You are on page 1of 7

EconS 501 - Microeconomic Theory I

Midterm exam #2 - Answer key

1. Gross Substitutes. Consider an economy with two individuals, Amelia and Bernardo,
with utility functions

uA (xA ; y A ) = minfxA ; 2y A g for Amelia, and


uB (xB ; y B ) = minf2xB ; y B g for Bernardo,

and initial endowments are given by eA = (1; 0) for Amelia and eB = (0; 1) for
Bernardo.

(a) Find the Walrasian demands of each individual.


Amelia. The UMP of Amelia is

max minfxA ; 2y A g
xA ;y A 0

subject to px xA + py y A px

since she only owns one unit of good x, eA = (1; 0) the market value of her
resources (as captured in the right-hand side of the budget constraint) is px .
As she would consume (xA ; y A ) pairs at the kink of her L-shaped indi¤erence
curves, optimal consumption bundles satisfy xA = 2y A . Plugging xA = 2y A
into her budget line, px xA + py y A = px , yields

px 2y A + py y A = px

and solving for y A , we obtain Amelia’s Walrasian demand of good y


px
yA =
2px + py

while her demand for good x is


2px
xA = 2y A =
2px + py

Bernardo. Similarly, Bernardo’s utility maximizing bundles (xB ; y B ) satisfy


2xB = y B (bundles at the kink of his indi¤erence curve) and px xB +py y B = py
(budget line since he only owns one unit of good y). Simultaneously solving
for xB and y B yields
py 2py
xB = and y B =
px + 2py px + 2py

(b) Find the excess demand functions, zx (px ; py ) and zy (px ; py ).

1
The excess demand for good x is

2px py px py (py )2
zx (px ; py ) = + 1 0=
2px + py px + 2py (2px + py )(px + 2py )

while that of good y is

px 2py px py (px )2
zy (px ; py ) = + 0 1=
2px + py px + 2py (2px + py )(px + 2py )

(c) Check that Walras’law holds.


In order to check that p z(p) = 0, we need

px py (py )2 px py (px )2
px zx (px ; py ) + py zx (px ; py ) = px + py
(2px + py )(px + 2py ) (2px + py )(px + 2py )
2 2 2 2
(px ) py px (py ) + px (py ) (px ) py
= =0
(2px + py )(px + 2py )

thus con…rming Walras’law.


(d) Check if goods are gross substitutes, i.e., for any two goods k 6= j where k; j =
fx; yg their excess demand functions satisfy @zk (p
@pj
x ;py )
> 0.
Using zx (px ; py ), we …nd

@zx (px ; py ) 2(px )3 4(px )2 py 7px (py )2


=
@py (2(px )2 + 2(py )2 + 5px py )2

which is positive if the numerator is positive, that is,


2px
py < p ' 0:32px
2+3 2
Similarly, using zy (px ; py ), we …nd that

@zy (px ; py ) 2(py )3 4px (py )2 7(px )2 py


=
@px (2(px )2 + 2(py )2 + 5px py )2

which is positive if the numerator is positive, that is,


px p
py > 3 2 + 2 ' 3:12px
2
Figure 1 depicts in the (px ; py )-quadrant the two cuto¤s we identi…ed:
– price pairs in area C entail that good x is a gross substitute of good y;
whereas
– price pairs in area A imply that good y is a gross substitute of good x.

2
In other words, the conditions for goods to be gross substitutes are asymmet-
ric, as there is no region where both good x is a gross substitute of y and vice
versa.
Last, note that price pairs in area B entail that good x is a gross complement
of good y and, simultaneously, good y is a gross complement of good x.

Figure 1. Areas for which goods x and y can be gross substitutes.

2. Concave transformation of a utility function. Consider an individual with the


utility function,
u (x) = x
where 0 1, and x > 0 represents the outcome that the individual receives.

(a) Consider the concave transformation g (y) = ln y, where y > 0. Find the Arrow-
Pratt coe¢ cient of absolute risk aversion for the composite function g (u (x)).
Show that this function exhibits stronger risk aversion than the utility function
u (x).
The composite function is

h (x) g (u (x))
= ln (x )
= ln x

Di¤erentiating the composite function, h (x) g (u (x)), with respect to x,


we obtain
dh (x)
h0 (x) =
dx x
d2 h (x)
h00 (x) =
dx2 x2

3
so the Arrow-Pratt coe¢ cient of absolute risk aversion of the composite func-
tion is
h00 (x) x2 1
rA (x; h) = 0
= = .
h (x) x
x
We can now di¤erentiate the original utility function, u (x), with respect to
x, …nding
du (x)
u0 (x) = x 1
dx
d2 u (x)
u00 (x) = (1 )x 2
dx2
Therefore, the Arrow-Pratt coe¢ cient of absolute risk aversion of u(x) is

u00 (x) (1 )x 2
1
rA (x; u) = = =
u0 (x) x 1 x
Comparing the Arrow-Pratt coe¢ cients of absolute risk aversion, we obtain
that
1 1
rA (x; h) = = rA (x; u)
x x
for all 2 [0; 1]. Therefore, the composite utility function, g (u (x)), exhibits
stronger risk aversion than the simple utility function u (x). Graphically, the
concave transformation makes h(x) more concave than u(x), thus making the
individual more averse to playing lotteries.
(b) Suppose the individual plays a lottery with equal probability of winning x and
3x. Find the certainty equivalent of this lottery for the individual with (i) the
utility function u (x), and (ii) the composite utility function g (u (x)).
The certainty equivalent is the amount that makes this individual indi¤erent
to the expected utility of the lottery. Therefore, for the initial utility function
u (x), the certainty equivalent solves
1 1
u (CE ( ; x; u)) = E (u (x)) = x + (3x)
2 2
1+3
(CE ( ; x; u)) = x
2
and, solving for CE, we …nd
1
1+3
CE ( ; x; u) = x:
2
For the composite utility function g (u (x)), the certainty equivalent solves a
similar problem:
1 1
u (CE ( ; x; h)) = E (h (x)) = ln x + ln 3x
2 2
ln (CE ( ; x; h)) = (2 ln x + ln 3)
2

4
and, solving for CE, we …nd

2 ln x + ln 3
CE ( ; x; h) = exp
2

(c) Let = 21 . Does the individual require a lower certainty equivalent with utility
function u (x) or with the composite utility function g (u (x))? Interpret.
1
Substituting = 2
into the certainty equivalents we found in part (b), we
obtain that
1 p !2
1 1 + 31=2 1=2
1+ 3
CE ; x; u = x= x
2 2 2
1 2 ln x + ln 3
CE ; x; h = exp
2 2
1 1
Let us check if CE 2
; x; h < CE 2
; x; u , which entails
p !2
2 ln x + ln 3 1+ 3
exp < x
2 2
p
ln 3 1+ 3
ln x + < ln x + 2 ln
2 p 2
1+ 3
ln 3 < 4 ln
2
which simpli…es to 1:1 < 1:25 that holds. Intuitively, the individual is more
risk adverse under the composite utility function g (u (x)) than under the
initial utility function u (x), so that this individual is willing to accept a
lower certainty equivalent under the composite utility function than the initial
utility function.

3. Monopolist interested in fairness. Consider a monopolist who faces a market


with two segments, with demand functions q1 (p1 ) = a1 p1 and q2 (p2 ) = a2 p2 ,
where a2 > a1 , and production costs are normalized to zero, c = 0. Suppose that she
maximizes pro…t subject to the constraint that the outcome is fair in the sense that
consumer surpluses coincide, that is,

CS1 (q1 ) = CS2 (q2 ).

(a) Formulate the optimization problem of this monopolist and solve the problem.
The monopolist solves
max p1 q1 + p2 q2
q1 ;q2 0

subject to CS1 (q1 ) = CS2 (q2 ).

5
Since demand functions are linear,
Z
CSi (qi ) = (ai qi ) dqi (a q )q
| i {z i} i
pi

1 2
= ai q i q (ai qi ) qi
2 i
1 2
= q ;
2 i
Therefore, the constraint implies that 21 q12 = 12 q22 , which holds only if q1 =
q2 = q, meaning that the monopolist sells the same quantity in each segment.
Using q1 = q2 = q in the objective function, the monopolist problem above
simpli…es to
max p1 q + p2 q = (a1 q)q + (a2 q) q
q 0

Di¤erentiating with respect to q, yields

a1 2q + a2 2q = 0

and, solving for q, we obtain


a1 + a2
q = .
4
Inserting q into the inverse demand functions of each segment, we …nd the
equilibrium prices
a1 + a2 3a1 a2
p1 (q ) = a1 = , and
4 4
a1 + a2 3a2 a1
p2 (q ) = a2 = .
4 4
(b) Find equilibrium output and prices if, instead, the monopolist seeks to maximize
pro…ts without the fairness constraint.
If the monopolist seeks to maximize pro…ts without the fairness constraint,
she solves
max p1 q1 + p2 q2 = (a1 q1 )q1 + (a2 q2 ) q2
q1 ;q2 0

Di¤erentiating with respect to q1 , yields a1 2q1 = 0, which entails q1m = a21 .


Similarly, di¤erentiating with respect to a2 , we obtain a2 2q2 = 0, which
entails q2m = a22 . Inserting these output levels in the inverse demand functions
of each segment, we …nd that equilibrium prices are
a1 a1
p1 (q1m ) = a1 = , and
2 2
a2 a2
p2 (q2m ) = a2 = .
2 2
(c) Compare your results in parts (a) and (b). Rank equilibrium prices, output, and
interpret.

6
Comparing equilibrium prices, we …nd that the price high-demand customers
pay satis…es
3a1 a2 a1
p1 (q ) = > = p1 (q1m )
4 2
which simpli…es to a1 > a2 , which holds by assumption. In contrast, the price
that low-demand customers pay satis…es
3a2 a1 a2
p2 (q ) = < = p1 (q1m )
4 2
meaning that high-demand customers pay more when the monopolist is con-
trained by fairness considerations than otherwise. Low-demand customers,
however, pay less when the monopolist is contrained by fairness considera-
tions than otherwise.
Comparing equilibrium output, we …nd that the sales to high-demand cus-
tomers satis…es
a1 + a2 a1
q = < = q1m
4 2
since a2 < a1 . In contrast, the sales to low-demand customers satis…es
a1 + a2 a2
q = > = q2m
4 2
meaning that the high-demand customers purchase fewer units when the mo-
nopolist is constrained by fairness than otherwise, while low-demand cus-
tomers buy more units.

You might also like