You are on page 1of 35

American Economic Association

The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change, and Economic Growth
Author(s): Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson, James Robinson
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 95, No. 3 (Jun., 2005), pp. 546-579
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/4132729
Accessed: 04/12/2009 22:03

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless
you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you
may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=aea.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
American Economic Review.

http://www.jstor.org
The Rise of Europe:AtlanticTrade, InstitutionalChange,
and EconomicGrowth
By DARON ACEMOGLU,SIMONJOHNSON,AND JAMESROBINSON*

The rise of WesternEurope after 1500 is due largely to growth in countries with
access to the Atlantic Ocean and with substantial trade with the New World,Africa,
and Asia via the Atlantic. This trade and the associated colonialism affected Europe
not only directly, but also indirectly by inducing institutional change. Where
"initial" political institutions (those established before 1500) placed significant
checks on the monarchy,the growth of Atlantic trade strengthenedmerchantgroups
by constraining the power of the monarchy,and helped merchantsobtain changes
in institutionsto protect property rights. These changes were central to subsequent
economic growth. (JEL F10, N13, 010, P10)

The world we live in was shapedby the rapid There is little agreement,however, on why this
economic growth that took place in nineteenth- growth took place in Western Europe and why
century Western Europe. The origins of this it started in the sixteenth century.
growth and the associated IndustrialRevolution This paper establishes the patterns of eco-
are generally considered to lie in the economic, nomic growth in Western Europe during this
political, and social development of Western era, develops a hypothesis on the origins of the
Europe over the preceding centuries. In fact, rise of (Western)Europeand provideshistorical
between 1500 and 1800, Western Europe expe- and econometric evidence supportingsome of
rienced a historically unprecedentedperiod of the implications of this hypothesis.
sustained growth, perhaps the "First Great Di- We document that the differentialgrowth of
vergence" (i.e., the first major sustained diver- Western Europe during the sixteenth, seven-
gence in income per capita across different teenth, eighteenth, and early nineteenthcentu-
regions of the world), making this area substan- ries is almost entirely accounted for by the
tially richer than Asia and Eastern Europe. growth of nations with access to the Atlantic
Ocean, and of Atlantic traders. Throughoutthe
paper, the term Atlantic traderrefers to Britain,
* Acemoglu:Departmentof Economics,MassachusettsIn- France, the Netherlands, Portugal, and Spain,
stitute of Technology, E52-371, Cambridge, MA 02142 the nations most directly involved in trade and
(e-mail: daron@mit.edu);Johnson:Sloan School of Manage- colonialism in the New World and Asia. Atlan-
ment, MassachusettsInstituteof Technology, 50 Memorial tic trade, in turn, means trade with the New
Drive, Cambridge,MA 02139 (e-mail: sjohnson@mit.edu);
Robinson: Departmentof Government,HarvardUniversity, World, as well as tradewith Asia via the Atlan-
1875 Cambridge Street, Cambridge, MA 02138 (e-mail: tic, and includes colonialism- and slavery-
jrobinson@gov.harvard.edu). We thank Thomas Becker and related activities.' The differential growth of
Rui PedroEstevesfor outstandingresearchassistanceandJosh Atlantic traders suggests a close link between
Angrist, Abhijit Banerjee,Dora Costa, Jan de Vries, Stanley Atlantic tradeand the First GreatDivergence.In
Engerman,PhilipHoffman,PeterLindert,SebastidnMazzuca,
Joel Mokyr,LarryNeal, Steve Pincus,ChristinaRomer,David fact, it appearsthat the rise of Europebetween
Romer,AndreiShleifer,Alan Taylor,Hans-JoachimVoth,two 1500 and 1850 is largely the rise of Atlantic
anonymousreferees,andseminarparticipantsat the University
of California,Berkeley, the CanadianInstituteof Advanced
Research,Universityof ChicagoGraduateSchool of Business 1 Atlantic tradeopportunitiesbecame availableonly dur-
and Departmentof Political Science, George Mason Univer- ing the late fifteenthcentury, thanks to the discovery of the
sity, HarvardBusiness School, the HarvardEconomicHistory New World and the passage to Asia around the Cape of
Seminar,the LondonSchool of Economics,MIT,the National Good Hope. These discoveries resulted from a series of
Bureau of Economic Researcheconomic history, inequality, innovations in ship technology, primarilypioneeredby the
and economic growth groups, New York University, and Portuguese, that changed the rigging and hull design of
PrincetonUniversityfor commentsand suggestions. ships and developed knowledge of oceanic navigation.
546
VOL.95 NO. 3 ACEMOGLUET AL.: THE RISE OF EUROPE 547

25

20

1300 1400 1500 1600 1700 1750 1800 1850

Year

--e-- Western Europe -+- Eastern Europe Asia

IA.
FIGURE WESTERN EASTERN
EUROPE, ANDASIA:URBANIZATION
EUROPE, RATES,WEIGHTED
BYPOPULATION,
1300-1850

30

25

I 20
C
0

10-
10

1300 1400 1500 1600 1700 1750 1800 1850

Year
-*- Atlantictraders --- WesternEuropenotAtlantictraders -+- EasternEurope
FIGURE lB. ATLANTIC TRADERS, WEST EUROPEAN COUNTRIES NOT ATLANTIC TRADERS, AND EASTERN EUROPE:
URBANIZATION RATES, WEIGHTED BY POPULATION, 1300-1850

Europe, and is quite differentin naturefrom the easy access to the Atlantic, even such nonabso-
Europeangrowth that took place before 1500. lutist states as Venice and Genoa, did not expe-
Not all societies with access to the Atlantic rience any direct or indirect benefits from
show the same patternof growth, however. The Atlantic trade.
data suggest an importantinteraction between Figures 1 and 2 illustrate the central thesis
medieval political institutionsand access to the of this paper. Figure 1, panel A, shows that
Atlantic: the more rapid economic growth took urbanization in Western Europe grew sig-
place in societies with relatively nonabsolutist nificantly faster than in Eastern Europe after
initial institutions, most notably in Britain and 1500.2 Figure 1, panel B, shows that these
the Netherlands.In contrast,countrieswhere the
monarchy was highly absolutist, such as Spain
and Portugal, experienced only limited growth 2
For the purposesof this paper,WesternEuropeis taken
in the subsequentcenturies, while areas lacking to be all the countries west of the Elbe, i.e., Austria,
548 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 2005

2500

2000

1500

N
c 1000-

500 -

1500 1600 1700 1820 1870

Year

---- WesternEurope -+- EasternEurope --- Asia

2A. WESTERN
FIGURE EASTERN
EUROPE, ANDASIA:GDPPERCAPITA,
EUROPE, WEIGHTED 1500-1870
BYPOPULATION,

2500

2000

1500-
0

C 1000 --........

1500 1600 1700 1820 1870

Year
-
A-Atlantictraders --- WesternEuropenot Atlantictraders ---- EasternEurope
FIGURE 2B. ATLANTIC TRADERS, WEST EUROPEAN COUNTRIES NOT ATLANTIC TRADERS, AND EASTERN EUROPE: GDP PER
CAPITA,WEIGHTEDBY POPULATION,
1500-1870

differential trends are due in large part to 1850. In contrast,Atlantic tradersstartedwith a


the growth of Atlantic traders.The rest of West- lower average urbanizationrate of 8 percent in
ern Europehad a relatively high average urban- 1300 (and only 10.1 percent in 1500), which
ization rate of 10 percent in 1300 (and 11.4 almost tripled in the subsequent 550 years to
percentin 1500), but grew at approximatelythe reach 24.5 percent in 1850, overtaking average
same rate as EasternEuropefrom 1500 to 1850, urbanizationin the non-Atlantic parts of West-
by a factor of less than 2, to reach 17 percentby ern Europebetween 1600 and 1700 (see Table 1).
Panels A and B in Figure 2 show the same
pattern, using Angus Maddison's (2001) esti-
mates of GDP per capita. While GDP per capita
Belgium, Britain,Denmark,Finland,France,Germany,Ire-
land, Italy, the Netherlands,Norway, Portugal,Spain, Swe- rose by a factor of almost two among Atlantic
den, and Switzerland. Eastern Europe is all European traders between 1500 and 1820, in the rest of
countries to the east of the Elbe, including Russia and Western Europe it grew at approximately the
excluding Turkey. See Section I A for details on urbaniza- same rate as in Eastern Europe, just under 30
tion and GDP data. All averages are weighted by popula-
tion, using numbers from Colin McEvedy and Richard percent.
Jones (1978). The patternsdepicted in Figures 1 and 2 do
VOL.95 NO. 3 ACEMOGLUET AL.: THE RISE OF EUROPE 549

TABLE 1-DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS

Non-
Whole Whole Atlantic Atlantic
sample, sample, Western Western Eastern
unweighted weighted Europe Europe Europe Asia
Weighted by population
Urbanizationin 1300 6.6 9.9 8.0 10.0 4.1 11.0
(5.2) (3.2) (2.8) (6.1) (3.3) (0.7)
Urbanizationin 1400 7.6 10.3 8.5 12.1 3.9 11.1
(9.5) (3.6) (2.4) (10.0) (1.5) (0.5)
Urbanizationin 1500 8.3 10.6 10.1 11.4 4.0 11.5
(7.6) (3.4) (5.3) (6.8) (1.8) (0.7)
Urbanizationin 1600 9.6 11.7 13.6 14.0 4.4 12.0
(7.6) (4.0) (7.6) (8.8) (2.7) (0.7)
Urbanizationin 1700 10.7 11.2 14.5 13.1 3.7 11.6
(8.5) (4.1) (6.8) (8.1) (2.2) (0.7)
Urbanizationin 1800 14.1 10.3 19.8 16.9 7.0 8.9
(9.1) (4.9) (7.9) (7.5) (3.3) (1.4)
GDP per capita in 1500 627.54 608.3 721.46 850.73 506.94 575.0
(159.3) (118.0) (31.1) (217.1) (78.2) (35.4)
GDP per capita in 1600 740.73 630.5 916.31 908.22 578.29 576.8
(225.6) (144.2) (149.3) (167.3) (112.3) (35.3)
GDP per capita in 1700 862.12 622.2 1079.21 980.82 636.0 574.2
(348.4) (208.1) (321.4) (128.2) (136.1) (35.3)
GDP per capita in 1820 988.00 691.7 1321.95 1095.40 719.5 575.5
(373.6) (264.5) (348.7) (125.3) (174.9) (45.7)
Constrainton executive in 1500 1.67 1.73 1.75 1.99 1.46
(0.76) (0.79) (0.56) (0.99) (0.79)
Constrainton executive in 1600 1.67 1.53 1.62 1.54 1.45
(1.01) (0.84) (1.24) (0.59) (0.79)
Constrainton executive in 1700 1.83 1.52 1.83 1.41 1.30
(1.31) (1.17) (1.76) (0.94) (0.76)
Constrainton executive in 1800 2.25 2.18 4.00 1.90 1.00
(1.82) (1.83) (1.79) (1.78) (0.00)
Atlantic coastline-to-area 0.0057 0.0014 0.0118 0.0026 0.00 0.00
(0.0117) (0.0065) (0.0181) (0.0052)

Notes: Firstcolumn is unweightedmeans; other columns are mean values weighted by total populationin year indicated,from
McEvedy and Jones (1978). Standarddeviation is in parentheses. There are 24 European countries in these data. Atlantic
WesternEuropeis England,France,the Netherlands,Portugal,and Spain. Non-Atlantic WesternEuropeis Austria,Belgium,
Denmark, Finland, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Norway, Sweden, and Switzerland. Eastern Europe is Albania, Bulgaria, the
Czech Republic, Greece, Hungary,Poland, Romania, Russia, and Serbia. Asia is India and China. Urbanizationfor Europe
is percentageof populationliving in towns with populationof at least 5,000 at some time between 800 and 1800, from Paul
Bairoch et al. (1988) for Europe;comparabledata for Asia are from Bairoch (1998). GDP per capita is from Maddison (2001).
Constrainton executive is on a scale of 1 to 7, where a higher score indicates more constraints;this is coded using the Polity
IV methodology, as explained in the text. We have not coded constraint on the executive for Asia. Atlantic coast-to-area
includes those partsof Germany,Denmark,and Norway that are on the North Sea. For more detailed definitions and sources,
see Appendix, Table 1.

not simply reflect the tendency of more suc- coastal nations: Atlantic ports grew much
cessful nations to engage in Atlantic trade. faster than other European cities, while Med-
There is no differential growth of Atlantic iterranean ports grew at similar rates to inland
traders before the opening of Atlantic sea cities.
routes, and below we show similar results This evidence weighs against the most pop-
using an exogenous measure of access to the ular theories for the rise of Europe, which em-
Atlantic-ratio of Atlantic coastline to land phasize the continuity between pre-1500 and
area-instead of the distinction between At- post-1500 growth and the importanceof certain
lantic traders and nontraders. Nor do the re- distinctive European characteristics, such as
sults reflect some post-1500 advantage of culture, religion, geography, and features of the
550 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 2005

900
800
CU
S
700
S
6000
>1 0.
500
CQ 400
(D,
0)

0 200
> 100 00

1300 1400 1500 1600 1700 1750 1800

Year

peryear...... Mediterranean
--Atlantic voyages peryear
voyages
FIGURE 3. VOLUME OF ATLANTIC AND MEDITERRANEAN TRADE (VOYAGE EQUIVALENTS PER YEAR), 1300-1800

Europeanstate system.3 Instead, it is consistent Barry R. Weingast, 1989). The critical political
with theories that emphasize the importanceof institutions were those that constrained the
profits made in Atlantic trade, colonialism, and power of the monarchy and allied groups.5
slavery.4 Nevertheless, other evidence suggests Checks on royal power and prerogatives
that overseas trade and the associated profits emerged only when groups that favored them,
were not large enough to be directly responsible that is commercial interests outside the royal
for the process of growth in Europe. Stanley L. circle, became sufficiently powerful politically.
Engrman (1972) and Patrick K. O'Brien From 1500, and especially from 1600, onward,
(1982) demonstrate that the contribution of in countries with nonabsolutist initial institu-
profits from slavery and trade with the rest of tions and easy access to the Atlantic, the rise in
the world to Europeancapital accumulationwas Atlantic trade enriched and strengthenedcom-
modest. O'Brien (1982, p. 2) writes that trans- mercial interests outside the royal circle and
oceanic trade "... could in no way be classified enabled them to demand and obtain the institu-
as decisive for economic growth of Western tional changes necessary for economic growth.
Europe." Although recent work by Joseph E. Although profits from Atlantic tradewere small
Inikori (2002) estimates larger trade flows than relative to GDP, they were still substantial,and
those of O'Brien, his estimates are not large much larger than previous trading profits. For
enough to suggest that European growth was example, Figure 3 shows that by the end of the
driven solely by the direct impact of Atlantic seventeenth century, the volume of Atlantic
trade on profits or resources. tradewas much largerthan that of long-distance
We advance the hypothesis that West Euro- Mediterraneantrade (see the Appendix for the
pean growth duringthis period resulted, in part, construction of these series). The recipients of
from the indirect effects of internationaltrade these profits became very rich by the standards
on institutional development. Although there of seventeenth- and eighteenth-centuryEurope,
were some improvements in economic institu- and typically politically and socially very
tions in the late medieval and early modern powerful.
period, rapid economic development did not These changes did not take place in countries
begin until the emergence of political institu- with highly absolutistinstitutionssuch as Spain,
tions providing secure property rights to a
broader segment of society and allowing free
entry into profitable businesses (Douglass C. 5 It is importantto note that these new political institu-
tions neither protected the rights of all citizens nor were
North and Robert P. Thomas, 1973; North and democratic. They can best be characterizedas oligarchic,
since they increased the political power of wealthy mer-
chants, and at least in the British case, of the gentry and
3 See, e.g., Max Weber (1905), Eric Jones (1981), John nascent industrialinterests. Nevertheless, they constituteda
A. Hall (1985), and David S. Landes (1998). distinct improvement over the previous set of institutions,
4 E.g., Eric E. Williams (1944), Andre Gunder Frank which placed many fewer checks on the power of the
(1978), and Immanuel M. Wallerstein (1974-1980). monarchy.
VOL.95 NO. 3 ACEMOGLUET AL.: THE RISE OF EUROPE 551

Portugal,and to a large extent France,where the and Andrei Shleifer, 1993). Distinct from these
crownwas able to closely controlthe expansionof approaches,however, we offer an explanation,
trade.Consequently,in these countries,it was the based on the interactionbetween Atlantic trade
monarchyand groupsallied with it that were the and medieval political institutions, of why
main beneficiariesof the earlyprofitsfrom Atlan- strong private propertyrights emerged in West-
tic tradeandplunder,andgroupsfavoringchanges ern Europe, especially in Britain and the Neth-
in political institutionsdid not become powerful erlands, starting in the sixteenth century.
enoughto inducethem.Ourhypothesis,therefore, Although some scholars have noted the impor-
predicts an importantinteractionbetween initial tant role of overseas merchants in particular
institutionsandAtlantictrade,which is the pattern instances of political change during this period
we find in the data. (most notably Robert Brenner, 2003, and
The major premise presented in this paper is Steven Pincus, 2002, in the British case), we are
consistent with the emphasis of a number of not aware of a theory along the lines developed
historians, including, among others, Ralph in this paper.
Davis (1973a), Jan de Vries (1984), Paul The paper is organized as follows. Section I
Bairoch (1988), FernandBraudel(1992), and de documents the key premise of the paper, and
Vries and Ad van der Woude (1997). Although shows that the patternseen in Figures 1 and 2 is
this historical literatureemphasizes the differ- robust. Section II develops our hypothesis for
ential growth of Atlantic ports and Atlantic na- the rise of Europe and the role played by At-
tions, to the best of our knowledge, there are no lantic trade in this process, and provides histor-
other studies documenting the quantitativeim- ical evidence supporting our interpretation.
portance of Atlantic tradersand Atlantic ports, Sections III and IV provide evidence on some
or showing that the differentialgrowth of West- implications of our hypothesis (Section III
ern Europe is accounted for largely by the shows that the evolution of European institu-
growth of Atlantic traders. tions is closely linked to Atlantic trade, and
On the theoreticalside, our hypothesis builds Section IV documents an importantinteraction
on the notion that institutional change, even between initial institutionsand Atlantic tradein
when socially beneficial, will be resisted by European economic growth). Section V con-
social groups that stand to lose economic rents cludes. The Appendix summarizesthe construc-
or political power. Consequently,the process of tion of the variables used in the empirical
institutionalchange involves significantconflict analysis, and further detail can be found in
between different groups-in the European Acemoglu et al. (2002b).
context, between the monarchy and its allies,
versus commercial interests outside the royal I. Atlantic Trade and the Rise of Europe
circle.6 Our historical account can also be
viewed as a marriagebetween the Marxistthesis A. Data
linking the rise of the bourgeoisie and the de-
velopment of the world economy (e.g., among We use three data series to measureeconomic
others, Williams, 1944; Frank, 1978; and development. First, we construct estimates of
Wallerstein, 1974-1980) and the neoclassical urbanization based on the urban population
emphasis on the development of political insti- numbers of Bairoch et al. (1988). This is a
tutions and secure property rights in Western comprehensive dataset with information on all
Europe (e.g., North and Thomas, 1973; Eric L. 2,200 European cities that had, at some time
Jones, 1981; North, 1981; J. BradfordDe Long between 800 and 1800, 5,000 or more inhabit-
ants.7 We use these data as our measure of
6
See, for example, North (1981), MancurOlson (1982),
urban population and divide by the population
Per Krusell and Jose-Victor Rios-Rull (1996), Stephen Par-
ente and EdwardC. Prescott (1999), Acemoglu and Robin-
son (2000, 2002), and Raghuram G. Rajan and Luigi 7 These data begin in 800, and there are estimates for
Zingales (2003). Ronald Rogowski (1989) is particularly every 100 years until 1700, then for every 50 years through
notable in this context, since he also emphasizes how trade 1850. Bairoch et al. (1988) emphasize, however, that esti-
affects political coalitions via its impact on factor prices, mates before 1300 are rough and less reliable (and they skip
although he does not focus on how trade might induce the year 1100 due to lack of information).These data were
institutionalchange by strengtheningcommercial interests. used previously by De Long and Shleifer (1993).
552 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 2005

estimates of McEvedy and Jones (1978) to cal- firm the patternsshown in Figures 1 and 2. In
culate urbanization(percentage of the popula- the regression analysis, we will report both
tion living in cities with more than 5,000 weighted and unweighted results. The bottom
inhabitants).We also use estimatesof urbaniza- thirdof the table also shows the evolution of our
tion rates for Asia from the quantitative and measure of institutions, constrainton the exec-
qualitative assessments of Bairoch (1988). utive, which we will be described in greater
Bairoch (1988, ch. 1) and de Vries (1976, p. detail and used in Section III.
164) arguethat only areaswith high agricultural
productivityand a developed transportationnet- B. Economic Growth in Europe
work could supportlarge urbanpopulations. In
addition, in Acemoglu et al. (2002a) we pre- Figures 1A and IB show the evolution of
sented evidence that both in the time series and urbanizationrates in Western and EasternEu-
the cross section there is a close association rope, and contrastthe behaviorof Atlantictrad-
between urbanization and income per capita ers versus non-Atlantictraders.We firstlook at
before, as well as after, industrialization.We Atlantic traders, since the main beneficiaries
therefore take urbanizationas a proxy for GDP from the Atlantic should be those countriesthat
per capita. engaged in Atlantic trade and colonialism.
Second, we use estimates of GDP per capita However, whetheror not a countryis an Atlan-
from Maddison (2001). These estimates startin tic trader is clearly endogenous, i.e., it is the
1500 and are available for 1600, 1700, 1820, outcome of some political or economic process.
and then more frequently. Note that these esti- For this reason, we also present results using a
mates are no more than educatedguesses, espe- measure of access to the Atlantic, which is a
cially before 1820. We thereforethink of these country-level geographic characteristic.
GDP data as a check on our results using ur- We can test the idea that West European
banization data. growth after 1500 was due primarilyto growth
Third, we use the European city-level data in countries involved in Atlantic tradeor with a
from Bairoch et al. (1988) to investigate which high potential for Atlantic trade by estimating
urban centers were driving demographic and the following regression equation:
economic growth, and also to contrast the
growth of Atlantic ports to other ports and to (1) u,= d, + 8+ E a, *WEj'd,
inland cities. t? 1600
Table 1 gives the estimates of urbanization
and income per capita at various dates. The first + d, + Xj, + ejt
column is for the whole sample and is un- tr--1500 -,'PATj' t
weighted. The second column is weighted by
population in the correspondingyear, giving a where is urbanizationin countryj at time t,
better sense of the aggregate changes. The re- WEjis ujt
a dummy indicatingwhetherthe country
maining columns give weighted means for At- is in Western Europe, the d,'s denote year ef-
lantic traders(Britain, France, the Netherlands, fects, the 6j's denote country effects, Xj, is a
Portugal, and Spain), for West Europeancoun- vector of other covariates, and Ej, is a distur-
tries that were not Atlantic traders (Austria, bance term. In addition, PATP,our measure of
Belgium, Denmark,Finland, Germany,Ireland, the potential for Atlantic trade,is a dummy for
Italy, Norway, Sweden, and Switzerland), for Atlantic trader (Britain, France, the Nether-
East European countries, and for the Asian lands, Portugal, and Spain) or alternativelythe
countries in our sample.8 These numbers con- Atlantic coastline-to-arearatio (in both cases, a
time-invariant characteristic of the country).
The ,t's, the coefficients on the potential for
8 We take current countries as the unit of observation.

Although these do not always correspondto the independent


polities of the time, this discrepancy should not bias our
empirical inference. For example, if we had data on each number of observations, the standard errors would be
Italiancity-state, their average would show the same pattern smaller. The analysis of city-level growth in Section I B is
as our single Italy observation (presumingthat our data for informativeon differentialgrowth across historicalpolitical
the aggregateof Italy are accurate),but because of the larger boundaries.
VOL.95 NO. 3 ACEMOGLUET AL.: THE RISE OF EUROPE 553

TABLE2-ATLANTIC TRADEAND URBANIZATION


Dependent variable is country-level urbanization

Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel,


Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel, 1300-1850, 1300-1850, 1300-1850, Panel, Panel, 1300-1850,
1300-1850 1000-1850 1300-1850 1000-1850 unweighted with Asia without Britain 1300-1850 1000-1850 unweighted
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)
Potential for Atlantic trade is measured by:

Atlantic traderdummy Atlantic coastline-to-area

Panel A: Flexible specification

p-value for Western Europe [0.00] [0.00] [0.45] [0.09] [0.80] [0.00] [0.12] [0.09] [0.01] [0.78]
X year dummies, 1600-
1850
Potential for Atlantic trade 0.016 0.0086 0.055 0.014 0.018 0.50 0.38 0.75
X 1500 (0.021) (0.019) (0.026) (0.022) (0.016) (0.68) (0.65) (0.87)
Potential for Atlantic trade 0.006 -0.004 0.0495 0.0054 0.0085 0.21 0.03 0.94
x 1600 (0.023) (0.021) (0.028) (0.028) (0.018) (0.68) (0.64) (0.94)
Potential for Atlantic trade 0.032 0.022 0.071 0.032 0.024 1.81 1.64 2.01
x 1700 (0.021) (0.019) (0.028) (0.026) (0.016) (0.63) (0.58) (0.94)
Potential for Atlantic trade 0.032 0.022 0.073 0.032 0.023 2.16 1.99 2.60
x 1750 (0.021) (0.018) (0.028) (0.025) (0.015) (0.62) (0.57) (0.94)
Potential for Atlantic trade 0.048 0.038 0.110 0.047 0.028 3.30 3.12 3.76
x 1800 (0.019) (0.017) (0.028) (0.023) (0.015) (0.57) (0.51) (0.94)
Potential for Atlantic trade 0.085 0.076 0.115 0.084 0.043 5.05 4.88 4.67
x 1850 (0.018) (0.016) (0.028) (0.022) (0.014) (0.51) (0.44) (0.94)
R-squared 0.87 0.85 0.89 0.87 0.82 0.84 0.93 0.94 0.92 0.83
Number of observations 192 240 192 240 192 208 184 192 240 192

Panel B: Structuredspecification

p-value for Western Europe [0.00] [0.00] [0.35] [0.06] [0.83] [0.00] [0.11] [0.16] [0.02] [0.81]
X year dummies, 1600-
1850
Potential for Atlantic trade 0.011 0.0083 0.016 0.011 0.005 0.75 0.65 0.62
X volume of Atlantic (0.0024) (0.0020) (0.0034) (0.0029) (0.0018) (0.07) (0.06) (0.11)
trade
R-squared 0.87 0.85 0.88 0.86 0.81 0.84 0.92 0.92 0.90 0.82
Number of observations 192 240 192 240 192 208 184 192 240 192

Notes: Standarderrors are in parentheses.Panel regressions with full set of country and year dummies; regressions are weighted unless otherwise stated. Weighted
regressionsuse total populationin each year as weights, from McEvedy and Jones (1978). Dependent variable is level of urbanization(percentageof populationliving
in towns that had at least 5,000 populationat some point between 800 and 1800) in each country in each year. Urbanizationin Europe is from Bairoch et al. (1988),
and urbanizationin Asia is from Bairoch (1998). We reportresults with two different measures of potential for Atlantic trade: a dummy for whether a country was
an Atlantic trader(one for Britain, the Netherlands,France, Spain, and Portugal;zero for all others) in columns 3, 4, 5, 6, and 7; and the ratio of Atlantic coastline
to area for the Atlantic tradercountriesplus Belgium, Denmark,Germany,Ireland,and Norway (columns 8, 9, and 10). Column 6 includes the available data on Asia
(just for India and China) and column 7 drops the data for Britain. Volume of Atlantic Trade is the log average numberof voyages per year. For more detailed data
definitions and sources see Appendix, Table 1.

Atlantic tradeand the post-1500 time dummies, Western Europe than in Eastern Europe. For
are the main parametersof interest. Since our example, the point estimates (not shown in the
focus is on the rise of Western Europe as a table to save space) indicate that in the specifi-
whole, our basic regressions are weighted by cation of column 1, West European urbaniza-
population in each year, but we also report tion grew by 6.9 percentage points relative to
unweighted regressions for completeness. East European urbanizationbetween 1500 and
Columns 1 and 2 of Table 2 include only the 1850.
interaction terms between the Western Europe Column 3 allows differential growth for
dummy and dates from 1600, It 1600 t - WEjy countries engaged in Atlantic trade, by includ-
d,, which capture the differential growth of ing the term PATj d,. We include
West Europeancountriesrelative to EasternEu- 1500 as a "specification
It_15000oo t check" on the timing of
rope. The top row reports the p-value from the the effects. We startwith PATjas a dummy for
F-test of the joint significance of these interac- Atlantic trader.Significantpositive estimates of
tions. Column 1 includes data only for 1300-
3t's imply that Atlantic tradersgrew startingin
1850, while column 2 extends the sample back the period between 1500 and 1600. The esti-
to 1000. Consistent with Figure 1A, both spec- mates confirmthe patternseen in Figure 1B and
ifications show significantly faster growth in show large effects from the interactionbetween
554 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 2005

the Atlantic traderdummy and dates after 1600. pean countries are growing faster relative to the
These effects become statisticallysignificantaf- control group, which includes Asian countries
ter 1750; in columns 8-10, the effects are sta- (see Figure lA). Finally, column 7 excludes
tistically significant starting in 1700. For Britain from the sample and shows that the
example, the estimate for 1850, P185 = 0.085, results do not simply reflect British growth.The
implies that urbanizationamong Atlantic trad- estimates in column 7 are about half the size of
ers grew by approximately 8.5 percentage those in the other columns, but they show the
points more than in other Western and Eastern same pattern.
Europeannations. Notice also that the estimate An important concern with the results re-
of in this column, which measures the ported so far is endogeneity. Being an Atlantic
1500oo
differential growth of Atlantic tradersbetween traderis an ex post outcome, and perhapsonly
1300-1400 and 1500, is insignificantand small. countries with high growth potential-or those
This is reassuring;since Atlantic tradewas very that were going to grow anyway-engaged in
limited before 1500, this finding shows that substantialAtlantic trade and colonial activity.
there is no differentialgrowth for Atlantic trad- Belgium, Ireland,Denmark,Germany,andNor-
ers before Atlantic trade actually became way also had access to the Atlantic, either di-
important.9 rectly or via the North Sea, but they did not take
Consistent with the patterns shown in Fig- a major part in long-distance oceanic trade. In
ure 1B, the inclusion of the Atlantic trade columns 8, 9, and 10, we use a geographic
interactions explains almost the entire differ- measure of potential access to the Atlantic,
ential growth of West European nations rela- Atlantic coastline-to-area ratio, as our time-
tive to Eastern Europe. The invariant PATj variable, which gives positive
t?*WEj*
1600
d, terms are no longer statistically
Et-, significant, Atlantic trade potential to all these countries."1
and the point estimates (not shown in the This measure allows Atlantic trade to play a
table) imply that West European urbanization more importantrole in the growth of countries
grew only by 2.9 percentage points relative to with more Atlantic coastline relative to their
Eastern Europe between 1300-1500 and land area.12
1850, as opposed to 6.9 percentage points in
column 1.
Columns 4 and 5 show that the results are " Information on the length of coastline and the land
similar for the 1000-1850 period and when area of particular countries is taken from Integrated
observations are not weighted by population.'0 Coastline Management (http://icm.noaa.gov/country/
Column 6 includes Asian countries. This has ICM-pro.html), which reports a standardized measure.
We use only Atlantic coastline, i.e., omitting coastlines in
little effect on the estimates of the differential the Mediterranean, the Baltic, and the Arctic. Details are
growth of Atlantic traders,but now West Euro- provided in the Appendix of Acemoglu et al. (2002b). It
is important to exclude the Baltic coastlines of Denmark
and Germany from our measure, since significant Baltic
trade predated the rise of Atlantic trade, and economic
9 Although the analysis above does not count Denmark growth driven by Baltic trade could be an alternative
and Sweden as Atlantic traders,Sweden had a small colony explanation for the patterns we observe. In any case, our
on the Delaware river 1637-1681 and Denmarkcontrolled results are generally robust to including the Baltic or the
several small Caribbeanislands (now the U.S. Virgin Is- Arctic coastlines. For example, we obtain very similar
lands). To check the robustness of our results, we also results to those reported in Tables 2 and 3 when we
experimented with a more inclusive definition of Atlantic include the west coastline of Sweden, or when we include
traderthat includes Denmarkand Sweden, with results very the entire Norwegian coastline on the Arctic and the
similar to those reported in column 3. The p-value for entire German coastline on the Baltic. Our results are also
Western Europe X year interactions increases to [0.51], generally similar when we include all the coastline of
while the pattern of coefficients on potential for Atlantic Sweden, Germany, Norway, and the entire Baltic coast-
trade X year dummies is largely unchanged;the interactions line of Denmark, but the size of the coastline-to-area
before 1700 are insignificant, then 0.035 (s.e. = 0.022) in times year interactions are smaller than in our baseline,
1700, 0.035 (s.e. = 0.021) in 1750, 0.046 (s.e. = 0.02) in and Western Europe times year interactions become sig-
1800, and 0.08 (s.e. = 0.02) in 1850. nificant.
0oIn column 4, the interactionbetween the West Euro- 12
Alternatively, we could use the Atlantic coastline-to-
pean dummy and the post-1500 dates is significant at the area measure as an instrument for the Atlantic trader
10-percent level, which reflects the lower level of East dummy. The results we report can be thought of as the
European urbanization in the base period, which is now reducedform for this IV strategy(a univariateregressionof
1000-1400. the Atlantic traderdummy on the coastline-to-areameasure
VOL. 95 NO. 3 ACEMOGLUET AL.: THE RISE OF EUROPE 555

The results using the coastline-to-areamea- of In AT,. In all columns, the estimate of P, the
sure for PATj are similar to those using the coefficient on the interactionterm between the
Atlantic trader dummy. Most notably, the dif- log volume of Atlantic trade and potential for
ferential growth related to the Atlantic, now Atlantic trade at the country level, is highly
captured by interactions with the Atlantic significant, while the interactionterms between
coastline-to-arearatio, is still strong; the point Western Europe and dates from 1600 onward
estimates for the 3's are significant starting in are again insignificant. Notably, the R2 of this
1700 and quantitativelylarge. For example, the more restrictive regression is close to the R2 of
coefficient 131850 = 5.05 indicates approxi- the flexible specifications reported in panel A.
mately 6.5 percentagepoints more urbanization These results suggest that the significant inter-
growth in the Netherlandsthan in Italy between action between potential for Atlantic trade and
1300-1400 and 1850 (the Atlantic coastline-to- dates after 1600 is due to the importance of
area ratio for the Netherlandsis 0.013 and for Atlantic trade, not some other parallel process.
Italy it is 0). This explains over half of the Table 3, which has the same structure as
differential 12-percentage-point actual urban- Table 2, provides regression evidence using log
ization growth between Italy and the Nether- GDP per capita as the dependentvariable.Mad-
lands between these two dates. Other dison (2001) reports estimates of GDP per cap-
specifications using the Atlantic coastline-to- ita for 1500, 1600, 1700, 1820, and 1870. We
area measure in columns 9 and 10 give similar take 1500 as the base year, and add interactions
results. between our measure of potential for Atlantic
Equation(1) allows for an arbitrarypatternof trade, PATj, and the dates from 1600 on to
differential growth in Atlantic traders.Instead, capture the importance of Atlantic trade for
we might expect the differential growth of At- the country (so we can no longer test for pre-
lantic traders to be related to the volume of existing trends using the interaction between
Atlantic trade. For this reason, in panel B we PATj and 1500). Output numbers for 1870 are
report results from estimating a structured alreadyheavily influencedby differentialindus-
model of the form trializationexperiences of various countries, so
our baseline specification stops in 1820. For
(2) + j?+ I completeness, we also report regressions that
ujt= dt t21600
at WEj'dt extend the sample to 1870.
Parallelto our results in Table 2, West Euro-
+ p[ PA Tj In ATt + Xj y + ,jt pean countries grow faster after 1500, although
t this patternis somewhat less pronounced,espe-
where AT, denotes our estimate of the aggregate cially when we limit the sample to 1500-1820.
volume of Atlantic trade, shown in Figure 3. The interactions between the Atlantic trader
The construction of this variable is explained dummy and the dates after 1600 are typically
briefly in the Appendix, and furtherdetails and significant startingeither in 1600 or 1700, and
robustnessresults can be found in Acemoglu et quantitativelylarge. For example,the estimateof
al. (2002b).
31820 = 0.27 in column 3 indicatesthat Atlantic
Note that the model in equation (2) is more tradersgrew, on average, 31 percent (=0.27 log
restrictivethan that in (1), since we are forcing points) more than non-AtlantictraderWest Euro-
the patternof P,'s in (1) to be the same as that pean nationsbetween 1500 and 1820. Columns4
to 7 reportsimilarresultsto those in Table 2. The
patternis the same when the sampleis extendedto
in our samplehas an R2of 0.30). Nevertheless, we preferthe 1870, with unweightedregressions,when Britain
specification in the text, since it is plausible that, even is excluded from the sample, and when Asian
conditional on being an Atlantic trader, a country with
greater Atlantic coastline will trade and grow more than
countries are included. Columns 8 to 10 report
another with less coastline, making such an IV procedure similarresultsusing the Atlanticcoastline-to-area
invalid. In fact, a comparisonof columns 3-7 with columns measure.
8-10 shows that the fit of the models with the Atlantic
Panel B of Table 3 reportsstructuredmodels
coastline-to-arearatio is marginallybetter than those with
the Atlantic trader dummy, because the former measure similar to (2) where we include the interaction
gives greaterpotential for trade to Britain and the Nether- term, PATj ? In AT, instead of the full set of
lands, which have relatively high coastline-to-arearatios. post-1500 interactions between PATj and time
556 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 2005

TABLE 3-ATLANTIC TRADE AND GDP PER CAPITA


Dependent variable is country-level log GDP per capita

Panel,
Panel, Panel, 1500-1820, Panel,
Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel, 1500-1820, 1500-1820, without Panel, Panel, 1500-1820,
1500-1820 1500-1870 1500-1820 1500-1870 unweighted with Asia Britain 1500-1820 1500-1870 unweighted
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)

Potential for Atlantic trade is measured by:

Atlantic traderdummy Atlantic coastline-to-area

Panel A: Flexible specification

p-value for Western Europe X [0.44] [0.05] [0.92] [0.23] [0.17] [0.01] [0.89] [0.97] [0.58] [0.31]
year dummies, 1600-1820 or
-1870
Potential for Atlantic trade x 0.14 0.15 0.16 0.14 0.13 4.43 4.46 3.42
1600 (0.07) (0.11) (0.07) (0.13) (0.07) (2.42) (3.61) (2.21)
Potential for Atlantic trade x 0.18 0.19 0.21 0.18 0.14 8.84 8.80 6.32
1700 (0.07) (0.10) (0.07) (0.12) (0.06) (2.27) (3.40) (2.21)
Potential for Atlantic trade X 0.27 0.27 0.18 0.27 0.20 12.03 11.89 8.06
1820 (0.06) (0.10) (0.07) (0.11) (0.06) (2.10) (3.14) (2.21)
Potential for Atlantic trade X 0.22 15.84
1870 (0.09) (2.93)
R-squared 0.94 0.94 0.96 0.95 0.96 0.92 0.96 0.96 0.96 0.96
Number of observations 96 120 96 120 96 104 92 96 120 96

Panel B: Structuredspecification

p-value for Western Europe X [0.44] [0.051 [0.92] [0.48] [0.14] [0.01] [0.88] [0.99] [0.54] [0.23]
year dummies, 1600-1820 or
-1870
Potential for Atlantic trade x 0.069 0.040 0.047 0.069 0.051 3.21 3.18 2.22
volume of Atlantic trade (0.016) (0.017) (0.018) (0.028) (0.015) (0.53) (0.50) (0.58)
R-squared 0.94 0.94 0.96 0.95 0.96 0.92 0.96 0.96 0.96 0.96
Number of observations 96 120 96 120 96 104 92 96 120 96

Notes: Standarderrors are in parentheses.Panel regressions with full set of country and year dummies: regressions are weighted unless otherwise stated. Weighted
regressions use total populationin each year as weights, from McEvedy and Jones (1978). Dependentvariableis log GDP per capita, from Maddison(2001). We report
results with two different measures of potential for Atlantic trade: a dummy for whether a country was an Atlantic trader(one for Britain, the Netherlands,France,
Spain, and Portugal;zero for all others) in columns 3, 4, 5, 6, and 7; and the ratio of Atlantic coastline to area for the Atlantic tradercountriesplus Belgium, Denmark,
Germany,Ireland,and Norway (columns 8, 9, and 10). Column 6 includes the available data on Asia (just for Indiaand China) and column 7 drops the datafor Britain.
Volume of Atlantic trade is the log average numberof voyages per year. For more detailed data definitions and sources, see Appendix, Table 1.

dummies. This more structured specification regressions. The overall patterns are not af-
again shows that the differential growth of fected. To save space, Table 4 reportsonly the
Western Europe from 1600 is closely linked to structuredspecifications of equation (2).
the extension of Atlantic trader. Weber (1905) and Landes (1998) argue that
Overall both Table 2 and Table 3 show an religion is an important determinantof eco-
importantrole for Atlantic trade in West Euro- nomic and social development. To assess the
pean growth. When the effect of Atlantic trade importance of religion, we allow Protestant
is not taken into account, the estimates of ac's countries to grow at rates different from non-
are significant,positive, and large: Western Eu- Protestantcountriesby interactinga dummyfor
rope is growing faster than EasternEurope and being a majority Protestant country in 1600
Asia. Once Atlantic trade interactions are in- with year dummies starting in 1600.13 The p-
cluded, ac's are typically no longer significant, values from the joint significance test reported
while the effect of Atlantic tradeis very strong. in columns 1 of panels A and C show that when
Furthermore,the estimates show no evidence of the dependent variable is the urbanizationrate,
differential growth by Atlantic traders before these interactionsare either insignificantor only
the age of Atlantic trade. marginally significant. In contrast, when the
dependent variable is log GDP per capita and
C. OtherDeterminantsof EconomicPerformance

To check the robustness of our results, 13 See the Appendix for the constructionof the variables
Table 4 adds a numberof covariatesto our basic used in this subsection.
VOL.95 NO. 3 ACEMOGLUET AL.: THE RISE OF EUROPE 557

TABLE 4-ROBUSTNESS CHECKS

Panel, Panel,
Panel, Panel, 1300 to 1850, Panel, Panel, Panel, 1500 to 1820, Panel,
1300-1850, 1300 to 1850, controlling 1300 to 1850, 1500-1820, 1500 to 1820, controlling 1500 to 1820,
controlling controlling for Roman controlling controlling controlling for Roman controlling
for religion for wars heritage for latitude for religion for wars heritage for latitude
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Using Atlantic traderdummy measure of potential for Atlantic trade


Panel A: Dependent variable is level of urbanization Panel B: Dependent variable is log GDP per capita

p-value for Western Europe X [0.67] [0.42] [0.49] [0.09] [0.24] [0.91] [0.15] [0.85]
year dummies, 1600-1850
Atlantic traderdummy x volume 0.013 0.011 0.011 0.011 0.089 0.070 0.125 0.078
of Atlantic trade (0.002) (0.003) (0.003) (0.002) (0.013) (0.017) (0.017) (0.015)
p-value for ProtestantX year [0.07] [0.00]
Wars per year in preceding -0.0006 0.075
century (0.008) (0.029)
p-value for Roman heritage X [0.89] [0.00]
year
p-value for latitude X year [0.11] [0.00]
R-squared 0.89 0.89 0.89 0.89 0.97 0.95 0.97 0.97
Number of observations 192 176 192 192 96 88 96 96

Using Atlantic coastline-to-areameasure of potential for Atlantic trade


Panel C: Dependent variable is level of urbanization Panel D: Dependent variable is log GDP per capita

p-value for Western Europe X [0.19] [0.23] [0.39] [0.09] [0.99] [0.98] [0.71] [0.81]
year dummies, 1600-1850
Coastline-to-areaX volume of 0.79 0.76 0.75 0.78 2.78 3.33 3.32 2.96
Atlantic trade (0.08) (0.08) (0.07) (0.07) (0.54) (0.56) (0.54) (0.56)
p-value for ProtestantX year [0.51] [0.05]
Wars per year in preceding 0.0082 0.033
century (0.007) (0.026)
p-value for Roman heritage X [0.77] [0.32]
year
p-value for latitude X year [0.52] [0.38]
R-squared 0.93 0.93 0.92 0.93 0.97 0.96 0.97 0.97
Number of observations 192 176 192 192 96 88 96 96

Notes: Standard errors are in parentheses. Weighted panel regressions with full set of country and year dummies. Weights are total population of country
in each year from McEvedy and Jones (1978). Dependent variable in panels A and C is level of urbanization (percent of population living in towns with
more than 5,000 population). Urbanization in Europe is from Bairoch et al. (1988). Dependent variable in panels B and D is log GDP per capita, from Maddison
(2001). Panels A and B use the Atlantic trader dummy as the measure of potential for Atlantic trade (one for Britain, France, Spain, Portugal, and
the Netherlands; zero for all others). Panels C and D use the ratio of Atlantic coastline to area. Volume of Atlantic Trade is the log average number of
voyages per year. Protestant is a dummy for whether country was majority Protestant in 1600. Protestant x year is the Protestant dummy interacted with year
dummies for 1600 and after. Wars per year are in preceding century through 1700, 1700-1750 for 1750, 1750-1800 for 1800, and 1800-1850 for 1850. Roman
heritage is dummy for whether country was in the Roman Empire; this is interacted with year dummies for 1600 and after. Latitude is distance from the equator
for capital city of this country today; this is interacted with year dummies for 1600 and after. For more detailed data definitions and sources, see Appendix,
Table 1.

we use the Atlantic traderdummy for our po- Many social scientists view war-making as
tential Atlantic trademeasure (panel B), there is an important factor in the process of state
a significant effect from these religion times building and subsequent economic develop-
year interactions. Nevertheless, this has little ment (e.g., Otto Hintze, 1975; Paul Kennedy,
impact on the pattern of differential growth 1987; Charles Tilly, 1990). Incidence of wars
between Western and Eastern Europe, or be- might also proxy for the importance of inter-
tween Atlantic and non-Atlantic traders.More- state competition, which many historians, in-
over, the quantitative effects of Protestantism cluding Jones (1981) and Hall (1985), have
on economic growth are smaller than those of emphasized. To assess the importance of
Atlantic trade.14 wars, in columns 2 and 6 we include a vari-
able which is the average number of years at
war during the previous period (a century or
14 The point estimates (not reported)imply that Protes-
tant countries experienced 4.5 percentage points greater
urbanizationgrowthbetween 1500 and 1850, and 30 percent tions, including the Protestantdummy interactedwith dates
more GDP growthbetween 1500 and 1820. The correspond- from 1600, are 8.4 percentagepoints more urbanizationand
ing numbers for Atlantic traders in the flexible specifica- 41 percent more GDP growth.
558 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 2005

half-century).We find that this variableitself is Bairoch et al. (1988). Figure 4A shows that the
insignificantin the urbanizationregressionsand urbanexpansion of WesternEurope was driven
has no effect on the patternsdocumentedso far.15 by cities that were Atlantic ports. Table 5 con-
A popular view sees the roots of European firms this pattern with regression analysis. It
growth in the Roman Empire (e.g., Perry estimates models similar to (1), with the log of
Anderson, 1974; Jones, 1981; Landes, 1998), city-level urban population as the dependent
and perhaps in the culture of Ancient Greece. variable. The key right-hand side variable is
To investigate whether Roman heritage is im- the interaction between a dummy indicating
portant for the rise of Europe, we created a whether the city is an Atlantic port (or in our
dummy that indicates whether a country was alternative specification, whether it is a po-
part of the Roman Empire. We then interacted tential Atlantic port), denoted by APi, and
this variable with dates from 1600 onward to dummies from 1500.16 The sample for all re-
see whether there is differential growth de- gressions in Table 5 is the balanced panel of
pending on the extent of Roman heritage (col- cities for which we have observations in each
umns 3 and 7). These interactions are date.17
typically insignificant and do not affect the In column 1, APi is a dummy for Atlantic
patterns reported in the previous tables. The port, and observations are weighted by cur-
only exception is when we use log GDP per rent population in each year. The interactions
capita as the dependent variable and the At- between the Atlantic port dummy and dates
lantic trader dummy for PATj. But in this after 1600, the APi d, terms, are statistically
?
case, the results indicate that countries with and economically significant and positive. For
Roman heritage grew more rapidly between example, the coefficient of 0.79 implies that
1400 and 1600, and significantly more slowly Atlantic ports grew approximately 120 per-
thereafter. cent (P-0.79 log points) relative to other cities
Finally, in columns 4 and 8 we add inter- between 1300-1400 and 1800. Notably, there
actions between distance from the equator appears to be no differential growth of Atlan-
(the absolute value of the latitude of the na- tic ports before 1600, once again supporting
tion's capital) and dates from 1600 to see the notion that the growth of these ports is
whether the move of economic activity away related to the emergence of trading and colo-
from Southern toward Northern Europe can nial opportunities via the Atlantic. In the bot-
explain the rise of Atlantic nations. Once tom panel, we report results from a structured
again the addition of these variables does not specification similar to equation (2). Once
affect the importance of Atlantic trade, and again, the coefficient on the interaction term
the latitude interactions are typically insignif- between the volume of Atlantic trade and the
icant (except in panel B, where the point
estimates have the wrong sign).
16 See the Appendix of Acemoglu et al. (2002b) for the
D. Urban Expansion and Atlantic Ports list of Atlantic ports in our panel. In Figures 4 and5, we use
the definition of actual Atlantic port. In the regression
We next turn to an analysis of data on the analysis, we also reportresults with a dummy for potential
Atlantic port. The distinction between Atlantic port and
population of individual cities compiled by
potential Atlantic port parallels our use of Atlantic trader
dummy and the coastline-to-areameasure of potential for
Atlantic trade in Tables 2, 3, and 4.
15 As an alternative exercise more favorable to the war 17 The focus on a balanced panel of cities avoids

hypothesis, we also controlled for the average number of problems of composition bias, which would result from
years at war that ended in victory during the previous 50 or the fact that cities enter the dataset only once they exceed
100 years. To the extent that rich nations are more likely to a certain threshold (typically 5,000 people). For example,
succeed in war, the coefficient on this variable will be if an area is growing rapidly, the population of the
biased upward. The inclusion of this variable has remark- smaller cities in this area will also grow and exceed the
ably little effect on our estimates of the interactionbetween relevant threshold, but the addition of cities with popu-
access to the Atlantic (or Atlantic trader)and the post-1500 lation around 5,000 may reduce the average populationof
years (or the volume of Atlantictrade),and this war variable the cities in this area. Nevertheless, in practice this bias
itself is insignificant when the dependent variable is the does not seem to be important, and in Acemoglu et al.
urbanizationrate and marginally significant with log GDP (2002b) we report similar results using a larger, unbal-
per capita. anced panel of cities.
VOL.95 NO. 3 ACEMOGLUET AL.: THE RISE OF EUROPE 559

Year
-- West European cities Atlantic ports -- East European cities
FIGURE4A. AVERAGEOF LOG CITY POPULATION
IN ATLANTICPORTS,WEST EUROPEANCITIESTHAT ARE NOT ATLANTIC
PORTS,AND EASTERNEUROPE(BALANCEDPANEL), 1300-1850

5.

4.5

.0

T13 400OT1555 165 1700 1755018015

Year

-- InlandWestEuropean
cities--*--Atlantic
ports- ports
---Mediterranean
FIGURE4B. AVERAGEOF LOG CITY POPULATIONIN ATLANTICPORTS,MEDITERRANEAN PORTS,AND WEST EUROPEANCITIES
THAT ARE NOT PORTS(BALANCEDPANEL), 1300-1850

Atlantic port dummy is highly significant, and Amsterdam to show that the results are not
she R2 of this more restrictive regression is driven by these two major cities. The coeffi-
almost the same as the regression reported in cients on Atlantic port times year interactions
the top panel. are approximately halved from 1700 onward,
Column 2 reports estimates from an un- but they remain significant. Column 6 adds a
weighted regression.The results are similar,but full set of country times year interactions to
quantitatively smaller, since large Atlantic show the differential growth of Atlantic ports
ports, such as London and Amsterdam, no relative to other cities in the same country.The
longer get more weight. Columns 3 and 4 report coefficients on Atlantic port times year interac-
weighted and unweighted estimates from simi- tions after 1700 are about half those of column
lar models, with a dummy for potentialAtlantic 1, but still highly statistically significant.
port, that is, any city that in our balanced panel
could have been used as a port for Atlantic
trade. The results are similar to those in col- actual-Atlantic ports from 1400 to 1500, some of the
umns 1 and 2.18 Column 5 drops London and coefficients on potential Atlantic port are higher than the
correspondingcoefficients on Atlantic port. However, cu-
mulative growth between 1500 and any subsequentdate is
always higher for Atlantic ports than for potential Atlantic
18 To allow for the specificationtest discussed in the text, ports. It should also be noted that some potential Atlantic
these regressions use 1300-1400 as the base period. Be- ports flourished as a result of secondary trade from the
cause there was rapid growth in a few potential-but not Atlantic.
560 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 2005

TABLE5-GROWTHOFATLANTIC PORTS
Dependent variable is log city population

Balanced panel, Balanced panel,


Balanced 1300-1850, weighted
panel, weighted, Balanced 1300-1850,
Balanced Balanced Balanced Balanced 1300-1850, with full set panel, with
panel, panel, panel, panel, weighted, of country weighted Mediterranean
1300-1850, 1300-1850, 1300-1850, 1300-1850, without London X year 1300-1850, and Atlantic
weighted unweighted weighted unweighted and Amsterdam interactions with Asia ports
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Panel A: Flexible specification

Atlantic port Potential Atlantic port Atlantic port

p-value for Western Europe [0.34] [0.05] [0.30] [0.16] [0.28] [0.30] [0.41] [0.32]
X year dummies, 1600-
1850
Atlantic port x 1500 -0.04 -0.05 0.027 0.048 -0.008 -0.072 -0.03 -0.05
(0.19) (0.20) (0.17) (0.16) (0.20) (0.20) (0.20) (0.19)
Atlantic port X 1600 0.36 0.46 0.41 0.43 0.41 0.36 0.36 0.40
(0.16) (0.20) (0.14) (0.16) (0.17) (0.17) (0.16) (0.16)
Atlantic port X 1700 0.71 0.62 0.76 0.76 0.297 0.47 0.71 0.74
(0.14) (0.20) (0.13) (0.16) (0.17) (0.17) (0.15) (0.15)
Atlantic port x 1750 0.70 0.71 0.79 0.89 0.26 0.46 0.7 0.72
(0.14) (0.20) (0.13) (0.16) (0.16) (0.16) (0.15) (0.14)
Atlantic port X 1800 0.79 0.92 0.95 1.10 0.32 0.57 0.799 0.84
(0.14) (0.20) (0.12) (0.16) (0.15) (0.15) (0.14) (0.14)
Atlantic port X 1850 1.09 1.00 1.19 1.23 0.48 0.46 1.09 1.10
(0.13) (0.20) (0.12) (0.16) (0.14) (0.14) (0.14) (0.13)
p-value for Mediterranean
port X year dummies, [0.19]
1500-1850
R-squared 0.92 0.79 0.92 0.80 0.89 0.95 0.94 0.92
Number of observations 1544 1544 1544 1544 1528 1544 1624 1544

Panel B: Structuredspecification

p-value for Western Europe [0.23] [0.04] [0.23] [0.10] [0.31] [0.33] [0.30] [0.20]
x year dummies, 1600-
1850
Volume of Atlantic trade x 0.17 0.16 0.17 0.16 0.065 0.078 0.17 0.17
Atlantic port (0.02) (0.02) (0.017) (0.024) (0.019) (0.018) (0.018) (0.017)
p-value for Mediterranean
Port X year dummies, [0.14]
1500-1850
R-squared 0.92 0.79 0.92 0.79 0.89 0.95 0.94 0.92
Number of observations 1544 1544 1544 1544 1528 1544 1624 1544

Notes: Dependent variable is log city population, from Bairoch et al. (1988). Weighted regressions use current level of city population in each year as weights. All
columns reportbalanced panel regressionsfor 1300, 1400, 1500, 1600, 1700, 1750, 1800, and 1850, using only cities for which we have data in all eight time periods.
The Atlantic port dummy equals one for a city used as an Atlantic port. Potential Atlantic ports are all ports that could have been used for Atlantic tradeand include
Atlantic ports plus ports in Belgium, Germany, and Ireland(there are no potential Atlantic ports in Denmark or Norway in our balanced panel). Volume of Atlantic
tradeis log average voyages per year; this is multiplied by the Atlantic port dummy (or by the potential Atlantic port dummy);the coefficient on this interactionterm
is multipliedby 100. Year dummies are included for all years from 1400. Western Europe X year dummies are included for all years from 1600. For a list of Atlantic
ports and potential Atlantic ports, see the Appendix of Acemoglu et al. (2002b).

Column 7 adds Asian cities from Tertius Chan- column 8 show that Mediterranean portsgrew at
dler (1987), so now West European cities are similarrates to inland Europeancities; what we
being compared to both East European and findis not a generalporteffect butanAtlanticport
Asian cities. The results are similar, but also effect.
show the differential growth of all West Euro- Was the urban and economic expansion of
pean cities relative to Asian cities.19 Atlantic nations driven solely by the growth of
Is there somethingspecial aboutports, or is it Atlantic ports? Figure 5A shows the expansion
Atlanticports that are behaving differentlyafter of Iberian (Spanish and Portuguese) Atlantic
1500? To answer this question, Figure 4B and ports, other Iberian cities, and West European
inland cities. Almost all of the differential
growth of Spain and Portugal comes from At-
'9 We also investigatedthe importanceof the samecontrols lantic ports. In fact, non-Atlanticpartsof Spain
used in Table 4 for country-levelgrowth.The results,which
are reportedin Acemoglu et al. (2002b), show thatthe pattern and Portugal grew more slowly than West Eu-
in Table 5 is robustto the inclusionof these controls. ropeaninland cities. Relevant to our hypothesis
VOL.95 NO. 3 ACEMOGLUET AL.: THE RISE OF EUROPE 561

45

o
8A 4 --Aai i
.5-

-Iberian cities, not Atlantic ports


- Iberian Atlanticports
-.- Inland West European cities
IN IBERIANATLANTICPORTS,OTHERIBERIANCITIESTHATARE NOT
FIGURE5A. AVERAGEOF LOG CITY POPULATION
ATLANTIC ANDINLAND
PORTS, WESTEUROPEAN
CITIES PANEL),1300-1850
(BALANCED

6-

1300 1400 1500 1600 1700 1750 1800 1850

Year

-x- British
citiesnotAtlantic
ports
- British
Atlantic
ports
-- Inland
West Europeancities
FIGURE 5B. AVERAGE OF LOG CITY POPULATION IN BRITISH ATLANTIC PORTS, OTHER BRITISH CITIES THAT ARE NOT
ATLANTIC ANDINLAND
PORTS, WESTEUROPEAN
CITIES PANEL),1300-1850
(BALANCED

below, this Iberian pattern contrasts with the for Atlantic trade and post-1500 economic de-
steady growth of non-Atlantic British cities velopment, and suggests that the opportunities
shown in Figure 5B. (Notice that the non- to trade via the Atlantic, and the associated
Atlantic British line starts below the West Eu- profits from colonialism and slavery, played an
ropean line and overtakes it by 1850; see importantrole in the rise of Europe. This evi-
Acemoglu et al., 2002b, for furtherevidence.) dence weighs againsttheories linking the rise of
Western Europeto the continuationof pre-1500
E. Interpretation trends driven by certain distinctive characteris-
tics of European nations or cultures, such as
The evidence presentedso far has established Roman heritage or religion.
a significant relationshipbetween the potential At face value, this evidenceis more consistent
562 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 2005

with theories emphasizing the direct contri- II. Our Hypothesis


bution of profits from Atlantic trade, colonial-
ism, and slavery, such as those advanced A. The Argument
by Williams (1944), Frank (1978), and Wal-
lerstein (1974-1980). It is undoubtedly true Our hypothesis is that Atlantic trade-the
that colonial relations with the New World and opening of the sea routes to the New World,
Asia contributedto Europeangrowth. Neverthe- Africa, and Asia and the building of colonial
less, quantitativeanalyses, for example, Enger- empires--contributed to the process of West
man (1972), Engerman and O'Brien (1991), European growth between 1500 and 1850, not
O'Brien (1982), and Bairoch (1993, ch. 5), sug- only through direct economic effects, but also
gest that the volume of trade and the profits indirectlyby inducing fundamentalinstitutional
generated by Atlantic trade appear to be too change. Atlantic trade in Britain and the Neth-
small to account for much of Europeangrowth erlands (or, more appropriately,in Englandand
directly. Atlantic trademay also have played an the Duchy of Burgundy) altered the balance of
importantdirect role by inducing a reallocation political power by enriching and strengthening
of resources within Europe,even if profits from commercial interests outside the royal circle,
trading were low (as would be the case in a including various overseas merchants, slave
competitive economy). This direct channel is traders,and various colonial planters.Through
unlikely to be the whole story, however, since this channel, it contributed to the emergence
the volume of trade was small. For example, of political institutions protecting merchants
Bairoch (1993) calculates that commodity trade against royal power.21Our hypothesis also im-
between Western Europe and the rest of the plies that the tendency for institutionalchange
world amounted to less than 4 percent of the to emerge should have been much strongerin
GNP of WesternEuropebefore 1800. Although societies with existing checks on royal power
recent work by Inikori(2002) arguesthat profits than in countries with absolutist regimes and
from colonial activities, in particularfrom the monarchy-controlledtrademonopolies, because
slave trade, were largerthan those estimated by in these latter countries Atlantic trade did not
O'Brien, even with his estimates, the direct enrich and strengthenmerchantgroups outside
effect of Atlantic trade and colonialism could the royal circle as much, and did not disturbthe
account for the rise of Europe only with signif- political status quo.
icant increasing returns to scale in leading This hypothesis can be broken into 4 subhy-
sectors.20 potheses:
Overall, therefore, the weight of evidence
inclines us toward a view in which the rise of (a) Political institutionsplacing limits and con-
Europe reflects not only the direct effects of straints on state power are essential for the
Atlantic trade and colonialism but also a major incentives to undertakeinvestmentsand for
social transformation induced by these sustained economic growth;
opportunities. (b) In early modern Europe, such political in-
stitutions were favored by commercial in-
terests outside the royal circle, but were not
welcome by the monarchy and its allies;
20
For example, O'Brien (1982) calculates thattotal prof- (c) Institutions favored by economically and
its from British trade with less developed regions of the
world during the late eighteenth century were approxi-
mately ?5.6 million, while total gross investmentduring the
same period stood at ?10.3 million. Inikori (2002, Table
21
4.2) suggests that imports from the peripheryaround 1800 An additional channel via which Atlantic trade may
were about double O'Brien's estimate. During this period, have contributedto institutionalchange may be the desire of
the aggregate savings rate was between 12 and 14 percent, the monarchyto secure the propertyrights of merchantsin
so if we assume that this savings rate also applies to profits order to encourage long-term investments in long-distance
from trade, the contribution of these profits to aggregate trade. Our readingof the relevant history, discussed below,
capital accumulation would be less than 15 percent, even makes us believe that the greater contributionof Atlantic
using Inikori's estimates. Even assuming considerably trade to the development of capitalist institutions was by
higher savings rates, the contribution would remain rela- strengthening commercial interests in favor of political
tively small. change in their fight against the monarchy.
VOL.95 NO. 3 ACEMOGLUET AL.: THE RISE OF EUROPE 563

politically powerful groups are more likely B. Atlantic Trade and CommercialInterests
to prevail; and
(d) In countries with nonabsolutistinitial polit- We now discuss the major changes in the
ical institutions,Atlantic trade and colonial political institutions of Britain and the Nether-
activity enrichedand strengthenedcommer- lands. Our argument highlights that in both
cial interests,including new groupswithout cases: (a) the political institutions at the begin-
ties to the monarchy. ning of the sixteenth century, though not as
absolutist as in Spain and Portugal, did not
Together these four subhypotheses yield provide secure property rights to commercial
our main hypothesis. In countries with easy interests outside the royal circle;23(b) there was
access to the Atlantic and without a strong significant conflict between these merchant
absolutist monarchy, Atlantic trade provided groups and the monarchy; (c) Atlantic trade
substantial profits and political power for created large profits for some of these mer-
commercial interests outside the royal circle. chants who were in favor of institutional
This group could then demand and obtain change, and who then used part of these profits
significant institutional reforms protecting to supportthe conflict against the crown.
their property rights. With their newly gained
power and property rights, they took advan- Britain.-In the British case the two mile-
tage of the growth opportunities offered by stones in the emergence of political institutions
Atlantic trade, invested more, traded more, constrainingroyal power are the (English) Civil
and fueled the First Great Divergence.22 War of 1642-1649, when Parliamentarian
Initial institutions placing sufficient checks forces defeated CharlesI, and the Glorious Rev-
on the monarchy are essential for the fourth olution of 1688-1689, where James II was de-
subhypothesis, so that merchants not directly posed by Parliament with the help of an
associated with the crown benefit signifi- invading Dutch army, and replaced by William
cantly from Atlantic trade. When the power of of Orange and a parliamentaryregime with a
the crown was relatively unchecked, as in constitutional monarchy. Although there is no
Spain, Portugal, and France, trade was largely consensus among historians on the relative im-
monopolized and regulated, the crown and its portance of these two events, this is secondary
allies became the main beneficiaries of the for our focus. What is important is that there
Atlantic expansion, and institutional change was a major improvement in British political
did not take place. Therefore, our hypothesis institutions between the mid-seventeenth and
explains not only the major role played by early-eighteenthcenturies.
Atlantic trade in West European growth, but Although after the War of the Roses, Britain
also why economic growth took off in Britain was never as absolutist as France, Portugal,and
and the Netherlands, and not in Spain and Spain, both the Tudorand Stuartmonarchscon-
Portugal. sistently attemptedto expand their powers. The
Acemoglu et al. (2002b) provide historical insecurity of property rights was clear during
evidence consistent with these subhypotheses. the reign of Henry VIII, when there were con-
Space constraintspreclude us from going into tinual attemptsto regulate trade and undermine
details here. We refer the reader to that paper the powers of Parliament (see Geoffrey R. El-
for a more detailed discussion, and briefly dis- ton, 1991). A significant attemptto establish a
cuss the evidence related to the fourth subhy- form of absolutism came during the period of
pothesis, which is perhaps the most important so-called "personalrule" of Charles I, after he
for our argument. dissolved his third Parliament in 1629, raised
taxes in an unconstitutionalway, and used the

22 23
The establishmentof political institutionslimiting the More explicitly, these commercial interests included
power of the monarchy may have also created positive merchants not receiving crown-grantedmonopolies, slave
spillovers in the rest of the economy, especially for indus- traders, various producers in the colonies and parts of the
trial capitalists (consistent with the subsequent growth of gentry in Britain, and the majority of the Dutch merchants
non-Atlantic British cities in Figure 5B). not allied with the Habsburgmonarchy in the Netherlands.
564 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 2005

Star Chamberto manipulate legal decisions in similar. The East India Companyunderthe con-
his favor (Kevin Sharpe, 1992). trol of Josiah Child supported James II, his
Although undoubtedly complex social claim to tax without consent of Parliament,and
events, both the Civil War and the Glorious his right to granttradingmonopolies-of which
Revolution were also battles over the rights and it was the main beneficiary.But the majorityof
prerogatives of the monarchy.24In both cases, commercial interests, alienated by James II's
commercial interests (including large segments, grants of various monopoly privileges, and es-
but not all, of the merchants and the gentry) pecially the interlopers-merchants trying to
predominantlysided with those demanding re- break into trade with Asia-were on the side of
strictionson the power of the monarchy.During the revolution (Bruce G. Carruthers,1996; Pin-
the Civil War, for example, the majorityof the cus, 2002). These merchants also received
merchants, and even many of those with royal strong supportfrom Whigs who sought to con-
monopolies, supportedParliament(see Brenner, strainthe king (Henry Horwitz, 1978). Summa-
1973, 2003; Mary Keeler, 1954; Douglas Brun- rizing the evidence, Pincus (2002, p. 34)
ton and D. H. Pennington, 1954).25Membersof concludes, "England'smerchantcommunityac-
the Commons from the City of London, which tively supported William's plan for invasion,
was the main center of mercantile activity, as and provided a key financialprop to the regime
well as many non-London commercial constit- in the critical early months."
uencies, such as Southampton,Newcastle, and The victory of Parliamentin the Civil War
Liverpool, supported Parliament against the and after the Glorious Revolution introduced
King. David H. Sacks (1991, pp. 230-47) major checks on royal power and strengthened
shows that in Bristol trading, commercial and the rights of merchants.After the Civil War,the
industrialinterests outside of the MerchantAd- fraction of MPs who were merchantsincreased
venturers (the trading company then enjoying dramatically. Although even in the 1690s this
the royal monopoly) were Parliamentarians. number was not large enough to constitute a
Bruntonand Pennington(1954, p. 62) also note majorityon its own, as David Stasavage(2003)
that "in the country as a whole there was prob- shows, the interests of merchantswere assured
ably a preponderanceof Parliamentarianfeeling by the formation of the Whig coalition of mer-
among merchants." chants and Protestantlandowners. This period
The situation for the Glorious Revolution is also witnessed a series of policies favoringmer-
chants, including the Navigation Acts of 1651
and 1660, which restricted trade with British
24 Other prominent interpretationsof the English Civil
War have emphasized various factors apartfrom those we
colonies to British ships and merchants(J. E.
stress here. ConradRussell (1990) argues thatthe Civil War Farnell, 1964; J. P. Cooper, 1972) and strength-
was a plot by the traditionalaristocracyto regain power it ened the position of British overseas traders,
had lost under the Tudors. Many, for example, John S.
Morrill (1993), focus on the role of religious differences in
especially slave traders(see Geoffrey Holmes,
1993, p. 64). Similarly,the GloriousRevolution
determiningwho supportedwhich side, and recent work by
Brian Manning (1996) stresses more general class conflict. led to a series of economic reforms sought by
Although there are doubtless elements of truth in these merchantsoutside the royal circle, includingthe
approaches, the general role of mercantile interests seems dismantlingof all monopoly charters,except the
undeniable(see Roger C. Richardson, 1998, for a balanced East India Company (Perry Gauci, 2001) and
overview of the debate).
25 Valerie Pearl's seminal study (1961) arguedthat there
the establishmentof the Bank of England.The
were political divisions between such groups as the Mer- conventional wisdom in economic history em-
chant Adventurers,who benefited from monopolies granted phasizes the importance of these institutional
by the crown, and new merchants,who did not. For exam- changes for the protection of propertyrights,
ple, the two pre-Civil War MPs for Bristol, Humphrey and how they led to a wave of innovations in
Hooke and Richard Long, were Royalists. Robert Ashton
(1979, 1996), on the other hand, documented that even economic institutions, particularlyin financial
merchants who enjoyed monopolies tended to oppose the markets (e.g., North and Weingast, 1989; Car-
crown by the time of the Civil War, and argued "the ruthers, 1996; LarryNeal, 2000).
majority of the City fathers, far from being the natural Criticallyfor our thesis, the majorchangesin
supportersof Stuart absolutism at the end of the period of
Charles I's personal rule in the late 1630's, were as alien- political institutions and the new assertiveness
ated from royal policies as were the vast majority of the of merchant groups coincided with the expan-
political nation" (1996, p. 3). sion of British mercantile groups trading
VOL.95 NO. 3 ACEMOGLUET AL.: THE RISE OF EUROPE 565

through the Atlantic. The East India Company men's wages from E. H. Phelps Brown and
was founded in 1600, and from 1600 to 1630 Sheila V. Hopkins, 1955). These profits were
there was an unprecedentedwave of investment substantial relative to the personal wealth of
by merchants, gentry, and even some aristoc- merchants and gentry during this time period.
racy in overseas ventures (Theodore K. Rabb, For example, personal wealth of ?10,000 in the
1967). Virginia tobacco cultivation boomed in early seventeenth century was enough to be
the 1620s, and beginning in the 1640s, the very rich. A minimum investment of ?2,000
highly profitable Caribbeansugar colonies de- was required to become a director of the East
veloped. Finally, in the 1650s the British began India Company, and ?200 represented a sub-
to take over the Atlantic slave trade. stantial investment (Brenner, 1973, pp. 62-63;
A number of historians, most notably Bren- Brenner, 2003, p. 78). Moreover, because prof-
ner (2003), have emphasized that Atlantic mer- its from Atlantic trade were highly concen-
chants were critical in ensuring the military trated, they created a number of very wealthy
victory of Parliament in the Civil War. In his merchants (see Grassby, 1995, pp. 248 and
famous book, Lawrence Stone also points out 263). These profits were also large relative to
that "... other importantmerchantelements can the resources necessary to make a difference
now be identified, men interested especially in politically and militarily.26
the Americantrades, in New England coloniza- Many merchants used their profits from At-
tion, and in breaking the monopoly of the East lantic trade to support the conflict against the
India and Levant Companies. They were new crown. For example, the Earl of Warwick, who
men in new fields of entrepreneurialendeavor earned at least ?50,000 from privateeringin one
who chafed at the political and economic stran- year prior to the Civil War (W. Frank Craven,
glehold of the older established monopolistic 1930), applied his fortune and experience with
oligarchies. These men were important mem- naval warfare to effectively oppose the king.27
bers of the group of radicals who seized control More generally, Parliament during the Civil
of London at a critical moment in 1641, and so War was partlyfinancedby taxes on, and profits
swung the power and influence of the city de- from, Atlantic trade.Parliamentaryleaders such
cisively on the side of Parliament"(1973, p. as Sir Edwin Sandys and John Pym were active
144). in colonization and trade with the Americas.
Atlantic trade indeed createdlarge profits for James I, well aware of the links between major
the fortunate who succeeded in this high-risk Atlantic trading ventures and parliamentary
endeavor. In the Appendix, we use data on
profits from K. N. Chaudhuri (1965) and de
Vries and van der Woude (1997), on investment 26
From 1550 to 1688, the English monarchwas always
from Rabb (1967), on tradefrom Inikori (2002) short of cash, and war typically required additional funds.
and de Vries (2003), and on rates of returnfrom For example, King CharlesI was forced to recall Parliament
in 1640 because he needed to raise about ?300,000
Richard Grassby (1969, 1995) and O'Brien
(?250,000 in 1600 prices) for war against Scotland-
(1982) to estimate profits of various merchant enough to pay and equip about 12,000 soldiers for a year
companies, slave traders, and colonial planters (Ashton, 1960, p. 176). Total English governmentrevenues
from Atlantic trade during this period. These were around?500,000 in 1600 and about ?850,000 in 1640
estimates suggest that profits from Atlantic (RichardBean, 1973). Armies on both sides of the English
Civil War were small, 10,000 to 20,000 men, and most of
trade were negligible before 1575, about the conflict was small-scale local operations by regional
?40,000 on average per annum from 1576 to forces (Geoffrey Parker, 1988, pp. 28 and 41). Parliament
1600 (mostly from a few highly profitablepri- fielded 27,000 at the battle of MarstonMoor andjust 13,000
at Naseby; the presence or absence of a few thousandtroops
vateeringexpeditions), perhaps?200,000 on av- was therefore decisive (Parker, 1988, p. 41). Kennedy
erage per annumfrom 1601 to 1650, and around (1987, p. 63) estimates that the average annual cost of a
?500,000 per annumfrom 1651 to 1675. Profits soldier was around?27 in 1657 (about ?20 in 1600 prices).
then rose with the expansion of sugar and the 27 A privateer is an armed private vessel bearing the

slave tradeto around?900,000 per annumfrom authorizationor commission of a sovereign power to attack
an enemy, i.e., a privately funded and manned extension of
1676 to 1700, ?1.7m per annum from 1701 to a country's naval forces. Privateers typically engaged in
1750, and probablyabout?5m per annumin the trading activities as well as fighting (see, for example, the
late eighteenth century (all figures adjusted to case of John Hawkins discussed in N. A. M. Rodger, 1997,
1600 prices using the index of building crafts- p. 201).
566 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 2005

opposition, intervened in the election of trea- 1590, the successful Dutch offensives of 1591-
surer for the Virginia Company, saying, 1597 underthe commandof Mauriceof Nassau,
"Choose the devil if you will, but not Sir Edwin the embargoes against Dutch trade with Spain
Sandys"(Rabb, 1998, p. 349). Similarly, for the and Portugal in 1585-1590, 1598-1609, and
Glorious Revolution, Pincus (2002, pp. 32-33) 1621-1647, and the Twelve Years Truce from
provides evidence that "the merchant commu- 1609 to 1621.
nity poured money into William of Orange's The major turning point came in the 1590s
coffers in 1688"--perhaps around ?800,000 when importantchanges in Dutch military and
(about ?500,000 in 1600 prices), enough to pay commercial strategy became evident. New mil-
for a sizable army. itary tactics made it possible for the Dutch to
hold their own against experienced Spanish in-
The Netherlands.-Dutch merchants always fantry (Geoffrey Parker,1988, pp. 19-20). This
had considerable autonomy and access to prof- was combined with a fiscal and financial "rev-
itable tradeopportunities.Nevertheless, priorto olution" that allowed states, particularlyHol-
the Dutch Revolt, the Netherlands (in fact, the land, both to increase their tax revenues and
entire Duchy of Burgundy) was part of the borrow against future taxes in order to finance
Habsburg Empire, and the political power of the war effort (Fritschy, 2003). At the same
Dutch merchants was limited. The Habsburg time, the Dutch took the critical strategicstep of
monarchyconsistently attemptedto increase its seeking direct access to Asian and American
political dominance over and fiscal revenues tradecenters.This both enricheda generationof
from the Netherlands(W. Fritschy et al., 2001). Dutch merchantsand underminedSpanish and
The critical improvementin Dutch political in- Portuguese revenues sufficiently to induce
stitutions was thereforethe establishmentof the Philip III to offer peace. By 1605 it was clear to
independent Dutch Republic, with political a Spanish royal councillor, the Count of Oli-
dominance and economic security for mer- vares, that victory would go to "whoeveris left
chants, including both the established wealthy with the last escudo" (Parker, 1977, p. 238).
regents and the new merchants immigrating Merchantswere naturallythe primarypoliti-
from Antwerp and Germany.28 cal and economic force on the side of indepen-
Dutch politics was shaped by the conflict dence. De Vries and van der Woude (1997)
between Dutch merchants and the Habsburg argue that "urbaneconomic interests ultimately
monarchy starting in the fifteenth century, and believed it advantageous to escape the
before then by the conflict between merchants Habsburg imperial framework"(p. 369). They
and the Duke of Burgundy.By 1493 Maximil- also note that, in the case of Amsterdam,the
ian of Habsburghad reversed the Grand Privi- "[Habsburgs']opponents included most of the
lege of 1477, which gave the states general the city's internationalmerchants.... [I]n 1578 a
right to gatheron theirown initiative and curbed new Amsterdamcity council threwthe city's lot
the right of the ruler to raise taxes. After 1552, in with the Prince of Orange ... among the mer-
war with France and England increased the chants returning from ... exile were [those
Habsburgs'fiscal needs and led them to impose whose families] and several generationsof their
a large tax burdenon the Netherlands.Growing descendents would long dominate the city"
fiscal and religious resentmentin 1572 led to a (1997, p. 365).
series of uprisings,mostly orchestratedby com- Commercialinterestsinvolved in the Atlantic
mercial interests (see JonathanI. Israel, 1995). were particularlyimportantin the shapingof the
These culminated in a war of independence, conflict (see, for example, Israel, 1982, 1995;
which began with the Revolt in the 1570s and Herman van der Wee, 1993, pp. 272-73). In
did not end until 1648, punctuatedby Philip II 1609, in an attempt to prevent the creation of
diverting resources to intervene in France after the Dutch West India Company, Philip III of-
fered peace and independence in return for a
28
Dutch withdrawalfrom both the West and East
By the year 1600, a thirdof the populationof Amster-
dam was immigrants(Israel, 1995, p. 309). In 1631, there
Indies. But these terms were "simply not feasi-
were 685 citizens of Amsterdam with wealth over 25,000 ble politically because many regents and elite
florins. Only half of them were native Hollanders (Parker, merchants had invested heavily in the [Dutch
1977, p. 251). East India Company]" (Israel, 1995, p. 402).
VOL.95 NO. 3 ACEMOGLUET AL.: THE RISE OF EUROPE 567

Prominent in the anti-peace camp was the fa- Critical was the Dutch merchants' improv-
mous Dutch leader and general Mauriceof Nas- ing economic fortunes, partly from Atlantic
sau, who was heavily involved in colonial trade, which were used to field a powerful
trades, and "ReynierPauw, the preeminentfig- army against the Habsburg Empire. The Bal-
ure and leader of the anti-trucefaction in Hol- tic trade is widely recognized as important for
land who, besides being a championof the West the Dutch economy in the sixteenth century,
India Company project, had been a founder but profits from Atlantic trade quickly sur-
member of the East India Company and for passed those from Baltic trade and provided
many years a directorof its Amsterdamcham- the funds necessary for the Dutch military
ber" (Israel, 1982, p. 40). effort against the Habsburgs (Israel, 1989).
It is therefore no surprise that independence De Vries and van der Woude (1997) estimate
put merchantsfirmly in control of the political that the annual profits of the Dutch East India
process. De Vries and van der Woude (1997, p. Company alone between 1630 and 1670, 2.1
587) describe the new political elite following million guilders per annum, were more than
the Dutch Revolt as "6 to 8% of urban house- twice the total annual profits from the Baltic
holds with incomes in excess of 1,000 guilders grain trade between 1590 and 1599 (pp. 373
per year. This was the grote burgerij from and 447).
whom was drawn the political and commercial Fritschy (2003) estimates that, as a result of
leadershipof the country.Here we find, first and these developments, tax revenue per head in
foremost, the merchants."They also point out Holland rose nearly fivefold from 1575 to
how merchants dominated the governments of 1610, while population increased by a third
Leiden, Rotterdam, and the cities in the two (see also Tracy, 2001, Table 7.2). These rev-
largest states, Zeeland and Holland. enues enabled Holland to provide 960,000
The Dutch economy had been expanding guilders for the war in 1579 and to pay five
since the fifteenth century and experienced ad- million guilders in 1599 (Parker, 1977, p.
vances in economic institutions, including in 251). Israel (1995, pp. 241-42) summarizes
shipping, agriculture, and finance, particularly the basic reason for the Dutch victory as
public finance, prior to this revolt (James D. follows: "From 1590, there was a dramatic
Tracy, 1985; Jan Luiten van Zanden, 1993). improvement in the Republic's economic cir-
Nevertheless, the potential of these institutions cumstances. Commerce and shipping ex-
was severely limited under the Habsburgyoke panded enormously, as did the towns. As a
because of the threat of arbitrarytaxation. For result, the financial power of the states rapidly
example, MarjolienHartet al. (1997, fig. 2.3, p. grew, and it was possible to improve the army
19) show that, despite the changes in financial vastly, both qualitatively, and quantitatively,
institutions in the mid-sixteenth century, inter- within a short space of time. The army in-
est rates did not fall systematically until after creased from 20,000 men in 1588 to 32,000
1600, when they declined to about one-third of by 1595, and its artillery, methods of trans-
their pre-revolt level. Consequently, the econ- portation, and training were transformed." By
omy appearsto have experienced a majortrans- 1629, the Dutch were able to field an army of
formation after the process of political change 77,000 men, 50 percent larger than the Span-
began. Van Zanden (1993) notes, "We can see ish army of Flanders (Israel, 1995, p. 507).
the starting point of the rapid urbanization at Overall, both the British and Dutch evidence,
1580" (pp. 35-36), and continues, "duringthis therefore, appears favorable to our hypothesis
transformation process, the pre-1580 proto- that Atlantic trade enriched a group of mer-
capitalist structure disappeared... out of this chants who then played a critical role in the
'unspecialised' class of small-holders, fisher- emergence of new political institutions con-
men, homeworkersand sailors, separateclasses straining the power of the crown.
of large farmers, agricultural laborers and
craftsmen arose" (p. 39). Similarly, Braudel
(1995, p. 547) dates the start of the divergence Spain, Portugal and France.-There is gen-
between the South and North of Europeto 1590 eral agreementthat Spanish and Portuguesepo-
with the "explosion" of Dutch commerce and litical institutions at the turn of the sixteenth
the rise of Amsterdam. century were more absolutist than those in
568 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 2005

Britain and the Netherlands, and did not expe- France, on the other hand, can be viewed as
rience similar reform.29 an intermediatecase. Although French institu-
A key difference between these cases and the tions were equally absolutist (W. F. Church,
British-Dutch patterns is the organization of 1969; David Parrott,2001), early Atlantic ac-
trade which, in turn, reflected differences in tivity enriched some merchant groups, in par-
political institutions. Throughout this period, ticular the protestantHuguenots. However, the
the granting of trade monopolies was a central monarchy soon clashed with and defeated the
tool for the rulers to raise revenue. When the Huguenots, first with the siege of La Rochelle
power of the monarchs was constrained, they by Louis XIII and then the outlawing of the
were unable to use this fiscal tool. For example, Protestantchurchby Louis XIV (see, e.g., War-
the English Parliament successfully blocked ren C. Scoville, 1960). The monarchythen kept
many attempts of both Tudor and Stuart mon- much of overseas trading activity as a royal
archs to create such monopolies (Christopher monopoly, especially under Colbert (see, e.g.,
Hill, 1969). Consequently, in Britain "most Davis, 1973b, pp. 222-24; William Doyle,
trade was carried on by individuals and small 1974; pp. 210-11). Nevertheless, certainstrong
partnerships,and not by the Company of Mer- French commercial and industrialinterests de-
chant Adventurers, the Levant Company ... or veloped and, arguably, forced institutional
others of their kind" (Davis, 1973a, p. 41). At change before, during, and after the French
least by 1600 there was quite free entry into the Revolution (see G. Lefebvre, 1947, and Doyle,
British merchant class (R. G. Lang, 1974). In 1988, for the debateon the origins of the French
contrast, Rondo Cameron (1993, p. 127) de- Revolution).
scribes the Portuguese situation as follows: Overall, the evidence is therefore consistent
"The spice trade in the East Indies of the Por- with our thesis that in Spain and Portugal,and
tuguese Empire was a crown monopoly; the also largely in France, merchant interestswith
Portuguese navy doubled as a merchant fleet, sufficient power to challenge the crown did not
and all spices had to be sold throughthe Casa develop because the crown, and groupsallied to
da India (India House) in Lisbon ... no com- it, were the main beneficiaries of the profits
merce existed between Portugal and the East from transoceanictrade and plunder.
except that organized and controlled by the
state."(See also CharlesR. Boxer, 1985; Earl J. III. AtlanticTradeand InstitutionalChange
Hamilton, 1948.) Similarly, in Spain colonial
trade was a monopoly of the Crown of Castille We now attemptto substantiateour hypoth-
and was delegated to the Casa de Contratacid6n esis furtherby providingempirical evidence on
(House of Trade) in Seville, which was itself the link between changes in political institutions
closely monitoredby the government(James H. and Atlantic trade.A prerequisitefor this exer-
Parry, 1966, ch. 2). cise is a measure of relevant political institu-
tions. Unfortunately,no such measureexists for
this period.30So as a first step, we attemptedto
29Davis (1973a, p. create a measure of political institutions for
66), for example, emphasizes the
high degree of absolutecontrol by the monarchyin Spain, as European countries between 1300 and 1850,
follows: [in Castille] "the king ruled subject only to weak
constitutionalrestraints.In the first decades of the sixteenth adapting the definition of "constrainton the
executive" from Gurr'sPolity dataset.This is a
centurythe crown had reducedthe pretensionsof the Castil-
lian nobility and towns, so that the representativebody, the useful concept since it measures limitationson
Cortes, could obstructbut not in the last resortpreventroyal the arbitraryuse of power by the executive (for
tax raising," and contraststhis with the situation in Britain the relevant time period, the monarchy),and is
(e.g., Davis, 1973a, p. 210).
The modem literature,in particular,I. A. A. Thompson
(1994) and Michael A. R. Graves (2001), suggests that the
extent of Spanish absolutism has been overemphasizedby 30 An alternativeapproachwould be to use the terms of
scholars such as North and Thomas (1973), and points out finance for trading entities, as suggested by one of our
importantdifferences between Castille and such other parts reviewers. Although there are some data on this, the cov-
of Iberia as Aragon and Catalonia. Nevertheless, it is cer- erage is not broad enough for our purposes. Moreover,the
tainly true that the Spanish Crown was able to create trade terms of finance may be affected by the demand for and
monopolies and raise taxes in ways that the Tudor and supply of financial resources, as well as the underlying
Stuartmonarchies could not. security of propertyrights.
VOL. 95 NO. 3 ACEMOGLUET AL.: THE RISE OF EUROPE 569

presumablycorrelatedwith the securityof prop- results show significant differential improve-


erty rights for merchants and the control over ments in institutions among Atlantic traders
the monopoly of overseas trade by the and no evidence of differential existing
monarchy.31 trends. Unlike our results when urbanization
We follow the Polity IV coding handbook, was the dependent variable, however, even
giving a score of between 1 and 7 for constraint after the inclusion of Atlantic trade interac-
on the executive to each country.32For 1800 tions, there is some evidence of differential
and 1850, we use the Polity coding for con- West European effects.
straint on the executive, where available. For Other columns use the same controls and
earlier periods, we coded these measures our- time interactions as in Table 4. Although the
selves. The main source for this exercise was F-statistics show that many of these time inter-
William L. Langer (1972), a classic historical actions are significant, neither Protestantism,
encyclopedia, written with a focus on constitu- nor wars, nor Roman heritage, nor latitude ap-
tional events. We supplementedthis work with pears to have led to greaterinstitutionalchange
the more recent edition by Peter N. Stearns after 1500 (for example, institutions in Protes-
(2001). While there may be disagreementabout tant countries improved more rapidly until
the precise values used in particularyears, the 1750, and significantly more slowly thereafter).
general level of constrainton the executive does Overall, these results suggest that, following
not appearto be controversial.For example, the the surge in Atlantic trade, there were greater
absolutist regimes of France, Portugal, and strides toward better political institutionsin na-
Spain clearly had much less constraint on the tions engaged in Atlantic trade and colonialism
executive than did the Netherlands after inde- (or in those with a greaterpotentialto engage in
pendence or England after the Civil War. Atlantic trade).
Acemoglu et al. (2002b) give furtherdetails and
report the entire series. IV. The Role of Initial Institutions
Table 6 documents the differential changes
in institutions between Atlantic traders and We now investigate whether, as implied by
other West European nations by estimating an our hypothesis, it was predominantly societ-
equation similar to (1) with constraint on the ies with less absolutist initial institutions (and
executive as the left-hand-side variable. The relatedly, those without widespread royal
granted monopoly rights in overseas trade)
that took advantage of the opportunities of-
31
The measureof constrainton the executive may not be fered by Atlantic trade. We also investigate
ideal for our purposes, however, since a number of signif- the related hypothesis of North and Thomas
icant constraintson monarchs were imposed by the nobles (1973) and Jones (1981) that post-1500 de-
and did not necessarily serve to protect the rights of mer-
chants. For example, in much of the 1500-1750 period,
velopments largely reflect divergence be-
Poland had a highly constrained executive. But there was
tween societies that had very different
relatively little protectionfor urbanmerchants;most of the political institutions at the turn of the fifteenth
rights rested with the nobility. For this reason, we modified century. This differs from our hypothesis,
the definition of constraint on the executive to create an which emphasizes the interaction between
alternative measure, which we refer to as "protection for initial political institutions and Atlantic trade.
capital."The coding of this measure depends on the formal To investigate these ideas, we estimate mod-
rights given to urbanmerchants,particularlytheirprotection
in the event of a dispute with the nobility or monarch. The els of the following form:
results using this measure are similar to those using con-
straint on the executive, and are contained in Acemoglu et (3) = d,+ j+
8 a~ *WEj,*d
al. (2002b). ut t;1600
32 A value of 1 means "thereare no
regularlimitationson
the executive's actions," 3 means "thereare some real but
limited restraintson the executive," 5 means "the executive +/3 InAT, PATj
has more effective authoritythan any accountabilitygroup,
but is subject to substantial constraints by them," and 7 Yt
means "accountabilitygroups have effective authorityequal +•t 1500 "-j,1415
dt
to or greaterthan the executive in most activity." Scores of
2, 4, and 6 are used for intermediatevalues. See Monty G.
Marshall and Keith Jaggers (2000). + r . In AT, PATj. Ij,1415 + Ejt
570 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 2005

TABLE 6--ATLANTIC TRADE AND INSTITUTIONS


Dependent variable is constraint on the executive

Panel, Panel,
1300 to 1850, 1300 to 1850,
Panel, using Atlantic using Atlantic
Panel, Panel, 1300 to 1850, Panel, coastline-to-area coastline-to-area
1300-1850, 1300 to 1850, controlling 1300 to 1850, measure of measure of
Panel, Panel, Panel, controlling controlling for Roman controlling potential for potentialfor
1300-1850 1300-1850 1300-1850 for religion for wars heritage for latitude Atlantic trade Atlantic trade
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)

p-value for Western Europe [0.00] [0.35] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.26] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00]
x year dummies, 1600-
1850
Potential for Atlantic trade -0.42 -20.83
x 1500 (0.47) (22.94)
Potential for Atlantic trade -0.14 10.94
x 1600 (0.52) (22.91)
Potential for Atlantic trade 0.29 62.12
x 1700 (0.48) (21.14)
Potential for Atlantic trade 0.32 81.45
x 1750 (0.46) (20.78)
Potential for Atlantic trade 2.07 79.81
x 1800 (0.44) (18.97)
Potential for Atlantic trade 2.96 72.25
x 1850 (0.41) (17.13)
Potential for Atlantic trade 0.42 0.45 0.43 0.39 0.43 12.99
X volume of Atlantic (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (0.06) (2.31)
trade
p-value for Protestant X [0.00]
year effect
Wars per year in preceding -0.034
century (0.20)
p-value for Roman heritage [0.05]
x year
p-value for latitude X year [0.49]
R-squared 0.75 0.85 0.81 0.84 0.81 0.82 0.81 0.81 0.79
Number of observations 192 192 192 192 176 192 192 192 192

Notes: Standarderrorsare in parentheses.Weighted panel regressions with full set of countryand year dummies. Weights are total populationin each countryin each
year, from McEvedy and Jones (1978). Dependent variable is constrainton executive, which ranges from I to 7 where a higher score indicates more constraintson
arbitraryaction by the executive. All columns use the Atlantic traderdummy (one for Britain,France, Spain, Portugal,and the Netherlands;zero for all others) as the
measureof potential for Atlantic trade,apartfrom columns 8 and 9, which use the ratio of Atlanticcoastline to area (includingAtlantic tradersplus Belgium, Denmark,
Germany,Ireland,and Norway). Volume of Atlantic trade is the log average numberof voyages per year. Protestantis a dummy for whether countrywas majority
Protestantin 1600. ProtestantX year is the Protestantdummy interactedwith year dummies for 1600 and after. Wars per year are for the precedingcenturythrough
1700, 1700-1750 for 1750, 1750-1800 for 1800, and 1800-1850 for 1850. Roman heritageis dummy for whethercountrywas in the Roman Empire;this is interacted
with year dummies for 1600 and after. Latitude is distance from the equatorfor capital city of this country today; this is interactedwith year for 1600 and after.

where,as before,uj,is the urbanizationrate,InAT, these interactionterms.The InAT,- PATjterm,on


is our measure of Atlantic trade, PATj is again the other hand, measuresthe effect of Atlantic
eithera dummyfor Atlantictraderor the Atlantic tradefor a given level of institutions.In the table,
coastline-to-arearatio, and Ij,1415 is countryj's this term is evaluatedat the lowest scoreof insti-
initialinstitutions,calculatedas the averageof its tutions, i.e., for Ij,1415 = 1, so the coefficient on
constrainton the executivein 1400 and 1500. We this term measures the growth contributionof
choose the averageof these two dates to capture Atlantic trade and access to the Atlantic for a
the long-terminstitutionaldifferencesin the pre- society with the worstpossible initialinstitutions.
The variable In AT, * 9
1500 period. The y, Ij,1415 d, terms allow any
PATj' Ij,1415tests the
differentialeconomic trendsrelatedto differences hypothesis of interest. A significant coefficient
in initial institutionsthat would apply even with rqimplies that there were divergent paths taken
no access to the Atlantic.Significantcoefficients by countries with different initial institutions,
on these interactionterms would imply that at but this divergence relates significantly to
least part of the post-1500 developmentsin Eu- whether they took advantageof the opportuni-
rope reflect divergent paths taken by countries ties presented by Atlantic trade.
with differentinitial institutions,independentof The results are reportedin Table 7 using the
the effects of Atlantictrade.The table reportsthe Atlantic traderdummy for the potential for At-
p-value from a joint significance test for all of lantic trade, PATj (results using the coastline-
VOL. 95 NO. 3 ACEMOGLUET AL.: THE RISE OF EUROPE 571

TABLE7-INTERACTION BETWEEN
INITIALINSTITUTIONS
AND ATLANTICTRADE

UsingAtlantictraderdummyas measureof Atlantictrade


(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10)

Panel A: Dependent variable is urbanization


Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel,
1300-1850 1300-1850 1300-1850 1300-1850 1300-1850, 1000-1850 1000-1850 1000-1850 1000-1850 1000-1850,
unweighted unweighted
Atlantic traderdummy x 0.011 0.011 -0.0095 -0.0026 0.0082 0.0084 -0.012 -0.009
volume of Atlantic trade (0.002) (0.002) (0.0049) (0.0062) (0.0020) (0.0020) (0.004) (0.005)
p-value for initial institutions [0.61] [0.51] [0.71] [0.85] [0.12] [0.08] [0.42] [0.92]
x year (1600, 1700, 1750,
1800,1850)
Volumeof Atlantictradex 0.021 0.017 0.021 0.022
initial institutions x (0.004) (0.005) (0.004) (0.004)
Atlantic traderdummy
R-squared 0.87 0.88 0.89 0.90 0.83 0.86 0.86 0.87 0.87 0.81
Number of observations 192 192 192 192 192 240 240 240 240 240

Panel B: Dependent variable is Log GDP per capita


Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel,
1500-1820 1500-1820 1500-1820 1500-1820 1500-1820, 1500-1870 1500-1870 1500-1870 1500-1870 1500-1870,
unweighted unweighted
Atlantic traderdummy x 0.069 0.069 -0.068 -0.079 0.040 0.040 -0.123 -0.110
volume of Atlantic trade (0.016) (0.016) (0.028) (0.028) (0.017) (0.017) (0.030) (0.028)
p-value for initial institutions [0.40] [0.31] [0.004] [0.08] [0.66] [0.64] [0.01] [0.58]
X year (1600, 1700, 1750,
1800, 1850)
Volume of Atlantic trade x 0.14 0.12 0.16 0.11
initial institutions x (0.03) (0.02) (0.03) (0.02)
Atlantic traderdummy
R-squared 0.94 0.96 0.96 0.97 0.97 0.95 0.95 0.95 0.96 0.96
Number of observations 96 96 96 96 96 120 120 120 120 120

Panel C: Dependent variable is constrainton the executive


Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel, Panel,
1300-1850 1300-1850 1300-1850 1300-1850 1300-1850, 1500-1850 1500-1850 1500-1850 1500-1850 1500-1850,
unweighted unweighted
Atlantic traderdummy X 0.43 0.42 -0.001 -0.096 0.35 0.34 -0.11 -0.15
volume of Atlantic trade (0.06) (0.06) (0.12) (0.12) (0.05) (0.05) (0.10) (0.09)
p-value for initial institutions [0.27] [0.14] [0.008] [0.69] [0.43] [0.33] [0.01] [0.95]
X year (1600, 1700, 1750,
1800, 1850)
Volume of Atlantic trade X 0.44 0.26 0.47 0.29
initial institutions x (0.11) (0.09) (0.09) (0.07)
Atlantic traderdummy
R-squared 0.76 0.81 0.82 0.84 0.76 0.72 0.77 0.78 0.70 0.71
Number of observations 192 192 192 192 192 240 240 240 240 240

Notes: Standarderrorsare in parentheses.Weighted panel regressions with full set of country and year dummies. Weights are total populationin each country in each
year, from McEvedy and Jones (1978). Dependent variable is urbanizationin panel A, log GDP per capita in panel B, and constrainton the executive in panel C.
Western Europe dummies interactedwith years (from 1600) are included in all columns, but not reportedto save space. Urbanizationin Europe is from Bairoch et
al. (1988), and urbanizationin Asia is from Bairoch (1998). Log GDP per capita is from Maddison (2001). Constrainton the executive is coded from Langer (1972);
initial institutionsare the average of institutionsin 1400 and 1500. We use the Atlantic traderdummy as the measure of potentialfor Atlantic trade.Volume of Atlantic
Trade is the log average numberof voyages per year and is demeaned. Main effects are evaluated at initial institutions equal to one. For data definitions and sources,
see Appendix, Table 1.

to-area ratio measure are identical, and are AT, - PATj,is generally significantby itself, and
contained in Acemoglu et al., 2002b). Panel A also when entered against the y,
t Ij,1415 ? d,
presents estimates of equation (3), while panel terms. This shows that the ability to take advan-
B presents estimates of a similar equation with tage of Atlantic trade was of major impor-
log income per capita as the dependentvariable. tance for post-1500 developments. When we
Panel C shows the role of the interaction be- add the triple interaction In AT,> PAT.
tween initial institutions and Atlantic trade for ?
j,,1415, this is typicallythe only significantterm.33
the evolution of institutions.
The results in all threepanels are similar.The
interaction between the aggregate measure of 33 When the In AT, -
PATj Ij,1415 term is included, In
Atlantic tradeand potentialfor Atlantic trade,In AT, PATjhas typically a negative and sometimes significant
?
572 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 2005

For example,the coefficientof 0.021 on this triple emphasizing distinctive European characteris-
interactionterm in column 4 implies that urban- tics and purely internaldynamics, but is consis-
ization in an Atlantic traderwith an initial con- tent with those that give a prominent role to
straint on the executive equal to 3, like the Atlantic tradeand deemphasizethe continuation
Netherlands,grew by 15.7 percentagepointsmore of pre-1500 trendsor permanentEuropeanchar-
than urbanizationin an Atlantic tradercountry acteristics, such as religion, Roman heritage,or
with the worst initialinstitutions,1 (0.021 X 2 X Europeanculture.If these factors are important,
3.74 ; 0.157, where3.74 is the changein the log it must be because of the interactionbetween
volume of Atlantictradebetween 1500 and 1800). them and the opportunity to trade in the
These results imply that the patternsreported Atlantic.
so far are explained almost entirely by the fact We suggested that Atlantic trade contrib-
that countries with initially constrained rulers uted to European growth through an indirect
were able to take advantageof the opportunities institutional channel as well as via its more
presentedby Atlantic trade.Although Spain and obvious direct effects. Our hypothesis is that
Portugalbenefitedfrom the transferof resources Atlantic trade generated large profits for com-
fromthe New Worldduringthe sixteenthcentury, mercial interests in favor of institutional
they neither developed the political institutions change in countries that met two crucial pre-
to support economic growth nor experienced conditions: easy access to the Atlantic and
sustainedeconomic development.Our evidence nonabsolutist initial institutions. These profits
suggests that these differential patterns are swung the balance of political power away
closely related to the fact that they started the from the monarchy and induced significant
post-1500 era with absolutistregimes in control reforms in political institutions, which intro-
of overseas activity. On the other hand, it ap- duced more secure property rights and paved
pears that the Italian city-states, which started the way for further innovations in economic
with relatively nonabsolutistinstitutionsaround institutions. With their newly gained property
1500, did not experience furthereconomic de- rights, English and Dutch merchant nations
velopment because they did not have as easy invested more, traded more, and spurredeco-
access to the Atlantic as Britain and the Neth- nomic growth.
erlands did. Britain and the Netherlands were Our analysis stopped before West European
the economic winners because they had both industrialization,focusing instead on economic
relatively good political institutionsto startwith and political developments between the six-
and ready access to the Atlantic. teenth and nineteenth centuries. Consequently,
we did not investigate why some successful
V. Conclusion Atlantic nations, like the Dutch, did not indus-
trialize early, while Britain and some non-
This paperdocuments a distinctive and inter- Atlantic nations such as Germany did. We
esting fact related to the process of European suspect that the answer is related to interstate
growth: between 1500 and 1850, the growth of competition, "defensive modernization" re-
nations with access to the Atlantic, and the sponses of certain Europeannations, and, pos-
growth of Atlantic ports, accountfor most of the sibly, the adverse effects of oligarchies on
differential growth of Western Europe relative industrialization,but we leave furtherinvestiga-
to EasternEurope. It thereforeappearsthat the tion of this issue for future research.
rise of Europe between 1500 and 1850 was The process of early modern European
largely the rise of Atlantic Europe and the rise growth is undoubtedly multifaceted. We are
of Atlantic ports. This fact weighs against the- aware that our account leaves out many impor-
ories of the origins of European development tant aspects of the social and economic devel-
opment of WesternEurope.Our intentionis not
to offer a mono-causal explanation for the rise
coefficient, reinforcing the conclusion that nations with of Europe, but rather to suggest that Atlantic
absolutist institutions did not benefit much, or at all, from
the opportunityto trade in the Atlantic. In addition, in three
trade played a major role in this process. It is
specifications in Table 7, the interactions between initial
our hope that our hypothesis and the empirical
institutions and dates after 1600 are jointly significant, but patternsdocumented in this paper will encour-
the coefficients (not shown in the tables) are negative. age furtherresearch.
VOL.95 NO. 3 ACEMOGLUET AL.: THE RISE OF EUROPE 573

OF KEY VARIABLES
APPENDIX:CONSTRUCTION 1601-1650:-Profits for the vertically inte-
grated Dutch East India Company from
Country-Leveland City-Level Urbanization 1630-1670 were 2.1m guilders (de Vries and
Data.-Calculated from the urban population van der Woude, 1997, p. 447); British trade
dataset of Bairoch et al. (1988) and country with Asia was around a half of Dutch levels in
population estimates from McEvedy and Jones the seventeenth century (de Vries, 2003); and
(1978). Details are providedin the Appendix of the guilder-pound exchange rate fluctuated
Acemoglu et al. (2002b). around 10, so total British profits from Asian
trade (including interlopers and suppliers)
TradeMeasures.-Acemoglu et al. (2002b) were likely around ?100,000 per annum
explain in detail the construction of Atlantic (which is consistent with Chaudhuri, 1965).
and Mediterranean trade volume measures. Around ?10m was invested between 1600 and
These series are annual average voyages 1630 in joint stock companies active in the
equivalent for ships of 400 deadweight tons. New World and Africa (Rabb, 1967). Even
The Mediterranean trade estimates are based when a company failed to show returns, as
on information on Venetian trade levels from with the Virginia Company, individual colo-
Frederic Chapin Lane (1934), but we also nists and their suppliers could earn good prof-
include Genoa, Catalonia, and other trading its. Privateering in the 1630s and 1640s was
centers (Carla Rahn Phillips, 1990). Estimates highly profitable (Craven, 1930). We assume
exclude short-haul coastal trade and trade by the same level of earnings in the New World
the British and Dutch-these countries also as in East India trade, i.e., ?100,000 per an-
engaged in Mediterranean trade as they built num, yielding an estimate of average annual
their naval power and trading empires after profits of ?200,000 in 1600 prices.
1600.
Key sources for our Atlantic trade series 1651-1675:-From 1650 we use the annual
are de Vries (2003), Tracy (1990), Davis value of export production in British America
(1962), and N. Steensgaard (1974). We have from Inikori (2002, p. 181). This was
also constructed an alternative Atlantic trade ?421,000 in 1651-1670 and ?2.7m per annum
series based on Kevin H. O'Rourke and Jef- for 1711-1760; we take the average value for
frey G. Williamson (2002). Robustness re- 1651-1700 to be ?1m. O'Brien's (1982) num-
sults using this series are reported in bers suggest that profits were 50 percent of
Acemoglu et al. (2002b). The growth of our import volume, implying profits of ?500,000.
volume-based Atlantic trade series matches To this, we add ?100,000 per annum from
closely the sum of annual value of Europe- the East India trade with the same calcula-
Africa-New World commerce series in Inikori tion as above, yielding profits of ?600,000
(2002, Table 4.8, p. 202) and de Vries' (2003) per annum, or approximately?500,000 in 1600
trade flows with Asia. prices.

Estimatesof British Profitsfrom Trade.-All 1676-1700:-Inikori' s British America


figures are approximatelyin 1600 prices using trade estimate is ?2.7m per annum for 1711-
the index of building craftsmen's wages, con- 1760; we assume ?2m per annum for 1676-
structedby Phelps Brown and Hopkins (1955), 1700, which implies profits of ?1m. Adding
which shows a doubling of wages from 1500 to East India profits of ?100,000 gives an average
1600, then a 50 percent increase from 1600 to annual profit estimate of ?1.1m, or ?900,000 in
1650, followed by rough stability through 1700 1600 prices.
and a further 50 percent increase during the
eighteenth century. 1701-1750:-Inikori's British America trade
estimate is ?6.8m for 1761-1780; we take the
1576-1600:-Rabb (1967, pp. 61-62) calcu- average value for 1701-1750 to be ?4m, thus
lates that total profits from privateering in profits of ?2m. Adding again profits of
1585-1603 were ?700,000. Dividing by 25 ?100,000 from East India gives an average an-
years gives an average of ?28,000 per year, nual profit estimate of ?2.1m, about ?1.7m in
approximately?40,000 in 1600 prices. 1600 prices.
574 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 2005

APPENDIX, TABLE 1-VARIABLE DEFINITIONS AND SOURCES

Variable Description Source

Log GDP per capita in 1500, 1600, 1700, 1820, Logarithmof GDP per capita Maddison (2001)
and 1870
Population in 1000, 1200, 1300, 1400, 1500, Total population McEvedy and Jones (1978)
1600, 1700, 1750, 1800, and 1850
Urban population in 1000, 1200, 1300, 1400, Population living in urban areas Bairoch et al. (1988), as describedin the
1500, 1600, 1700, 1750, 1800, and 1850 Appendix. We use Bairoch (1988) for
urbanizationin Asia and Chandler(1996) for
Asian city population.
Atlantic and Mediterraneanports City that is on the Atlantic or Mediterranean Bairoch et al. (1988) for cities; location from
Doring Kindersley (DK) Publishers(1997).
Ratio of Atlantic coastline to area Length of Atlantic coastline divided by land area. Coastline is from IntegratedCoastline
Both assume modern borders. Atlantic coastline Management(on the Web). Land area is from
includes the whole coast of Portugal,Ireland, the World Bank, WorldDevelopment
Belgium, the Netherlands,and Britain. It also Indicators, CD-Rom, 1999.
includes half the coastline of Spain, two-thirds
the coastline of France, half the coastline of
Germany, one-quarterthe coastline of Denmark,
and half the coastline of Norway.
Dummy for Atlantic trader Equals one for Britain, France, the Netherlands, Coded by authorsbased on composition of
Portugal,and Spain Atlantic trade. Acemoglu et al. (2002b) for
details.
Dummy for Atlantic port Equals one for a city that was used as an Atlantic Bairoch et al. (1988) for cities; location from
port; zero otherwise DK Publishing (1997).
Dummy for potential Atlantic port Equals one for a city that is on the Atlantic; zero Bairoch et al. (1988) for cities; location from
otherwise DK Publishing (1997).
Volume of Atlantic trade Average voyages per year equivalent See Appendix. Acemoglu et al. (2002b) provide
full details.
Constrainton executive in 1800, 1850, 1960, A seven-category scale, from I to 7, with a higher Polity IV dataset, downloaded from Inter-
1970, 1990, and intervening years score indicating more constraints.Score of I University Consortiumfor Political and
indicates unlimited authority;score of 3 Social Research. Variable describedin Gurr
indicates slight to moderate limitations;score of (1997).
5 indicates substantiallimitations; score of 7
indicates executive parity or subordination.
Scores of 2, 4, and 6 indicate intermediate
values.
Constrainton executive from 1000 to 1800 A seven-category scale, from 1 to 7, with a higher Coded by authorsfrom Langer (1972); see
score indicating more constraints.Score of I Appendix for more details.
indicates unlimited authority;score of 3
indicates slight to moderate limitations; score of
5 indicates substantiallimitations; score of 7
indicates executive parity or subordination.
Scores of 2, 4, and 6 indicate intermediate
values.
Religion variables Majority religion of city or country Coded by authorsfrom Langer (1972)
Roman heritage Coded equal to one for countries that were part of Coded by authorsfrom Langer (1972)
the Roman Empireand not subsequentlypart of
the OttomanEmpire.
Wars per year Number of years of war in preceding 50 or 100 Coded by authorsfrom Kohn (1999)
years. Civil wars and colonial wars outside
Europe are excluded.
Latitude Absolute value of the latitude of the country, Countrydata from La Porta et al. (1999). City
scaled to take values between 0 and I, where 0 data from Bairoch et al. (1988).
is the equator

1751-1800:-Inikori's British America trade Finland, Germany, the Netherlands, Norway,


estimates of ?19,545 for 1781-1800 implies Sweden, and Switzerlandwere majorityProtes-
annual profits of around ?10m, i.e., double tant in 1600. Germany was largely Protestant,
O'Brien's profit estimate (approximately ?5m but the balance remained unclear until the end
in 1600 prices). of the 1600s. The results are robust to coding
It is worth noting that our profit estimates Germany as Catholic. We have also tried an
would be significantlyhigherpriorto 1650 if we alternative specification in which religion is
also included British and Dutch trade in Asian coded directly as Catholic, Muslim, Orthodox,
goods passing throughPortugal, Spain, and the or Protestant,with essentially identical results.
Levant (Israel, 1989; Brenner, 2003).
Roman Heritage.-From Langer (1972) the
Religion.-From Langer (1972) and Stearns following countrieshad a Roman heritage:Bel-
(2001), Britain, the Czech Republic, Denmark, gium, Britain, France, Italy, the Netherlands,
VOL.95 NO. 3 ACEMOGLUET AL.: THE RISE OF EUROPE 575

Portugal, Spain, and Switzerland. Bulgaria, Acemoglu,Daron;Johnson,Simonand Robinson,


Greece, Romania,and Yugoslavia had their Ro- James A. "Reversal of Fortune: Geography
man traditions eradicated by a long period of and Institutionsin the Making of the Modern
Ottoman rule. If they are also coded with Ro- World Income Distribution."QuarterlyJour-
man heritage,the effect of this variableis weak- nal of Economics, 2002a, 117(4), pp. 1231-
ened further. 94.
Acemoglu,Daron;Johnson,Simonand Robinson,
Wars.-George Childs Kohn (1999) lists James A. "The Rise of Europe: Atlantic
the dates of every European war from about Trade, Institutional Change and Economic
AD 1000, and a brief explanation of partici- Growth."National Bureau of Economic Re-
pants, duration, intensity, and outcome. We search, Inc., NBER Working Papers: No.
calculate the average number of years of 9378, 2002b.
war in a time interval before each date in Anderson,Perry.Passages from antiquitytofeu-
our dataset: for the preceding 100 years dalism. London: NLB Press, 1974.
through 1700 and for the preceding 50 years Ashton,Robert. The crown and the money mar-
for 1750, 1800, and 1850, excluding purely ket, 1603-1640. Oxford: Oxford University
civil wars and colonial wars outside Europe. Press, 1960.
Alternative codings such as dropping "minor" Ashton, Robert. The city and the court, 1603-
wars does not affect our main results. Kohn 1643. Cambridge: Cambridge University
(1999) does not provide reliable information Press, 1979.
on the wars of Finland and Greece during this Ashton,Robert."Insurgency,Counter-Insurgency
period, so we drop these countries from re- and Inaction:Three Phases in the Role of the
gressions involving the "wars per year" City in the GreatRebellion," in Stephen Por-
variable. ter, ed., London and the Civil War. New
York: St. Martin's Press, 1996.
Constraint on Executive.-This variable is Bairoch, Paul. Cities and economic develop-
coded using the method of Polity IV as de- ment: From the dawn of history to the
scribed in footnote 32. Our primary source in present. Chicago: University of Chicago
this exercise is the historical encyclopedia of Press, 1988.
Langer (1972), supplemented with Stearns Bairoch, Paul. Economics and world history:
(2001). Acemoglu et al. (2002b) provide more Myths and paradoxes. Chicago:University of
details on our coding, the full series, and Chicago Press, 1993.
robustness checks with some reasonable al- Bairoch,Paul;Batou,Jean and Chevre,Pierre.La
ternatives. We also checked our results using population des villes europeenees de 800 a
the three codings of institutions in De Long 1850: Banque de donnees et analyse som-
and Shleifer (1993), which are somewhat dif- maire des resultats. (Thepopulation of Euro-
ferent from ours, for example awarding a pean cities, 800-1850: Data bank and short
much better score to feudal systems than does summary of results.) Centre of International
coding based on the Polity criteria. Using Economic History Series, No. 2. Geneva: Li-
their measures leads to very similar results to brarie Droz, 1988.
those reported in the text. Bean, Richard."Warand the Birth of the Nation
State." Journal of Economic History, 1973,
REFERENCES 33(1), pp. 203-21.
Boxer, Charles R. Portuguese conquest and
Acemoglu,Daronand Robinson,JamesA. "Polit- commerce in Southern Asia, 1500-1750.
ical Losers as a Barrierto Economic Devel- Reprint, London: Variorum Reprints,
opment."American Economic Review, 2000, 1985.
90(2), pp. 126-30. Braudel, Fernand. Civilization and capitalism
Acemoglu,Daron and Robinson,James A. "Eco- 15th-18th Century:VolumeIlL Theperspec-
nomic Backwardness in Political Perspec- tive of the world. Reprint, Berkeley: Univer-
tive." National Bureau of Economic sity of California Press, 1992.
Research, Inc., NBER Working Papers: No. Braudel, Fernand. The Mediterranean and the
8831, 2002. Mediterraneanworld in the age of Philip II,
576 THEAMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 2005

Vol. II. Reprint,Berkeley: University of Cal- de Vries,Jan. The economy of Europe in an age
ifornia Press, 1995. of crisis, 1600-1750. Cambridge:Cambridge
Brenner, Robert. "The Civil War Politics of University Press, 1976.
London's Merchant Community." Past and de Vries, Jan. European urbanization, 1500-
Present, 1973, 58, pp. 53-107. 1800. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Brenner, Robert. Merchants and revolution: Press, 1984.
Commercial change, political conflict and de Vries, Jan. "ConnectingEurope and Asia: A
London's overseas traders, 1550-1653. Re- Quantitative Analysis of the Cape Route
print, London: Verso, 2003. Trade, 1497-1795," in Dennis Flynn, Arturo
Brunton, Douglas and Pennington,D. H. Mem- Giraldezand Richardvon Glahn,eds., Global
bers of the Long Parliament. London: Allen connections and monetary history, 1470-
and Unwin, 1954. 1800. London: Ashgate Publishers,2003.
Cameron,Rondo.A concise economic history of de Vries, Jan and van der Woude, Ad. Thefirst
the world from paleolithic times to the modern economy: Success, failure, and per-
present. 2nd Ed. New York: Oxford Univer- severance of the Dutch economy, 1500-
sity Press, 1993. 1815. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Carruthers,BruceG. Cityof capital: Politics and Press, 1997.
markets in the English financial revolution. Doyle,William.TheParliamentof Bordeauxand
Princeton:PrincetonUniversityPress, 1996. the end of the Old Regime, 1771-1790. Lon-
Chandler,Tertius.Four thousandyears of urban don: Ernest Benn, 1974.
growth: An historical census. Lewiston: St. Doyle, William. Origins of the French Revolu-
David's University Press, 1987. tion. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1988.
Chaudhuri, Kirti N. The English East India DorlingKindersley(DK)Publishers.Worldatlas.
Company: The study of an early joint-stock New York: DK Publishers, 1997.
company 1600-1640. London: FrankCass & Elton, Geoffrey R. England under the Tudors,
Co., 1965. 3rd Ed. New York: Routledge, 1991.
Church,WilliamF. The impact of absolutismon Engerman, Stanley L. "The Slave Trade and
France: National experience under Rich- British Capital Formation in the Eighteenth
elieu, Mazarin, and Louis XIV. New York: Century: A Comment on the Williams The-
John Wiley & Sons, 1969. sis." Business History Review, 1972, 46(4),
Cooper, J. P. "Social and Economic Policies pp. 430-43.
under the Commonwealth,"in GerardE. Ay- Engerman,Stanley L. and O'Brien, Patrick K.
lmer, ed., The interregnum: The quest for "Exportsand the Growthof the BritishEcon-
settlement 1646-1660. London: Macmillan, omy from the Glorious Revolution to the
1972. Peace of Amiens," in Solow, BarbaraL., ed.,
Craven, W. Frank. "The Earl of Warwick, a Slavery and the rise of the Atlantic system.
Speculator in Piracy." The Hispanic Ameri- Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
can Historical Review, 1930, 10(4), pp. 457- 1991.
79. Farnell,J. E. "The Navigation Act of 1651, the
Davis, Ralph. The rise of the English shipping First Dutch War, and the London Merchant
industry in the seventeenth and eighteenth Community." Economic History Review,
centuries. London: Macmillan & Co. Ltd., 1963/1964, 16, pp. 439-545.
1962. Frank, Andre G. Dependent accumulation
Davis, Ralph. English overseas trade and underdevelopment. London: Macmil-
1500-1700. London: Macmillan & Co. Ltd., lan, 1978.
1973a. Fritschy, Wantje. "A 'Financial Revolution'
Davis,Ralph.The rise of the Atlantic economies. Reconsidered: Public Finance in Holland
Ithaca:Cornell University Press, 1973b. During the Dutch Revolt, 1568-1648." Eco-
De Long, J. Bradford and Shleifer, Andrei. nomic History Review, 2003, 56(1), pp.
"Princes and Merchants: European City 57-89.
Growth before the Industrial Revolution." Fritschy,Wantje; Hart, Marjoleinand Horlings,
Journal of Law and Economics, 1993, 36(2), Edwin. "Continuities and Discontinuities in
pp. 671-702. Dutch Fiscal History, C. 1515-1913," Eco-
VOL.95 NO. 3 ACEMOGLUET AL.: THE RISE OF EUROPE 577

nomic History Congress. Madrid, June 21- trade, 1585-1740. Oxford: ClarendonPress,
23, 2001. http://www.eh.net/XIIICongress/ 1989.
cd/papers/12FritschyHartHorlings86.pdf. Israel, JonathanI. The Dutch Republic: Its rise,
Gauci,Perry. Thepolitics of trade: The overseas greatness and fall 1477-1806 VolumeI: The
merchant in state and society 1660-1720. Oxfordhistory of early modern Europe. New
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001. York: Oxford University Press, 1995.
Grassby,Richard."The Rate of Profitin Seven- Jones, Eric L. The European miracle: Environ-
teenth-CenturyEngland."English Historical ments, economies, and geopolitics in the his-
Review, 1969, 84(333), pp. 721-51. tory of Europe and Asia. New York:
Grassby, Richard. The business community of CambridgeUniversity Press, 1981.
seventeenth-century England. Cambridge: Keeler, Mary F. The Long Parliament, 1640-
CambridgeUniversity Press, 1995. 1641: A Biographical Study of Its Members.
Graves, Michael A. R. The parliaments of Philadelphia: American Philosophical Soci-
early modern Europe. New York: Long- ety, 1954.
man, 2001. Kennedy,Paul M. The rise and fall of the great
Gurr,Ted Robert."PolityII: Political Structures powers: Economic change and military con-
and Regime Change, 1800-1986." Unpub- flict from 1500 to 2000. New York: Random
lished Paper, 1997. House, 1987.
Hall, John A. Powers and liberties: The causes Kohn, GeorgeC. Dictionary of war, revised edi-
and consequences of the rise of the West. tion. New York: Facts on File, Inc., 1999.
Oxford: Blackwell, 1985. Krusell,Per and Rios-Rull,Jose-Victor."Vested
Hamilton,Earl J. "The Role of Monopoly in the Interests in a Theory of Stagnation and
Overseas Expansion and Colonial Trade of Growth."Review of Economic Studies, 1996,
Europe before 1800." American Economic 63(2), pp. 301-30.
Review, 1948, 38(2), pp. 33-53. La Porta, Rafael; Lopez-de-Silanes,Florencio;
Hart, Marjolein;Jonker, Joost and van Zanden, Shleifer,Andrei and Vishny, Robert W. "The
Jan L. A financial history of the Netherlands. Quality of Government." Journal of Law,
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, Economics, and Organization, 1999, 15(1),
1997. pp. 222-79.
Hill, Christopher.From Reformation to Indus- Landes, David S. The wealth and poverty of
trial Revolution 1530-1780. Baltimore:Pen- nations: Why some are so rich and some so
guin Books, 1969. poor. New York: W. W. Norton & Co., 1998.
Hintze,Otto. "MilitaryOrganizationand the Or- Lane, FredericC. Venetianships and shipbuild-
ganization of the State,"in Felix Gilbert,ed., ing of the Renaissance. Baltimore: Johns
The historical essays of Otto Hintze. New Hopkins University Press, 1934.
York: Oxford University Press, 1975, pp. Lang, R. G. "Social Origins and Social Aspira-
178-215. tions of Jacobean London Merchants."Eco-
Holmes,Geoffrey.The makingof a great power: nomic History Review, Second Series, 1974,
Late Stuart and early Georgian Britain. New 27(1), pp. 28-47.
York: Longman, 1993. Langer, William L. An encyclopedia of world
Horwitz, Henry. "The East India Trade, the history, 5th Ed. Boston: Houghton Mifflin
Politicians, and the Constitution: 1698- Co., 1972.
1702." The Journal of British Studies, Lefebvre,Georges(Translatedby R. R. Palmer).
1978, 17(2), pp. 1-18. The coming of the French Revolution.Prince-
Inikori, Joseph E. Africans and the Industrial ton: Princeton University Press, 1947.
Revolution in England: A study in interna- Maddison, Angus. The world economy: A mil-
tional trade and economic development. lennial perspective. Paris: OECD, Develop-
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, ment Center, 2001.
2002. Manning,Brian.Aristocrats,plebeians, and rev-
Israel, JonathanI. The Dutch Republic and the olution in England, 1640-1660. New Haven:
Hispanic world, 1606-1661. Oxford:Oxford Pluto Press, 1996.
University Press, 1982. Marshall,MontyG. and Jaggers,Keith.Polity IV
Israel, Jonathan I. Dutch primacy in world Project, political regime characteristics and
578 THE AMERICANECONOMICREVIEW JUNE 2005

transitions 1800-1999, dataset users man- Parry, James H. The Spanish seaborne empire.
ual. College Park: Center for International Berkeley: University of California Press,
Development and Conflict Management, 1966.
University of Maryland,2000. Pearl, Valerie. London and the outbreakof the
McEvedy, Colin and Jones, Richard. Atlas of Puritan revolution: City governmentand na-
world population history. New York: Facts tional politics, 1625-43. London: Oxford
on File, Inc., 1978. University Press, 1961.
Morrill, John S. The nature of the English Phelps Brown, Ernest H. and Hopkins,Sheila V.
Revolution. London: Longman Publishing "Seven Centuries of Building Wages." Eco-
Group, 1993. nomica, New Series, 1955, 22(87), pp. 192-
Neal, Larry. "How It All Began: The Mone- 206.
tary and Financial Architecture of Europe Phillips,Carla Rahn. "The Growthand Compo-
During the First Global Capital Markets, sition of Tradein the IberianEmpires, 1450-
1648-815." Financial History Review, 1750," in James D. Tracy, ed., The rise of
2000, 7(2), pp. 117-40. merchant empires: Long-distance trade in
North, DouglassC. and Thomas, Robert P. The the early modern world, 1350-1750. Cam-
rise of the Westernworld: A new economic bridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990,
history. Cambridge: Cambridge University pp. 34-101.
Press, 1973. Pincus,Steven."Civic Republicanismand Polit-
North, DouglassC. Structureand change in eco- ical Economy in an Age of Revolution:Law,
nomic history. New York: W. W. Norton & Politics, and Economics in the Revolution of
Co., 1981. 1688-89." Unpublished Paper, 2002.
North,DouglassC. and Weingast,BarryR. "Con- Rabb,TheodoreK. Enterpriseand empire:Mer-
stitutionsand Commitment:The Evolution of chant and gentry investmentin the expansion
InstitutionsGoverning Public Choice in Sev- of England, 1575-1630. Cambridge, MA:
enteenth-CenturyEngland."Journal of Eco- HarvardUniversity Press, 1967.
nomic History, 1989, 49(4), pp. 803-32. Rabb,TheodoreK. Jacobean gentleman:Sir Ed-
O'Brien, Patrick K. "EuropeanEconomic De- win Sandays, 1561-1629. Princeton:Prince-
velopment: The Contributionof the Periph- ton University Press, 1998.
ery." Economic History Review, Second Rajan, RaghuramG. and Zingales,Luigi.Saving
Series, 1982, 35(1), pp. 1-18. capitalism from the capitalists: Unleashing
O'Rourke, Kevin H. and Williamson,Jeffrey G. the power of financial markets to create
"After Columbus: Explaining the Global wealth and spread opportunity. New York:
Trade Boom 1500-1800." Journal of Eco- Crown Publishing Group, 2003.
nomic History, 2002, 62(2), pp. 471-56. Richardson,Roger C. The debate on the English
Olson, Mancur.The rise and decline of nations: Revolution, 3rd Ed. Manchester:University
Economic growth, stagflation, and economic of ManchesterPress, 1998.
rigidities. New Haven: Yale University Rodger, N. A. M. The safeguard of the sea: A
Press, 1982. naval history of Britain, 660-1649. New
Parente, Stephen L. and Prescott, Edward C. York: W. W. Norton & Sons, 1997.
"Monopoly Rights: A Barrier to Riches." Rogowski, Ronald. Commerce and coalitions:
American Economic Review, 1999, 89(5), pp. How trade affects Domestic Political Align-
1216-33. ments. Princeton:PrincetonUniversityPress,
Parker, Geoffrey.The Dutch Revolt. New York: 1989.
Penguin Books, 1977. Russell,Conrad.The causes of the English Civil
Parker, Geoffrey.The military revolution: Mili- War. New York: Oxford University Press,
tary innovation and the rise of the West, 1990.
1500-1800. Cambridge:CambridgeUniver- Sacks, David H. The widening gate: Bristol and
sity Press, 1988. the Atlantic economy, 1450-1700. The New
Parrott, David. Richelieu's army: War, govern- Historicism:Studies in CulturalPoetics, Vol.
ment and society in France, 1624-1642. 15. Berkeley and Oxford: University of Cal-
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, ifornia Press, 1991.
2001. Scoville, Warren C. The persecution of
VOL.95 NO. 3 ACEMOGLUET AL.: THE RISE OF EUROPE 579

Huguenots and French economic develop- Berkeley: University of California Press,


ment, 1680-1720. Berkeley: University of 1985.
California Press, 1960. Tracy, James D. The rise of merchant empires:
Sharpe, Kevin. The personal rule of Charles I. Long-distance trade in the early modern
New Haven: Yale University Press, 1992. world, 1350-1750. Cambridge: Cambridge
Stasavage,David. Public debt and the birth of University Press, 1990.
the democratic state: France and Great Brit- Tracy, James D. "Keeping the Wheels of War
ain, 1688-1789. Cambridge,New York and Turning: Revenues of the Province of Hol-
Melbourne:CambridgeUniversityPress,2003. land, 1572-1619," in GrahamDarby,ed., The
Stearns,Peter N. The encyclopedia of world his- origins and developmentof the Dutch Revolt.
tory, 6th Ed. Boston: HoughtonMifflin Com- New York: Routledge, 2001.
pany, 2001. van der Wee, Herman."TheEconomy as a Fac-
Steensgaard,Niels. TheAsian trade revolutionof tor in the Revolt of the Southern Nether-
the seventeenthcentury. Chicago: University lands," in Hermanvan der Wee, ed., The low
of Chicago Press, 1974. countries in the early modern world. Brook-
Stone,Lawrence.The causes of the English Rev- field: Variorum, 1993.
olution, 1529-1642. New York: Routledge, van Zanden, Jan L. The rise and decline of
1972. Holland's economy. Manchester:University
Thompson,I. A. A. "Castile, Absolutism, Con- of ManchesterPress, 1993.
stitutionalismand Liberty,"in Philip T. Hoff- Wallerstein,Immanuel M. The modern world-
man and KathrynNorberg,eds., Fiscal crisis, system. 3 Volumes. New York: Academic
liberty and representativegovernment.Stan- Press, 1974-1980.
ford: StanfordUniversity Press, 1994. Weber,Max. The Protestant ethic and the spirit
Tilly, Charles.Coercion, capital, and European of capitalism. London: Routledge, 1993.
states, AD 990-1990. Cambridge: Basil Williams,Eric. Capitalism and slavery. Chapel
Blackwell, 1990. Hill: University of North Carolina Press,
Tracy, James D. A financial revolution in the 1944.
Habsburg Netherlands: Renten and Rent- World Bank. World development indicators.
eniers in the countryof Holland, 1515-1565. Washington, DC: World Bank, 1999.

You might also like