You are on page 1of 33

Microeconomic Analysis (806L1)

Topic 5: Consumer Theory Part 2

Matthew Embrey

University of Sussex

Autumn 2023

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 1 / 18


Consumer Theory
Visual scheme

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 2 / 18


Consumer Theory
Visual scheme

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 2 / 18


Expenditure Mimimisation
The Dual Problem – Problem Statement

The consumer’s expenditure minimisation problem:


The desired
 level of utility u ⇒ utility constraint set
P = (x1 , x2 ) ∈ R2+ |u (x1 , x2 ) ≥ u
Given prices p1 , p2 , choose cheapest bundle from utility constraint set
Objective is to minimise expenditure, p1 x1 + p2 x2

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 3 / 18


Expenditure Mimimisation
The Dual Problem – Problem Statement

The consumer’s expenditure minimisation problem:


The desired
 level of utility u ⇒ utility constraint set
P = (x1 , x2 ) ∈ R2+ |u (x1 , x2 ) ≥ u
Given prices p1 , p2 , choose cheapest bundle from utility constraint set
Objective is to minimise expenditure, p1 x1 + p2 x2
Specific example with General case:
u (h1 , h2 ) = h1 h2 :

min p1 h1 + p2 h2 min p1 h1 + p2 h2
h1 ,h2 h1 ,h2

subject to subject to
h1 h2 ≥ u u (h1 , h2 ) ≥ u
h1 ≥ 0 h1 ≥ 0
h2 ≥ 0 h2 ≥ 0

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 3 / 18


Expenditure Mimimisation
The Dual Problem – Problem Statement

The consumer’s expenditure minimisation problem:


The desired
 level of utility u ⇒ utility constraint set
P = (x1 , x2 ) ∈ R2+ |u (x1 , x2 ) ≥ u
Given prices p1 , p2 , choose cheapest bundle from utility constraint set
Objective is to minimise expenditure, p1 x1 + p2 x2
Specific example with General case:
u (h1 , h2 ) = h1 h2 :

min p1 h1 + p2 h2 min p1 h1 + p2 h2
h1 ,h2 h1 ,h2

subject to subject to
h1 h2 ≥ u u (h1 , h2 ) ≥ u
h1 ≥ 0 h1 ≥ 0
h2 ≥ 0 h2 ≥ 0

Form the Lagrangian: Form the Lagrangian:

L = p1 h1 + p2 h2 + µ(u − h1 h2 ) L = p1 h1 + p2 h2 + µ(u − u (h1 , h2 ))

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 3 / 18


Expenditure Minimisation
First Order Conditions

Specific example (cont.): General case (cont.)

L = p1 h1 + p2 h2 + µ(u − h1 h2 ) L = p1 h1 + p2 h2 + µ(u − u (h1 , h2 ))

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 4 / 18


Expenditure Minimisation
First Order Conditions

Specific example (cont.): General case (cont.)

L = p1 h1 + p2 h2 + µ(u − h1 h2 ) L = p1 h1 + p2 h2 + µ(u − u (h1 , h2 ))

First order conditions (FOC): First order conditions (FOC):

∂L ∂L
L1 = = p1 − µh2 = 0 L1 = = p1 − µu1 (h1 , h2 ) = 0
∂h1 ∂h1
∂L ∂L
L2 = = p2 − µh1 = 0 L2 = = p2 − µu2 (h1 , h2 ) = 0
∂h2 ∂h2
∂L ∂L
Lµ = = u − h1 h2 = 0 Lµ = = u − u (h1 , h2 ) = 0
∂µ ∂µ

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 4 / 18


Expenditure Minimisation
First Order Conditions

Specific example (cont.): General case (cont.)

L = p1 h1 + p2 h2 + µ(u − h1 h2 ) L = p1 h1 + p2 h2 + µ(u − u (h1 , h2 ))

First order conditions (FOC): First order conditions (FOC):

∂L ∂L
L1 = = p1 − µh2 = 0 L1 = = p1 − µu1 (h1 , h2 ) = 0
∂h1 ∂h1
∂L ∂L
L2 = = p2 − µh1 = 0 L2 = = p2 − µu2 (h1 , h2 ) = 0
∂h2 ∂h2
∂L ∂L
Lµ = = u − h1 h2 = 0 Lµ = = u − u (h1 , h2 ) = 0
∂µ ∂µ

Eliminate µ: Eliminate µ:
p1 p2 p1 p2
=µ= =µ=
h2 h1 u1 (h1 , h2 ) u2 (h1 , h2 )
⇒ ⇒
h2 p1 u1 (h1 , h2 ) p1
= =
h1 p2 u2 (h1 , h2 ) p2

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 4 / 18


Expenditure Mimimisation
Hicksian Demands

This yields the familiar tangency condition


u
For the specific example, re-write utility constraint as h2 = h1 and
substitute into tangency condition
u p1
=
h12 p2

p2 u 1
h1∗ = ( )2
p1
Similarily,
p1 u 1
h2∗ = ( )2
p2

These are the Hicksian or compensated demands (functions of price


and utility).
Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 5 / 18
Change in Price
Marshallian v. Hicksian Demands

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 6 / 18


Change in Price
Marshallian v. Hicksian Demands

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 6 / 18


Expenditure Mimimisation
Expenditure function

The expenditure function e(u, p⃗) informs us about the minimum level
of income required to achieve utility u in face of prices p⃗.
Useful in public-policy analyses - we can monetize trade-offs (instead
of dealing with ‘utils’.)
From our simple example:
Solving expenditure minimisation yields the Hicksian demands:
1 1
h1 = ( pp21ū ) 2 and h2 = ( pp12ū ) 2
1
e = p⃗ · ⃗h = 2(p1 p2 ū) 2
Properties of the expenditure function e(u, p⃗):
Homogeneous of degree 1 in prices (i.e. double all prices ⇒ double
expenditure needed to maintain utility level without changing ⃗h)
Shephard’s lemma: hi = ∂e(u,⃗
∂pi
p)

Concave in p⃗

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 7 / 18


Expenditure Mimimisation
Shephard’s lemma

∂e
Shephard’s lemma: ∂pi = hi
Minh1 ,h2 e = p1 h1 + p2 h2 subject to u ≥ ū
Form the Lagrangian: L = p1 h1 + p2 h2 + µ(ū − u)
Recall the following FOC: µ = pu11 = pu22

∂L ∂h1 ∂h1 ∂h2 ∂h2


= h1 + (p1 − µu1 ) + (p2 − µu2 )
∂p1 ∂p1 ∂p1 ∂p1 ∂p1
∂h1 p1 ∂h1 ∂h2 p2 ∂h2
= h1 + (p1 − u1 ) + (p2 − u2 )
∂p1 u1 ∂p1 ∂p1 u2 ∂p1
= h1

∂L ∂e
Thus ∂p 1
= ∂p 1
= h1
This result can also be derived directly by applying the envelope
theorem to e(⃗p , u).

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 8 / 18


Expenditure Mimimisation
Concavity of the expenditure function

Intuitively, as price of a good rises, consumer adjusts bundle (substitutes away) so


that expenditure does not rise proportionally.

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 9 / 18


Expenditure Mimimisation
Concavity of the expenditure function

Intuitively, as price of a good rises, consumer adjusts bundle (substitutes away) so


that expenditure does not rise proportionally.
Formally, for any p⃗1 , p⃗2 and p⃗ = α⃗p 1 + (1 − α)⃗
p 2 for α ∈ [0, 1],
1 2
p , u) ≥ αe(⃗
e(⃗ p , u) + (1 − α)e(⃗ p , u). Proof:
Let ⃗h1 , ⃗h2 , ⃗h be the Hicksian demands at prices p ⃗1 , p⃗2 , p
⃗ respectively.
p 1 , u) = p
e(⃗ ⃗1 · ⃗h1 ≤ p
⃗1 · ⃗h (since ⃗h1 is the expenditure minimising bundle at p ⃗1 ).
Similarly, e(⃗ 2
p , u) = p 2
⃗ ·h ≤p⃗ 2 2 ⃗
⃗ · h.
αe(⃗p 1 , u) + (1 − α)e(⃗ p 2 , u) ≤ (α⃗ p 2 ) · ⃗h = p
p 1 + (1 − α)⃗ ⃗ · ⃗h = e(⃗
p , u)

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 9 / 18


Duality in Consumer Theory
Duality graphically

Maximizing utility subject to a budget constraint leads to the same x ∗


as minimising expenditure subject to a utility level.
The first case leads to Marshallian demand x ∗ (m, p⃗) while the second
leads to Hicksian demand x ∗ (ū, p⃗).

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 10 / 18


Duality in Consumer Theory
Duality graphically

Maximizing utility subject to a budget constraint leads to the same x ∗


as minimising expenditure subject to a utility level.
The first case leads to Marshallian demand x ∗ (m, p⃗) while the second
leads to Hicksian demand x ∗ (ū, p⃗).

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 10 / 18


Duality in Consumer Theory
Duality graphically

Maximizing utility subject to a budget constraint leads to the same x ∗


as minimising expenditure subject to a utility level.
The first case leads to Marshallian demand x ∗ (m, p⃗) while the second
leads to Hicksian demand x ∗ (ū, p⃗).

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 10 / 18


Duality in Consumer Theory
Duality graphically

Maximizing utility subject to a budget constraint leads to the same x ∗


as minimising expenditure subject to a utility level.
The first case leads to Marshallian demand x ∗ (m, p⃗) while the second
leads to Hicksian demand x ∗ (ū, p⃗).

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 10 / 18


Duality in Consumer Theory
Duality graphically

Maximizing utility subject to a budget constraint leads to the same x ∗


as minimising expenditure subject to a utility level.
The first case leads to Marshallian demand x ∗ (m, p⃗) while the second
leads to Hicksian demand x ∗ (ū, p⃗).

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 10 / 18


Duality in Consumer Theory
Duality graphically

Maximizing utility subject to a budget constraint leads to the same x ∗


as minimising expenditure subject to a utility level.
The first case leads to Marshallian demand x ∗ (m, p⃗) while the second
leads to Hicksian demand x ∗ (ū, p⃗).

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 10 / 18


Duality in Consumer Theory
Duality graphically

Maximizing utility subject to a budget constraint leads to the same x ∗


as minimising expenditure subject to a utility level.
The first case leads to Marshallian demand x ∗ (m, p⃗) while the second
leads to Hicksian demand x ∗ (ū, p⃗).

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 10 / 18


Duality in Consumer Theory
Duality graphically

Maximizing utility subject to a budget constraint leads to the same x ∗


as minimising expenditure subject to a utility level.
The first case leads to Marshallian demand x ∗ (m, p⃗) while the second
leads to Hicksian demand x ∗ (ū, p⃗).

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 10 / 18


Duality in Consumer Theory
Indirect utility and expenditure as inverses

Utility maximisation: v (m, p⃗) = max⃗x u(⃗x ) subject to p⃗ · ⃗x ≤ m; let


v ∗ be indirect utility (function of income and price) achieved at the
optimum.
Expenditure minimisation: e(v ∗ , p⃗) = min⃗x p⃗ · ⃗x subject to u(⃗x ) ≥ v ∗ .
Same solution ⃗x ∗ in both cases although function of different
parameters.
1
Lagrange multipliers are inverse of each other: λ = µ
Identities:
e(v (⃗p , m), p⃗) ≡ m; the minimum expenditure required to reach utility
v (m, p⃗) is m.
v (e(u, p⃗), p⃗) ≡ u; the maximum achievable utility from income e(u, p⃗)
is u.

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 11 / 18


Consumer Theory
Visual scheme

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 12 / 18


Consumer Theory
Slutsky equation

There is a close relationship between the Marshallian and Hicksian


demands.

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 13 / 18


Consumer Theory
Slutsky equation

There is a close relationship between the Marshallian and Hicksian


demands.
Duality implies that for any chosen utility level ū:
⃗x (⃗ p , ū)) = ⃗h(⃗
p , e(⃗ p , ū)
But the two demand functions respond differently to a price change.
Differentiate the above equality for good 1 w.r.t p1 :
∂h1 ∂x1 ∂x1 ∂e
= +
∂p1 ∂p1 ∂m ∂p1
∂x1 ∂h1 ∂x1 ∂e
= −
∂p1 ∂p1 ∂m ∂p1
∂x1 ∂h1 ∂x1 ∂e
= − h1 (using Shephard’s lemma, = h1 )
∂p1 ∂p1 ∂m ∂p1

This last equation is the Slutsky equation linking the price responses
of Marshallian and Hicksian demands.
Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 13 / 18
Consumer Theory
Substitution and Income effects

∂x1 ∂h1 ∂x1


= − h1
∂p1 ∂p1 ∂m
The first term on the RHS is the substitution effect.
The substitution effect is the compensated price response.
It is always negative (it represents movement along an indifference
curve which slope downwards).
The Hicksian demand curve is composed only of the substitution effect.
The second term is the income effect.
The income effect is scaled by the effective change in income due to
∂e
the price change (recall that h1 = ∂p 1
)
If the consumer is buying a lot of good 1 i.e. h1 is large, a change in p1
has a large income effect.
The sign of the income effect is positive for a normal good and
negative for an inferior good.

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 14 / 18


Consumer Theory
Marshallian and Hicksian demand curves

Hicksian steeper than Marshallian for a normal good. For instance, an


increase in p1 reduces purchasing power. Consumer has to be
compensated to stay on the same indifference curve and so there is a
smaller drop in q1 .

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 15 / 18


Consumer Theory
Giffen goods

∂x1 ∂h1
Recall the Slutsky equation: ∂p1 = ∂p1 − h1 ∂x
∂m .
1

If a good is strongly inferior ( ∂x


< 0), then it could be Giffen
∂m
1

(demand goes up as price rises)


Rice & wheat noodles (staple foods) in China as Giffen goods?
Rice in Hunan while wheat noodles in Gansu province.
Vouchers for price subsidy on the staples distributed to poor urban
households in a randomised trial.
About 70% of calories derived from the staple food.
Enough vouchers i.e. a price reduction on the staple with no quantity
constraint.
Evidence of Giffen good for poor (just above subsistence) households -
reduction in purchase of staple and a shift towards expensive meat.
No such shift seen for rich households (staple share of their budget was
very low to being with).
Very poor (subsistence level) households increased their consumption.

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 16 / 18


Consumer Theory
Welfare change - Compensating Variation

How do we measure the welfare impact of


a price change?
Say customer originally at point a with
utility u0 .
Now price of x1 rises from p10 to p11 ?
Optimum shifts from a to b (lower utility).
Compensating variation (CV) is the
amount of monetary compensation that
would restore the customer to u0 (point c)
p 1 , u0 ) − e(⃗
CV = e(⃗ p 0 , u0 )
∂e
Shephard’s lemma: ∂p 1
= h1
R p11 R p11
CV = p0 de = p0 h1 (⃗ p , u0 )dp1
1 1

CV is the area under the Hicksian demand


curve: ACp11 p10 .

Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 17 / 18


Consumer Theory
Welfare change and Marshallian demand

Consider the Marshallian demand curve


x(⃗
p , m).
Consumer initially at A (x10 , p10 ).
p1 rises to p11 ; consumer shifts to B.
Hicksian demand curves through A and B
are h1 (⃗
p , u0 ) and h1 (⃗
p , u1 ).
CV is area ACp11 p10 .
Equivalent variation (EV) is how much the
consumer is willing to pay to return to old
prices at the new level of utility.
R p1
EV = p01 h1 (⃗p , u1 )dp1 ; area DBp11 p10 .
1

CV or EV can be used to measure welfare


changes.
If income effects are small, area under the
Marshallian demand curve is a good
approximation.
Matthew Embrey (University of Sussex) Microeconomic Analysis (806L1) Autumn 2023 18 / 18

You might also like