You are on page 1of 8

POLICY NOTE

Uncertainties Hold Back Achievement of OECD Pillar 2


Goals

Antonio Tomassini* & Marica De Rosa**

The Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) Pillar 2 that was designed to levy a minimum tax on multinationals in all of the
countries in which they operate still has many areas of uncertainty. These include issues from the more general uncertainties concerning the politics,
including the apparent desire not to adopt a multilateral convention for its implementation to the technical ones that revolve around the complexity of the
rules for calculating the effective tax rate (ETR) (which also increases compliance costs), with the risk of jeopardizing the Pillar 2 project’s objectives of
simplicity and uniformity. Moreover, the Biden Administration’s unequivocal support for Pillar 2 has not translated into action in the US Congress, and
any administrative steps the United States intending to undertake the implementation of Pillar 2 (in lieu of action in Congress) are also not evidenced.
Keywords: Pillar, base erosion, treaty, multilateral convention, effective tax rate, covered taxes, CFC, GILTI, BEAT, minimum tax, anti-avoidance, inclusive
framework, aggressive tax planning, GloBE, substance carve-out, incentives, top-up-tax, UTPR, STTR.

1 INTRODUCTION The Pillar 2 initiative is expected to help curb harmful tax


The OECD Pillar 2 initiative stems from the Actions of competition among states and, at the same time, foster uni-
the Organization for Economic Cooperation and form anti-avoidance regulations such as the those on con-
Development (OECD) Base Erosion and Profit Shifting trolled foreign companies (CFC) or the US Global Low-
(BEPS) Project and aims at identifying a shared solution Taxed Income (GILTI) and Base Erosion and Ant-abuse
to the base erosion and profit shifting to low-tax jur- Tax (BEAT) regimes from which Pillar 2 took inspiration.
isdictions by generally reforming the international taxa-
tion rules to ensure that multinational enterprises 2 STATUS OF PLAY AT OECD
(MNEs) pay a fair amount of tax wherever they generate
profits in today’s digital and global economy. To achieve On 20 December 2021, the OECD issued the Model
this, the OECD/G20 Inclusive Framework designed a Rules2 that contain the basics to implement the GloBE.
set of rules to guarantee that large MNEs pay a mini- They define the scope and establish the mechanisms for
mum level of tax regardless of the countries where they determining the effective tax rate (ETR) on a jurisdic-
are headquartered or in in which they operate. It seeks tional basis, the transition rules to be applied in the first
to achieve this broadly with the operation of two year when an MNE first comes into the scope of Pillar 2,
mechanisms: a subject to tax rule (STTR) and the global and the rules on the interaction of Pillar 2 with other tax
anti-base erosion (GloBE) rules.1 The latter rules pro- regimes (e.g., CFC and fiscal transparency). In March
vide for the application of an effective minimum tax of 2022, a companion Commentary on the Model Rules
15% (global minimum tax) for companies with more was published providing interpretative guidance and a
than EUR 750 million in turnover through two primary number of concrete examples.
interlinked rules, i.e., the income inclusion rule (IIR) The OECD is also developing a framework of rules that
and the under taxed profit rule (UTPR). can facilitate the coordinated implementation of the

Notes
*
DLA Piper, Partner, PhD and Adjunct Professor in tax law. Email: antonio.tomassini@dlapiper.com.
**
DLA Piper, Head US-Italian desk NYC, LL.M international tax law. Email: marica.derosa@dlapiper.com.
1
On 1 Jul. 2021, the OECD/G20 Inclusive Framework on BEPS issued a statement providing that broad agreement had been reached on a two pillar approach to resolving issues
related to the taxation of the digital economy. The statement, titled Statement on the Two-Pillar Solution to Address the Tax Challenges Arising from the Digitalization of the Economy (the
‘2021 Statement’) included the agreed key components of Pillars One and Two. On 8 Oct. 2021, the 2021 Statement was updated (the ‘Oct. 2021 Update’) covering various rates
and thresholds, information on the scope of carve-outs, and a detailed implementation plan. The Oct. 2021 Update was agreed by 137 members of the Inclusive Framework.
2
Tax Challenges Arising from the Digitalization of the Economy – Global Anti-base Erosion Model Rules (Pillar Two), OECD / G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project, Inclusive
Framework on BEPS (20 Dec. 2021) (OECD 2021).

INTERTAX, Volume 51, Issue 2


183
© 2023 Kluwer Law International BV, The Netherlands
Intertax

GloBE rules by both multinational and the tax authorities non-existent) have announced that they will soon intro-
of the various jurisdictions. On December 20, 2022 the duce a minimum domestic tax of 15%. The big
OECD released a first set of documents as part of the unknown remains the United States that, although
implementation package including the following: (1) gui- Secretary Yellen had stated that they would come to an
dance on Safe Harbours and Penalty Relief; (2) a public understanding on implementation, for now, is still
consultation document on the GloBE Information Return; struggling to give substance to their commitment espe-
(3) a public consultation document on Tax Certainty for cially after failing to pass Pillar 2 implementing
the GloBE Rules. legislation.
In particular, the guidance on Safe Harbors and
Penalty Relief is aimed at securing a soft landing on
the GloBE for MNEs introducing the use of CbCR 5 STRUCTURE OF GLOBE RULES
data as basis for the calculations and a penalty relief The GloBE rules provide for the application of a mini-
regime which suggests the exemption of cases where mum tax rate of 15% for companies with consolidated
the MNE took a reasonable approach in the application sales exceeding EUR 750 million. The main intercon-
of GloBE. nected mechanisms implementing them are4
(1) IIR that imposes a top-up tax on the parent com-
3 EUROPEAN UNION DEVELOPMENTS pany – ultimate parent company (UPE) – in relation
to profits that have not been subject to an appro-
In December 2021, the European Commission circulated
priate level of taxation; and
a proposal for an EU Directive aimed at implementing
(2) as a secondary mechanism, the UTPR. It operates as
Pillar 2 in the Member States. It was published in a draft
a backstop to the IIR by providing an additional
form that contains the provisions (basically mirroring the
mechanism (secondary rule) for collecting the top-up
Model Rules) to be adopted by Member States ideally in
tax in relation to the income of a constituent entity
early 2024 in order to achieve a coordinated and timely
(a subsidiary company in a given country) that falls
implementation. Almost a year after publication, the
outside the scope of the IIR.
Member States achieved unanimity in the European
Council to approve the directive. The proposed directive An additional (treaty) levy mechanism that precedes the
is essentially in accordance with what has been established application of the GloBE rules, shall also be introduced
within the OECD Framework setting the minimum ETR and is known as the STTR. This represents a minimum
of 15% and the relevant Model Rules. It expands the standard unlike the GloBE rules that are merely a com-
scope (including MNEs without entities abroad with mon approach. The STTR operates at the source jurisdic-
same EUR 750 million threshold) and tends to the har- tion level on flows of income taxed in the recipient’s
monization of a binding IIR within the EU (as a conse- jurisdiction at a nominal rate of less than 9%. It is treated
quence, once implemented, there will less pressure on the as a covered tax in the recipient’s jurisdiction under the
need for a UTPR).3 While the directive generally closely GloBE rules. The rule has been designed with the intent
follows the OECD Model Rules, it extends its scope to to grant developing source countries a right to ‘tax back’
large-scale (same EUR 750 million threshold) purely up to the agreed minimum rate when intragroup pay-
domestic groups in order to ensure compliance with the ments are structured to take advantage of low nominal
fundamental freedoms. rates in the payee’s jurisdiction. It is a treaty-based rule
(to be implemented via a multilateral instrument5 (MLI)
to be worked out by the Inclusive Framework) that should
4 INITIATIVES OUTSIDE THE EU interact with any existing withholding rate in the relevant
Meanwhile, other jurisdictions outside the EU, including treaty.6
Switzerland and the United Kingdom, have already pub- It is worth noting a very significant change to the Pillar
lished draft regulations for the domestic implementation 2 rules that was introduced in the Model Rules of
of the GloBE rules. Additionally, jurisdictions such as December 2021, specifically, an optional and additional
UAE and Bahrain that traditionally do not have a corpo- levy mechanism that precedes the application of the IIR
rate tax system (direct corporate taxation is essentially and the UTPR that is referred to as the qualified domestic

Notes
3
About the Proposal, see Ana Paula Dourado, The EC Proposal of Directive on a Minimum Level of Taxation in Light of Pillar Two: Some Preliminary Comments, 50(3) Intertax (2022).
4
For an illustration of possible combinations of the four interlocking types of rules, see Ana Paula Dourado, The Pillar Two Top-Up Taxes: Interplay, Characterization, and Tax
Treaties, 50(5) Intertax (2022).
5
OECD, Statement on a Two-Pillar Solution, supra n. 1.
6
The need for treaty amendments might limit the benefits coming from the STTR for developing countries, as highlighted by Ana Paula Dourado, Editorial: Pillar Two Model
Rules: Inequalities Raised by the GloBE Rules, the Scope, and Carve-Outs, 50(4) Intertax (2022).

184
Uncertainties Hold Back Achievement of OECD Pillar 2 Goals

top-up tax (QDMTT). If a company’s ETR in a jurisdic- global economy. Viewed this way, the contrast with the
tion is less than 15%, this instrument gives source jur- treaty provisions aimed at allocating taxing rights among
isdictions the opportunity to collect the top-up tax states (Article 7 and from 10–13 of the Model Tax
domestically instead of partly ceding its taxing power to Convention) becomes clear.12 The GloBE rules attempt a
another jurisdiction through the IIR or UTPR.7 The general reform of the international tax system inspired by
reasonable expectation is that most of the jurisdictions the single tax principle13 according to which taxes must
will conform their approach in this direction and imple- be paid at least once thereby avoiding double non-
ment domestic minimum taxes that are compatible with taxation.
the GloBE rules in order to collect revenues that other Given that at least until the impasse within the
countries would otherwise collect.8 European Council is overcome, the GloBE rules will be
In the transition from the Blueprint (the first report implemented solely through domestic legislations, and
detailed by the OECD on Pillars One and Two) to the the treaty incompatibility problem will be magnified.
Model Rules, a change (that was not properly contextua-
lized) of the under taxed payment rule to the UTPR
occurred. This has been lambasted by certain authors.9 6 INTERACTION OF THE CFC RULES
The acronym remains the same but, in addition to chan- WITH THE GLOBAL MINIMUM TAX
ging diction, the substance of the allocation key changes
as well. Until the October version of the Blueprint,10 the Under the Model Rules, whether the IIR or UTPR is
UTPR was only relevant for intercompany transactions imposed on income earned in a given jurisdiction by
and required, in order for the rule to be applicable, that a CFCs or Permanent Establishments of an MNE depends
deductible intercompany payment be made by one con- on that country’s ETR with respect to that income. In
stituent entity to another that was resident in a jurisdic- determining that ETR, the Model Rules take into account
tion with taxation below 15%. With the Model Rules, the ‘covered taxes’ imposed on such income. These include
this precondition is removed. Therefore, the UTPR can corporate (or equivalent, i.e., substitutive, withholding)
be applied without any transaction occurring between taxes imposed by the CFC jurisdiction provided they are
the constituent entities. It is widely believed11 that this recorded in the financial statements (indirect, excise, and
has exacerbated the already existing incompatibility pro- digital taxes are not covered taxes). Additionally, under a
files with the OECD Model (and thus with treaties). special rule, taxes (CFC taxes) imposed by the jurisdiction
Hence, including the GloBE rules in an MLI, a convo- of the parent entity on income of a CFC under a CFC
luted route but one that would overcome the issue of regime are also considered covered taxes (i.e., allocated to
compatibility with bilateral treaties, becomes highly the CFC’s jurisdiction for purposes of determining its
significant. ETR) subject to the following limitation with respect to
The question of potential incompatibility with treaties passive income. The CFC taxes treated as covered taxes are
is generally compounded due to the nature of the GloBE limited to the lesser of (1) the amount of CFC taxes
rules not being a pure anti-avoidance mechanism but a attributable to the CFC’s passive income and (2) the
new way to allocate the taxable base among states and to CFC jurisdiction’s ‘top-up tax percentage’ multiplied by
secure a minimum effective rate of taxation. The GloBE the CFC’s passive income that is taken into account in the
rules are founded on the need to curtail excessive base parent jurisdiction’s CFC regime. The top-up tax percen-
erosion, yet aggressive tax planning is not a prerequisite tage equals 15% less the CFC jurisdiction’s ETR (not
for their application. They are ‘new rules’, and perhaps taking into account CFC taxes treated as covered taxes).
they should be viewed as a type of update to the old rules This limitation ensures that the amount of CFC taxes
embodied in treaties as a kind of response to the new treated as covered taxes may not exceed a maximum of

Notes
7
For in depth considerations on key design issues of such domestic minimum taxes regimes and their implications for the application of the GloBE rules, see Noam Noked,
Designing Domestic Minimum Taxes in Response to the Global Minimum Tax, 50(10) Intertax.
8
M. Baraké, P. E. Chouc, T. Neef & G. Zucman, Revenue Effects of the Global Minimum Tax Under Pillar Two, 50(10) Intertax. The authors present an empirical simulation of
the revenue effects of the GloBE minimum tax, demonstrating the different impact on revenues based on the country that gets to collect them according to the ordering
rules.
9
C. Plunket, What‘s in a Name? The Under Taxed Profits Rule, Tax Notes International (28 Mar. 2022). S. Picciotto, Formulary Approach: The Last Best Hope for MNEs, Tax Notes
International (31 Oct. 2022). J. Vanderwolk, The UTPR Disregards the Need for Nexus, Tax Notes International (3 Nov. 2022). For a different position see A. Christians & T.
Diniz Magalhães, Undertaxed Profits and the Use-It-or-Lose-It Principle, Tax Notes International (7 Nov. 2022), wherein the authors defend Pillar 2’s UTPR by arguing that it
is supported by fundamental principles of international tax law and economic logic.
10
Tax Challenges Arising from Digitalization – Report on Pillar Two Blueprint, OECD / G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting Project, Inclusive Framework on BEPS (OECD
2020).
11
J. Li, The Pillar 2 Undertaxed Payments Rule Departs from International Consensus and Tax Treaties, 105 Tax Notes Int’l (21 Mar. 2022).
12
See Dourado, supra n. 5, at 395.
13
See S. Avy-Yonah, Who Invented the Single Tax Principle?: An Essay on the History of US Treaty Policy, 59(2) N. Y. L. Sch. L. Rev. (2015).

185
Intertax

15% of the CFC’s ‘passive income’. It should be noted in ability to offer credits and other incentives for boosting
this regard that the concept of ‘passive income’ under the their economies. Tax credits are one of the primary tools to
Model Rules may be narrower than under the CFC encourage investment according to a mantra that has else-
regimes of most countries. Any CFC taxes in excess of where been referred to as a ‘tax stimulus’.
this maximum amount remain covered taxes in the parent In any case, Pillar 2 does not eliminate the possibility of
company jurisdiction. As a practical matter, these excess taking advantage of tax incentives; indeed, it would not be
CFC taxes that remain in the parent jurisdiction become a compatible with the OECD mandate, however, their benefit
non-factor for Pillar 2 because there is no other practical can no longer be established ex ante and, in order to assess
way to utilize them under it. This result, i.e., excess CFC their overall effect, a modelling exercise applied to each
taxes remaining in the parent jurisdiction, arises when the specific case might be necessary. After the publication of
parent jurisdiction imposes tax at a rate in excess of the the Model Rules in December 2021, a number of business
Pillar 2 minimum rate of 15% thus the excess of CFC organizations submitted comments on the provision, and
taxes just represent this tax rate difference. The objective discussions with governments and the OECD are ongoing.
of Pillar 2 is to establish a minimum but not a maximum In October 2022, the OECD released a new report on Pillar 2
tax, and any jurisdiction’s taxes in excess of the minimum entitled, ‘Tax Incentives and the Global Minimum
rate are not intended to be reallocated to other jurisdic- Corporate Tax’ providing insights into jurisdictions’ future
tions under the Pillar 2 framework. Additionally, the CFC use of tax incentives. The report was addressed to govern-
rules having an anti-avoidance purpose (which is different ments and tax authorities and proposes several recommenda-
from the GloBE ones) needs to be coordinated with the tions as well as a number of tax policy considerations.
GloBE rules but would probably be maintained by states Although the OECD’s guidance is meant to provide a
that are intending to protect their right to secure higher basis for jurisdictions to perform their own analysis of
taxation. their tax incentives, the report may be a beneficial tool
for assessing the potential impact of Pillar 2 on the tax
profile of multinational companies and help shape their
7 TREATMENT OF TAX INCENTIVES strategy as the implementation of Pillar 2 approaches.
Many jurisdictions are already in the process of revisiting
Another issue at the centre of the international debate14 is
their tax incentive framework ahead of the contemplated
the characterization of tax incentives in this new, to say the
implementation of Pillar 2. Public consultation opportu-
least, complex paradigm of the Pillar 2. Domestic tax
nities are likely to arise affording multinationals the
incentives, in fact, are substantially relevant in the
opportunity to provide input on policy decisions within
calculation15 of the tax for its purposes. Specifically, the
jurisdictions implementing the GloBE rules.
Model Rules consider only those tax credits for which
The key takeaways from the report are: (1) certain tax
refunds can be claimed from the relevant tax authorities
incentives are less affected by Pillar 2; (2) some jurisdic-
within four years as qualified incentives for purposes of tions may focus more heavily on providing these incen-
computing the minimum ETR.16 The GloBE rules treat
tives in order to continue attracting foreign investments;
a qualified credit in the same way as income or a subsidy
and (3) the OECD report does not provide clarity on the
which means that the credit is taken into account in the
politically sensitive topic of the treatment of refundable
denominator of the calculation of the ETR and therefore
versus non-refundable tax credits. In fact, the OECD
does not directly reduce the taxes paid in the year. All other
acknowledges the difference of treatment under the
tax credits that do not qualify under the Model Rules, on
GloBE rules. It is expected that further political debate
the other hand, are treated as an actual reduction in covered
will follow related to this topic.
taxes meaning that they reduce the numerator of the ETR
formula and thus the ETR itself. The risk is that the use of
the non-qualified tax incentives – because they reduce 8 SUBSTANCE-BASED CARVE-OUT
covered taxes – may consequently reduce the constituent AND INCENTIVES
entity’s ETR in its home country below 15% even though
it may be well above 15% for local tax purposes. This At the same time, while it is true that tax incentives
would result in the need to apply a top-up tax in a country reduce the ETR, it should be noted that the substance-
that already imposes a high tax rate. Governments would based carve outs might provide some reprieve. In fact, the
then quickly realize that such a novelty will reduce their deduction (based on a formula) provides for a certain value

Notes
14
See among others, M. Herzfeld, Tax Credits and Incentives Under a Global Minimum Tax Regime, Tax Notes Today International (27 Jun. 2022).
15
M. P. Devereux, M. Simmler, J. Vella & H. Wardell-Burrus, What Is the Substance-Based Carve-Out Under Pillar 2? And How Will It Affect Tax Competition?, Oxford
University Centre for Business Taxation (17 Nov. 2021).
16
Article 3.2.4. Model Rules, above. Art. 10, para. 134 through 138 Tax Challenges Arising from the Digitalization of the Economy – Commentary to Global Anti-base Erosion Model
Rules (Pillar Two) (OECD 2022).

186
Uncertainties Hold Back Achievement of OECD Pillar 2 Goals

to be attributed to factors representing the ‘substance’ of US Treasury officials have indicated that, although the
the activities carried out in the local jurisdiction and GILTI in its current form is not a qualifying IIR, as a CFC
essentially grants a subsidy for labour costs and invest- regime, it is a covered CFC tax regime in principle under
ments in tangible assets for the jurisdictions where MNEs the model rules, however, there is still a need for the US
have operating activities. At the same time, it does not Treasury to administratively design a mechanism for allo-
reward (or penalize) companies that generate profits pri- cating the GILTI tax among US parent companies’ CFCs.
marily from the use of intellectual property and other In absence of US tax legislation adopting Pillar 2, treating
intangible assets. A corollary (the authors do not know the GILTI as a covered CFC tax regime substantially
how intended) of the substance carve-out is that the Pillar reduces the mismatch between the US tax system and
2 would also have an impact on the allocation of business Pillar 2. US Treasury officials seem to take the position
types to certain jurisdictions rather than others. that, with the following definition, a CFC tax regime
under the Model Rules should cover the GILTI:

9 THE US GILTI, CAMT, AND THE a set of tax rules (other than an IIR) under which a
INTERPLAY WITH PILLAR 2 direct or indirect shareholder of a foreign entity (the
controlled foreign company or CFC) is subject to cur-
9.1 GILTI: Is the GILTI a Qualifying CFC Tax? rent taxation on its share of part, or all of the income
earned by the CFC, irrespective of whether that income
The GILTI under current law is incompatible with the is distributed currently to the shareholder.
Pillar 2 model rules for a number of reasons: (1) the
GILTI17 tax rate is less than the Pillar 2 minimum rate
Although the GILTI is, by statute, a tax on blended
of 15%; (2) Pillar 2 requires a conforming IIR to be based
income of a US parent company’s CFCs,18 per US
on a country-by-country determination, yet the GILTI
Treasury officials, it is still a current tax on the direct or
regime aggregates the income of all controlled foreign
indirect shareholder of all of the CFCs for which their
corporations owned by a US shareholder regardless of
income is so blended that is not itself disqualifying. From
jurisdiction and thus allows the blending of income
the authors’ discussions with OECD personnel directly
from high and low tax jurisdictions; (3) the amount sub-
involved in the design and implementation of Pillar 2,
ject to the GILTI tax is reduced by a deemed return of
it was ascertained that they agree with the US Treasury
10% of the tax carrying value of depreciable tangible
position and indicate that they are working cooperatively
property Qualified Business Asset Investment (QBAI)
with them on designing an allocation key for the GILTI.
used to produce the GILTI; and, finally, (4) the GILTI
What this actually means is that the OECD is working on
is calculated based on tested income that is a purely US
an additional layer of rules so that the United States
tax law concept while Pillar 2 calculations are based on
remains part of the Pillar 2 framework.
book income.
Assuming the US Treasury (in coordination with
The Biden Administration engaged with members of
OECD Secretariat) is able to design such an allocation
the OECD and with the OECD Secretariat to drive the
key for the GILTI tax, that paid by a US parent company
current consensus around the Pillar 2 minimum rate with
would qualify as a covered tax in the jurisdictions of the
a commitment to pass tax reform to conform the GILTI
relevant CFCs thereby increasing the respective ETRs of
with Pillar 2. In fact, the Build Back Better legislation in
the CFCs.19 Once such an allocation key has been pub-
2021 passed by the US House of Representatives but not
lished, it will be interesting to see whether some of the
taken up by the US Senate included changes that would
countries involved in the Inclusive Framework raise objec-
have conformed the GILTI to Pillar 2, i.e., to a qualifying
tions and how these are resolved. For now, the impression
IIR. Unfortunately, the US tax reform legislation passed
remains that the US Treasury and the OECD Secretariat
recently by the US Congress, i.e., the Inflation Reduction
do not anticipate any such problems.
Act, did not include the changes to the GILTI that were
Some observers have commented that treating the
included in the Build Back Better legislation passed by
GILTI as a covered CFC tax but not as a qualifying
the US House of Representatives in 2021.
IIR tax creates an unfair cream-skimming opportunity

Notes
17
GILTI, which stands for global intangible low taxable income, is the regime of CFC c.d. catch-all of the US tax system that was introduced in 2017 to subject to tax all CFC
income of US parent companies that, until then, had not been intercepted by the regime CFC Subpart F with the result that 100% of the income of a CFC (both assets and
liabilities) is subject to taxation. Unlike the scheme Subpart F that levies tax on CFCs at a regular rate of 21% with a deduction for foreign tax credits, the GILTI is levied at
an ETR of 10.5% (13.125% following the application of limitations on foreign tax credits). In addition, compared to other CFC regimes, the GILTI and the related tax
payable by the US parent company are not determined country by country. Instead, it allows the offset of income and losses of all CFCs of a US parent company regardless of
the jurisdiction of incorporation.
18
A. Velarde, Treasury Defends GILTI as Good Pillar 2 Regime, Tax Notes Today International (16 May 2022); R. S. Avi-Yonah & B. Wells, Pillar 2 and the Corporate AMT, Tax
Notes Today International (8 Aug. 2022). R. Cassanos, NYSBA Tax Section Focuses on U.S. Tax Implications of OECD Reform, Tax Notes Today International (22 Jul. 2022).
19
S. Soong Johnston, OECD Working Party Considering Options to Allocate CFC Taxes, Tax Notes Today International (29 Jun. 2022).

187
Intertax

for the United States, i.e., unfairly gives the United UTPR) ahead of other jurisdictions looking to the revenue
States the first opportunity to tax profits that could to impose additional tax within the Pillar 2 framework.
otherwise be collected by source countries, including However, under the Model Rules, the source country has
under Pillar 2.20 the opportunity to impose a QDMTT; if the source coun-
This line of commentary appears to be based on a try fails to impose a QDMTT, then other countries may
partial view of the structure of the US international tax impose the UTPR or IIR. The United States (having
system and the structure of the Inclusive Framework as failed to adopt an IIR) cannot, in principle, even mini-
reflected in the model rules as distilled in the following mally benefit from the potential Pillar 2 top-up tax.
paragraphs. A common thread in commentaries suggesting that
treating the GILTI as a qualifying CFC tax is a calculated
move by the United States attempting to invert the
9.2 GILTI Does Not Override the Primary ordering rule under Pillar 2 and thereby achieve an advan-
Taxation Right of the Source Country tage over the rest of the world is the assumption that
perhaps the GILTI tax rate will be increased in order to
The structure of the US international tax system respects
capture any tax that could otherwise be collected by
the primary right of source countries to impose corporate
source countries under QDMTT regimes. On the contrary,
income tax at rates only such countries determine. When
low tax source countries exercise this primary tax right to the United States has recently doubled down on the
GILTI statutory tax rate of 10.5% by not changing the
impose corporate income tax at rates below the GLOBE
statutory rate in its recently passed Inflation Reduction
minimum rate, they do so by pursuing specific tax com-
Act, thus it is a reasonable expectation that the GILTI tax
petition policies. Post-Pillar 2 implementation, these low
that the United States collects is not going to be increased
tax countries retain this primary taxing right and indeed
with a potential top-up tax opportunity under Pillar 2.
could elect to increase their regular corporate income tax
rates to be at least equal the GloBE minimum rate. Doing
so should already eliminate any concern that the United 9.3 Why the GILTI Tax as a Covered CFC Tax
States or any other parent jurisdictions could engage in (But Not a Compliant IRR) Is Not an
inappropriate planning in order to circumvent the GloBE
Advantage for US MNEs
ordering rules. However, it could be argued that, in
general, those countries in need of competitive tax rates Another reason why it is difficult to affirm that treating
are the developing countries that might see foreign capital the GILTI as a CFC tax regime (but not a qualifying IIR)
investment directed elsewhere if their tax systems no creates an advantage for the United States is the quanti-
longer offer certain benefits. tative factor tied to how US MNEs are required to calcu-
The structure of the US international tax system late foreign tax credits. US MNEs, it appears, would not
respects the primary right of source countries to impose benefit materially by treating the GILTI as a CFC tax
corporate income tax by incorporating a foreign tax regime (but not a qualifying IIR) because, under the
regime in both of the United States’ CFC Model Rules, the covered CFC tax component of the
regimes – Subpart F and the GILTI. In calculating the GILTI tax would be computed assuming that it is charged
GILTI tax (Subpart F tax, for that matter), the United at the statutory rate less available Foreign Tax Credits
States allows a foreign tax credit (subject to certain lim- (FTCs). However, because of the expense allocation
itations) for source country corporate income taxes and for mechanism in the United States FTC regime, US MNEs
source country withholding taxes on income taxed under end up paying a higher GILTI effective rate, meaning that
the GILTI regime. Indeed, a scenario could be envisioned only a portion of a US MNE’s GILTI tax will be available
where the GILTI tax could be satisfied in its entirety by as Pillar 2 covered tax.
foreign tax credits when the source countries’ average tax Ordinarily, the United States allows FTCs limited to
rates are at least equal to or exceed the GILTI tax rate. In the US corporate tax rate on foreign taxable income
such a scenario, the United States would have no residual (foreign source income multiplied by the US corporate
tax to collect on the GILTI income. tax rate). Under this approach, if the source country’s
Of course, it could be argued that the United States, corporate income tax rate equals or exceeds the US corpo-
like any other jurisdiction that imposes a CFC tax, is rate income tax rate, in principle, the United States
situated at the front of the queue when taxing its CFCs’ should not impose any residual tax on those profits
undertaxed income (i.e., before a QDMTT, IRR, or under its CFC regimes. The expense allocation rules21

Notes
20
Some notable commentaries on the GLOBE ordering include: Mindy Herzfeld CFC Rules, 175 Tax Notes Fed. (2 May 2022), and Heydon Wardell-Burrus Should CFC
Regimes Grant a Tax Credit for Qualified Domestic Minimum Top-Up Taxes?, 106 Tax Notes Int’l (27 Jun. 2022).
21
Treasury Regulations ss 1.861–8 and 1.861–10T.

188
Uncertainties Hold Back Achievement of OECD Pillar 2 Goals

taken into account in calculating the FTC limitation, aggregation or blending such as that occurring under
however, modify this general approach in a manner that the GILTI regime. This CFC-by-CFC determination
results in US MNEs paying residual US tax even when the makes a rather straightforward application of the Pillar 2
source country corporate income taxes equal or exceed the jurisdiction-by-jurisdiction framework. Additionally, US
US corporate income tax rate. tax on Subpart F income is imposed at the regular corpo-
The expense allocation rules require that, for purposes rate income tax rate of 21%, i.e., does not have the 50%
of calculating the US FTC, certain US expenses (interest, deduction nor the QBAI benefit. Notably, there has not
research and development (R&D), and stewardship been any commentaries suggesting that the Subpart F
expenses) of the US parent company should be partially regime should not be a qualifying CFC regime that trans-
reclassified as expenses incurred with respect to foreign lates into a covered tax for the GloBE calculation.
source income as they are fungible expense incurred by the
parent company to support its activities and activities of
foreign subsidiaries.22 Hence, the US expenses of the 9.5 Corporate Alternative Minimum Tax
parent company allocated to foreign source income reduce (CAMT): Could the Tax Be Considered
its amount that is taken into account in calculating the a QDMTT?
US foreign tax credit limitation. Although this does not
The CAMT that imposes a 15% rate on the book earnings
change the amount of foreign source taxable income, it
of US corporations (and foreign-parented multinationals
decreases the FTC limitation, resulting in an MNE bear-
that include at least one US domestic corporation (a
ing residual GILTI tax even when the GILTI income has
Foreign Group) with average financial statement income
been subject to source country tax rates higher than the
(overaged over three years) in excess of USD 1 billion
US corporate income tax rate.
appears to be another layer of non-conformity of the US
Formally, the Model Rules and commentaries do not
tax rules with Pillar 2. On one hand, the CAMT is applied
(and the authors have not heard that there is any OECD
on financial statement income which brings the US mini-
proposal that would expand the Model Rules to do so) take
mum tax much closer to the OECD rules in terms of the
into account the US FTC expense allocation rules as such
tax base. However, on the other hand, it does not provide
rules are not common in other countries. Additionally, it is
for a country-by-country allocation of such additional
unlikely that any further development of the implementa-
taxes but instead is based on a blended consolidated rate
tion framework would consider such arcane provisions and
test. As a result, it appears that the CAMT would create
factor them in when calculating the amount of the GILTI
the same concerns as the GILTI in not having a country-
tax treated as a covered CFC tax. Stated otherwise, with
by-country allocation mechanism and would require a
expense allocation rules, US MNEs operating in countries
similar creative solution from the OECD.23
with tax rates at least as high as the GILTI statutory rate
Another important and politically sensitive reason why
(10.5%) could pay the GILTI tax at an effective rate sub-
the CAMT would not be a Pillar 2-styled QDMTT is that
stantially higher than 10.5% and yet still be subject to a
the AMT allows the exclusion from the calculation of the
top-up tax because the Pillar 2 starting point is not the
general business credits, R&D credits, low-income hous-
higher effective GILTI rate but the GILTI statutory rate.
ing tax credits, and the new renewable energy incentives
This would unfortunately change the character of the Pillar
that were added as a part of the Inflation Reduction Act.
2 top-up tax from one designed to achieve a minimum rate
Although, in its design and intent, it was never supposed
to, effectively, a surtax.
to be a QDMTT, it is difficult not to ask why the United
States missed another opportunity to reform the architec-
9.4 Subpart F, a Traditional CFC Rule ture of its tax system so as to embrace the Pillar 2
framework.
The Subpart F regime is the historic US CFC regime that
was introduced in the 1960s to prevent the deferral of US
taxation on certain types of passive income of US parent 10 SCENARIOS AND PROSPECTS
companies’ CFCs. The GILTI regime, in contrast, was
established in 2017 to prevent the deferral of US taxation Pillar 2 is a framework agreement by which the signatory
of all income of CFCs that was not previously taxed under countries have defined a ‘common approach’. The Model
the Subpart F regime. A key difference between the Rules represent mere guidelines (a soft law initiative just
Subpart F regime and the GILTI regime is that the former like many others in the past few years) for possible
applies on a CFC-by-CFC basis thus there is no domestic legislation but do not exercise any binding effect

Notes
22
Cody Kallen Expense Allocation: A Hidden Tax on Domestic Activities and Foreign Profits, Tax Foundation (26 Aug. 2021).
23
For different perspective on the interpretation of CAMT in the context of Pillar 2 see Reuven S. Avi-Yonah, Bret Wells Pillar 2 and the Corporate AMT, Tax Notes
International (8 Aug. 2022).

189
Intertax

in the fashion of international agreements. After all, the could be the adoption of the EU Directive on global
OECD itself made it clear in October 2021 that, while minimum tax and the United States taking a clear posi-
Pillar 1 will be the subject of an MLI, the implementation tion pro Pillar 2.25
of Pillar 2 is primarily at the discretion of individual Concisely, the interpretative and application aporias
countries. However, given the complications outlined from both a policy and a technical perspective are many
above, the members of the OECD Inclusive Framework and only partially addressed in this contribution.
might want to consider the adoption of an MLI also for Certainly, there is a need for corrective mechanisms,
Pillar 224 as a more effective solution to ensure coordina- for special regimes, and incentives even if this is to
tion and consistent implementation of the GloBE rules. In the detriment of simplicity. The logic for complex
fact, proceeding with the implementation of Pillar 2 with- corrective mechanisms seems to have inspired the
out an MLI would lead to uncertainty and a surge of tax GloBE rules themselves when providing a substance
litigation. Indeed, the risks of double taxation due to based carve-out, i.e., an exclusion for an amount of
possible conflicting qualification and interpretation of income that is at least 5% of the book value of tangible
various transactions would increase whenever the defini- assets and payroll. This exclusion could actually have
tions provided by the Model Rules are not in accordance very significant impacts, including possibly neutralizing
with the domestic ones (e.g., CFC rules, QDMTT, rules the minimum tax.
for allocation of income to permanent establishments and If the main objective of the GloBE is to avoid arbi-
on transparent entities). This seems to be contrary to the trary profit shifting and create a mutually advantageous
objectives set forth by the OECD. To this purpose, the situation, the introduction of exceptions, perhaps gov-
latest document released for public consultation by the erned by local regulations, may undermine the objective
OECD on Tax Certainty for the GloBE Rules, considered and expose companies to an excessive increase in com-
the proposal for a mechanism similar to ICAP pliance costs and likely require the use of ad hoc software
(International Compliance Assurance Programme) to pre- and complex country-by-country audits of the many
vent disputes, as well as instruments for dispute resolution variables related to the minimum tax framework. To
such as an MLI or a domestic provision. Unfortunately, this purpose, it is paramount (also on the baseof the
even if probably the best option, the procedures for the consultation document on the GloBE Information
adoption of an MLI are quite complex and are likely to Return) to establish a clear outline of the information
lengthen the amount of time for the implementation of to be collected and reported by MNEs and identify
Pillar 2. The only avenue for acceleration, therefore, possible simplification strategies.

Notes
24
M. Lebovitz, G. B. Wilcox, W. S. Payne, L. Giardelli, J. F, Lopez Valek & M. K. Hall, If Pillar 1 Needs an MLI, Why Doesn’t Pillar 2, Tax Notes International (29 Aug.
2022).
25
For the controversial details of the directive, see Ana Paula Dourado, Is There a Need for a Directive on Pillar Two?, 50(6&7) Intertax (2022).

190

You might also like