You are on page 1of 21

Urban Studies

http://usj.sagepub.com/

Optimality in City Size, Systems of Cities and Urban Policy: a Sceptic's View
Harry W. Richardson
Urban Stud 1972 9: 29
DOI: 10.1080/00420987220080021

The online version of this article can be found at:


http://usj.sagepub.com/content/9/1/29

Published by:

http://www.sagepublications.com

On behalf of:
Urban Studies Journal Foundation

Additional services and information for Urban Studies can be found at:

Email Alerts: http://usj.sagepub.com/cgi/alerts

Subscriptions: http://usj.sagepub.com/subscriptions

Reprints: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.nav

Permissions: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav

Citations: http://usj.sagepub.com/content/9/1/29.refs.html

>> Version of Record - Feb 1, 1972

What is This?

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at Afyon Kocatepe Universitesi on May 14, 2014


OPTIMALITY IN CITY SIZE, SYSTEMS OF CITIES
AND URBAN POLICY : A SCEPTIC'S VIEW

HARRY W. RICHARDSON

In developed economies the share of agriculture knowledge is an important prerequisite for


and other primary products in GNP is generally worthwhile future research . This paper falls into
so small (and declining) that it is excusable to three parts : the next section, the core of the
think of economic growth in terms of urban paper, deals with the concept of optimal city
growth . If so, we may treat the national system size ; the following three sections review some of
of cities as the spatial form of organisation the literature on the national urban hierarchy ;
adopted by the industrial economy to achieve its and the final three sections look at the goals and
growth goals. This adds another dimension to instruments of urban policy, and explore the
discussions of growth in the aggregate economy, policy implications of the earlier arguments .
and the spatial-urban dimension is fully as worthy
of study as the more familiar macroeconomic and Optimal city size
sectoral approaches. As in the latter cases, the An integral aspect of the problem of an optimal
question of optimality figures prominently in the distribution of cities and whether or not it is
spatial-urban context. Is there an optimal city feasible to influence this by government action is
size and/or an optimal distribution of city sizes? the question of whether there is an optimal city
How true is the widespread belief that the large size, or even an efficient range of sizes . This
city makes a much greater contribution to question is now arousing increasing interest, but
national growth than to the welfare of its citizens? deriving firm conclusions is made more difficult
What are the implications of findings on these by the sparsity and poor quality of the available
questions for formulating a national urban statistical evidence . However, it will be shown
policy? that even from a theoretical viewpoint the search
Since the sparse literature on this subject is for the optimal city size is unsound . There may
littered with inconsistencies and confusion, I be more sense in trying to identify efficient ranges
make no apology for the fact that this is a con- of city sizes between a minimum threshold and a
ceptual and discussion paper rather than the scale at which further incr&ses in size are not
results of hard research . Clarification of some accompanied by additional agglomeration econo-
of the issues arising out of the existing state of mies. Even so, we may expect the efficient range

The author is Director of the Centre for Research to the Social Sciences, University of Kent at Canterbury,
England .
29

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at Afyon Kocatepe Universitesi on May 14, 2014


30 HARRY W . RICHARDSON

to vary, possibly dramatically, according to the may be transfer payments rather than real
functions and the structure of the cities in resource costs .
question . A more fundamental objection is that urban
Much of the early work on the optimal city size government service costs are only one part,
problem concentrated on examining how the perhaps a relatively minor part, of the costs and
costs of urban government services varied with revenues that affect optimising decisions in the
city population size, and many observers have choice between cities . Very little has been dis-
argued the case for the traditional U-shaped covered about the relationship of private costs
curve and derived the optimal city size from the (i.e. producers' costs and consumer costs) to city
bottom point of this curve . This is both theoreti- size, and the evidence is inconclusive (Alonso,
cally unsatisfactory and incomplete. However, 1970b) . There is somewhat stronger evidence
even if we accept this approach at its face value that productivity (as measured by output per
it yields ambiguous results . Estimates of the capita) increases with city size, primarily as a
most efficient size range have varied widely : result of agglomeration economies . Presumably
50-100,000 (Hirsch, 1959) ; 100-150,000 (Lomax, there is also some point on the curve when it
1943) ; 500-1,000,000 (Duncan, 1956) ; 100- stops rising and turns down again as diseconomies
200,000 (Clark, 1945) ; 30-250,000 (SVIMEZ, predominate over economies, though this point
1967-quoted by Cameron, 1970) ; 100,000- may not yet have been reached in most cities . If
250,000 (R .C. on Local Government in Greater we combine public and private costs into a single
London, 1960) ; 250,000-1 million (Redcliffe- cost curve then we can derive both a cost and
Maud Commission, 1969) . It is not surprising, product curve similar to the cost and revenue
however, that estimates should vary from curves in the theory of the firm, with the exception
country to country and over time as the compo- that population rather than quantity of output is
nents of the urban government service mix and measured on the horizontal axis . Since we would
relative cost conditions alter . never expect the optimal position for each and
Apart from this, the procedure has several every firm to occur at the same level of output,
drawbacks . The urban government service mix why should we expect the optimal point in each
varies even among cities of the same size . The city to be located at the same population size?
theoretical solution of a `representative bundle One possibility (not firmly refuted by the
of services of given quality in a standardised city' evidence) is that the marginal and average
is unacceptable not only because weighting product curves rise continuously and that the
changes with scale but even more awkward the average cost (= marginal cost) curve is approxi-
number of services supplied will tend to increase mately horizontal. In this case there is no
with city size.' Furthermore, most empirical optimum. A more critical case is where the
work has looked at how expenditures per head product curves rise continuously but where the
change with increases in population, but this cost curves are U-shaped. The intersection of the
throws light on scale economies only if demand AP curve with the downward falling AC curve
is inelastic ; what is really needed are measures of represents the minimum threshold size, and the
the influence of scale on unit costs of homo- bottom point of the latter is the minimum cost
geneous output (Gupta and Hutton, 1968). population size . Neither is an optimum . There
Other difficulties are that the division between are, however, several different optima in this
public and private services is arbitrary and can model, each reflecting a particular perspective .
vary according to the institutional traditions of For the resident the optimal size is that which
the economy and that some costs in the estimates maximises the gap between AP and AC . For the

I Isard's objections to weighting procedures in aggregating separate cost curves remain as valid as
ever (Isard, 1960, pp . 527-533).

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at Afyon Kocatepe Universitesi on May 14, 2014


OPTIMALITY IN CI Y SIZE 31

planner there are two social optima . The first is But it is hardly practicable . In a free economy
where MP = MC ; here the city maximises its where migration is left largely to individual
contribution to total output provided that there choice itis not possible to redistribute population
is no more productive locality elsewhere for the from one centre to another in the fine marginal
increase in population . However, this is a true increments that might be needed to equate
optimum only if either there is an unlimited marginal product and costs in each centre .
population or all other cities are at the equili- The existence of divergent city size optima for
brium (MP = MC) point. The second social different interested groups blurs any meaning
optimum is more usual ; this occurs at a smaller attached to the concept . There is no reason why
city size where MP exceeds MC by an amount the optimum for households and for business
equal to the opportunity cost of siting the popula- firms should coincide, and though one solution
tion in alternative cities . might be to regard the planning optimum of the
A very different result is obtained when we urban policymaker as the super-optimum this
look at the optimum from the viewpoint of the can also yield ambiguous results . The reason is
individual firm. Firms are not tied to a given that the social optimum size depends upon the
city but choose from the available range of city goals and objectives of the planners, and these
sizes the scale of urban area that maximises its vary depending on the breadth of perspective
own profits . As von Boventer (1970) has shown, of the planners (specifically, whether they are
the optimal city for a firm is that city size which national-, regional- or local-oriented) and upon
maximises the difference between agglomeration their priorities as revealed in the ranking of
economies for that firm and the costs of urban objectives .
services incurred in that city . Since the impor- Furthermore, many of the costs and benefits of
tance of agglomeration economies varies from city size are not expressed in monetary valuations
one firm to another, so will the optimal city size . as embodied in the cost and product curves .
Thus, the optimal city size is indeterminate with- Social costs associated with increasing city size,
out detailed information about the firm's such as pollution, noise and congestion, are not
characteristics . To obtain more objective overall registered in market prices. Because of these
city size optima it is necessary to find out how unwanted and, as yet, non-quantifiable exter-
many firms have their optima at each particular nalities a social optimum size may be reached at a
city size, to aggregate their labour forces and point where the marginal product curve is still
translate them via use of population/labour force rising faster than the marginal cost curve . Yet
ratios into an overall city population . However, because incoming firms and migrants have to
this suggests the possibility of incompatibility pay only the private costs and not the social costs
between the city sizes necessary to maximise of locating there, market forces may stimulate
profits for individual firms and the city sizes continued expansion of the city well beyond this
implied by the location of optimising firms . The optimum . The situation may be exacerbated by
analysis is incomplete because the firm's optimal the existence of crude if inevitable pricing policies
location assumes that city size is given yet it is the that result in average cost rather than marginal
summation of all firms finding their optimum at a cost pricing for most urban services .
particular centre that determines, and might A second and not unrelated point is that there
indeed alter, the population of that centre . This is no inherent reason why the optimum should be
is the result of adopting a step-by-step procedure an economic optimum . Duncan (1956) listed all
in a problem that requires simultaneous deter- kinds of factors that might be relevant to deter-
mination . mination of an optimum : accessibility, health,
Of these several optima, the second planning crime and safety, educational facilities, leisure
optimum (MP = MC+opportunity costs) is and recreational activities, social institutions,
probably the most important for urban policy . community and family ties, psychological and
us 9c
3

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at Afyon Kocatepe Universitesi on May 14, 2014


32 HARRY W . RICHARDSON

mental health hazards, and the desire for political standard size and where the policymaker's job is
participation . More important than any of these to fill each bottle to the brim in turn then move
are probably the locational preferences of house- on and fill the next. This might be a practicable
holds in regard to size of place (Hansen, 1970) urban strategy but it is most unlikely to lead to
though these preferences undoubtedly subsume an efficient system of cities . A modification of
some of the criteria listed above . Hansen has this approach is for urban policymakers to hold
referred to survey results that indicate residential up population expansion when the so-called
site preferences in favour of medium-sized cities optimum is reached and then to shift attention
or smaller towns rather than the large metro- to increasing per capita income. In an expanding
polises (Hansen, 1970 ; Gallup, 1968 ; Girard and economy this will be difficult without interurban
Bastide, 1960). How important these non- migration controls since cities experiencing rapid
economic determinants are depends, yet again, increases in per capita income will also be
on the policymakers' objectives and on the attractive to potential migrants . Moreover, in a
characteristics of the social preference function dynamic setting a large city may be functioning
that these presumably represent . However, once efficiently even if the gap' (AP-AC) is not
we accept the relevance of non-economic and maximised or even if MC > MP . This is because
non-quantifiable criteria we are faced with a in the broader framework of a system of cities the
weighting problem that is virtually insoluble . efficiency of a large centre may be related to how
There is a close degree of kinship between the well it performs its nationwide functions as a
concepts of optimum city size and optimum distributor of innovational activity, new ideas and
national population . No serious economist managerial expertise down the city hierarchy .
would use the optimum population concept The fourth objection to the optimum popula-
nowadays, and it is paradoxical that urban tion concept is possibly most serious of all .
economists, supposedly extending the frontiers of Optimum city size is invariably discussed in terms
a new field, should find themselves chasing, if of city population . It is unclear whether this is
only in an analogous form, such anancientwill-o'- because the level of population is considered to
the-wisp . The gross defects of the theory of the be the most suitable index for determining the
optimum population are well known : the depen- optimum (on the grounds that agglomeration
dence on marginal productivity theory and the economies and diseconomies can be functionally
law of diminishing returns, the assumption of a related in a more or less precise way to population
closed economy, the use of a static model in a size), or whether population is used as a surrogate
subject that cries out for growth dynamics, and for other size variables for which we lack data.
the use of population as an index of economic Reliance on population data may be forced upon
well-being . The first is sometimes excusable for us by the poverty of urban social accounts, but
analytical and pedagogic convenience . Second, much of the literature gives the impression that
the `openness' of city economies accentuates the the choice is deliberate . In fact, although useful
theory's irrelevance for urban economics . Third, for some purposes, e .g . determining the minimum
a static framework is totally inappropriate since threshold `market' for health and educational
the optimum population concept has been dis- facilities, some types of retail trade and public
cussed in the context of economic development . transport systems, population is a poor size
Similarly, the notion of optimum city size is not proxy in many other respects . Particularly in
immediately consistent with the framework of a medium or small cities, the same population
growing system of cities . It is true that the two could imply very different total urban incomes
things can be made compatible, but the results and widely dissimilar mixes and scale of public
do not make very good sense . For instance, we and private services . Moreover, for many busi-
could treat urban policy as a kind of bottling ness firms the agglomeration economies derived
plant where each city represents a bottle of a from locating in a centre of given size may have

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at Afyon Kocatepe Universitesi on May 14, 2014


OPTIMALITY IN CITY SIZE 33

little connection with its population level but density.2 Of course, there is generally some
instead may be related to the number of compet- relationship between the height of the density
ing firms, the availability of specialised business gradient and total city population so that city
services, and so on. Of course, for other firms size and average population density tend to be
(e .g . either those in consumer industries or those closely correlated. Nevertheless, there are
with specialised labour requirements) the popula- extremes within a given city size (e .g. Los Angeles
tion size of the centre may be the chief determi- and Chicago). There has been very little re-
nant of market potential and labour market search into the relationship between urban costs
economies . and population density, but with city population
A further difficulty is that a city's population is held constant we might hypothesise a U-shaped
an ambiguous measure depending very much on function with heavy costs at high and very low
the arbitrariness c;f geographical and political average population densities (due to congestion
boundaries . Intertemporal, cross-spatial and and long average trip journeys respectively) and
cross-cultural comparisons require standardisa- the bottom point of the function found at medium
tion in urban delimitation . There are several densities . This is a subject worthy of further
solutions : aggregation of population within a research . 3 If this hypothesis is confirmed . i t
given radius from the CBD ; counting the popula- suggests a switch of attention in discussions of
tion within a city region where the boundaries optimality in the city (as opposed to the question
of the region are fixed by where the population of minimum thresholds) to efficiency in spatial
falls to rural density levels ; using a population structure rather than to the problem of aggregate
potential index . Of course, the boundary prob- size, and that analysis of optimality in the urban
lem arises with the adoption of other size vari- economy that abstracts from space is grossly
ables too. inadequate .
Even if, in the absence of output or income data, Other criteria have been suggested for deter-
we can use population as a criterion for minimum mining optimal city size . For instance, it is
threshold city size, is it really useful in deter- sometimes argued that urban development and
mining an optimum? Assuming that data con- infrastructure construction costs are lower in
straints require us to work with population, is medium-sized towns which offer the economies of
the level of population more important than its scale and accessibility to building material
spatial distribution? The focus of this Confer- sources frequently not found in small centres yet
ence on national urban development strategies do not suffer from the high costs of development
and the concept of a national system of cities in large cities . But the latter is primarily due to
presumably implies that within the national high land costs which as a transfer payment
economy the spatial distribution of economic rather than a resource cost do not necessarily
activity and population between cities is a key mean high real costs unless economising on land
element inefficiency. Should not the argument be in selecting factor coefficients involves higher
extended down the scale on the lines that the costs, e.g. because of inelasticities in the supply
intra-city spatial distribution of population is of other factors . Moreover, the discounted
more important than the aggregate city popula- stream of urban development costs is such a small
tion? Emphasis on the spatial distribution of fraction of the total economic product of the city .
population is justified by the fact that many and differences in streams among cities of dif-
external diseconomies are due to congestion and ferent size much smaller still, that urban con-
can be treated as a function of population struction costs form much too narrow a criterion .

2 Rothenberg (1969) has shown the close links between pollution, possibly the most important
externality, and congestion.
3 For some first steps in examining the relationship between infrastructure, costs, distance and
population density see Treuner (1971), especially pp . 94-98 .

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at Afyon Kocatepe Universitesi on May 14, 2014


34 HARRY W . RICHARDSON

Another factor, stressed by Thompson (1965a to the industrial composition of the area, the
and b), is the emergence of managerial dis- skills required, turnover rates in individual
economies when the running of a city becomes a industries, and many other considerations . In
large-scale operation . In specific cases large general, however, the odds favour large labour
cities may be run inefficiently because of a markets, especially if they are spatially concen-
scarcity of high quality urban management trated . They offer more chance of locational
personnel, but I doubt whether such diseconomies compatibility, i .e. that the aggregate demand for
are inevitable. In the United Kingdom at least, labour at the city's workplaces will match the
impressionistic evidence points the other way : total supply within travelling distance (see
that small authorities are more likely to be in- Goldner, 1955), and large size ensures threshold
efficiently run primarily because successful urban pool levels even for highly specialised types of
management calls for highly skilled specialised labour .4
staff that can be justified and afforded only by These arguments lead us to reject the value of
large authorities . Furthermore, to what extent the optimal city size concept, even in a simplified
are managerial diseconomies in business due to comparative statics framework . When we
the physical impossibility of handling problems transfer the concept into a dynamic setting, its
above a certain scale or to the inefficiencies of value depreciates even further . One reason for
monopoly power? The latter scarcely apply in this is that urban growth dynamics require us to
the urban context since the major cities of the look at the individual city against the background
system are in competition with each other to of the wider system of which it forms a part, and
attract business firms and migrants . As Baumol in this wider framework it becomes clear that
(1967) pointed out, no modern city can let its tax different cities perform different functions (purely
rates or quality of urban services get too far out local, regional, national, or cosmopolitan), and
of line with its competitors . Moreover, within some cities perform all four . If we accept the
each city-size class efficiency is normally distri- implications of multifunctional cities, there is no
buted among cities much as it is among firms of a possibility of a unique optimum since optimality
given size in a particular industry . I suspect that makes sense only in the context of efficient
the `efficiency gap' between cities within a given achievement of objectives, and these objectives
size class may be about as wide as between cities vary according to the type and functions of the
of extremely different size . individual city . Because of multiple functions
Optimal city size discussions stress the impor- and intercity specialisation, cities will differ in the
tance of agglomeration economies, and an oft- local orientation of their industries and activities
quoted element in these is the benefit of a large, so that the local population threshold will be
centralised labour market. Others at this relevant in some cases but not in others . The
Conference are much better qualified to speak on efficient ranges of place size will be determined by
labour economics, so my remarks will be restric- the functions which each type of place has to
ted to one or two obvious points . First, if there perform . If the hierarchical structure implied by
were a precise scale for an efficient city labour differentiation in function extends to the national
market, this could still mean substantial variation system of cities, there would appear to be a basic
in city population sizes because of intercity inconsistency between the optimal city size
differentials in labour participation rates . Second, concept and an efficient national urban hierarchy .
the notion of an optimal scale is probably as This conflict, though obvious, has been neglected
dubious in regard to labour markets as to cities in the literature.
themselves. An efficient scale will vary according If optimality were a relevant objective, a

4 A recent United States study (Stanback and Knight, 1970) has shown that in the 1950s it was the
labour markets in the 200,000-1,600,000 range that grew fastest .

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at Afyon Kocatepe Universitesi on May 14, 2014


OPTIMALITY IN CITY SIZE 35

distinction would need to be drawn between large proportion of the city sizes in the hierarchy .
optimality in a single city and optimality in Fourth, with increasing decentralisation from
urban systems as a whole-the difference between major cities into urban subcentres around the
partial equilibrium and general equilibrium . metropolises it becomes arbitrary whether we
Thus, if city size equilibrium were an appropriate speak of one city or a family of linked cities .
policy objective, attempts to pursue it would run Since large cities of a prescribed size may imply
up against the problems arising from the theory conglomerations of smaller urban centres of
of second best since it is impossible to optimise variable size, it is possible depending on the
the spatial distribution of cities instantaneously. definitions of urban areas adopted to envisage an
It is perhaps possible to argue (Rashevsky, 1947) optimal metropolitan area size which simulta-
that a general inter-urban equilibrium is obtained neously embraces a hierarchy of city sizes .
when productivity per head is equalised . But it Finally, if optimal urban scale is measured not in
is doubtful whether the resulting distribution terms of absolute size but of optimum density,
would be consistent with the national urban the potential inconsistency may be resolved since
hierarchy . Moreover, whereas population might average densities may vary less than absolute city
redistribute itself among cities in this way if neo- sizes and the concept of optimum density (if it
classical marginalist assumptions held, it is most exists) is culturally and institutionally determined .
unlikely that either' inter-urban or rural-urban A minimum threshold size for a city may be
migration conforms to such a model . The bene- more sensible than an optimal size . If a clear-cut
fits of higher urban productivity frequently fall minimum size could be found, its rationale could
upon businesses rather than the individuals, be based on two arguments . First, it could
while the sharing of urban service costs through represent the population level needed to provide
the tax structure and its incidence on different a demand for all major services without having
groups blurs the connection between population to rely on other cities ; once again, this raises
expansion and rising urban costs . Furthermore, acute questions of definition and industry/service
the lack of urban data makes equalising per mix . Second, it could imply a threshold in urban
capita productivity infeasible as a policy goal . growth beyond which growth becomes self-
In any event an equilibrium based on equalising sustaining. Theoretically, there is no reason
inter-urban productivity is static, whereas hier- why these two minima should coincide . More-
archical distributions, such as the rank-size rule, over, centres below the minimum might be quite
represent a dynamic equilibrium in the sense that efficient if conceived as part of a wider system,
the distribution remains more or less the same e .g . if they perform lower order functions, or
overall even though the rank and rates of growth were locations for key national industries with
of individual cities in the hierarchy change nuisance creating properties that require isolated
(allometric growth) . sites . Criteria used to determine efficient minima
Can the concept of optimal city size be made for cities include demand thresholds, engineering
compatible with the existence of a national urban cost functions for urban services, high growth
hierarchy? The answer to this question depends rates (an analogy to the `survivor' technique for
on what is meant by optimal city size . As we estimating efficient firms), subjective observa-
have seen, von Boventer's concept of subjective tions of the range and quality of services offered
optima variable between firms is consistent with in cities of different sizes, etc . The evidence is not
the hierarchy of city sizes . Second, instead of a wholly conclusive, but much of it supports the
single optimal city size it may be more meaningful view that 200-250,000 is a minimum city popula-
to conceive of an optimal size for each rank order tion for providing a comprehensive range
in the urban hierarchy . Third, if the looser of services (Berry, 1968 ; Thompson, 1965a :
concept of an efficient range of city sizes is inter- Cameron, 1970 ; Neutze, 1965 ; Clarke, 1945 ;
preted very widely, a wide range may cover a Alonso, 1970b ; Redcliffe-Maud, 1969 ; Hansen,
3 *

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at Afyon Kocatepe Universitesi on May 14, 2014


36 HARRY W. RICHARDSON

1970) . This is not to deny that for many services though this is by no means a necessary implica-
a population of 30,000, 50,000 or 100,000 may be tion, central place hierarchies tend to refer to the
sufficient, while for certain specialised services regional system while the rank size rule is usually
(e .g. in the transport, medical and cultural fields) applied to nations.
a population of, at least one million may be We do not need to give much attention to the
necessary. statistical aspects of the rank size rule, for these
To sum up, to search for an optimal city size is are familiar. The rank-size rule states that we
almost as idle as the quest for the philosopher's can derive the rank in the urban system of a centre
stone . Optimality may have meaning in the from knowledge of its population size :
urban economy if it relates size to form and ry = aPz a (1)
structure, but the crude measures of size in the
literature have lacked any spatial dimension. It where P2 = population of centre x, r = rank,
may be more meaningful to explore the concept and a and q are constants .' A special case of (1)
of minimum critical size, though thresholds will is
vary according to the functions performed by the Pr = Pl (2)
urban centre and the service mix selected by its r
residents. There may be more truth in the idea in which a = P 1 , the population of the primate
of an efficient range of sizes within each broad city, and q = 1 . Where the special case is valid,
size-function class of cities . There may even be a we obtain the population of any centre by
theoretical maximum size beyond which cities dividing the population of the leading city by the
are likely to encounter increasing obstacles to rank of the centre in question .6 Finally, if the
efficiency and growth . But these modifications entire population of the system is urban then the
destroy the concept of a unique optimum . This total population,
is, in fact, reassuring for the dynamic analysis of
Pt = aZr - Q (3)
city systems since these invariably seem to take
the form of a hierarchical structure . Weiss (1961) demonstrated that, by choosing
appropriate values for the parameters a and q, it
is possible to fit the cumulative population data
The rank size rule for the U .S . to within 1 %, and that this covered
There has been little by way of formal analysis 4,000 cities and towns and 59 % of the population.
on the distribution of city sizes apart from the If the sum held until all the U.S. population was
classical concepts of the rank-size rule and the exhausted, 12,000 centres would be required .
urban hierarchies derived from the application of There are at least three important questions
Christaller-Losch market area principles . It can raised by the rank-size rule . How far does it
be shown that there are certain similarities apply? Can it be explained? Does it represent,
between rank-size and central place principles in any sense, an optimal distribution of city sizes?
and that the two distributions can be made The empirical evidence for the rank-size rule is
consistent with each other (Parr, 1970) . However, mixed : it holds in some countries but not in
there are basic differences . First, the rank-size others ; in one or two cases, perhaps Western
rule is an empirical relationship ('a fact in search Europe is the most notable example, it fits a
of a theory'?) while central place hierarchies can multinational system better than for a single
be deduced by a priori reasoning. Second, al- nation. If anything, it is more likely to apply in

5 Thus jog r, = log a-q log P, so that if we plot rank against size on double log paper we should,
if the rule holds precisely, obtain a straight line with the slope of -q.
6 The special case is very much a special case . The leading metropolis in the system may diverge
widely from the city size needed to support equation (2) while Moore (1959) showed that in both
the U .S. and the U.S .S .R., q< I and declines over time .

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at Afyon Kocatepe Universitesi on May 14, 2014


OPTIMALITY IN CITY SIZE 37

large countries with a long history of urbanisation tendency for economists by force of habit to
and with a complex economic structure . At the equate the equilibrium solution with the desired
same time, Berry (1961) found no clear relation- or optimal solution, but this is a danger to be
ship between conformity to the rank size and the resisted, Indeed, there is a degree of incompati-
level of economic development ; though others bility in the notion of an optimum resulting from
(Bell, 1962 ; Friedmann, 1963 ; and Boal and a process that is essentially stochastic. On the
Johnson, 1965) disagree . other hand, it is consistent with the mass of
A more important question, once we accept individuals making optimal location decisions
that in many highly urbanised economies there is since probability theory suggest that the total
a distribution of city sizes which approximates, effect of a large number of optimising decisions
to a greater or lesser extent, to a rank-size may appear as random. But as we know, once
relationship, is whether there is a satisfactory we acknowledge the existence of imperfections
explanation of why systems of cities structure in competition and externalities, the sum of
themselves in this way . There is no acceptable individual optimising decisions is not necessarily
economic theory but there is wide support for an a societal optimum . It would be foolish to treat
explanation that is partly based on statistical the rank-size distribution as an ideal state and to
theory, partly on an analogy drawn from adopt an urban policy aimed at correcting
thermodynamics (Vining, 1965 ; Berry, 1961 and deviations from it . What the evidence on distri-
1964 ; Curry, 1964 and 1967 ; Olsson, 1966) . bution of city sizes does suggest, however, is that
Vining, for example, argued that the rank-size a strongly hierarchical distribution always results
rule is a time dependent stochastic process and from the operation of competitive forces in an
that the distribution of city sizes maintains urbanised economy . This implies that a national
stability (a form of `statistical equilibrium') even urban hierarchy is perhaps an efficient distribu-
though there is a great deal of individual flux, tion for achieving national and regional objec-
e .g. city populations changing over time, rises tives .
and falls in rank, births and deaths of towns, etc .
Olsson demonstrated that the most probable or The need for a national urban hierarchy
equilibrium state of a system of settlements is It is well known that a hierarchy of urban
equivalent to the rank-size rule, and that `a centres is the efficient way of organising produc-
system of cities obeying the rank-size rule is in a tion and distribution within a region, i .e. the
state of equilibrium in which "entropy" has been central place system . Similarly, the national
maximised' .? Curry (1964) similarly showed that urban hierarchy performs a number of important
the rank-size rule conformed to the most functions in the national economy which may
probable distribution of a random arrangement make it an efficient medium for the distribution
of a given number of people in a given number of of the total population even if some individual
cities . Randomness has the effect of avoiding cities in the size distribution are outside the
too much concentration in large cities and en- efficient size range from the point of view of the
suring that the population is spread (though not cities when considered alone .
evenly of course) among all cities . Although central place theory, with its empha-
Even if the rank-size rule is the most probable sis upon supplying central services to the hinter-
state of the system of cities, this does not mean it is lands around towns, can be used only to explain
in any way an optimal distribution . If it repre- the regional hierarchy, and then convincingly
sents an entropy-maximising state there may be a solely in rural regions, it nevertheless has relevant

7 The concept of entropy is derived from the second law of thermodynamics . This specifies the
direction in which a closed system in disequilibrium will move in order to reach equilibrium : thus,
energy moves from hotter to cooler bodies . Entropy is a measure of the degree of equalisation
reached within a system, and entropy is maximised when the system is in equilibrium .

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at Afyon Kocatepe Universitesi on May 14, 2014


38 HARRY W . RICHARDSON

implications for analysis of the national hier- place regional hierarchy. Towns of similar size
archy .s First, it accounts for the lower orders in may produce quite different `mixes' of goods and
the distribution of city sizes since the national services, the same industry may locate in cities of
hierarchy is merely the sum of all regional hier- different size, and even large scale economy
archies . The small sub-regional urban centres industries may be found in small cities . On the
will feature as low-ranking towns in the national other hand, the larger a city the more likely that it
system, leaving to be explained in other ways only will be specialised in national market industries .
the system formed by the leading cities in each The national hierarchy of leading cities fulfils
region and why these assume a hierarchical other purposes that give justification to the view
structure from the standpoint of the national that it is an instrument for achieving national
economy. Second, the principle behind central growth . First, the urban hierarchy is an efficient
place theory-that industries have market areas vehicle for transmitting new technology, mana-
of different size-is still of value at the national gerial expertise and general economic functions
level. from the centre of the economy to the periphery .
The modifications to the Christaller central This permits social and economic change to'leap-
place analysis needed for explanation of the frog' over distance and avoid the slower gradual
national hierarchy owe a lot to Losch (1954), diffusion over space from the central city . This
Stolper (1955), Tinbergen (1961) and Bos (1965) . transmission function is aided by the fact that
The basic difference is that whereas in the central many modem forms of business organisation (in
place hierarchy centres of the same size always commerce, finance and industry) are themselves
produce the same order of goods and services and hierarchical with head offices and centres of
the industries with large market areas and scale decision making in the metropolitan centres and
economies are always produced in the larger their decision trees spread out spatially down the
cities, this is not necessarily the case with the urban hierarchy . Given the large scale and
national distribution . City size is positively multiple establishments characteristic of modern
linked with the number of activities located business, a hierarchy of cities makes it easier to
there and since economies of scale and market distribute the hierarchical structure and func-
area threshold differentials rule out the presence tions of business organisation over the economy
of each industry in each city, we obtain cities of as a whole .
different size . The largest city will be that which Second, a hierarchy of cities permits speciali-
captures the highest proportion of national (and sation, division of labour and differentiation in
international) market industries while at the economic function. Market size requirements,
same time encompassing most other industries infrastructure needs and agglomeration econo-
with smaller market areas . The place of other mies differ between firms in the same industry
cities in the hierarchy will similarly be determined (many industries have a size distribution of firms
by how many particular industries and of what similar in form to the distribution of city sizes)
size it attracts . This cannot be predicted with and between industries . A hierarchy of cities
accuracy since the attractive power of cities offers firms a wider choice in location and
depends upon the quality of their services, the enables them to operate more efficiently (von
size and compactness of their markets, and the Boventer, 1970) . Third, the hierarchical struc-
strength of their agglomeration economies . ture of cities dominant within their own regions
The national hierarchy lacks the systematic enables each city to function in a manner appro-
order and the predetermined pattern of the central priate to the size and character of its hinterland

s By this, I mean economic implications . It has been argued (Hoover, 1955 ; Beckmann, 1958 ; Parr,
1969 and 1970) that there are statistical similarities between a central place system and the rank-
size distribution .

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at Afyon Kocatepe Universitesi on May 14, 2014


OPTIMALITY IN CITY SIZE 39

region . The leading city in a peripheral region, uniform population densities) . In particular,
for instance, clearly plays an important role the dispersion around the theoretical aver-
in the development of that region (the growth age increases with city size because large
centre strategy) . Since regions vary in area, popu- cities (and hence the number of observations) are
lation and level of economic development it is few.
inevitable that their leading cities will also vary Second, the existing distribution of cities in a
in size . developed economy reflects historical patterns of
growth, and the inititial location of many cities
may have been due to factors (raw material
The spacing of cities
orientation, access to strategic transport routes,
A distinction must be drawn between the size random elements) other than market area
and the spatial distributions of cities in the influences . For instance arguing ab initio in a
national economy. The urban size hierarchy and uniform plain model, the main centre should be
the urban spatial hierarchy are not necessarily located so as to minimise transport costs to and
symmetrical . For instance, the size hierarchy from all parts of the economy, i .e . at the centre of
may appear very efficient in terms of the distri- the plain . Yet in many countries, particularly
bution of population among existing centres outside Europe, the largest metropolis is often
but it could be grossly sub-optimal because found on or near the coast reflecting the fact that
of irregular spacing . the countries were originally opened up for
Geographers and other spatial analysts have development by colonisation from overseas . The
developed one or two simple rules to determine international and entrepot functions of these
the average distances between centres . One of leading cities may persist almost indefinitely .
these (Stewart, 1958) is that the distance between Thus, the historically evolved pattern of urban
two cities is proportional to the multiple of their settlement constrains subsequent development .
populations, i .e . d t = PPPt/G, where G is a For the purposes of analysis, the fact that the
constant . Another (Curry, 1967) is that in an n location of some cities is predetermined (due to
order hierarchy the distances between centres in spatial irregularities and good natural sites as
the same rank can be related to distances well as to historical factors) makes it much
between centres of other ranks by the function simpler to assign locations to the others, but it
d„ = d',S I . This is a special case of the does distort the actual from the theoretically
Christaller-Losch general principle that predicted spatial distribution . Third, the dis-
do = do -I/k, where k = number of settlements tance between cities is not independent of the size
supplied by n of rank n-1 . Thus, the results of the economy, particularly with regard to area
vary according to whether the nesting pattern and population density . For instance, Losch
refers to 3, 4 or 7 centres . found that in the United States rural densities
While it is true that economic factors lie behind declined with movement westward and average
these principles in that the distances can be inter-urban distance increased . Even more
deduced from market area analysis and while obvious, inter-urban distances will tend to
limited conclusions may be drawn from them be shorter in small and/or highly urbanised
(e .g . the obvious point that average distance countries .
between centres increases as we ascend the urban A more sophisticated economic analysis of
hierarchy), we should not expect too much simi- interrelationships in space l5~t`ween urban centres
larity between the theoretical and actual spatial has been presented by von Boventer (1969 and
distributions. There are three main reasons for 1970) . He argues that two main factors influence
this . First, the distances referred to are average the ideal location for a city or a town : agglomera-
not uniquely determined distances, bound by the tion economies gained by locating near a larger
assumptions of the market area models (e .g. centre and hinterland effects which are small (or

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at Afyon Kocatepe Universitesi on May 14, 2014


40 HARRY W . RICHARDSON

negative) near large cities because of their com- and big and far' . Furthermore, by adopting a
petitive power but are strong at a distance development axis approach with centres built up
because of the protection of a sheltered market along axes from or between metropolitan cities it
area . The optimal distance for a city from the may be possible to retain access to agglomeration
nearest larger or equal-sized city is that which economies without having to sacrifice hinterland
maximises the sum of agglomeration and hinter- effects . The whole argument suggests that a
land effects . The ideal distance may be difficult polinucleated megapolitan structure, far from
to pinpoint, but von Boventer argues that there being an untidy and ugly urbanised sore, could
is some intermediate distance (the pessimum be an efficient constellation of urban centres for
distance) at which the city will be worse off. fostering national growth . The most appropriate
Thus, an urban centre has better growth pros- method of stimulating growth in lagging regions,
pects if it is either close by a vigorous bigger city on the other hand, could be to reinforce their
or far away from all competitors . largest cities .
The broad policy implications of this analysis
are more important than any attempt to deter- The goals of a national urban policy
mine precisely either the ideal or the pessimum Even though several policies pursued by
distance .9 From the point of view of maximising governments in developed economies have had
growth in the economy as a whole, it is undesir- the effect, and sometimes the explicit intention,
able that large cities should be close together of influencing the spatial distribution of popula-
since a large city can create its own agglomeration tion between cities and towns, it would be mis-
economies which can support smaller centres and leading to speak as if these countries had a clear
(via a growth centre strategy) regional expansion national urban policy . In the UK for instance,
at a distance . Small urban centres, on the other measures have been implemented in an ad hoc
hand, have few positive hinterland effects and a and piecemeal fashion without any conception of
location far away from a metropolis offers no a comprehensive strategy. Also, since they were
benefit . Thus, small centres thrive best if they introduced very late in the day in a heavily
are not too far away from a metropolitan centre industrialised, highly urbanised society, such
so that they can profit from agglomeration econo- measures have not been able to plan the develop-
mies and spillover effects, though it is obviously ment of an urban system (as in Turkey and much
an advantage if there are no competitors of less successfully in Brazil) but merely to modify
similar size nearby . This argument is strength- an old-established structure, and in a very minor
ened if there are diseconomies of scale in urban way. British `policy' has had three major aspects :
size, since the small city near the large metropolis decentralisation of people and activities from the
reaps the benefits of agglomeration without the great metropolises (primarily London but also
pains of large size . In Alonso's (1970b) succinct Liverpool, Manchester, Birmingham, Tyneside
phrase : `Policies of small and far, which are not and Glasgow), the main manifestation of which
uncommon, perhaps should be small and near, has been overspill policy ; the related, but

9 It should be noted, however, that there is possible conflict between von Boventer's findings and the
earlier empirical study of spatial aspects of urban growth in the United States by Madden (1958-9) .
Madden found that the growth rates of urban centres declined with distance from the metropolis
up to 45 miles, grew steadily in the 45-64 miles range (also urban centres in this range tended to
be larger than those nearer to or farther from the metropolis), declined again up to 114 miles,
and were high but unstable beyond 115 miles . The implication of this is that there could, in fact,
be an optimum distance where hinterland effects are strong but the competitive pull of the larger
centre very weak . This raises two questions . Does the distance over which a major metropolis
exerts agglomeration effects differ from the radius of its competitive pull? Would hinterland
effects be reduced by a location further away from the metropolis than shown in Madden's study
because of falling population densities? Answers to these questions might reconcile the
potential conflict .

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at Afyon Kocatepe Universitesi on May 14, 2014


OPTIMALITY IN CITY SIZE 41

overrated, New Towns policy ; and more recently, form for the guidance of policymakers . Some
examination of the possibility of stimulating are ambiguous . Others are clear but are either
growth centres in the Development Areas, but too costly or impossible to make operational .
little action . It is unnecessary to detail the evalua- These points may be illustrated by commenting
tion and execution of these policies . They are on each goal .
well known, and in any event they do not add up In a country without a significant rural surplus
to a national urban strategy.' o The New Towns, of labour, goal (i) implies that each city grows at
despite being the most distinctive feature of UK its natural rate. Although this could alter the
urban policy, served predominantly especially city size distribution if there were large inter-
in the early years as overspill pockets for London, urban differences in fertility, this is unlikely to
and did not represent the emergence of a strategy bring about much change in urban rankings .
for a national system of cities . From this point However, despite locational preferences for a
of view, they make less sense than the metropoles familiar environment, such a goal is unattainable .
d'equilibre of France which have the dual It may make more sense to modify the objective
function of acting as a counterweight to Paris and to minimising `involuntary' migration, but this
of promoting the development of their hinterland raises acute questions of definition . In any
regions ." To the extent that the new towns were event, any policy involving a reduction in the
an innovation, this was as social and architectural overall rate of migration is likely to interfere with
experiments within the towns not as a major national growth objectives.
influence on the urban hierarchy, since they Objective (ii) is not very specific, though it
merely added another score or so of towns to the clearly implies restrictions on the growth of large
900 or so smaller towns of less than 75,000 in metropolises. However. we have seen that there
Great Britain . is no evidence to suggest that a more even size
It is possible for a national urban policy to be distribution of large cities implies greater effi-
based on the pursuit of a single objective . ciency and higher welfare than a skewed distribu-
Alternative objectives might be : tion . Even if an even distribution were con-
(i) minimisation of inter-urban migration ; sidered desirable, it is doubtful whether available
(ii) prevention of urban imbalance ; policy instruments could achieve much by way
(iii) convergence of interregional income and of cutting down the size of great cities. Moreover,
growth differentials ; 12 there are political difficulties in the way of
(iv) maximisation of innovation diffusion strengthening these instruments . Large city
potential ; governments are powerful, and are unlikely to
(v) creation of a market for cities ; take kindly to national policymakers who attempt
(vi) equating the private and social costs of to reduce their territory and tax base . The inter-
urban expansion . ference in local autonomy that this national-local
Many of these are too broad for implementation conflict necessarily involves is itself a far from
and need to be translated into a more specific negligible social cost .

10 It is true that attempts to deal with the problems of metropolitan concentration, size and inter-
urban distance were made in both The Strategy for the South East (1967) and Strategic Plan for
the South East (1970) . However, these are regional rather than national strategies, and in any
event have not yet been implemented .
11 This does not mean that the equilibrium metropolis policy is very successful ; merely, that it
implies a more clearly discernible national urban strategy .
12 A variant of this might be the promotion of income equity within cities . I have not discussed this
for two reasons . First, I would argue that the efficiency of the city as an instrument of national
economic growth depends on inequities . Second, it is arguable that appropriate policies for
dealing with extreme income inequalities are primarily national welfare and social measures
rather than part of an urban policy .

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at Afyon Kocatepe Universitesi on May 14, 2014


42 HARRY W . RICHARDSON

The third goal is also difficult as long experi- tion which involves risks and doubtful payoffs .
ence with regional policy shows . In regard to A serious objection to the relevance of this goal
urban policy it requires controlling city growth is that an extremely wide choice in urban
in rich regions and expanding urban centres in environments, life styles and service-tax mixes
lagging regions. If the rich regions contain the can be found within a very large metropolitan
largest cities, then operationally this policy be- area without having to create a differentiated
comes similar to the urban growth strategies system of separate cities .
pursued inmost countries However, as it stands Goal (vi) is a favoured single objective . It
it may be an oversimplification since the argu- requires measures to redistribute inter-urban
ment assumes that income and growth indicators population until the private and social costs of
move together . If large cities have high propor- urban expansion are matched in each city . The
tions of low income residents the policy implica- rationale is that the divergence between social
tions may be rather different with a possibility of and private costs leads to excessive growth of
conflict between growth and income equalisation cities. This happens because households and
(equity), i .e . high growth rates may require large firms make location decisions on the basis of
cities in backward regions but these may create average costs, but the marginal costs of their entry
rather than reduce poverty. into a city fall on the entire community, and these
The maximisation of innovation diffusion costs are much higher than average costs because
potential, though important, is unlikely to prevail cost curves are rising . Thus, market decisions
as a single urban policy goal but to be associated result in cities becoming too big unless in-migrants
with others . We know that realisation of such a can be forced to pay the marginal costs associated
goal requires a national hierarchy of cities with with their arrival. The trouble with this objective
strong communication links between them and is that it is incomplete and it is non-operational .
multi-plant corporations operating in or near It is incomplete because it ignores the benefit side
many centres in the hierarchy . Where our of the picture . In-migrants may also create social
knowledge is deficient is in identifying more benefits and these may or may not exceed the
precisely the most efficient hierarchical distribu- gap between social and private costs . It is
tion for the diffusion of innovation, technical non-operational because we cannot accurately
progress, new management methods, etc . Accor- measure social costs and benefits and hence
dingly, other than investing in the communica- cannot fix the appropriate levels of taxes (subsi-
tions networks it is difficult to know what pursuit dies) even if a marginal cost pricing policy was
of this goal implies by way of policy measures . politically acceptable . Moreover, there are
The argument of goal (v) is that community dangers in applying a static pricing framework to
welfare is increased by offering households and a dynamic problem. For instance, rising margi-
firms a wider freedom of choice in the types of nal costs of in-migration might be incurred only
urban centre in which they choose to locate . in the short run because the rate of in-migration
Pursuit of this goal simply requires the govern- is temporarily too fast to be absorbed . In other
ment to stimulate product differentiation in the words, they may result from inelasticities in
types and quality of urban living by developing short-run supply functions rather than from
a system of cities of widely different size and with higher social costs in the long run .
very varied environments and urban life styles . These comments suggest that the apparent
This strategy, the creation of a `market for cities', simplicity of a single goal national urban policy
is an extension on a wider front of Tiebout's is deceptive . The overall comprehensive goal is
(1956) case for a varied inter-urban mix of urban often vague and frequently subsumes several
service-tax structures. It probably requires other implicit and not necessarily consistent
extensive Government subsidies since more objectives . It is usually not specific enough for
product differentiation needs urban experimenta- us to translate it into clear criteria for action .

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at Afyon Kocatepe Universitesi on May 14, 2014


OPTIMALITY IN CITY SIZE 43

Many of the dimensions of the goal cannot be is true depends upon whether individuals are
quantified, and this means that optimising deci- `forced' to live in large cities or whether their
sions must be to some extent subjective since they residential location decisions reflect a'free choice'
rely on the policymaker's own weights . It and a personal favourable balance of benefits
follows that a workable strategy for a national over costs . Furthermore, if higher social costs
urban policy is likely to be based on several goals are generated in large cities, it is unclear whether
with all the possibilities of conflict that multiple this is a direct consequence of size itself or simply
goals imply . The nature of these goals will vary reflects remediable managerial and organisa-
from one society to another according to levels of tional inefficiencies, the absence of pollution
economic development and socio-cultural values, control policies, or lags in the response of urban
as will the priorities among selected goals . In governments to past population pressure . If the
most developed economies, however, we would former there may be a prima facie case for decen-
expect to find the following minimum set : tralising population into smaller urban centres,
(a) the pursuit of national growth ; but if the latter factors explain the high social
(b) the promotion of interregional equity ; costs the answer may lie in more effective city
(c) a `quality of life' goal . management and improvements in intra-city
There is, of course, the possibility of other goals, spatial distribution .
either independent from those on the list or sub- The presence of multiple goals and the fact that
sumed within them . 13 priorities will differ among national, regional and
Goal (a) has implications for the distribution urban policymakers mean that it is difficult to
of city sizes, both in regard to the structure and prescribe an optimal strategy to fulfil the stated
spacing of the hierarchy as a whole and to the objectives . Goal conflicts will have to be
importance of leading cities as generators of reconciled, the 'best' technical solutions will have
growth and innovation . Although goal (b) to be modified by the constraints of political
may call for controls on urban growth in pros- feasibility and by the need to satisfy community
perous regions, mainly via redirecting expanding and individual preferences . Optimisation is
industry to lagging regions, its main focus will be scarcely practicable. In particular, it is im-
on building up smaller urban centres in backward possible for all the objectives of urban policy
regions to that critical minimum size which (faster growth, the revival of lagging regions, the
guarantees agglomeration economies . . The control of environmental nuisances, etc .) to be
`quality of life' goal-goal (c)-is possibly the satisfied by a unique optimum in the distribution
most important component of an urban policy of cities. For instance, even if it were true that
strategy, yet it is the most nebulous . It refers large cities were always more efficient economi-
primarily to the possible divergence between cally than small, this would not rule out the
productivity and welfare in cities due to non- possibility that a hierarchy of sub-optimal cities
measurable social costs and intangible benefits . could be more `efficient' in relation to goal
We still know very little about what constitutes a achievement (including growth goals) than the
good environment for urban living, though we encouragement of a pattern of a few ever-
do know that perception of and response to increasing metropolises. Finally, in a multiple
environment differ a great deal from individual goal framework it is difficult to know whether a
to individual and between groups. Moreover, particular policy measure works in the right
the social costs, however defined, may be offset direction since its impact one attainment of one
by higher real incomes and less quantifiable goal may be offset by unforeseen disturbances on
benefits associated with large city life ; how far this the attainment of others . All this amounts to a
13 For example, in the United States an important social goal would refer to attaining desirable class-
status-race mixes within cities of different size, and this would encompass still other goals, e .g.
relating to income redistribution, education, labour markets, etc .

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at Afyon Kocatepe Universitesi on May 14, 2014


44 HARRY W . RICHARDSON

plea for very careful pragmatism rather than In distinguishing between policy instruments,
ambitious and inevitably abortive attempts to we must be careful to draw the line between those
optimise the size and spatial distribution of directly and those incidentally related to urban
cities . policy . For example, the central government's
national policies-industrial policies, monetary
and fiscal measures, transport policy, health,
The instruments of urban policy
education and welfare expenditures-have dif-
Even if urban policy goals have been precisely ferential impacts on cities . Regional measures
specified and it is known what changes will occupy an intermediate role since policies to
achieve them, there remains the problem of redistribute industry between regions are bound
whether the instruments are, or can be made, to have large urban side-effects because most
available to bring about the required changes . population and economic activity is urban .
It is arguable that a centrally planned economy Measures to influence the inter-regional distribu-
would be needed to attain a particular distribu- tion of industry (investment incentives, tax
tion of city sizes in a spatial framework, and even allowances, payroll subsidies, prohibitive controls
in planned economies experience in attempting such as i .d .c.s .) can also be used to implement
to halt the growth of large cities has not been very urban policy goals, but only in rare circumstances
successful . Secondly, and this is the crucial will their use in this context be compatible with
point, the instruments available within the city their role as a regional policy instrument . For
to change the intra-urban spatial distribution of instance, controls on office building in Greater
activities are more powerful and their effects London since 1964 have been primarily associated
more predictable than the instruments available with attempts to persuade firms to relocate in the
for modifying the inter-urban spatial distribution. Outer Metropolitan Area, and this has done
This is primarily because planning, zoning and nothing to correct imbalance in expanding service
land-use controls are more effective (though not industries between the South East and the outer
necessarily more efficient) than investment incen- regions of Britain . Other measures, such as the
tives, tax-subsidy measures, etc . Moreover, provision of infrastructure and social overhead
measures to improve the efficiency and organisa- capital, simultaneously serve national, regional
tion of the great metropolises may not only be and urban ends. In this sense, decisions on the
more practicable than measures to prevent their location of infrastructure might be regarded as
growth but also more important in the sense that the unifying theme in the co-ordination of national
they will affect more people . 14 The arguments urban policy, except for the facts that infra-
for emphasis on metropolitan rather than city structure decisions are taken at different levels of
size distribution solutions to policy problems government and that successful realisation of
should not be interpreted as a case for leaving urban goals also requires a sequence of compatible
policy in the hands of local governments. For if private decisions by households and firms to
polinucleated clusters of cities are desirable and rationalise and justify the prior (or associated)
efficient (because they create large markets and infrastructure decisions .
offer a flexible structure for expansion), they Apart from public infrastructure investment,
need intermetropolitan and national policies to the two most obvious urban policy instruments
cope with common problems-transport, water are (i) planning, land and zoning controls and (ii)
and sewage, open space and recreation require- pricing methods, such as congestion taxes, user
ments, and air pollution. charges for public services, etc . Both can be

14 Dissenters from this view may argue that reducing the size of the metropolis will not only raise
the welfare of those induced to locate elsewhere but also the welfare of all remaining households
and firms in the metropolis . This may be so, but I doubt whether social costs are easily rever-
sible.

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at Afyon Kocatepe Universitesi on May 14, 2014


OPTIMALITY IN CITY SIZE 45
justified in general by reference to 'externality' to equalise the size of cities, but it does not help us
arguments . The trouble arises when attempts are to decide whether one hierarchical structure is
made to justify the application of specific superior to another. There are a few general
measures in relation to the achievement of urban indications . First, variety in urban form, struc-
policy goals, especially if these goals include an ture and environment both in regard to differen-
efficiency in resource allocation component . The tials in city size and within a specific size-class is
repercussionary effects of land use controls are probably a good thing because it offers individual
difficult to trace, while the importance of non- households and firms a wider choice . Given
measurable social costs makes it impossible to heterogeneous tastes, wider choice implies greater
set `optimal' congestion taxes . In addition, the welfare. Second, if a first-order metropolis is a
widespread use of pricing methods to control seedbed for innovation, managerial expertise and
urban scale is suspect on the grounds of political growth and a `port of entry' for new technology
feasibility . The crudity of our policy instruments and ideas into a region, then every region should
once more reinforces the case for pragmatism . contain a large city (relative to the size of the
In devising an urban growth strategy, goals set as region). If this condition is fulfilled, a national
targets are more likely to be attainable than goals hierarchy of regional cities will further devolve
expressed in terms of optimal efficiency . The into sets of central place systems . Third, what-
best we can do is to take action in response to ever the size distribution of the top level of the
specific and clear-cut problems in the hope that national hierarchy, its efficiency depends as much
we nudge the spatial allocation of resources a on the quality of the transport and communica-
little in the desired direction . tions networks linking the major cities as on the
balance between agglomeration economies and
urban costs within them.
Conclusions
The promotion of growth centres in lagging
If it implies an optimal distribution of national regions is in many cases a valid policy objective,
population through the nation's existing and but it is much more relevant to regional than to
planned urban centres, a national system of cities urban policy. A growth centre strategy involves
is not a sensible object of public policy . This is an attempt to maximise regional growth potential
not to say that a national urban policy is undesir- via spatial concentration of development and to
able or unnecessary . But such a policy should obtain cost-effectiveness in urban infrastructure
be goal-oriented, and we can identify several spending. Much more central to a national
separate if overlapping and frequently conflicting urban policy is what, if anything, should be done
goals . Moreover, the magnitudes of change about a nation's large cities . We know that all is
needed to achieve these goals are in some cases not well, that our great metropolises have genera-
not easily, if at all, measurable . With many goals, ted considerable social costs . The fact that many
and when some of these cannot be translated into of these are difficult, or impossible, to measure
quantifiable objectives, the case for optimisation cannot deny their existence and importance .
loses much of its strength. Certainly, there is no What we do not know, however, is how far these
unique spatial distribution of population which social costs may be offset by social benefits in the
can be said to achieve these goals . Von Boventer form of higher urban productivity . Some, but
(1970) has pointed out that deriving an optimal not all, of this higher productivity may be
distribution of population is difficult . I will go captured in higher real incemes, but the incom-
further ; in a policy context, it is impossible . pleteness of urban data makes it difficult even to
A hierarchy of cities is an efficient system for quantify the measurable component . If higher
promoting national growth and for producing costs were outweighed by higher productivity, we
and distributing goods and services to society . would have not a diseconomy of scale question
This suggests that it would be foolish to attempt but an income distribution question, since the

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at Afyon Kocatepe Universitesi on May 14, 2014


46 HARRY W. RICHARDSON

burden of social costs falls heavily on those too for providing an array of different environments
poor to evade them, while the benefits of higher for businesses and people. Furthermore, there
urban productivity are not equally shared but is not a single unique efficient distribution of city
accrue to owners of urban land, business corpora- sizes, but many, and given multiple goals we
tions and other monopoly groups . Furthermore, should not be too worried about minor irregulari-
it is unclear whether higher social costs are ties in the city size distribution .
inherent in the phenomenon of large size or A pragmatic approach does not rule out
whether they might not be transient due, say, to a measures that affect the national urban hierarchy .
too fast rate of in-migration relative to the in- These might include action to boost leading cities
crease in urban capacity, i .e . a problem of absorp- in backward regions or to bring small cities up to
tion rate rather than absolute scale . If so, the a minimum critical size compatible with efficiency
appropriate remedies would be to monitor and and continued growth . Also, measures to
control the rate of expansion of large cities not to decentralise activities from our largest cities are
attempt to reduce them in size . not inconsistent with a national urban policy .
Even if we suspect that the net social benefits But such measures are unlikely to be successful if
of the present distribution of urban population they aim at reducing the scale of our metropolitan
are negative, there are two further considerations . areas by redistributing population to other
First, the policy instruments available in a mixed distant urban centres in other regions . Better
economy are probably not strong enough to prospects are offered by dispersing population
reduce the size of large cities . By influencing the from the central city itself to interconnected
distribution of jobs and the provision of housing smaller centres within the metropolitan region .
and infrastructure, however, it may be possible The promotion of a polinucleated system enables
to alter the spatial distribution of urban popula- the smaller cities to benefit from the agglomera-
tion in a period of population expansion by tion economies offered by access to the metro-
operating on the relative growth rates of indivi- polis. It is also more likely to achieve results
dual cities . Second, a danger in pursuing, since it probably satisfies locational preferences
possibly ineffective, measures to persuade people much more than an interregional-interurban
and activities to leave the large metropolises is redistribution .
that this may provide a pretext for neglecting the Most important of all, however, is that the
pressing problems of improving the urban most effective policy, especially if we accept the
environment and central city poverty . These argument that there are many efficient city size
problems are not directly related to scale, and distributions, could well be to improve the
will persist even if the size of large cities could be efficiency and management of our large cities by
reduced . acting on the intra-city spatial distribution and
Does all this mean that nothing is left of an by correcting the most obvious resource mis-
urban policy strategy? Not at all . However, it allocations within the city . The large city is an
implies that such a strategy should be pragmatic, important engine for growth, and we know that
even piecemeal, rather than based on an optimisa- rapid urban expansion may improve welfare
tion approach aiming to achieve a dynamic rather less than it boosts growth . Is it not, there-
spatial equilibrium at one stroke. Moreover, a fore, a sensible urban policy objective to concen-
national urban policy ought not to include trate on improving the urban environment and
measures to attain optimal size for an individual `livability' within the city? In this way
city. Optimality in this context has no real more people will benefit than by measures to
meaning . Even if this were not the case, from the stimulate out-migration from the cities which
viewpoint of national policy an artificial system might adversely affect growth potential without
of cities of `optimal size' would be less efficient achieving a commensurate reduction in social
than a hierarchy both for economic growth and costs.

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at Afyon Kocatepe Universitesi on May 14, 2014


OPTIMALITY IN CITY SIZE 47

REFERENCES Urban Hierarchies : An Empirical Note. JRS, Vol .


10, pp . 253-255 .
ALONSO, W . (1970a) . What are New Towns For? HIRSCH, W. Z . (1959) . Expenditure Implications of
Urban Studies, Vol 7, pp. 37-55 . Metropolitan Growth and Consolidation . Review
- (1970b) . The Question of Urban Size . Paper read of Economics and Statistics, Vol . 41, pp. 232-241 .
at Regional Science Association Conference, London, HOOVER, E. M . (1955) . The Concept of a System of
August . Cities : A Comment on Rutledge Vining's Paper .
BAUMOL, W. J. (1967) . Macroeconomics of Unbalanced E.D.C.C., Vol . 3, pp. 196-198.
Growth : the Anatomy of Urban Crisis . American -(1970) . Transport Costs and the Spacing of Central
Economic Review, Vol. 57, pp. 415-426 . Places . P.P.R.S.A ., Vol . 25, pp . 255-274 .
BECKMANN, M . J . (1958). City Hierarchies and the ISARD, W . (1960) . Methods of Regional Analysis . MIT
Distribution of City Size . Economic Development Press, 1960 .
and Cultural Change, Vol . 6, 243-248. LOMAx, K. S . (1943) . Expenditure per Head and Size of
- (1968) . Location Theory . Random House, 1968 . Population . Journal of the Royal Statistical Society
BELL, G . (1962) . Change in City Size Distribution in Vol . 106 .
Israel. Ekistics, Vol . 13 . LoscH, A . (1954). The Economics of Location . Yale
BERRY, B . J. L . (1961). City Size Distribution and U .P .
Economic Development . E.D .C.C., Vol . 9, pp. MADDEN, C . H . (1958-9). Some Spatial Aspects of
573-587 . Urban Growth in the U.S. E.D .C.C., Vol . 6, pp .
- (1964). Cities as Systems within Systems of Cities . 371-387.
Papers and Proceedings of Regional Science Associa- MOORE, F. T . (1959) . A Note on City Size Distributions .
tion, Vol . 13, pp. 147-163 . E.D .C.C., Vol . 7, pp . 465-466 .
- Geography of Market Centres and Retail Distribu- NEUTZE, G . M . (1965). Economic Policy and the Size of
tion. Prentice-Hall, 1967. Cities. Kelley.
- A Summary-Spatial Organisation and Levels of OLSSON, G. (1966) . Central Place Systems, Spatial
Welfare : Degree of Metropolitan Labour Market Interaction and Stochastic Processes. P.P.R.S.A .,
Participation as a Variable in Economic Develop- Vol . 18, pp. 13-45 .
ment . Research Review (EDA), July 1968, pp . 1-6 . PARR, J. B . (1969). City Hierarchies and the Distribu-
BOAL, F. W . and JOHNSON, D . B. (1965) . The Rank- tion of City Size. J.R .S., Vol . 9, pp . 239-254 .
Size Curve : A Diagnostic Tool? Professional - (1970). Models of City Size in an Urban System .
Geographer, Vol . 17, pp. 21-23 . P.P.R .S.A., Vol. 25, pp . 221-253 . '
Bos, H . C. (1965) . Spatial Dispersion of Economic RASHEVSKY,N .(1947). Mathematical Theory of Human
Activity . North Holland . Relations. Bloomington : Principia Press .
CAMERON, G . C . (1970). Growth Areas, Growth REDCLIFFE-MAUD, LORD (1969) . Royal Commission
Centres and Regional Conversion . Scottish Journal on Local Government in England. Cmnd . 4040,
of Political Economy, Vol . 21, pp. 19-38 . H .M.S .O.
CLARK, C. (1945). The Economic Functions of a City RODwIN, L . (1970). Nations and Cities: A Comparison
in Relation to its Size. Econometrica, Vol. 13, pp . of Strategies for Urban Growth . Houghton-Mifflin .
97-113. ROTH EN BERG, J . (1970) . The Economics of Congestion
CURRY, L. (1967) . Central Places in the Random and Pollution : An Integrated View. American
Spatial Economy. Journal of Regional Science, Vol. Economic Review, 60 papers, pp . 114-121 .
7, pp . 217-238 . Royal Commission on Local Government in Greater
DUNCAN, O . D . (1956). The Optimum Size of Cities, London (1960) . Cmnd . 1164 .
in J. J . Spengler and O. D. Duncan (eds.) . Demo- STANBACK, T . M . Jr. and KNIGHT, R. V . (1970). The
graphic Analysis. Free Press. Metropolitan Economy: The Process of Employment
FRIEDMANN, J . (n.d.) . Economic Growth and Urban Expansion . Columbia U.P .
Structure in Venezuela. Guademos de la Sociedad STEWART, C . T . Jr. (1959) . The Size and Spacing of
Venezolana de Planificacion. Special Issue . Cities, in H. Mayer and C. F . Kohn . Readings in
GIRARD, A. and BASTIDE, H. (1960) . Les Problemes Urban Geography. Chicago U .P.
demographiques devant l'opinion . Population, Vol . STOLPER,W.F .(1955) . Spatial Order and the Economic
15 . Growth of Cities : A Comment on Eric Lampard's
GOLDNER, W . (1955). Spatial and Locational Aspects Paper. E.D .C.C., Vol . 3, pp. 137-146 .
of Metropolitan Labour Markets . American SOUTHEAST JOINT PLANNING TEAM (1970) . Strategic
Economic Review, Vol . 45 . Plant for the South East . H .M .S.O.
GUPTA, S . P and HUTTON, J . P . (1968) . Economies SOUTHEAST ECONOMIC PLANNING COUNCIL (1967) .
of Scale in Local Government Services . R.C. on The Strategy for the South East. H .M .S.O .
Local Government in England. Research Studies, THOMPSON, W . R. (1965a) . A Preface to Urban
No . 3 . Economics. Johns Hopkins .
HANSEN, N. M. (1970). A Growth Centre Strategy for - (1965b) . Urban Economic Growth and Develop-
the United States'. Review of Regional Studies, ment in a National System of Cities, pp . 431-490 in
Vol . 1, pp . 161-173 . P . M . Hauser and L. F. Schnore, The Study of
HIGGS, R . (1970). Central Place Theory and Regional Urbanisation. Wiley.
Us 9D
4

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at Afyon Kocatepe Universitesi on May 14, 2014


48 HARRY W. RICHARDSON

TIEBOUT, C . M . (1956) . A Pure Theory of Local Aspects of an Economic System . E.D .C.C., Vol. 3,
Expenditures . Journal of Political Economy, Vol . 64, pp . 147-195 .
pp . 416-424 . VON B6VENTER, E . (1969). Determinants of Migra-
TINBERGEN, J . (1961) . The Spatial Dispersion of tion into West German Cities, 1956-61, 1961-66.
Production : a Hypothesis. Schweizerishe Zeit- P.P.R.S.A ., Vol . 23, pp. 53-62.
schrift ffir Volkwirtschaft and Statistik, Vol . 97, pp. - (1970) . Optimal Spatial Structure and Regional
412-419. Development. Kyklos, Vol. 23, pp. 903-924.
T R EU N E R, P. (1971). An Infrastructure Cost Model for WEiss, H. K . (1961). The Distribution of Population
a System of Central Places . P.P.R.S.A ., Vol . 24, and an Application to a Servicing Problem . Opera-
pp . 85-101 . tions Research, Vol . 9, pp. 860-874.
VINING, R . (1955). A Description of Certain Spatial

Acknowledgments . I wish to thank my colleagues Murray Stewart and Joan Vipond for comments
on an earlier draft of this paper.

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at Afyon Kocatepe Universitesi on May 14, 2014

You might also like