You are on page 1of 27

ADVANCE PUBLICATION

Thomas Edward Cliffe Leslie’s


Enthralling Journeys and His
Critique of Ricardianism: From
Inductive Political Economy to the

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


Emergence of Brit­ish Historical
Economics
Manolis Manioudis

1. Introduction
Irish his­tor­i­cism is con­sid­ered the orig­i­nal pre­lude of the Brit­ish his­tor­i­cal
school (Coleman 1987; Kadish 1989; Koot 1975, 1987; Hodgson 2001).
Two of its lead­ing mem­bers, Thomas Edward Cliffe Leslie (1825–82) and
John Kells Ingram (1823–1907), are gen­er­ally regarded as its authen­tic
found­ers, since they attempted to rebuild eco­nom­ics on an induc­tive,
his­tor­i­cal, and obser­va­tional basis (Bladen 1941: 21). For Hodgson (2001:
69), among “the two lead­ing Irish his­tor­i­cists, Leslie made the more sig­
nif­i­cant the­o­ret­i­cal con­tri­bu­tion” and laid the foun­da­tions of the Brit­ish
his­tor­i­cal move­ment in eco­nom­ics. For Koot (1975), Leslie, together with
Richard Jones (1790–1855), was one of the pio­neers of the induc­tive and
his­tor­i­cal method in Great Britain.
Cliffe Leslie was born in 1825 and learned Latin, Greek, and Hebrew at
a very young age (Ingram 1888: ix). He attended King William’s College,
and then at the age of fif­teen he entered Trin­ity College Dublin (Lipkes
1999: 137). He was an excel­lent stu­dent and grad­u­ated in 1847 with the
gold medal in logic and eth­ics (137). In 1853 he was appointed pro­fes­sor

Correspondence may be addressed to Manolis Manioudis, Department of Economics, Univer­


sity of Crete (m​­.manioudis@uoc​­.gr). I am grate­ful to Kevin Hoover for help­ful edi­to­rial revi­
sions and sug­ges­tions and to Paul Dudenhefer’s edi­to­rial capac­ity. Also, I would like to thank
two anon­y­mous review­ers for their con­struc­tive com­ments.
History of Political Economy 56:1 DOI 10.1215/00182702-10956596
Copyright 2024 by Duke University Press
140 History of Political Economy 56:1 (2024)

of juris­pru­dence and polit­i­cal econ­omy at Queens College Belfast, suc­


ceeding William Neilson Hancock (1820–88) from 1853 until 1882
(Boylan and Foley 1993: 124). In the late 1850s, he began to write essays
and crit­i­cal reviews for (the rad­i­cal) Frazer’s Magazine, the Athenaeum,
the Academy, and John Morley’s Fortnightly Review. During the same

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


period, he com­menced his fre­quent vis­its to the Euro­pean con­ti­nent, espe­
cially to Belgium and to some dis­tricts of France and Germany. During
these trips, he col­lected eco­nomic, judi­cial, and social mate­rial that fig­
ured impor­tantly in his sub­se­quent writ­ings. As Ingram (1888: x)
observed, Leslie, in this way, “gained exten­sive and accu­rate acquain­
tance with Continental rural econ­omy, of which he made excel­lent use in
study­ing par­al­lel phe­nom­ena at home.”
Cliffe Leslie’s eco­nomic writ­ings were published in three col­lected vol­
umes: the Essays in Political Economy (1879), the Essays in Political and
Moral Philosophy (1879), and his early Land Systems and Industrial
Economy of Ireland, England, and Continental Countries (1870).
Unfortunately, the draft of what was to be his mag­num opus on English
eco­nomic and legal his­tory was lost in 1875 dur­ing his unfor­tu­nate trip to
Nancy.1 Leslie’s essays high­light two impor­tant phases in his polit­i­cal
econ­omy (Ingram 1882). The first is the “early phase,” which is marked by
his texts on applied polit­i­cal econ­omy. This period attained its cli­max in
1870 with the pub­li­ca­tion of his Land Systems. As Ingram (1882) observed,
“Leslie’s work may be dis­trib­uted under two heads, that of applied polit­i­
cal econ­omy, and that of dis­cus­sion on the phil­o­soph­i­cal method of the
sci­ence” (quoted in Collison Black 2002: 17). In the first period Leslie
wrote exten­sively on applied eco­nomic mat­ters, such as the polit­i­cal econ­
omy of mil­i­tary sys­tems, fis­cal issues, the gold ques­tion, wage deter­mi­na­
tion, and land ten­ures in con­ti­nen­tal Europe. Indeed, his fre­quent trips
pro­vided him the oppor­tu­nity to col­lect mate­rial, for his applied polit­i­cal
econ­omy and his cri­tique of Ricardianism. The applied char­ac­ter of these
texts had drawn the atten­tion of J. S. Mill, who char­ac­ter­ized Leslie as an
emi­nent applied polit­i­cal econ­o­m ist of his age. The “later phase” is
stamped by Leslie’s dis­cus­sion on the phil­o­soph­i­cal method of polit­i­cal
econ­omy and the his­tory of eco­nomic thought (Milonakis and Fine 2009:
142). The most illus­tri­ous prod­uct of this period is his 1876 essay, “On the
Philosophical Method of Political Economy,” which was a his­tor­i­cist

1. He attempted, unsuc­cess­fully, to rewrite the most impor­tant parts of the lost man­u­script
but the pro­ject was beyond his abil­i­ties. He never published a full-length book.

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
Manioudis / Cliffe Leslie’s Critique of Ricardianism 141

cri­tique of Ricardian polit­i­cal econ­omy. This arti­cle turned out to be the


clas­si­cal meth­od­o­log­i­cal foun­da­tion of his­tor­i­cal eco­nom­ics in Britain
(Koot 1987). During this period, Leslie directed his attack on David
Ricardo (1772–1823) and post-Ricardians—espe­cially Robert Lowe
(1811–92)—and drafted his mag­num opus on Brit­ish legal and eco­nomic

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


his­tory which, as already noted, was lost.
This arti­cle fol­lows Ingram’s (1882) pro­posed peri­od­i­za­t ion and
attempts to delin­eate the “core ele­ments” of the “early Lesliean phase.” By
exam­in­ing Cliffe Leslie’s records of his enthrall­ing jour­neys, we show
how his induc­tive sur­veys on Euro­pean land sys­tems pre­pared the ground
for the emer­gence of English his­tor­i­cal eco­nom­ics. Presenting Leslie’s
applied polit­i­cal econ­omy in detail is beyond the scope of this arti­cle.
Collison Black (2002) discussed Leslie’s views on the Irish land ques­tion
and on sev­eral aspects of polit­i­cal econ­omy. In this arti­cle an attempt is
made to go beyond it, by sketching out Leslie’s influ­ences. We pro­pose a
fresh rereading of his travel notes as being of crit­i­cal impor­tance in pre­
par­ing his attack on Ricardian eco­nom­ics. As Boianovsky and Maas
(2022: 383) point out, there are “man­i­fold rela­tions between econ­o­mists,
their trav­els, and the devel­op­ment of the eco­nomic dis­ci­pline.” Thus, by
discussing Leslie’s views of Belgium, Germany, and France, we pres­ent
the rela­tion between his jour­neys and his applied polit­i­cal econ­omy, jour­
neys that were cru­cial in lay­ing the ground for the emer­gence of the Brit­
ish his­tor­i­cal school.

2. Cliffe Leslie’s Influences: The Inductive Side of Adam Smith


and the Importance of the Millian Heritage
Cliffe Leslie stud­ied “avail­­able polit­i­cal econ­omy exten­sively and in-
depth” (Milonakis and Fine 2009: 146) and was well informed about its
epi­ste­mic evo­lu­tion.2 Leslie was influ­enced by the induc­tive (his­tor­i­cal)
side of Adam Smith and John Stu­art Mill (Manioudis 2020), by Thomas
Robert Malthus (Koot 1987: 42), by the his­tor­i­cal juris­pru­dence and legal
his­tory of Sir Henry Maine (Collison Black 2002; Tribe 2002: 16;
Milonakis and Fine 2009: 143), by the English his­to­rian William Stubbs
(Tribe 2002: 16), by the his­tor­i­cal pro­test of Richard Jones, and by the

2. Sir William Ashley informs us that “Cliffe Leslie had been among the first Englishmen to
under­stand the work of the Ger­man his­tor­i­cal school” and “had wide Euro­pean con­tacts”
(quoted in Koot 1987: 39–40).

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
142 History of Political Economy 56:1 (2024)

heret­i­cal tra­di­tion of Trin­ity College Dublin (Koot 1987: 32). Furthermore,


he admired the work of com­par­a­tive agrar­ian polit­i­cal econ­o­mists such
as Léonce Guilhaud de Lavergne (1809–80) and Émil Louis Victor de
Laveleye (1822–92), who called for the cre­a­tion/effi­ciency of small pro­
pri­e­tor­ships (Winch 2013: 16). In Leslie’s (1879: vi) words, the polit­i­cal

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


econ­o­mist should be trained “in the schools of both Mr. Stubbs and Sir
Henry Maine, as well as in that of Mr. Mill.” Adam Smith’s and (chiefly)
J. S. Mill’s influ­ence was deci­sive for the devel­op­ment of Lesliean polit­i­
cal econ­omy (Hollander 1911: 697). Mill’s influ­ence impelled some
schol­a rs to char­ac­ter­ize him as a “way­ward dis­ci­ple” of Mill (Moore
1995: 58) or even a “her­e­tic” stu­dent of the emi­nent polit­i­cal econ­o­mist
(Lipkes 1999).
According to Cliffe Leslie, Smith’s work represented an exam­ple of
an explicit induc­tive inves­ti­ga­tion within a nat­ur­ al law frame­work (Tribe
2002: 15). As he pointed out, the meth­od­o­log­i­cal col­li­sion between
induc­tive and deduc­tive polit­i­cal econ­o­mists is rooted in Smith’s Wealth
of Nations. In his inter­est­ing essay titled “The Political Economy of
Adam Smith” (1870), he traced the meth­od­ol­og­i­cal dual­ity within the
Smithian eco­nomic meth­od­ol­ogy (Koot 1987: 40). Leslie ([1870] 1888:
23) observed that Smith used a pri­ori, deduc­tive rea­son­ing in cer­tain
aspects of his sys­tem of polit­i­cal econ­omy, but at the same time his
method “was in a large mea­sure induc­tive.” He noted that Smith was
influ­enced by Montesquieu’s (1689–1755) induc­tive method, which
protected him “from many errors into which the method of deduc­tion”
would have falsely led him (Leslie [1870] 1888: 31). Leslie adopted a
vari­ety of Smith’s notions—such as “the nat­u­ral prog­ress of opu­lence,”
the tight con­nec­tion between secu­rity and eco­nomic advance­ment, and
the “stages the­ory”—while remaining crit­i­cal of the deduc­tive side of
his method. At the same time, he praised him for being the first econ­o­
mist who applied the induc­tive method in his polit­i­cal econ­omy.
Furthermore, Cliffe Leslie was highly influ­enced by Mill. Mill believed
that Leslie was an emi­nent applied polit­i­cal econ­o­mist, and he wrote to
him fre­quently. Late in his life, Mill included his review essay on Leslie’s
Land Systems in his vol­u me of selected essays, Dissertations and
Discussions. As just men­tioned, in Mill’s inter­est­ing cor­re­spon­dence,
Leslie’s name appears many times, indi­cat­ing his respect for Leslie’s
work. Mill’s first let­ter to Leslie is dated August 18, 1860. It is the first
expres­sion of Mill’s inter­est in Leslie’s draft ver­sion of his 1860 essay,
“The Future of Europe Foretold in History,” published in Macmillan’s

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
Manioudis / Cliffe Leslie’s Critique of Ricardianism 143

Magazine.3 In this, Mill ([1860] 1972: 702–3) expressed his agree­ment


with Leslie’s attack on Buckle’s gen­er­al­iza­tions.4
The sec­ond let­ter from Mill to Leslie appeared in Novem­ber 1861 and
contained a sym­pa­thetic review of Leslie’s views on sav­ing (Mill [1861]
1972a). On Decem­ber 20, 1861, Mill ([1861] 1972b) crit­i­cized Leslie’s

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


draft of his “Income-Tax Reform” and expressed his var­i­ance “on sev­eral
mat­ters of detail & some of prin­ci­ple” (756). In Novem­ber 1863 Mill
wrote to Leslie and praised the draft ver­sion of his cel­e­brated “The
Distribution and Value of the Precious Metals in the Sixteenth and
Nineteenth Century,” which was published in Macmillan’s Magazine in
August 1864. Mill ([1863] 1972: 898) encour­aged Leslie to con­tinue the
elab­o­ra­tion of the pro­ject, while at the same time mak­ing a set of revi­sions
“here and there.” Furthermore, in one of his let­ters to Thomas Hughes
(1822–96), the law­yer and lib­eral pol­i­ti­cian, Mill ([1866] 1972: 1222)
noted that Leslie “is an excel­lent pop­u­lar expos­i­tor of sci­en­tific thought”
and “one of our best polit­i­cal econ­o­mists.” In one of his let­ters to John
Elliott Cairnes (1823–75), on July 23, 1867, Mill ([1867] 1972) recom­
mended Cliffe Leslie for a one-year replace­ment for Cairnes in the chair
of polit­i­cal econ­omy at University College. Mill pointed out that “Leslie
is, next to you, by far the fit­test per­son I know to fill the place, among
those who would take it” (1294). In his cor­re­spon­dence with Edwin
Chadwick (1800–1890), the cel­e­brated social reformer, Mill ([1868] 1972:
1350) noted that Leslie’s “Military Systems of Europe” “is very impor­
tant, and ought to be made widely known if pos­si­ble.” This essay was
published in the North Brit­ish Review and intro­duced Leslie to English
aca­de­mia.
The next let­ter from Mill to Leslie is dated Feb­r u­ary 8, 1869.5 Mill
([1869] 1972a) expressed his plea­sure for Cliffe Leslie’s twin 1869 essays:
“Changes in Prices” (Jan­u­ary 1869), published in the Economist; and “A
Visit to La Creuse, 1868” (Feb­ru­ary 1869). Mill thought highly of Leslie’s

3. Cliffe Leslie sent his essay man­u­script to Mill in August; Mill revised the text and sent
cor­rec­tions to Cliffe Leslie, who published it the fol­low­ing month. Collison Black (2002: 21)
noted that this essay “first caused J.S. Mill to make con­tact with Leslie.” However, it seems evi­
dent that Cliffe Leslie sought Mill’s views upon his essay and had com­mu­ni­cated it to him.
Lipkes (1999: 72), in the same direc­tion, points out that “Mill gen­er­ously commented at some
length on the draft or proof, and Leslie incor­po­rated some sug­ges­tions.”
4. Henry Thomas Buckle (1821–62) was a his­to­rian and friend of John Stu­art Mill.
5. Lipkes (1999: 72) rightly observes that although the first exchange of let­ters between Mill
and Leslie “took place not long after Mill had met Cairnes and Fawcett, the friend­ship was
slower to ripen.”

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
144 History of Political Economy 56:1 (2024)

induc­tive sur­veys and asked him to con­tinue his vis­its to con­ti­nen­tal


Europe. He believed that Leslie’s sur­veys, like that of La Creuse, con­trib­
uted to the sci­ence of polit­i­cal econ­omy and were “use­ful arti­cles of
travel” (Mill [1869] 1972b: 1600). Mill, once again, expressed his plea­sure
in Leslie’s induc­tive stud­ies, as in one of his let­ters to him, on Octo­ber 5,

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


1869, he observed, “You seem to have had a long & var­ied tour & I look
for­ward with much plea­sure to read­ing your obser­va­tions on the dis­tricts
you vis­ited, more espe­cially as I have but lit­tle per­sonal acquain­tance with
most of them” (Mill [1869] 1972c: 1642). In June 1870 Mill com­posed a
pos­i­tive review of Leslie’s Land Systems, which was published in the
Fortnightly Review. Mill ([1871] 1972) wrote again to Leslie on Decem­ber
1, 1871, as a reply to his draft of “Financial Reform.” Mill’s let­ters to
Cliffe Leslie and his cor­re­spon­dence with Cairnes and oth­ers illus­trate his
great will­ing­ness to sup­port Leslie’s can­di­dacy for a vari­ety of pro­fes­sor­
ships. Moreover, his cor­re­spon­dence reveals that he regarded Leslie as
one of the well-rounded econ­o­mists of the late nineteenth cen­tury.
Leslie ([1869] 1888: 128) also thought highly of Mill and believed that
every­thing Mill said “was saga­cious and instruc­tive.” Leslie ([1876] 1888:
168) thought that Mill was the “illus­tri­ous suc­ces­sor” of Smith, being a
great English phi­los­o­pher ([1868] 1870: 366) and “the great leader of eco­
nomic sci­ence” ([1873] 1888a: 162). Leslie ([1876] 1888: 168) noted that
Mill did not employ “a sys­tem­atic appli­ca­tion of his­tor­i­cal and induc­tive
inves­ti­ga­tion” but adopted the major­ity of his rad­i­cal tenets regard­ing the
rel­a­tiv­ity of eco­nomic doc­trines, eco­nomic meth­od­ol­ogy, eco­nomic pol­
icy, and the role of his­tory. Leslie crit­i­cized Mill’s def­i­ni­tion of polit­i­cal
econ­omy but shared his views on the impor­tance of dis­tri­bu­tion. For
instance, Leslie, among oth­ers, praised Mill in correcting Ricardo by not­
ing that “the rate of profit depends, not on the wages, but on the cost of
labour” ([1879] 1888b: 234). In addi­tion, Leslie commended Mill’s mature
con­sid­er­ation in abandoning the wage-fund doc­trine and adopted Mill’s
view that dis­tri­bu­tion is a socially/his­tor­i­cally deter­mined pro­cess (Leslie
[1876] 1888).6 He noted that Mill had illus­trated the fact that “human
insti­tu­tions, laws of prop­erty and suc­ces­sion, are nec­es­sary chief agen­
cies” in deter­min­ing the dis­tri­bu­tion of pro­duced wealth (Leslie [1870]

6. For Leslie ([1876] 1888: 174), “One has but to think of the dif­fer­ent par­ti­tion of land in
England and France, of the dif­fer­ent par­ti­tion of real and per­sonal prop­erty in England and
France, of the dif­fer­ent par­ti­tion of real and per­sonal prop­erty in England, of the dif­fer­ent par­
ti­tion of both between the two sexes, of the influ­ence of the State, the Church, the Family, of
mar­riage and suc­ces­sion.”

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
Manioudis / Cliffe Leslie’s Critique of Ricardianism 145

1888: 36). He adopted Mill’s firm belief that dem­o­cratic insti­tu­tions are
asso­ci­ated with a more just dis­tri­bu­tion of wealth. For Leslie ([1869] 1888:
131–32), “If dem­o­cratic insti­tu­tions be com­pared with monar­chic or aris­
to­cratic, abun­dant proof will, it is true, be found of the supe­rior ten­dency
of the first to dif­fuse mate­r ial pros­per­ity through­out the mass of the

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


peo­ple.”
Cliffe Leslie’s col­lected vol­ume of essays on land sys­tems was an ode
to small pro­pri­e­tor­ships, which were regarded by him as the appro­pri­ate
insti­tu­tion “for the evils of the wretched state of Ireland” ([1870] 1888:
30). Leslie’s polit­i­cal econ­omy of small pro­pri­e­tor­ships seems to be influ­
enced by Mill’s twin scripta: The Principles of Political Economy (1848)
and England and Ireland (1868). Leslie ([1870] 1888: 21) con­sid­ered from
many angles the Millian the­sis of the rel­a­tiv­ity of eco­nomic doc­trines,
which moved him away from Ricardian polit­i­cal econ­omy: “Political
econ­omy is not a body of nat­u­ral laws in the true sense, or of uni­ver­sal
and immu­ta­ble truths, but an assem­blage of spec­u­la­tions and doc­trines
which are the result of a par­tic­u­lar his­tory, coloured even by the his­tory
and char­ac­ter of its chief writ­ers.” He believed that Mill pos­sessed a bril­
liant his­tor­i­cal mind and that his thought was influ­enced by John Austin,
Jeremy Bentham, and James Mill (Leslie [1875] 1888: 56). In addi­tion, he
praised Mill’s open­ness to new ideas by observ­ing that “his­tory affords
scarcely another exam­ple of a phi­los­o­pher so ready to review his posi­
tions, to aban­don them if unten­a­ble, and to take les­sons from his own dis­
ci­ples” (Leslie [1875] 1888: 54).
To con­clude, Cliffe Leslie adopted Mill’s meth­od­o­log­i­cal dis­tinc­tion
between the “laws of pro­duc­tion” and those “of dis­tri­bu­tion” and incor­po­
rated it into his anal­y­sis (Vallier 2010: 116). Generally, Mill’s influ­ence is
more appar­ent in the first period of his author­ship, which is char­ac­ter­ized
by his induc­tive sur­veys, his applied polit­i­cal econ­omy, and his essays on
the Irish land ques­tion. In his early essays, which received Mill’s praise,
Leslie elab­o­rated on the epis­te­mo­log­i­cal the­sis of the rel­a­tiv­ity of eco­
nomic doc­trines, illus­trated the meth­od­o­log­i­cal and the­o­ret­i­cal impor­
tance of dis­tri­bu­tion, and expressed his thoughts on the Irish land ques­tion.
This mate­rial turned out to be his means for pre­par­ing his cri­tique of
Ricardian polit­i­cal econ­omy. Although Mill influ­enced Leslie in impor­
tant ways, Leslie’s work was in no way a sim­ple by-prod­uct of Mill’s eco­
nomic thought. As is well known, Mill attempted to rel­a­tiv­ize Ricardian
prin­ci­ples. However, Cliffe Leslie’s polit­i­cal econ­omy was far more rad­i­
cal (Moore 1999).

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
146 History of Political Economy 56:1 (2024)

3. Rereading Cliffe Leslie’s Land Systems


The first period of Cliffe Leslie’s eco­nomic thought is marked by his volu­
minous Land Systems, published in 1870 (Ingram 1882). Strangely
enough, although Land Systems attracted Mill’s atten­tion and has to be
con­sid­ered as the mag­num opus of Leslie’s polit­i­cal econ­omy, it is under­

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


estimated in the his­tory of eco­nomic thought. The sec­ond part of the
book, in which Leslie discusses his vis­its to and impres­sions of Euro­pean
countries such as Germany, France, and Belgium, is almost mar­ginal
among his­to­ri­ans of eco­nomic thought. However, the essays in the sec­ond
part are far more descrip­tive than those in the first part, which are devoted
to the land sys­tems of Ireland and England (Lipkes 1999: 133). This sec­
tion pro­poses a rereading of Leslie’s Land Systems while attempting to
show how this work pre­pared the ground for the emer­gence of Brit­ish
his­tor­i­cism.
Cliffe Leslie followed Maine’s pro­posal that polit­i­cal econ­omy should
“begin with a com­par­a­tive and his­tor­i­cal study of land sys­tems” (Koot
1987: 47). Through his fre­quent trips in the 1860s he sketched out a set of
induc­tive and his­tor­i­cal sur­veys that are inter­est­ing even to the mod­ern
social sci­en­tist. Leslie’s his­tor­i­cally and insti­tu­tion­ally informed approach
con­trib­uted to the pen­ning of a con­sid­er­able bulk of papers that are full of
his­tor­i­cal inter­est. His invi­ta­tion to polit­i­cal econ­o­mists to con­duct empir­
i­cal sur­veys and describe them at length recalls Smith’s syn­thetic method
as delin­eated in his History of Astronomy. In Leslie’s ([1867] 1870: 296)
verba, “They ought . . . ​to regard such inquires as most use­ful, because
they add the book of nature to their stud­ies; for every branch of human
sci­ence, to what­ever the stat­ure it has grown, gath­ers, Antaeus-like, fresh
vig­our from fall­ing back on earth, from which Newton him­self learned
the move­ments of the heav­ens.”
Leslie believed that geo­graph­i­cal disparities test the validity of the­o­ret­
i­cal prin­ci­ples, improve the cor­pus of existing the­ory, and con­trib­ute to
the for­ma­tion of new prin­ci­ples through the assis­tance of the induc­tive-
his­tor­i­cal and com­par­a­tive method. For him, empir­i­cal facts, instead of
being irrel­e­vant to the polit­i­cal econ­o­m ist, “are the phe­nom­ena from
which he must infer his gen­eral prin­ci­ples, and by which he ought con­
stantly to ver­ify his deduc­tions” (Leslie [1868] 1870: 358). His empir­i­cal
sur­veys con­sti­tute an inte­gral part of his polit­i­cal econ­omy and attest to
the plu­ral­is­tic nature of his eco­nomic meth­od­ol­ogy. His empir­i­cal stud­ies
exhibit the close con­junc­tion of polit­i­cal econ­omy, eco­nomic his­tory,

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
Manioudis / Cliffe Leslie’s Critique of Ricardianism 147

eco­nomic geog­ra­phy, polit­i­cal sci­ence, and anthro­pol­ogy and are quite


dif­fer­ent from the dom­i­nant Ricardian mode of eco­nomic think­ing. In his
empir­i­cal sur­veys, Leslie was assisted by key inform­ers, while his excel­
lent acquain­tance with English and Irish sta­tis­tics helped him to employ
his com­par­a­tive method.

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


Initially, Cliffe Leslie’s his­tor­i­cal and insti­tu­tion­ally focused anal­y­sis of
Westphalia was presented in two papers published in 1869 and 1870. He
vis­ited the region twice and recorded the dif­fer­ences. These essays reflect
de Lavergne’s and de Laveleye’s influ­ence, since Leslie illus­trated the
impor­tance of phys­i­cal con­di­tions, geo­log­i­cal par­tic­u­lar­i­ties, and cli­mate
diver­si­f i­ca­t ions in the deter­m i­na­t ion of eco­nomic phe­nom­ena. For
instance, he pointed out that dif­fer­ent nat­u­ral advan­tages of dif­fer­ent
local­i­ties pro­duce con­sid­er­able inequalities in prof­its, wages, and rents.
This view moved Leslie’s (induc­tive) polit­i­cal econ­omy closer to Mill’s
(Mill [1848] 1965: bk. 2, chaps. 6–7).7 This move­ment made him note that
it is impos­si­ble to under­stand inequalities through Ricardian polit­i­cal
econ­omy, as it had “taken away the key of knowl­edge—the inves­ti­ga­tion
of facts—which Adam Smith and Mr. Mill had put into our hands” (Leslie
[1873] 1888b: 363).
Cliffe Leslie believed that local dif­fer­en­ti­a­tions, even within the same
prov­ince, are of prime impor­tance in deter­min­ing eco­nomic, social, polit­
i­cal, and even cul­tural phe­nom­ena. This view is meth­od­o­log­i­cally crys­tal­
lized in his com­par­a­tive-his­tor­i­cal method, in the con­text of which he
decided to divide spe­cific regions—such as Auvergne or Westphalia—
into smaller par­ti­tions and draw care­ful gen­er­al­iza­tion from them. Such a
meth­od­o­log­i­cal stance helped him to per­ceive dif­fer­en­ti­a­tions in seem­
ingly iden­ti­cal prov­inces. Leslie ([1869] 1870b: 230) noted that in
Westphalia, as in Auvergne (see sec. 4), “the old world and the new, the
world of immo­bil­ity and cus­tom, and the world of change and prog­ress,
[are] seen in closer prox­im­ity and con­trast.” For him, Westphalia is con­
nected with the rapid march of Prussian indus­try (230). In what can be
called an early ver­sion of eco­nomic geog­ra­phy and eco­nomic his­tory, he
informs us that the Ruhr Basin (which occupies the mid­dle region of
Westphalia) is the min­ing and manufactur­ing cen­ter of the prov­ince. The
moun­tain­ous regions of Sauerland and Siegerland are ves­tiges of an
ancient mode of rural life (230–31). Leslie observed and recorded in min­
ute detail the ancient cul­ti­vat­ing meth­ods of the iso­lated dis­trict of south

7. Thanks to an anon­y­mous reviewer for bring­ing this to my atten­tion.

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
148 History of Political Economy 56:1 (2024)

Westphalia, where the “plough as old as the time of Arminius is a sign of


the tenac­ity with which ancient cus­tom is still clung” (237). Based on his
induc­tive anal­y­sis he noted that the main­te­nance of cus­tom­ary farm­ing
tech­niques is the direct con­se­quence of the phys­i­cal and cli­matic envi­ron­
ment of this region. According to his broad-brush geol­ogy/eco­nomic

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


geog­ra­phy, in Westphalia moun­tains “have played a great part in shap­ing
the his­tory of man­kind; they have been staunch guard­ians of cus­toms, and
obsta­cles to new ideas and arts” (237). For him, the for­ma­tion of peas­ant
pro­pri­e­tor­ships, together with the con­struc­tion of rail­ways, is an effi­cient
way to trans­mit those ideas. Following Mill’s crit­i­cism of the “law of pri­
mo­gen­i­ture,” Leslie con­cluded that in south Westphalia, the con­ces­sion of
peas­ant lands to the eldest son had been a prima causa of con­stant pau­
per­ism in towns.
Cliffe Leslie vis­ited the indus­trial cen­ter of Westphalia, the Ruhr Basin,
and observed that min­ing and manufactur­ing enter­prises were car­ried out
on a grand scale. He noted that the coal of the Ruhr Basin had “since
raised the prov­ince to the first rank of indus­trial Europe” (Leslie [1869]
1870b: 240). Leslie added that the Krupp firm has to be regarded as the
most rep­re­sen­ta­tive man­u­fac­turer of the Ruhr Basin since its build­ings
form a con­sid­er­able town and “the steel-works alone give employ­ment to
upwards of 8.000 men, who with fam­i­lies of those who are mar­ried, make
a pop­u­la­tion of 25.000 maintained by this sin­gle estab­lish­ment” (242).8
Leslie, like Smith and Mill, stressed the role of power in the deter­mi­na­
tion of eco­nomic affairs. He illus­trated the impor­tance of Krupp in the
econ­omy of the Ruhr Basin. He noted that Alfred Krupp (1812–87),
through the exer­tion of his power, deter­mined polit­i­cal deci­sions and the
for­ma­tion of eco­nomic insti­tu­tions. Leslie employed Krupp’s exam­ple to
illus­trate the fact that English polit­i­cal econ­o­mists had ignored the role of
power in deter­min­ing the wealth of man­kind (243). As early as the late
1860s, Leslie had observed the rapid eco­nomic devel­op­ment of Germany.
He cited sta­tis­ti­cal data from the Ruhr Basin’s coal pro­duc­tion to illus­trate
his view that the Ruhr Basin pro­duced in 1868 “nearly half as much coal
as the great north­ern coal-field of England” (244). Leslie attrib­uted the
sud­den eco­nomic growth of the Ruhr Basin to the intro­duc­tion of rail­ways

8. Cliffe Leslie offered fac­tual data to sup­port his views. He pointed out that in 1867 the
steel­works included “412 melt­ing-fur­naces, 195 steam-engines, some of them of a thou­sand
horse-power, 49 steam ham­mers, 110 smiths’ forges, 675 dif­fer­ent machines; and all­these num­
bers now are exceeded” (242).

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
Manioudis / Cliffe Leslie’s Critique of Ricardianism 149

and the low charge for the car­riage of coal. For him, the “rail­ways and
coal-mines ren­d er each other recip­ro­cal ser­v ice; the car­riage of
Westphalian coal is now one of the most impor­tant branches of traf­fic on
sev­eral of the chief Prussian lines, and the low rates at which it is car­ried
enable it to find a dis­tant mar­ket” (245).

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


In con­trast to David Ricardo and J. R. McCulloch (1789–1864), Cliffe
Leslie expressed his sym­pa­thy for trade unions. He noted that in the Ruhr
Basin there are “admi­ra­ble insti­tu­tions and reg­u­la­tions for the ben­e­fit of
the workmen” due to trade union­ism (Leslie [1869] 1870b: 248). He
pointed out that the con­cord between cap­i­tal­ists and work­ers is the direct
con­se­quence of trade unions. He noted fur­ther that in the Ruhr Basin
small pro­pri­e­tor­ships are extended and, as a con­se­quence, the wealth of
the peas­antry had “enor­mously increased in the last twenty years, and the
so-called bauer is some­times a man worth above 15.000l.” (251), while
“steam threshing-machines are com­mon, lent or hired from one farm to
another” (252).
On his sec­ond visit to Westphalia (1869), Cliffe Leslie observed the
eco­nomic prog­ress of the south­ern region due to the dif­fu­sion of rail­ways.
However, he also detected scanty har­vests in south Westphalia and
expressed his belief that small pro­pri­e­tor­ships could offer a con­sid­er­able
rev­e­nue to the peas­ant, argu­ing that it “would be bet­ter for the man to give
up his trade than his land” (Leslie 1870d: 258). In the Rhine, where small
pro­pri­e­tor­ships were lim­ited, chil­dren in the vil­lages of south Westphalia
“are all­com­fort­ably clothed, and are never seen bare-footed, as both chil­
dren and adults are in the plain of the Rhine, where so many fam­i­lies are
with­out a bauer-gut [pro­pri­e­tor­ship]” (258).9 Leslie cited his­tor­i­cal data to
stress the dif­fer­ences in wages between dif­fer­ent regions of south
Westphalia and pointed out that they are “gen­er­ally lower than in the Ruhr
Basin” (258). Furthermore, he pointed out that wage rates even in the
same region, as south Westphalia, exhibited con­sid­er­able inequalities.
Leslie, once again, expressed his direct oppo­si­tion to the “iron law of
wages” and con­cluded that “what­ever con­clu­sions Ricardo’s hypoth­e­ses
may lead to, the real eco­nomic con­di­tions of pro­duc­tion and dis­tri­bu­tion

9. Cliffe Leslie noted that “in these vil­lages . . . ​it should be remem­bered that many of the
peo­ple are them­selves the chil­dren of serfs—of sclaven, as the author has heard them say; a
term which, though not the cor­rect one, for their legal sta­tus was not that of slav­ery, shows how
abject their con­di­tion really was, and from what pros­tra­tion they have risen under their land
sys­tem to inde­pen­dence and com­fort, in a period dur­ing which the peas­antry of a great part of
England have socially and eco­nom­i­cally sunk” (258).

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
150 History of Political Economy 56:1 (2024)

have nowhere equalised wages, prof­its, or rent” (259). His descrip­tions of


south Westphalia recall Mill’s sta­tion­ary state, in which eco­nomic activ­ity
is bounded by cus­tom­ary struc­tures and social bonds. However, in Leslie’s
account, the pro­mo­tion of small pro­pri­e­tor­ships secures a bal­anced agri­
cul­tural devel­op­ment that would pre­serve the “nat­u ­ral prog­ress of

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


opu­lence.”
In 1868 Cliffe Leslie vis­ited La Creuse, a region of cen­tral France, and
sketched out its econ­omy and soci­ety. His anal­y­sis, like that of
Westphalia, reveals his eco­nomic thought and meth­od­ol­ogy. Leslie
([1869] 1870a: 266) noted that La Creuse contained des­ert hills, ham­lets,
and a vanishing peas­antry. He informs us that the region had not changed
since the Middle Ages, as it was with­out “a rail­way until the other day,
ill-pro­vided with roads, and its nar­row val­leys blocked up as it were in
culs-de-sac by the pecu­liar for­ma­tion of its moun­tains and hills” (266).
Following Adam Smith, Leslie pointed out that the divi­sion of labor,
owing to small mar­kets, is under­de­vel­oped in La Creuse: “One may see,
for exam­ple, from the car­riage a woman tending cat­tle or sheep, knit­ting
at the same time a stock­ing or a waist­coat, while under her arm is the
sig­nal for the train—at once shep­herd­ess, man­u­fac­turer, and rail­way
offi­cial” (267).
Cliffe Leslie pointed out that prop­erty rights in land are mostly com­
mu­nal and observed that the “towns” “are all­vil­lages, the ‘vil­lages’ ham­
lets, often no more than four or five cot­tages” (Leslie [1869] 1870a: 268).
What is more, in Le Creuse there is no retail trade, “even of the common­
est arti­cles of cloth­ing,” and the pop­u­la­tion is steadily diminishing (274).10
Leslie, once again, employed his empir­i­cal sur­veys to dem­on­strate the
futil­ity of Ricardian eco­nom­ics. He crit­i­cized the clas­si­cal view that the
depop­u­la­tion of La Creuse could be attrib­uted to the sim­plis­tic for­mula of
the demand for and the sup­ply of labor. He noted that “on each side of La
Creuse lie flourishing indus­trial cit­ies—on its east­ern bor­der Montluçon,
the entrepôt of a great coal basin; on its west­ern bor­der Limoges, ‘the pot­
ter­ies’ of France; yet no emi­gra­tion takes place to either, nor does the one
sol­i­tary seat of man­u­fac­ture in La Creuse itself, Aubus­son, obtain any
increase of pop­u­la­tion from the coun­try around it” (276).

10. Cliffe Leslie cited fac­tual evi­dence to illus­trate the depop­u­la­tion of La Creuse. He noted
that in 1865 the pop­u­la­tion was esti­mated at 279,000 and “in 1866, the total had decreased to
274.000; it is now [i.e., 1869] fur­ther reduced, and a dou­bled con­scrip­tion threat­ens to con­sum­
mate the depop­u­la­tion of the depart­ment” (274).

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
Manioudis / Cliffe Leslie’s Critique of Ricardianism 151

Leslie con­cluded his inter­est­ing essay by not­ing that the depop­u­la­tion


of the French coun­try­side, and the intense urban­i­za­tion of great towns, is
the direct con­se­quence of admin­is­tra­tive pol­i­cies from the impe­rial gov­
ern­ment. For Leslie (1870c: 283), the “land sys­tem of France can­not be
esti­mated fairly with­out ref­er­ence to the polit­i­cal con­di­tions under which

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


it has been tried.” He believed that the French land sys­tem con­trib­uted to
the tran­si­tion from the sim­ple peas­ant of La Creuse to the builder of pal­
aces in Paris.
Lastly, Cliffe Leslie pro­vided an empir­i­cal sur­vey of the peas­antry and
the farm sys­tem of Belgium through two for­ma­tive essays published in
Frazer’s Magazine.11 He pointed out that Bel­gian agri­cul­ture is an inter­
est­ing study for pol­i­ti­cians and polit­i­cal econ­o­mists, as it com­bines “the
respec­tive effects of large estates and large farms on the one hand, and
peas­ant prop­er­ties and la petite cul­ture upon the other” (Leslie [1867]
1870: 294). The main pur­pose of his twin vis­its to Belgium was, through
his com­par­a­tive method, to illus­trate the sim­i­lar­i­ties between Belgium
and Ireland and to pro­pose the neces­sity of adopting small pro­pri­e­tor­
ships in Irish land. This atti­tude moves Leslie closer to think­ers such as
Henri de Saint-Simon (1760–1825) and Jean Charles Léonard de
Sismondi (1773–1842) and Mill (Mill [1848] 1965; Collison Black 2002;
Manioudis 2020).
Based on his eco­nomic geog­ra­phy and com­par­a­tive/his­tor­i­cal method,
Leslie ([1867] 1870: 297) observed that Belgium should not be stud­ied as
a uni­form whole, as it was “remark­able for broad con­trasts.” He employed
a kind of etho­log­i­cal anal­y­sis, not­ing that these con­trasts are exem­pli­fied
by the fact that two dif­fer­ent ethnolinguistic groups in Belgium speak dif­
fer­ent lan­guages:12 “one, occu­py­ing the north­ern half, famous now for its
hus­bandry alone, though once as famous for pre-emi­nence in man­u­fac­
tures; the other, back­ward for the most part, by com­par­i­son in agri­cul­ture,
but hold­ing a fore­most posi­tion in man­u­fac­tures which is of mod­ern date”
(297). For Leslie, the most strik­ing fea­ture of Bel­gian agri­cul­ture is that
the trav­eler “sees the most per­fect and most pro­duc­tive cul­ti­va­tion where
the soil is most ster­ile by nature, and where there is no min­eral wealth
what­ever to cre­ate for the farmer great indus­trial mar­kets; while, on the

11. Mill ([1870] 1875: 126) noted that although Cliffe Leslie’s “essays on the Ruhr Basin and
on La Creuse are most inter­est­ing read­ing,” his essays on Belgium are “the most valu­able for
the gen­eral pur­pose of the book.”
12. I would like to thank Kevin Hoover for bring­ing this to my atten­tion.

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
152 History of Political Economy 56:1 (2024)

con­trary, agri­cul­ture is found back­ward, not in rude regions alone . . . ​but


within easy reach of rich and busy mines and a flourishing man­u­fac­ture
indus­try” (298).
Following de Laveleye, Cliffe Leslie pointed out that there are four
farm­ing tech­niques in Belgium. In the first of them, half of the ara­ble land

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


was always sub­ject to fal­low; in the sec­ond, “the fal­low comes only every
third year”; in the third, there is the cycli­cal rota­tion of crops; and in the
fourth, which is the typ­i­cal tech­nique in Flanders, “the ground not only is
never let rest, but gives two crops in the year” (Leslie [1867] 1870: 298).
Through a com­par­a­tive anal­y­sis of these tech­niques, he offered some
broad strokes toward an agri­cul­tural, eco­nomic, and social his­tory of
Belgium. He noted that the first tech­nique sur­vives in the Bel­gian prov­
ince of Luxemburg and is char­ac­ter­ized as an ancient prac­tice exem­pli­fied
by “the pas­ture of cat­tle in the rud­est fash­ion” (299). Leslie pointed out
that, according to the Smithian stages the­ory, this part of the Bel­gian
prov­ince has remained in the hunt­ing and fish­ing stage, “for not only do
fish and fly­ing game abound, but the for­ests are alive with deer and boar,
and the wolf still holds his own” (299). Leslie cited de Laveleye’s “inim­i­
ta­ble pic­tures” of the Ardenne region of Belgium,13 and he noted that the
emi­nent agri­cul­t ur­ist stressed “their hos­pi­t al­ity to strang­ers” (301).
Following Leslie’s etho­log­i­cal approach, we under­stand that this hos­pi­tal­
ity is a sign of the “hunt­ing and fish­ing” stage of eco­nomic devel­op­ment,
as it “is a prim­i­tive vir­tue, some­times accom­pa­nied by that prim­i­tive
devel­op­ment of the intel­lect” (301). Leslie did not pro­vide details for the
sec­ond and the third tech­nique, but he exten­sively described the insti­tu­
tion of small pro­pri­e­tor­ships.
Once again, Cliffe Leslie reminds us of Mill by observ­ing that the
inten­sive cul­ti­va­tion of the soil, which is tightly connected with small pro­
pri­e­tor­ships, implies increased farm­ing pro­duc­tiv­ity. He noted that even
Smith, in his cel­e­brated Wealth of Nations (1776), had pointed out the
pros­per­ity of Flem­ish hus­bandry and reg­is­tered its won­der­ful prod­ucts.
Leslie believed that this pros­per­ity was the direct con­se­quence of small,
intensely cul­ti­vated farms, which had accel­er­ated “the nat­u­ral prog­ress of
opu­lence” and led to for­eign trade and manufactur­ing at home (Leslie
[1867] 1870: 319). He pointed out that the emer­gence of small pro­pri­e­tor­
ships in Flanders was not the result of the devel­op­ment of man­u­fac­tures

13. Leslie spelled Ardenne with no s on the end.

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
Manioudis / Cliffe Leslie’s Critique of Ricardianism 153

and com­merce, but was a spe­cific fea­ture of the Flem­ish econ­omy.14


According to his descrip­tions, “the great major­ity of the non-agri­cul­tural
pop­u­la­tion of Flanders is engaged in oper­a­tions aris­ing directly out of
agri­cul­ture” (318–19). In addi­tion, Leslie cited de Laveleye’s lively pic­
tures to illus­trate the fact that the small pro­pri­e­tor­ship (or la petite cul­

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


ture) is not com­pat­i­ble with its soil and cli­mate—which in real­ity are not
appro­pri­ate for petty till­age—but is “an evi­dent proof that the soil owes
almost all­its value to cul­ture” (305). He cited data to illus­trate his views
and noted that 12l. are given by a hect­are in its nat­u­ral state while 120l.
were given by la petite cul­ture (305). Leslie, as in the major­ity of his
induc­tive sur­veys, presented the advan­tages of the small pro­pri­e­tor­ship in
direct com­par­i­son to la grande cul­ture. He cited de Laveleye’s Essai sur
l’ economie rurale de la Belgique (1863) and noted that the Flem­ish land
sys­tem had four dis­tinct fea­tures: “first, the great vari­ety of crops; sec­
ondly, the exten­sive prac­tice of inter­me­di­ate crop­ping; thirdly, the abun­
dant use of the most active manures; and lastly the extreme minute­ness of
the farms” (306).
Cliffe Leslie regarded the minute­ness of farms as the nec­es­sary con­di­
tion for earning the ben­e­fits of the Flem­ish land sys­tem. He observed that
“min­ute care, min­ute econ­omy, are the nat­u­ral con­se­quences: noth­ing is
lost; the most are made of the least, and multum in parvo [much in lit­tle]
is the result” (Leslie [1867] 1870: 307). For him, la petite cul­ture allows
the farmer to cul­ti­vate with­out fal­low, and as a result, con­trary to the
ancient tech­nique, “his ground, being never left to rest, becomes as active
as him­self” (307). In his etho­log­i­cal anal­y­sis the small pro­pri­e­tor­ship is
the chief rea­son for the fact that the cul­ti­va­tor loves his ground and likes
his efforts (309). This “love” ema­nated from the fact that “half the small
farm­ers of Flanders own at least a part of the land they cul­ti­vate” (309).
Leslie believed that the small pro­pri­e­tor in Flanders is “in real­ity not
worse fed than many of his fel­lows in England, and he is always well
housed” (310). He has learned, “in the neat cot­tages surrounding him
from his child­hood, those hab­its of clean­li­ness, care, and econ­omy which
make half the suc­cess of la petite cul­ture, and which he will carry with
him into la grande cul­ture, if he suc­ceeds in enlarg­ing his farm” (311).
Furthermore, the Flem­ish peas­ant, due to the micro­man­age­ment of his

14. Cliffe Leslie cited de Laveleye’s obser­va­tions, according to which “each vil­lage being,
more­over, the dwell­ing-place of a cer­tain num­ber of small pro­pri­e­tors, con­sti­tutes a cen­tre of
local activ­ity inde­pen­dent of the chief towns of the prov­ince” (316).

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
154 History of Political Economy 56:1 (2024)

farm, devel­oped abil­i­ties that dif­fer­en­ti­ated him from the typ­i­cal land­less
farm-laborer. Leslie con­cluded that the Flem­ish peas­ant was the secur­est,
fre­est, and boldest of his time and cited fac­tual data to illus­trate his social
and eco­nomic posi­tion, which, in his mind, was much bet­ter than the
English one. He pointed out that in 1856 “there were 100 houses to every

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


102 fam­i­lies in East Flanders, and every 101 fam­i­lies in the west­ern prov­
inces. Even the pau­per thinks exis­tence insup­port­able with­out a sep­a­rate
cot­tage” (329). Leslie observed that even in the late 1840s, when pau­per­
ism was at its height in East Flanders, the “peas­ant pro­pri­e­tor of a farm of
even five acres is never in indi­gence” (329).
On his sec­ond visit to Belgium, in 1870, Leslie (1870a: 343) observed
that the small pro­pri­e­tor­ship con­tin­ued to be the dom­i­nant mode of farm­
ing.15 He noted that the burst of com­mer­cial activ­ity, and the emer­gence of
crowded mar­kets, was an addi­tional impe­tus for the exten­sion of small-
scale farm­ing. For him, “the prog­ress of man­u­fac­tures and trade tend nat­
u­rally, not to the accu­mu­la­tion of land, but its dif­fu­sion” (350). He
observed that “the change in com­par­a­tive prices, con­se­quent on com­mer­
cial prog­ress, . . . ​is a rev­o­lu­tion in favour of small farm­ing every­where”
(344), while the sci­en­tific prog­ress of agri­cul­tural chem­is­try is an addi­
tional stim­u­lus to the advance­ment of small pro­pri­e­tor­ships and con­trib­
utes to the nonexhaustion of fer­tile soil (346). For instance, he cited the
offi­cial report of the Bel­gian Ministry of Agriculture and pointed out that
new manures have come into com­mon use among farm­ers, “includ­ing, in
addi­tion to guano, ani­mal black, super­phos­phate of lime, pulverised bones
&c” (346), while not­ing that the “steam threshing-machine again has
made great way even in the last four years” (346).
The mutual fea­ture of Cliffe Leslie’s twin essays on the Bel­gian land
sys­tem is that in Belgium, despite the dis­ad­van­tages of soil and cli­mate,
the small pro­pri­e­tor­ship is per ­pet­u­ally advanc­ing.16 Moreover, Leslie,
through his sec­ond visit to Belgium, once more illus­trated the fal­sity of
the wage-fund doc­trine, or “the the­ory of wages propounded by Ricardo
and M’Culloch” (Leslie 1870a: 354). He cited fac­tual data in sup­port of
this fal­sity. For instance, he observed that the price of agri­cul­tural labor in

15. Cliffe Leslie cited sta­tis­ti­cal data from the “Enquête agricole” and noted that “in East
Flanders, of 88,300 cul­ti­va­tors of less than three hect­a res (less than seven acres and a half)
32,201 are pro­pri­e­tors, 37,283 are ten­ants under lease. Of cul­ti­va­tors of above three hect­ares,
12,346 are pro­pri­e­tors, against 11,481 ten­ants” (343).
16. Leslie (1870a: 348) observed that the “soil of Flanders, more­over, is so poor by nature,
that even ‘sec­ond’ or inter­me­di­ate crops . . . ​require spe­cial manure.”

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
Manioudis / Cliffe Leslie’s Critique of Ricardianism 155

the Wal­loon prov­ince, where grand estates are the most fre­quent form of
landed prop­erty, is dou­ble that in Flanders. As in Westphalia, Leslie
employed his eco­nomic geog­ra­phy by not­ing that wage dif­fer­ences are the
direct con­se­quence of a “dif­fer­ence in local geo­log­i­cal con­di­tions” (354).
Later, Leslie, noted that the wage-fund doc­trine was condemned by a

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


vari­ety of con­ti­nen­tal polit­i­cal econ­o­mists, such as Gustav Cohn (1840–
1919), de Laveleye, and de Lavergne, and was crit­i­cized by other polit­i­cal
econ­o­mists includ­ing the youn­ger Mill, Henry Fawcett (1833–84), and
William Stanley Jevons (1835–82). For Leslie ([1879] 1888d: 98), the pur­
est ref­u­ta­tion of the “wages fund doc­trine” lies in the fact that there is no
such a thing as per­fect mobil­ity of both cap­i­tal and labor “as would make
all­the sums expendible in wages prac­ti­cally one fund.” Leslie uti­lized
fac­tual data from his jour­neys to doc­u­ment the inequalities of wages in
dif­fer­ent parts of the same coun­try, not­ing that inequalities in wages and
prices cor­re­spond to spe­cific his­tor­i­cal and geo­graph­i­cal par­tic­u­lar­i­ties.
Lastly, it must be noted that Cliffe Leslie’s essays on Belgium had a
polit­i­cal dimen­sion. He believed that the exam­ple of Flanders should be
the “core par­a­digm” of Ireland, as his father­land had those advan­tages of
fer­til­ity, beauty, and cli­mate that are appro­pri­ate for the devel­op­ment of
small pro­pri­e­tor­ships. Leslie ([1867] 1870: 335) noted that agri­cul­tural
pro­duc­tive­ness is higher in Flanders owing to the pres­ence of secu­rity of
ten­ure and “the pro­tec­tion of numer­ous cen­tres of civic life and lib­erty,
dur­ing cen­tu­ries in which the inhab­i­tants of most other parts of Belgium
were far­ther both from the busy mart and the vig­or­ous repub­lic.” What is
more, Leslie stressed the impor­tance of insti­tu­tions in ensur­ing the secu­
rity of ten­ure and pro­mot­ing— through the com­plete move­ment from sta­
tus to con­tract—the nat­u­ral prog­ress of opu­lence.

4. Cliffe Leslie’s Journey to Auvergne


One of the most well-known sur­veys writ­ten by Cliffe Leslie, and not
included in his Land Systems, is his ana­lyt­i­cal pre­sen­ta­tion of the econ­
omy and soci­ety of Auvergne. Leslie’s account of Auvergne was praised
by Mill and pro­vided to him mate­rial to spec­ify the role of his­tory in
deter­min­ing eco­nomic phe­nom­ena. In this jour­ney, Leslie ([1874] 1888:
415) observed that Auvergne’s “chief eco­nomic and social phe­nom­ena . . . ​
are . . . ​so related to some of its phys­i­cal fea­tures, that the lat­ter can­not be
left alto­gether unno­ticed.” He pro­vided a min­ute geo­graph­i­cal anal­y­sis of
the region of Auvergne and pro­vided a vari­ety of spa­tial, nat­u ­ral,

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
156 History of Political Economy 56:1 (2024)

eco­nomic, social, and cul­tural details.17 He followed again a his­tor­i­cal


approach and stressed the impor­tance of the insti­tu­tional frame­work in
deter­min­ing eco­nomic affairs. He pointed out that non­eco­nomic fac­tors,
such as cus­tom, tra­di­tions, and cul­ture, deter­m ine prop­erty rights and
direct pro­duc­tion and dis­tri­bu­tion. According to Leslie, prop­erty rights in

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


land are dif­fer­ent in its plain and moun­tain­ous dis­tricts. He noted that the
dom­i­nant form of prop­erty in the plain is the small pro­pri­e­tor­ship (la
petite propriete), while in the moun­tains the large prop­erty (la grande
propriete) is fre­quently found. In a highly etho­log­i­cal note, he observed
that this sort of dif­fer­ence is a mat­ter of cus­tom and tra­di­tion. Leslie elab­
o­rated on his­tor­i­cal facts to illus­trate his views and quoted the report of
the “Enquête agricole”:
In the plain an inher­i­tance is almost always partitioned or sold when a
suc­ces­sion (of more than one child) takes place; if partitioned, each of
the heirs takes a part of each par­cel; if it is sold, it is so in detail, and by
the smallest frac­tions, in order the more read­ily to find buy­ers.
Everything thus con­trib­utes to indef­i­nite sub­di­vi­sion in the plain. In the
moun­tains they cling to the con­ser­va­tion of the inher­i­tance unbro­ken,
and do all­that is pos­si­ble in order not to destroy the work of the fam­ily,
and not to divide the pater­nal dwell­ing. (Leslie [1874] 1888: 418–19)
According to his anal­y­sis, the emi­gra­tion of moun­tain peo­ple was asso­
ci­ated—on top of the com­par­a­tive unproductiveness of moun­tain land—
with cus­tom­ary/insti­tu­tional struc­tures, such as the “law of pri­mo­gen­i­ture.”
He noted that “the youn­ger sons, as the ‘Enquête Agricole’ states, seek a
sub­sis­tence else­where, to leave the prop­erty undi­vided to the elder brother;
or occa­sion­ally it is the elder brother who emi­grates, relinquishing his
share to a youn­ger one remaining at home” (419).18 Leslie’s approach leads
him to point out that the his­tor­i­cal ele­ment is of prime impor­tance in
under­stand­ing eco­nomic and social affairs. For instance, he informs us
that, “in the Auvergne moun­tains at this day, ‘the youn­ger brother sinks
into the priest,’ just as Sir Henry Maine describes him as doing under the
influ­ence of pri­mo­gen­i­ture in feu­dal soci­ety” (421). According to Leslie,

17. John Morley (1838–1923), the edi­tor of the Fortnightly Review, told to Leslie that Mill
said to him “that no one wrote accounts at once so instruc­tive and inter­est­ing as your nar­ra­tives
of your for­eign vis­its” (Leslie 1888: x–xi).
18. Cliffe Leslie, fol­low­ing Mill, pointed out that ideas/insti­tu­tions, such as pri­mo­gen­i­ture
or entails, “are among the oldest in human soci­ety—sub­or­di­na­tion to the male head of the fam­
ily, and con­ser­va­tion of the fam­ily prop­erty, unalien­ated and unpartitioned” (420).

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
Manioudis / Cliffe Leslie’s Critique of Ricardianism 157

the sur­vival of medi­e­val insti­tu­tions—such as the “law of pri­mo­gen­i­ture”


or the “law of entails”—had reversed the “nat­u­ral prog­ress of opu­lence”
and resulted in con­di­tions that can­not become under­stand­able through the
doc­trines of clas­si­cal polit­i­cal econ­omy. Because of its his­tor­i­cal/insti­tu­
tional frame­work, the econ­omy of Auvergne can­not be exem­pli­fied by

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


clas­si­cal motifs such as the wage-fund doc­trine.
Cliffe Leslie pro­vided valu­able infor­ma­tion about the edu­ca­tion, reli­
gion, and cul­ture of the Auvergne peo­ple and illus­trated the diver­sity of
hab­its, thought, and beliefs even in the same prov­ince.19 He noted that
reli­gious feel­ings and fam­ily bonds are of prominent impor­tance in the
for­ma­tion of prop­erty rights, pro­duc­tion, and the dis­tri­bu­tion of wealth in
the moun­tain­ous Auvergne. According to Leslie, this social sta­tus is the
direct con­se­quence of the dif­fer­ences in the phys­i­cal envi­ron­ment and the
eco­nomic con­di­tions of life. He observed that “on its moral and social
side, the con­trast between moun­tain and plain is the con­trast between the
old world and the new; between the cus­toms, thoughts, and feel­ings of
ancient and mod­ern times” (Leslie [1874] 1888: 421).
He extended his judi­cial anal­y­sis and noted that in Auvergne, the pos­i­
tive law of the plain was directly opposed to the cus­tom­ary struc­tures of
the moun­tain­ous area. According to him, such a con­flict had to be ascribed
to phys­i­cal, cli­matic, and cul­tural dif­fer­ences. He expressed his sym­pa­thy
toward “moun­tain­ous” peo­ple, but observed that the “moun­tain is, as it
were, the coun­try in its rud­est prim­i­tive form, while the plain is, as it
were, a great sub­urb of the towns it con­tains and has con­tin­ual inter­course
with” (423). Following Mill, de Lavergne, and de Laveleye, Cliffe Leslie
pointed out that a small pro­pri­e­tor­ship in the plain leads to the devel­op­
ment of indi­vid­u­al­ity and to the dis­in­te­gra­tion of fam­ily bonds that were
pow­er­ful enough in pre­vi­ous soci­e­tal forms. In this vein, we may say that
this view moved Leslie closer to a kind of insti­tu­tional indi­vid­u­al­ism that
was devel­oped by Smith, Mill, and even Turgot (Song 1995; Fontaine
1997; Zouboulakis 2002).
At the same time, Cliffe Leslie described the “watering-places” of
Auvergne and noted that its inhab­i­tants “spend here in the mass a great
sum of money at hotels, and on baths, car­riages, sad­d le-horses,

19. For instance, Leslie ([1874] 1888: 421) observed that “there are no girls’ schools in the
moun­tains; the daugh­ters of par­ents who can afford it are, there­fore, sent to con­vents to be edu­
cated, and the edu­ca­tion they receive both unfits them and gives them a dis­taste for the rude life
of a moun­tain farm­house. They learn to make lace and embroi­dery, but not to mend stock­ings
or to make but­ter or cheese.”

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
158 History of Political Economy 56:1 (2024)

sedan-chairs, shops, the casino, &c.; and as their num­bers yearly increase,
local prices rise” (Leslie [1874] 1888: 432). He informs us that one of its
chief towns, Bourboule, is a tour­ist cen­ter that attracted “mem­bers of the
National Assembly, authors, coun­try gentlemen, Parisians, pro­vin­cial
towns­peo­ple, mil­i­tary men, eccle­si­as­tics, besides a mul­ti­tude of non­de­

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


script young gentlemen and ladies” (432–33). According to Leslie’s induc­
tive research, Bourboule’s eco­nomic con­d i­tion is deter­m ined by its
phys­i­cal con­di­tions and cli­mate.
Cliffe Leslie’s anal­y­sis is opposed to the ahis­tor­i­cal nature of Ricardian
eco­nom­ics and is illus­tra­tive of his etho­log­i­cal mode of anal­y­sis, where
the “national char­ac­ter” (an influ­en­tial fac­tor in eco­nomic activ­ity) is
deter­m ined by phys­i­cal, cli­matic, intel­lec­t ual, and cul­t ural fac­tors.
According to him, local (phys­i­cal) con­d i­tions deter­m ine the struc­
ture/func­tion of social and eco­nomic phe­nom­ena and “pro­duce dis­tinct
types of human life, char­ac­ter, and pur­suit” (Leslie [1874] 1888: 431). In
his words,
The per­sis­tence in the Auvergne moun­tains of ancient ideas and feel­
ings on such sub­jects as both the clergy and fam­ily prop­erty . . . ​affords
an instruc­tive exam­ple, on the one hand, of the pro­found influ­ence of
phys­i­cal geog­ra­phy on the men­tal con­sti­tu­tion of man, and the his­tory
of the dif­fer­ent branches of the race, and, on the other hand, of the
oper­a­tion of laws of human nature and motives to human con­duct, pow­
er­fully affect­ing the eco­nomic struc­ture of soci­ety, the divi­sion of
occu­pa­tions, the amount and the dis­tri­bu­tion of wealth, which are abso­
lutely ignored in what still passes with some pro­fessed econ­o­mists for a
sci­ence of wealth. (424)
Leslie remarked that cli­mate and phys­i­cal con­di­tions are of prime impor­
tance in directing the eco­nomic activ­ity of nations. He observed that this
fact was ignored by clas­si­cal econ­o­mists. For him, “Climate cer­tainly
plays a great part in deter­min­ing the eco­nomic con­di­tion of man­kind; and
its agency, along with other phys­i­cal influ­ences, has been too gen­er­ally
overlooked by econ­o­mists in their eager­ness to explain the whole econ­
omy of soci­ety by ref­er­ence to the sin­gle assump­tion of a desire of every
one to obtain addi­tional wealth” (428).
Cliffe Leslie’s induc­tive, etho­log­i­cal, and his­tor­i­cal anal­y­sis illus­trated
the impor­tance of his­tory, eco­nomic geog­ra­phy, and other social fac­tors.
For him, the diver­si­ties in the eco­nomic struc­tures of Auvergne are tightly
asso­ci­ated with cul­tural, cus­tom­a ry, phys­i­cal, and even psy­cho­log­i­cal

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
Manioudis / Cliffe Leslie’s Critique of Ricardianism 159

con­di­tions. His plu­ral­is­tic, com­par­a­tive, and insti­tu­tional approach moved


him away from the abstracted schemes of Ricardian polit­i­cal econ­omy
and revealed the impor­tance of his­tor­i­cal spec­i­fic­ity in eco­nomic anal­y­sis.
Leslie crit­i­cized the use of the abstract char­ac­ter of the deduc­tive method
of Ricardo, as to “iso­late a sin­gle force, even if a real force and not a mere

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


abstrac­tion, and to call deduc­tions from it alone the laws of wealth, can
lead only to error, and is rad­i­cally unsci­en­tific” (Leslie [1879] 1888c: 212).
Thus, according to Leslie ([1874] 1888: 434), the ana­lyt­i­cal descrip­tion of
Auvergne suf­fices to show “the impor­tance of tak­ing account, in eco­
nomic inves­ti­ga­tions, of phys­i­cal geog­ra­phy and envi­ron­ment, and the
nec­es­sary fal­la­cious­ness of a the­ory which professes to account for the
divi­sion of labour in every coun­try, the amount and dis­tri­bu­tion of its
wealth, and the move­ments of money and prices, by deduc­tions from the
prin­ci­ple of pecu­ni­ary inter­est.”

5. Cliffe Leslie’s “On the Philosophical Method of Political


Economy” (1876) and the Emergence of Historical Economics
in Britain
As already noted, Cliffe Leslie’s jour­neys offered him the oppor­tu­nity to
develop an eco­nomic approach that moved him closer to Mill, yet even
fur­ther. Leslie called for a his­tor­i­cal and induc­tive polit­i­cal econ­omy. In
his 1876 clas­si­cal paper, “On the Philosophical Method of Political
Economy,” which can be con­sid­ered as the man­i­festo of Brit­ish his­tor­i­cal
eco­nom­ics, Leslie was sure that the relativization of Ricardian polit­i­cal
econ­omy was impos­si­ble. He noted that the abstract (or deduc­tive) method
“yields no expla­na­tion of the causes which reg­u­late either the nature or the
amount of wealth” (Leslie [1876] 1888: 174). For Leslie, the bane of
Ricardian polit­i­cal econ­omy “has been the haste of its stu­dents to pos­sess
them­selves of a com­plete and sym­met­ri­cal sys­tem, solv­ing all­the prob­
lems before it with math­e­mat­i­cal cer­tainty and exact­ness” (189). Leslie
was well aware of this already from the late 1860s. Through his empir­i­cal
stud­ies of con­ti­nen­tal Europe, he tested the validity of the laws of
Ricardian polit­i­cal econ­omy and con­cluded that these laws were far from
possessing “the uni­ver­sal­ity or inde­pen­dence of time and place usu­ally
attrib­uted to them” and have to “be con­di­tioned and qual­i­fied, if not aban­
doned” (Leslie [1869] 1888: 126). The rad­i­cal char­ac­ter of Leslie’s induc­
tive polit­i­cal econ­omy is syn­op­sized in his view that polit­i­cal econ­omy “is
not a body of nat­u­ral laws in the true sense, or of uni­ver­sal and immu­ta­ble

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
160 History of Political Economy 56:1 (2024)

truths, but an assem­blage of spec­u­la­tions and doc­trines which are the


result of a par­tic­u­lar his­tory . . . ​that, so far from being of no coun­try, and
unchange­able from age to age, it has var­ied much in dif­fer­ent ages and
countries” (Leslie [1870] 1888: 21; empha­sis added).
Cliffe Leslie’s crit­i­cism of Ricardianism is explicit in his sem­i­nal “On

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


the Philosophical Method of Political Economy,” where he observed that
wealth, which is the core notion of polit­i­cal econ­omy, “undergoes great
changes in kind in dif­fer­ent states of soci­ety, and one of the most impor­
tant fea­tures of eco­nom­i­cal his­tory is the evo­lu­tion of new kinds, pro­
foundly affect­ing the mate­rial as well as the moral con­di­tion of nations”
(Leslie [1876] 1888: 164).20 Thus, Leslie crit­i­cized Ricardian polit­i­cal
econ­omy—and post-Ricardians, such as Lowe—for iden­ti­fy­ing wealth
with the abstracted cat­e­gory of the “desire for wealth,” which con­founds a
great diver­sity of dif­fer­ent and essen­tially het­ero­ge­neous motives. For
Leslie, the main onto­log­i­cal tenet of Ricardian and post-Ricardian eco­
nom­ics, the “desire for wealth,” is his­tor­i­cally ani­mated, as it is influ­enced
by the state of soci­ety and is deci­sively deter­mined by the stage of eco­
nomic and social devel­op­ment. Similarly, the accu­mu­la­tion of wealth,
con­sump­tion, expen­di­ture, and so on are deter­mined by the state of soci­
ety and are influ­enced by dif­fer­ent insti­tu­tions and surrounding con­di­tions
such as “pas­sions, appe­tites, affec­tions, moral and reli­gious sen­ti­ments,
fam­ily feel­ings, aes­thet­i­cal tastes, and intel­lec­tual wants” (178). Evidently,
there­fore, according to Lesliean polit­i­cal econ­omy, the the­o­ries of pro­duc­
tion, con­sump­tion and dis­tri­bu­tion of wealth vary according to dif­fer­ent
states of soci­ety and, as such, polit­i­cal econ­omy is tightly asso­ci­ated with
eco­nomic his­tory. Leslie is more than explicit when he noted that “out
wealth is his­tor­i­cal wealth, has been made what it is by his­tor­i­cal causes,
and pre­serves vis­i­ble traces of its his­tory” (178). Thus, any eco­nomic doc­
trine is his­tor­i­cally (and socially) rel­a­tive. In his own words,
The amount of wealth has been proved to depend on all­the con­di­tions
deter­min­ing the direc­tion and employ­ments of human ener­gies, as well
as on the state of the arts of pro­duc­tion, and the means of sup­ply. And
the dis­tri­bu­tion of wealth has been shown to be the result, not of
exchange alone, but also of moral, reli­gious, and fam­ily ideas and

20. According to Leslie’s eco­nomic his­tory, “The wealth of Rome under the Cae­sars dif­
fered from its wealth in the first age of the Republic, in qual­ity as well as quan­tity; and there are
essen­tial dif­fer­ences, as well as resem­blances and his­tor­i­cal rela­tions, between the con­stit­u­ents
of medi­e­val and mod­ern wealth” (164).

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
Manioudis / Cliffe Leslie’s Critique of Ricardianism 161

sen­ti­ments, and the whole his­tory of the nation. The dis­tri­bu­tion . . . ​
varies at dif­fer­ent stages of social prog­ress, and is by no means in
accor­dance with the doc­trines of a pri­ori polit­i­cal econ­omy. (189–90)
Cliffe Leslie then directed his fierc­est crit­i­cism toward polit­i­cal econ­o­
mists of the clas­si­cal tra­di­tion, according to whom polit­i­cal econ­omy “has

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


no nation.” Following his his­tor­i­cal approach, the Brit­ish econ­omy is the
his­tor­i­cal result of spe­cific cir­cum­stances, and as such the the­ory to ana­
lyze it is his­tor­i­cally rel­a­tive to these cir­cum­stances. For him,
The eco­nomic soci­ety which we behold in England, and which is the
result of the social evo­lu­tion referred to, is, how­ever, one which dis­plays
on every side the influ­ence of tra­di­tion, cus­tom, law, polit­i­cal insti­tu­
tions, reli­gion and moral sen­ti­ment; it is one in which the State, the
Family, and even the Church, are pow­er­ful ele­ments directly or indi­
rectly, and in which the pur­suits of indi­vid­u­als, the nature and value of
dif­fer­ent kinds of wealth, the struc­ture of trades and pro­fes­sions, are
inca­pa­ble of expla­na­tion apart from his­tory. (179)
Leslie’s arti­cle includes an over­all cri­tique of clas­si­cal polit­i­cal econ­omy
and encompasses his vehe­ment attack which was incu­bated in his trav­els
across the Continental Europe. Leslie’s rad­i­cal views contested the over­
sim­pli­fi­ca­tion of eco­nomic real­ity as was pro­moted by clas­si­cal polit­i­cal
econ­o­mists. The meth­od­o­log­i­cal aspects of Leslie’s cri­tique pro­vided the
frame­work of the “rel­a­tiv­ity of eco­nomic doc­trines” the­sis which turned to
be the epis­te­mo­log­i­cal pil­lar of the Brit­ish his­tor­i­cal school and of his­tor­i­
cal econ­o­mists as Sir William Ashley (1860–1927). In discussing Political
Economy in the United States Leslie ([1880] 1888: 142) noted that:
Economic the­o­ries and sys­tems may be regarded in sev­eral dif­fer­ent
lights: (1) in ref­er­ence to their causes, as the prod­ucts of par­tic­u­lar,
social, polit­i­cal, and phys­i­cal con­di­tions of thought; (2) in ref­er­ence to
their truth or error; (3) as fac­tors in the for­ma­tion of pub­lic opin­ion
and pol­icy.

6. Conclusion
Cliffe Leslie’s jour­neys offered him the oppor­tu­nity to col­lect descrip­tive
mate­rial and pre­pare his attack on the Ricardian School of polit­i­cal econ­
omy. Cliffe Leslie’s polit­i­cal econ­omy is far more rad­i­cal than Smith’s and
Mill’s. For the founder of Brit­ish his­tor­i­cism, the rela­tion between

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
162 History of Political Economy 56:1 (2024)

eco­nomic phe­nom­ena and the moral, intel­lec­tual, and polit­i­cal super­


struc­ture is totally “undreamt of by the old school of econ­o­mists” (Leslie
[1874] 1888: 435). Leslie believed that with­out the his­tor­i­cist, com­par­a­
tive, and holis­tic sur­vey of laws, cus­toms, tra­di­tions, mores, and reli­gion
of a par­tic­u­lar soci­ety, gen­er­al­iza­tions result in mis­lead­ing and void con­

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


clu­sions. However, the tran­si­tion from polit­i­cal econ­omy to eco­nom­ics
ostra­cized the his­tor­i­cal and social ele­ments from eco­nomic rea­son­ing
(Milonakis and Fine 2009). It is inter­est­ing to note that Cliffe Leslie,
although on cor­dial terms with Jevons, expressed his antip­a­thy to his
deductivism and marginalism (Leslie [1879] 1888a). Not sur­pris­ingly,
Cliffe Leslie’s jour­neys pre­pared the ground for the meth­od­o­log­i­cal raison
d’être of his­tor­i­cism, through the destruc­tion of Ricardian polit­i­cal econ­
omy. According to Leslie ([1874] 1888: 436–37, “The method of abstract
rea­son­ing from crude assump­tion, in place of care­ful inves­ti­ga­tion of eco­
nomic phe­nom­ena and their causes, has prevented the dis­cov­ery of a mass
of evi­dence respect­ing the real ori­gin of dif­fer­ences in the aims, qual­i­ties,
and cir­cum­stances of man­kind in dif­fer­ent countries and sit­u­a­tions.”
Cliffe Leslie’s polit­i­cal econ­omy, and espe­cially his applied work, can
then be viewed as fol­low­ing the induc­tive ele­ments of Smith’s and Mill’s
polit­i­cal econ­omy, con­trary to Ricardo’s deductivism. His early induc­tive
texts illus­trated the ties between the induc­tive (his­tor­i­cal) side of clas­si­cal
polit­i­cal econ­omy and Brit­ish his­tor­i­cism, pre­par­ing in this way the emer­
gence of the Brit­ish his­tor­i­cal school.

References
Bladen, Vincent Wheeler. 1941. “Mill to Marshall: The Conversion of the
Economists.” Journal of Economic History 1, no. 1: 17–29.
Boianovsky, Mauro, and Harro Maas. 2022. “Introduction: Roads to Economic
Knowledge; The Epistemic Virtues of Travel across the History of Thought.”
History of Political Economy 54, no. 3: 383–92.
Boylan, Tom, and Tadhg Foley. 1993. “The Teaching of Economics at the Queen’s
Colleges in Ireland (Belfast, Cork, Galway), 1845–1900.” In The Market for
Political Economy: The Advent of Economics in Brit­ish University Culture,
1850–1905, edited by Alon Kadish and Keith Tribe, 111–36. London: Routledge.
Coleman, David. 1987. History and the Economic Past: An Account of the Rise and
Decline of Economic History in Britain. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Collison Black, R. D. 2002. “The Political Economy of Thomas Edward Cliffe Leslie
(1826–82): A Re-assess­ment.” Euro­pean Journal of the History of Economic
Thought 9, no. 1: 17–41.

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
Manioudis / Cliffe Leslie’s Critique of Ricardianism 163

Fontaine, Philippe. 1997. “Turgot’s ‘Institutional Individualism.’” History of Political


Economy 29, no. 1: 1–20.
Hodgson, Geoffrey. 2001. How Economics Forgot History. London: Routledge.
Hollander, James. 1911. “The Letters of John Stu­art Mill.” Political Science Quarterly
26, no. 4: 697–706.
Ingram, John Kells. 1882. “Thomas Edward Cliffe Leslie.” Encyclopaedia Britannica

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


14:477–78.
Ingram, John Kells. 1888. “Biographical Notice of the Author.” In Essays in Political
Economy, by Thomas Edward Cliffe Leslie, ix–xii. London: Longmans, Green, &
Co.; Dublin: Hodges, Figgis, & Co.
Kadish, Alon. 1989. Historians, Economists, and Economic History. London:
Routledge.
Koot, Gerard M. 1975. “T. E. Cliffe Leslie, Irish Social Reform, and the Origins of
the English Historical School of Economics.” History of Political Economy 7,
no. 3: 312–36.
Koot, Gerard M. 1987. English Historical Economics, 1870–1926: The Role of
Economic History and Neomercantilism. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. (1867) 1870. “The Peasantry and Farms of Belgium, 1867.” In
Leslie 1870b: 294–340.
Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. (1868) 1870. “Political Economy and the Rate of Wages.” In
Leslie 1870b: 357–79.
Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. (1869) 1870a. “A Visit to La Creuse, 1868.” In Leslie 1870b: 265–
82.
Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. (1869) 1870b. “Westphalia and the Ruhr Basin, 1868–1869.” In
Leslie 1870b: 230–53.
Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. (1869) 1888. “Political Economy in the United States.” In Leslie
1888: 126–54.
Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. 1870a. “The Farms and Peasantry of Belgium, 1870.” In Leslie
1870b: 341–55.
Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. 1870b. Land Systems and Industrial Economy of Ireland,
England, and Continental Countries. London: Longmans, Green.
Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. 1870c. “A Second Visit to La Creuse.” In Leslie 1870b: 265–93.
Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. 1870d. “Westphalia and the Ruhr Basin, 1869–1870.” In Leslie
1870b: 254–64.
Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. (1870) 1888. “The Political Economy of Adam Smith.” In Leslie
1888: 21–40.
Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. (1873) 1888a. “Economic Science and Statistics.” In Leslie 1888:
155–62.
Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. (1873) 1888b. “Prices in England in 1873.” In Leslie 1888: 363.
Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. (1874) 1888. “Auvergne.” In Leslie 1888: 414–37.
Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. (1875) 1888. “John Stu­art Mill.” In Leslie 1888: 54–59.
Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. (1876) 1888. “On the Philosophical Method of Political Economy.”
In Leslie 1888: 163–90.

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
164 History of Political Economy 56:1 (2024)

Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. 1879. Essays in Political and Moral Philosophy. London:


Longmans, Green; Dublin: Hodges, Figgis.
Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. (1879) 1888a. “Jevons’ ‘Theory of Political Economy.’” In Leslie
1888: 66–72.
Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. (1879) 1888b. “The Known and the Unknown in the Economic
World.” In Leslie 1888: 234–42.

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. (1879) 1888c. “Political Economy and Sociology.” In Leslie 1888:
191–220.
Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. (1879) 1888d. “Roscher’s ‘Principles of Political Economy.’” In
Leslie 1888: 95–100.
Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. (1880) 1888. “Political Economy in the United States.” In Leslie
1888: 126–54.
Leslie, T. E. Cliffe. 1888. Essays in Political Economy. London: Longmans, Green;
Dublin: Hodges, Figgis.
Lipkes, Jeff. 1999. Politics, Religion, and Classical Political Economy in Britain:
John Stu­art Mill and His Followers. London: Macmillan.
Manioudis, Manolis. 2020. “J. S. Mill and the Irish Land Question: From Irish
Economic History to Coherent Socialism and Irish Historicism.” Irish Economic
and Social History 48, no. 1: 27–46.
Mill, John Stu­art. (1848) 1965. Principles of Political Economy with Some of Their
Applications to Social Philosophy. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.
Mill, John Stu­art. (1860) 1972. Letter to T. E. Cliffe Leslie. August 18. In vol. 2 of
The Later Letters of John Stu­art Mill, 1849–1873, edited by Francis E. Mineka
and Dwight N. Lindley, 702–4. Toronto: University of Toronto Press; London:
Routledge & Kegan Paul.
Mill, John Stu­art. (1861) 1972a. Letter to T. E. Cliffe Leslie. Novem­ber. In vol. 2 of
The Later Letters of John Stu­art Mill, 1849–1873, edited by Francis E. Mineka
and Dwight N. Lindley, 746–47. Toronto: University of Toronto Press; London:
Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Mill, John Stu­art. (1861) 1972b. Letter to T. E. Cliffe Leslie. Decem­ber 20. In vol. 2
of The Later Letters of John Stu­art Mill, 1849–1873, edited by Francis E. Mineka
and Dwight N. Lindley, 756–58. Toronto: University of Toronto Press; London:
Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Mill, John Stu­art. (1863) 1972. Letter to T. E. Cliffe Leslie. Novem­ber 14. In vol. 2 of
The Later Letters of John Stu­art Mill, 1849–1873, edited by Francis E. Mineka
and Dwight N. Lindley, 897–99. Toronto: University of Toronto Press; London:
Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Mill, John Stu­art. (1866) 1972. Letter to Thomas Hughes. Decem­ber 18. In vol. 3 of
The Later Letters of John Stu­art Mill, 1849–1873, edited by Francis E. Mineka
and Dwight N. Lindley, 1221–22. Toronto: University of Toronto Press; London:
Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Mill, John Stu­art. (1867) 1972. Letter to John Elliott Cairnes. July 23. In vol. 3 of The
Later Letters of John Stu­art Mill, 1849–1873, edited by Francis E. Mineka and

UNCORRECTED PROOFS
Manioudis / Cliffe Leslie’s Critique of Ricardianism 165

Dwight N. Lindley, 1293–94. Toronto: University of Toronto Press; London:


Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Mill, John Stu­art. (1868) 1972. Letter to Edwin Chadwick. Jan­u­ary 9. In vol. 3 of The
Later Letters of John Stu­art Mill, 1849–1873, edited by Francis E. Mineka and
Dwight N. Lindley, 1350–51. Toronto: University of Toronto Press; London:
Routledge and Kegan Paul.

Downloaded from http://read.dukeupress.edu/hope/article-pdf/doi/10.1215/00182702-10956596/2012255/10956596.pdf by guest on 14 October 2023


Mill, John Stu­art. (1869) 1972a. Letter to T. E. Cliffe Leslie. Feb­ru­ary 8. In vol. 4 of
The Later Letters of John Stu­art Mill, 1849–1873, edited by Francis E. Mineka
and Dwight N. Lindley, 1557–58. Toronto: University of Toronto Press; London:
Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Mill, John Stu­art. (1869) 1972b. Letter to T. E. Cliffe Leslie. May 8. In vol. 4 of The
Later Letters of John Stu­art Mill, 1849–1873, edited by Francis E. Mineka and
Dwight N. Lindley, 1599–601. Toronto: University of Toronto Press; London:
Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Mill, John Stu­art. (1869) 1972c. Letter to T. E. Cliffe Leslie. Octo­ber 5. In vol. 4 of
The Later Letters of John Stu­art Mill, 1849–1873, edited by Francis E. Mineka
and Dwight N. Lindley, 1642–43. Toronto: University of Toronto Press; London:
Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Mill, John Stu­art. (1870) 1875. “Professor Leslie on the Land Question.” In vol. 5 of
Dissertations and Discussions: Political, Philosophical, and Historical. New
York: Henry Holt.
Mill, John Stu­art. (1871) 1972. Letter to T. E. Cliffe Leslie. Decem­ber 1. In vol. 4 of
The Later Letters of John Stu­art Mill, 1849–1873, edited by Francis E. Mineka
and Dwight N. Lindley, 1857–59. Toronto: University of Toronto Press; London:
Routledge and Kegan Paul.
Milonakis, D., and B. Fine. 2009. From Political Economy to Economics. London:
Routledge.
Moore, Gregory C. G. 1995. “T. E. Cliffe Leslie and the English Methodenstreit.”
Journal of the History of Economic Thought 17, no. 1: 57–77.
Moore, Gregory C. G. 1999. “John Kells Ingram, the Comt­ean Movement, and the
English Methodenstreit.” History of Political Economy 31, no. 1: 53–78.
Song, Hyun-Ho. 1995. “Adam Smith as an Early Pioneer of Institutional
Individualism.” History of Political Economy 27, no. 3: 425–48.
Tribe, Keith. 2002. “Historical Schools of Economics: Ger­man and English.” Keele
Economics Research Papers, Department of Economics, Keele University.
Vallier, Kevin. 2010. “Production, Distribution, and J. S. Mill.” Utilitas 22, no. 2:
103–25.
Winch, Donald. 2013. “Land Reform and Popular Political Economy in Vic­to­r ian
Britain.” Intellectual History Archive, University of St. Andrews. https:​­/​­/arts​­.st​
­-andrews​­.ac​­.uk​­/intellectualhistory​­/items​­/show​­/82.
Zouboulakis, Michalis. 2002. “John Stu­a rt Mill’s Institutional Individualism.”
History of Economic Ideas 10, no. 3: 29–45.

UNCORRECTED PROOFS

You might also like