You are on page 1of 6

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/311907938

Firm Resources

Chapter · June 2016


DOI: 10.1057/978-1-349-94848-2_481-1

CITATIONS READS
4 9,680

2 authors:

Raphael Amit Paul Schoemaker


University of Pennsylvania University of Pennsylvania
113 PUBLICATIONS 40,651 CITATIONS 125 PUBLICATIONS 20,135 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

All content following this page was uploaded by Paul Schoemaker on 10 December 2017.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


By: Raphael Amit and Paul J.H. Schoemaker
The Palgrave Encyclopedia of Strategic Management
Mie Augier; David Teece
ISBN: 9781137294678
Palgrave Macmillan
firm resources complex interactions among the firm’s resources.
Such processes can be thought of as intermediate
Definition
A firm’s resources are available factors or inputs, both
goods generated by the firm to provide enhanced
tangible and intangible, that are owned and/or controlled productivity of its resources, as well as strategic
by the firm. Resources consist, among other things, of flexibility and protection for its final product or ser-
financial or physical assets (e.g., property, plant and vice. Resources naturally give rise to firm-specific
equipment), know-how that can be traded (e.g., patents capabilities, which develop organically by carrying
and licences) and human capital (e.g., talent, expertise and and exchanging information through the firm’s
experience). human capital. Capabilities are often developed in
Abstract
functional areas (e.g., brand management in mar-
The nature and value of a firm’s resources – especially the keting; drug development in the R&D department of

Copyright material from www.palgraveconnect.com - licensed to University of Delaware - PalgraveConnect - 2015-07-14


firm’s ability to deploy them to enhance their strategic a pharmaceutical company) or by combining physi-
value – are central to strategic management. Advances in cal, human and technological resources at the cor-
information and computing technology that blur firm porate level (e.g., M&A capabilities).
boundaries reinforce the important role of resource Some of the firm’s resources, and especially its
deployments that span firm and industry boundaries (Zott capabilities, may be subject to market failure, that is,
and Amit, 2010). In this article we provide an overview of an inability to trade these factors in perfect markets.
what constitutes a firm’s resources and identify Multiple sources of market failure have been sug-
characteristics that increase their strategic value. We draw gested: Williamson (1975) points to small numbers,
on theoretical perspectives such as the RESOURCE-BASED VIEW
opportunism and information impactedness; Klein,
and the DYNAMIC CAPABILITIES model of the firm, as well as
insights from networking and business model theory,
Crawford and Alchian (1978) focus on factor spe-
among others, to discuss current developments and future cialization in terms of use or location; Caves (1984)
directions. highlights sunk costs and suggests that a factor’s value
is inversely related to the extent of its specialization
for a particular use or industry setting.
A firm’s resources are available factors or inputs, both
tangible and intangible, that are owned and/or
controlled by the firm. Resources consist, among
other things, of financial or physical assets (e.g., Characteristics affecting the strategic value of a
property, plant and equipment), know-how that can firm’s resources
be traded (e.g., patents and licences) and human In general, the strategic value of a firm’s resources
capital (e.g., talent, expertise and experience). Bond- and capabilities (hereafter called R&C) increases with
ing mechanisms that firms use to convert these an increase in some key characteristics. The more
resources into final products or services include difficult the firm’s R&C are to buy, sell, imitate or
technology, management information systems, incen- substitute, the greater their strategic value to the firm.
tive systems and routines, trust between management For example, invisible assets such as tacit organiza-
and labour, organizational culture and norms, and tional knowledge or trust between management and
others. Grant (1991) provides a detailed list of firm labour cannot be traded or easily replicated by
resources; Barney (1991) discusses their strategic competitors, since they are deeply rooted in the
importance. The emphasis on resources gave rise to organization’s history. Such firm-specific and often
an important new perspective in strategic manage- tacit assets accumulate slowly over time (see Dierickx
ment in the 1980s, namely the RESOURCE-BASED VIEW and Cool, 1989). This idiosyncrasy and imperfect
(RBV) first articulated by Wernerfelt (1984). mobility make them difficult to imitate, and their
Access to resources in factor markets (for labour development time usually cannot be easily com-
capital, technology etc.) can be an important source pressed. The presence of complementarity – meaning
of COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGE. Equally important, how- that the firm’s R&C are of higher value when com-
ever, is a firm’s capacity to deploy resources, usually bined than if deployed individually – further
in combination with distinct organizational pro- enhances their strategic value to the firm. Conversely,
cesses. This capacity entails information-rich tangible the strategic value of the firm’s R&C declines to the
and intangible processes developed over time through extent that they are substitutes.

r Palgrave Publishers Ltd 1

10.1057/9781137294678 - The Palgrave Encyclopedia of Strategic Management, Edited by Mie Augier and David Teece
By: Raphael Amit and Paul J.H. Schoemaker
The Palgrave Encyclopedia of Strategic Management
firm resources Mie Augier; David Teece
ISBN: 9781137294678
Palgrave Macmillan
The more scarce, firm-specific and durable the entry or mobility barriers, or by building ‘isolating
firm’s R&C are, the more valuable they can be to the mechanisms’ as impediments to imitation (Rumelt,
firm. First, firms with a scarce resource or capability 1984). Such barriers may arise from limited market
can pursue market strategies based on these char- size, superior access to distribution channels, legal
acteristics to develop their competitive advantage, restrictions, economies of scale and scope and more.
since most other firms would find these strategies too Ghemawat (1991) especially emphasizes the role of
costly and time-consuming. Second, firm-specificity commitment and the firm’s superior access to
and the presence of transaction costs suggest that the resources.
value of some R&C will be lower when deployed by
other firms in the same or in alternative uses. Third,
the more durable the R&C, the smaller the invest- Theories

Copyright material from www.palgraveconnect.com - licensed to University of Delaware - PalgraveConnect - 2015-07-14


ment, if any, required to offset their depreciation. The resource-based view (RBV) is an important
Unlike physical capital, most capabilities are strategy perspective that builds on Penrose (1959). It
enhanced with use, since more experience is gained. was formally articulated by Wernerfelt (1984) as a
These characteristics of the firm’s R&C reflect a complement to the prevailing industrial organization
trade-off between the specialization of assets (a view of strategy pioneered by Porter (1980). RBV
necessary condition for realizing above-normal emphasizes the fact that imperfections in factor
profits or economic rents) and the robustness of these markets, such as frictions in labour and capital
assets across alternative futures. When firms develop markets that create imperfect mobility of inputs, can
specialized R&C, they usually do so at the cost of give rise to systematic differences in firm perfor-
reduced flexibility in the face of Schumpeterian mance (Wernerfelt, 1989). Limited transferability of
shocks (Schumpeter, 1934). This trade-off is a core resources, as well as their scarcity, complementarity
issue in deciding which R&C to develop and how (see and firm appropriability, are key conditions giving
Schoemaker, 1992). Firms may gain sustainable rise to economic rent opportunities in this view (see
advantage when existing and potential competitors Figure 1). RBV focuses on internal and institutional
(new entrants) lack either the ability or desire to factors, emphasizing the slow evolutionary paths by
imitate the rent-producing R&C. A firm’s managers which firm-specific resources and capabilities typi-
can lessen the incentives of competitors to imitate or cally develop (Nelson and Winter, 1982). These
develop close substitutes by, for example, erecting capabilities may include executive talent, culture and

Complementarity Scarcity Low tradeability

Rents due to
Overlap with firm’s resources
strategic industry and capabilities Inimitability
factors (strategic assets)

Limited
Durability Appropriability
substitutability

Figure 1 Desired characteristics of the firm’s resources and capabilities. Source: Amit and Schoemaker (1993).

2 r Palgrave Publishers Ltd

10.1057/9781137294678 - The Palgrave Encyclopedia of Strategic Management, Edited by Mie Augier and David Teece
By: Raphael Amit and Paul J.H. Schoemaker
The Palgrave Encyclopedia of Strategic Management
Mie Augier; David Teece firm resources
ISBN: 9781137294678
Palgrave Macmillan
other less tangible dimensions that have received the one hand, and (2) dynamically adjust capabilities
limited attention in standard models of rational to exploit new opportunities quickly? Since capabilities
behaviour. Further, RBV does not place dominant develop organically with limited time compression, it
economic focus on general equilibrium in the econ- takes time to adjust them to fit a revised strategy and
omy and structural determinants. Instead, dis- even longer to develop new capabilities from scratch.
equilibrium and process dynamics loom as primary Some will wonder if the inherent lags in adjusting
(Peteraf, 1993). dynamic capabilities reduce their value as a basis of
Amit and Schoemaker (1993) build on RBV by strategy in fast-changing environments. Nonetheless,
examining conditions underlying sustainable eco- developing an organizational capacity to modify,
nomic rents. They emphasize the fact that uncer- extend and create new capabilities is of crucial stra-
tainty about which future scenarios may prevail tegic importance in a changing environment.

Copyright material from www.palgraveconnect.com - licensed to University of Delaware - PalgraveConnect - 2015-07-14


(Schoemaker, 1991) gives rise to idiosyncratic man-
agerial decisions across firms. This in turn creates
asymmetries as to which R&C firms develop, and Current developments
thus can become a source of sustainable economic Two important extensions of RBV strategies are
rent. Amit and Schoemaker (1993) focus on key currently emerging, namely: (1) the role of network-
linkages between Porter’s industry analysis frame- based capabilities that are only partly owned and
work, the resource-based view of the firm and controlled by the firm; and (2) the increasingly
behavioural decision biases (Tversky and Kahneman, important role of BUSINESS MODELS in which a focal
1974, 1981), as well as organizational implementation firm leverages its own R&C with those of its partners.
issues. Owing to uncertainty, complexity and conflict The information revolution continues to offer
(both inside and outside the firm), different firms will firms unprecedented reach, connectivity and low-cost
employ different R&C, without any one set being computing power. This allows companies to explore
demonstrably optimal or easily imitated. At best, entirely new ways of leveraging their R&C and
managers can devise heuristic solutions that navigate creating value for shareholders. We can begin to
between the numerous biases characteristic of understand these new ways with insights from net-
humans and organizations (Schoemaker, 1990). It is work theory (Kleindorfer and Wind, 2009), where the
argued that organizational asymmetry stems from focus is on the topography and structure of rela-
imperfect and discretionary decisions to develop and tionships. But we also need to include notions of
deploy selected resources and capabilities. Such purpose, acceptance, fairness, coherence and viability
decisions are made by ‘boundedly rational managers’ (Zott and Amit, 2009) to fully appreciate the power
(Russo and Schoemaker, 2002) who have to deal with and challenges of network-based strategies.
high uncertainty, complexity and intra-firm conflict. A related body of literature which centres on a
Teece, Pisano and Shuen (1997) developed an firm’s business model has developed since the early
important DYNAMIC CAPABILITIES view of the firm that 2000s (Zott, Amit and Massa, 2011). The business
centres on the capacity to create or modify R&C. This model concept refers to how a firm’s activity system is
theory emphasizes a subset of capabilities deemed designed and enabled by a focal firm to meet per-
vital for evolutionary fitness – a perspective influ- ceived market needs. An activity system is the set of
enced by technical fitness (measured as quality per interdependent organizational activities within and
unit of cost), market demand and competition (see around the focal firm but also encompasses activities
Helfat et al., 2007). How can firms develop man- conducted by its partners, customers or vendors. As
agerial and organizational processes that allow them such, it transcends the focal firm and spans across the
to search for opportunities and select the best ones? market environment and possibly its industry
According to Teece, Pisano and Shuen, the key is to boundaries. An activity in a focal firm’s business
build on the R&C the firm already possesses while also model is defined as the engagement of human, phy-
creating new ones needed for future success. This sical and/or capital resources.
dynamic view of capabilities raises an interesting The business model defines the structural template
dilemma for resource-based views of strategy. Can by which the firm deploys its own R&C, as well as
theorists have it both ways? Can firms: (1) exploit those of its partner firms, to advantage (Amit and
hard-to-develop-and-imitate core competencies on Zott, 2001). Importantly, the firm’s business model

r Palgrave Publishers Ltd 3

10.1057/9781137294678 - The Palgrave Encyclopedia of Strategic Management, Edited by Mie Augier and David Teece
By: Raphael Amit and Paul J.H. Schoemaker
The Palgrave Encyclopedia of Strategic Management
firm resources Mie Augier; David Teece
ISBN: 9781137294678
Palgrave Macmillan
includes the strategic ways in which these various Dierickx, I. and Cool, K. 1989. Asset stock accumulation and
activities (and related R&C) are linked with those of sustainability of competitive advantage. Management Science
external constituents in both factor and product 35, 1504–1511.
Ghemawat, P. 1991. Commitment. New York: Free Press.
markets (Zott and Amit, 2010) for mutual gain. Grant, R. B. 1991. A resource based theory of competitive
Entrepreneurial managers of focal firms actively advantage: implications for strategy formulation. California
design (i.e., construct, link, sequence) boundary- Management Review 33, 114–135.
spanning exchanges and activities, which then Helfat, C. E., Finkelstein, S., Mitchell, W., Peteraf, M. A.,
become core elements of the business model. The Singh, H., Teece, D. J. and Winter, S. G. 2007. Dynamic
Capabilities: Understanding Strategic Change in Organizations.
focal firm is far more than a passive participant in its Malden, MA, and Oxford: Blackwell Publishing.
surrounding networks. It purposefully structures its Klein, B., Crawford, R. G. and Alchian, A. A. 1978. Vertical
destiny through cooperation and co-creation with integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive

Copyright material from www.palgraveconnect.com - licensed to University of Delaware - PalgraveConnect - 2015-07-14


other stakeholders as part of a broader network-based contracting process. Journal of Law & Economics 21,
ecosystem (see Prahalad and Ramaswamy, 2004). The 297–326.
Kleindorfer, P. and Wind, J. eds. 2009. The Network Challenge:
logic of this structure lies at the heart of the firm’s Strategy, Profit and Risk in an Interlinked World. Upper
business model, which can be viewed as an ‘engine’ Saddle River, NJ: Wharton Publishing.
for orchestrating and deploying network-based Nelson, R. and Winter, S. 1982. An Evolutionary Theory
strategies. of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press.
Penrose, E. T. 1959. The Theory of Growth of the Firm.
Conclusion New York: Wiley.
The resource-based view of the firm, in which Peteraf, M. 1993. The cornerstone of competitive advantage: a
resources and capabilities play a central role, has been resource-based view. Strategic Management Journal 14,
179–191.
one of the main theoretical perspectives in strategic Porter, M. 1980. Competitive Strategy. New York: Free Press.
management theory since the mid-1980s. It comple- Prahalad, C. K. and Ramaswamy, V. 2004. The Future of
ments the industry perspective (Porter, 1980) in Competition: Co-creating Unique Value with Customers.
examining and explaining the sources of firms’ Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.
Rumelt, R. P. 1984. Towards a strategic theory of the firm. In
competitive advantage. As industry boundaries
Competitive Strategic Management, ed. R. B. Lamb.
evolve and firm boundaries blur – due to continued Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
technological progress, deregulation and innovation Russo, J. E. and Schoemaker, P. J. H. 2002. Winning Decisions.
– firms increasingly use the resources and capabilities New York: Doubleday.
of partners as an integral part of their own activity Schoemaker, P. J. H. 1990. Strategy, complexity and economic
rent. Management Science 36, 1178–1192.
systems. Continued theoretical and empirical
Schoemaker, P. J. H. 1991. When and how to use scenario
research on these complex dynamics offers the pro- planning. Journal of Forecasting 10, 549–564.
mise of better grounded normative models. These in Schoemaker, P. J. H. 1992. How to link strategic vision to core
turn can spawn the predictive and prescriptive tools capabilities. Sloan Management Review 34, 67–81.
we need to enrich the science and practice of strategic Schumpeter, J. 1934. The Theory of Economic Development.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
management.
Teece, D. J., Pisano, G. and Shuen, A. 1997. Dynamic
RAPHAEL AMIT AND PAUL J. H. SCHOEMAKER
capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management
Journal 18, 509–533.
See also
Tversky, A. and Kahneman, D. 1974. Judgment under
BUSINESS MODEL, THE; COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGE; DYNAMIC CAPABILITIES;
uncertainty: heuristics and biases. Science 185, 1124–1131.
RESOURCE-BASED VIEW
Tversky, A. and Kahneman, D. 1981. The framing of decisions
and the psychology of choice. Science 211, 453–458.
References Wernerfelt, B. 1984. A resource based view of the firm.
Amit, R. and Schoemaker, P. J. H. 1993. Strategic assets and Strategic Management Journal 5, 171–180.
organizational rent. Strategic Management Journal 14, 33–46. Wernerfelt, B. 1989. From critical resources to corporate
Amit, R. and Zott, C. 2001. Value creation in e-business. strategy. Journal of General Management 5, 171–180.
Strategic Management Journal 22, 493–520. Williamson, O. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies. New York:
Barney, J. B. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive Free Press.
advantage. Journal of Management 17, 99–120. Zott, C. and Amit, R. 2009. The business model as the
Caves, R. E. 1984. Economic analysis and the quest for engine of network-based strategies. In The Network
competitive advantage. American Economic Review 74, 127–132. Challenge: Strategy, Profit and Risk in an Interlinked World,

4 r Palgrave Publishers Ltd

10.1057/9781137294678 - The Palgrave Encyclopedia of Strategic Management, Edited by Mie Augier and David Teece
By: Raphael Amit and Paul J.H. Schoemaker
The Palgrave Encyclopedia of Strategic Management
Mie Augier; David Teece firm resources
ISBN: 9781137294678
Palgrave Macmillan
ed. P. R. Kleindorfer and Y. J. Wind. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Zott, C., Amit, R. and Massa, L. 2011. The business model:
Wharton School Publishing. recent developments and future research. Journal of
Zott, C. and Amit, R. 2010. Business model design: an activity Management 37, 1019–1042.
system perspective. Long Range Planning 43, 216–226.

Copyright material from www.palgraveconnect.com - licensed to University of Delaware - PalgraveConnect - 2015-07-14

r Palgrave Publishers Ltd 5

View publication stats


10.1057/9781137294678 - The Palgrave Encyclopedia of Strategic Management, Edited by Mie Augier and David Teece

You might also like