rani (2001): ‘Economic Reforms and
– (1990c): Supplement to Annual Survey of Industries 1989-90, Summary Productivity Trends in Indian Manufacturing’, Economic and Political
Results for Factory Sector by State and Industry. Weekly, 36(41): 3915-22.
– (1995a): Annual Survey of Industries 1994-95, Summary Results for Vaidyanathan, A (1995): The Indian Economy: Crisis Response and Prospects,
Factory Sector by State and Industry. Orient Longman, Hyderabad.
– (1995b): Supplement to Annual Survey of Industries 1994-95, Summary Varshney, A (2001): ‘Mass Politics of Elite Politics? India’s Economic
Results for Factory Sector by State and Industry. Reforms in Comparative Perspective’ in Jeffery Sachs, Ashutosh Varshney
– (2002): Annual Survey of Industries (Factory Sector) 1999-2000, Volume 1, and Nirupam Bajpai (eds), India in the Era of Economic Reforms, Oxford
Ministry of Statistics and Programme Implementation. University Press, New Delhi.
Das, D K (2003): ‘Manufacturing Productivity under Varying Trade Regimes: Zagha, R (2001): ‘Labour and India’s Economic Reforms’ in Jeffery Sachs,
India in the 1980s and 1990s’, Working Paper No 107, Indian Council Ashutosh Varshney and Nirupam Bajpai (eds), India in the Era of
for Research on International Economic Relations, New Delhi. Economic Reforms, Oxford University Press, New Delhi.

4580 Economic and Political Weekly October 9, 2004

View publication stats

You might also like