You are on page 1of 12

Journal of Family Business Strategy 12 (2021) 100420

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Journal of Family Business Strategy


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jfbs

How do family businesses grow? Differences in growth patterns between


family and non-family firms
Ana M. Moreno-Menéndez *, José C. Casillas
Universidad de Sevilla, Facultad de Ciencias Económicas y Empresariales, Avda Ramón y Cajal, 1, 41018, Seville, Spain

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

Keywords: Family businesses vary considerably in size, ranging from small entrepreneurial ventures over medium-sized
Firm growth companies to large global corporations. However, we know little about how family businesses grow. Our
Family business research analyses differences in growth patterns between family and non-family businesses, considering two
Socioemotional wealth
dimensions of business growth: sales (performance) and employees (resources). Based on the Penrosean resource-
Resource-based view
Spain
based view of the firm and socioemotional wealth (SEW) perspective, we test and find —using a panel of 2000
Spanish manufacturing companies (2006–2014) —that family businesses tend to grow less than non-family
businesses in terms of sales but more in terms of employees. Our research casts doubt on the myth of low
growth in family businesses and shows that SEW should complement the Penrosean approach to explain the
growth of family businesses.

1. Introduction and Nieto, 2006; Sciascia, Mazzola, & Chirico, 2013) or diversification
(Gomez-Mejía et al., 2010). Prior research suggests that family busi­
Despite the importance of family businesses to most economies, the nesses usually grow slower than non-family businesses, although there
majority of these firms remains relatively small in size (Bjuggren, are important exceptions to this rule, like the case of hidden champions
Johansson, & Sjögren, 2011; Chang, Chrisman, Chua, & Kellermanns, (De Massis, Audretsch, Uhlaner, & Kammerlander, 2018; Debicki et al.,
2008; Shanker & Astrachan, 1996). While some family businesses are 2016; Duran, Kammerlander, van Essen, & Zellweger, 2016). This
able to grow into large publicly listed entities, such as S&P 500 firms apparent paradox suggests that the relevant question is not whether
(Anderson & Reeb, 2003), there is limited research that explains the family businesses are able to grow or not, compared to non-family firms,
differences in growth patterns between family and non-family busi­ but how they achieve this growth. The answer to this question remains
nesses, and the little research that does exist yields inconclusive results. inconclusive, as studies that investigated potential differences in growth
Nevertheless, growth is often considered a company’s primary goal and between family and non-family businesses have yielded mixed results.
frequently viewed as an indicator of its performance and success (Autio, One explanation for the inconclusive findings may be differences in
Sapienza, & Almeida, 2000; Davidsson, Steffens, & Fitzsimmons, 2009; the way growth was measured. Growth is a complex and heterogeneous
Moreno-Menéndez & Casillas, 2008), ultimately affecting both eco­ process (Achtenhagen, Naldi, & Melin, 2010) with various dimensions,
nomic and social welfare (Storey, 1994; Wiklund, Patzelt, & Shepherd, requiring particular attitudes, such as entrepreneurial orientation (Bet­
2009). tinelli, Sciascia, Randerson, & Fayolle, 2017; Casillas,
Although the topic of business growth has been researched exten­ Moreno-Menendez, & Barbero, 2011; Naldi & Davidsson, 2014) and
sively in recent decades from a variety of perspectives (Geyer, 2016; certain specific types of resources and capabilities (Penrose, 1959). We
Pendergast, 2011; Wiklund et al., 2009), only a few studies have looked therefore started from the idea that the unique combination of resources
at understanding family business growth in depth (Campopiano, Bru­ and capabilities of family businesses (Sirmon & Hitt, 2003) is respon­
mana, Minola, & Cassia, 2020; Stenholm, Pukkinen, & Heinonen, 2016). sible for how much family firms grow compared to their non-family
Some family business studies have used firm growth as a measure of counterparts. To investigate the growth process of family and
performance (Casillas and Moreno-Menendez, 2010) or have focused on non-family businesses empirically, we asked: Do family and non-family
a specific type of growth, such as international expansion (Fernández businesses grow in the same way? In an attempt to provide answers to

* Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: ammoreno@us.es (A.M. Moreno-Menéndez), casillas@us.es (J.C. Casillas).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfbs.2021.100420

Available online 9 March 2021


1877-8585/© 2021 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
A.M. Moreno-Menéndez and J.C. Casillas Journal of Family Business Strategy 12 (2021) 100420

this question, we investigated (a) the difference in growth between management literature. From an economics perspective, most research
family and non-family firms along two main dimensions of growth (sales has been developed around the validation of Gibrat (1931), which
and employees), and (b) the moderating role of initial firm age and size proposes that a firm’s growth is unconnected to its size. At the same
(just before the period of 2006–2014 considered) on the effect of family time, the relation between a firm’s age and growth has also been
control and involvement on firm growth. investigated extensively (Almus & Nerlinger, 2000; Bechetti & Trovato,
We proposed three pairs of hypotheses based on two theoretical 2002; Correa, Acosta, González, & Medina, 2003). Adopting a man­
approaches: the Penrosean theory of the growth of the firm (Penrose, agement approach, research has focused on the endogenous variables
1959; Sirmon & Hitt, 2003) and the socioemotional wealth (SEW) that promote or slow down firm growth. The resources/capabilities
perspective (Berrone, Cruz, & Gomez-Mejia, 2012; Gómez-Mejía, Hay­ view, based on the seminal work by Edith Penrose (1959), dominates
nes, Núñez-Nickel, Jacobson, & Moyano-Fuentes, 2007). While the this approach and explains business growth through the ability of
Penrosean approach explains that discrepancies in growth are based on managers to envision productive uses for firm resources (Penrose, 1959;
differences in availability of certain resources and capabilities, the focus Pettus, 2001). From these seminal approaches, the literature has grown
of the SEW perspective was to explain why family and non-family firms significantly in recent decades. Wiklund et al. (2009) identify five
not only have access to different types of resources and capabilities, but dominant perspectives in the small business growth literature, relating
also how they employ them in distinctive ways. The first two hypotheses to (1) entrepreneurial orientation, (2) the role of the firm’s environment,
refer to how much family businesses grow, compared to non-family (3) strategic fit, (4) resources, and (5) attitude to growth. A recent
firms. We proposed that family businesses will grow less than meta-analysis of the resource-based view and growth of the firm shows
non-family firms in terms of sales, but not in the number of employees. that versatile resources are associated with higher levels of growth,
The second pair of hypotheses introduces the effect of firm age as a whereas valuable, rare, inimitable, and non-substitutable (VRIN) re­
predictor of the family nature - firm growth relationship. Finally, the last sources are not (Nason & Wiklund, 2018).
two hypotheses consider the effect of firm size in the relationship be­ Recent global crises have stalled the increasing interest in growth, as
tween family nature and firm growth. researchers and practitioners have shifted their primary focus to survival
The empirical research is based on a sample comprising a panel of (Campopiano, de Massis, & Kotlar, 2019; Dolz, Iborra, & Safon, 2019), a
15,790 firm-year observations over a nine-year period (2006–2014), process even more intensive due to the recent Covid-19 pandemic (Kraus
corresponding to nearly 2000 medium and large Spanish manufacturing et al., 2020). However, the 2008 financial crisis has shown the greater
companies. The results indicate that family firms experience lower sales fragility of small businesses in the face of global economic collapse, and
growth but higher employment growth than non-family businesses. We various public (European Commission, 2010; Eurostat-OECD, 2007;
also found that both firm age and firm size moderate the family nature – OECD, 2000) and private institutions (NESTA: Anyadike-Danes, Bonner,
firm growth relationship, but in different ways depending on the Hart, & Mason, 2009) are demanding public policies that are oriented
dependent variable (sales versus employee growth). Our findings toward encouraging firm growth, especially in those countries with a
contribute to the literature on firm growth and family business, showing higher proportion of micro-enterprises. In Spain, for example, the
that family ownership and involvement have an impact on the way in average number of employees per firm is lower than 5 and more than 95
which firms develop and grow. First, our article further dispels the myth percent of firms have fewer than 10 employees (IEF: Casillas,
of low growth among family businesses, showing that there is no glass López-Fernández, Meroño, Pons, & Beiges, 2015).
ceiling for growth in family firms, but rather, a different pace of growth. Although family businesses dominate most economies (Bjuggren
Second, we contribute to the family business literature by regarding firm et al., 2011; Chang et al., 2008 in the USA; IFERA, 2003; Shanker &
age as a potential intensifying factor for the influence of SEW on busi­ Astrachan, 1996 in the USA), only a limited number of studies have
ness behaviour. Our results suggest that older family businesses are directly focused on the growth of family firms (Cirillo, Huybrechts,
more reluctant to grow than younger family businesses. Interestingly, Mussolino, Sciascia, & Voordeckers, 2020; Miroshnychenko, De Massis,
this effect is not present in the case of non-family businesses. This Miller, & Barontini, 2020). Using a large sample of French SMEs,
finding may be due to a more entrepreneurial behaviour in the family Hamelin (2013) argues that the lack of financial resources and the more
firms’ initial lifecycle stages. The final contribution is to the firm growth conservative attitude towards growth of family-owned SMEs explain the
literature. Our work focuses the attention on the role of non-economic lower growth rate of family firms and Seibold (2021) analyses the role of
goals, in particular the preservation of SEW, and long-term orientation generational transition on family business growth using a sample of 350
as potential dimensions for explaining differences in growth between big industrial family-owned businesses in Germany. Another line of
family and non-family businesses. In other words, our findings provide research analyses the relation between entrepreneurial orientation (EO)
another illustration that mainstream theories may require adaptation and firm growth in family businesses (Casillas and Moreno-Menendez,
when applied to family business (Astrachan, 2010). Specifically, the 2010; Casillas et al., 2011; Stenholm et al., 2016), finding that EO
Penrosean approach to the growth of the firm appears insufficient to positively influences growth only in second-generation family busi­
fully explain the growth of family businesses and would benefit from nesses. This relationship is moderated by environmental dynamism and
incorporating non-economic determinants of growth, such as those hostility. Overall, these studies propose that the unique characteristics of
proposed in the SEW perspective. family firms (Habbershon & Williams, 1999; Sirmon & Hitt, 2003) in­
The remainder of the article is structured as follows. In the next fluence the EO-growth relationship through their influence on the
section, we lay out the theoretical background of the paper, examine the different dimensions of EO, such as innovativeness, risk-taking, proac­
literature on growth theory and family business and propose our six tiveness, competitive aggressiveness, and autonomy (Covin & Slevin,
hypotheses. Next, we describe the methodology used to test the pro­ 1990; Lumpkin & Dess, 1996; Miller, 1983). Nevertheless, the results are
posed relationships, sample characteristics, measures and statistical far from conclusive. For example, the influence of family business
models. Then, we interpret the results, and finally conclude with a dis­ characteristics on innovation behaviour and its implications for perfor­
cussion of the main findings, implications, limitations and future mance and growth remain the subject of intense debate (Aparicio,
research suggestions. Iturralde, & Sanchez-Famoso, 2019; Arsubiaga, Maseda, Uribarri, &
Palma, 2019; Duran et al., 2016; Souder, Zaheer, Sapienza, & Ranucci,
2. Theory and hypotheses 2016). Cumulatively, these results suggest that the relationship between
family ownership and involvement is complex, and our current knowl­
2.1. Literature review edge is scant. As previous reviews of the growth literature indicate, the
influence of family ownership and management has been largely over­
Business growth has been a recurring topic in the economics and looked (Davidsson, Achtenhagen, & Naldi, 2010; Henrekson &

2
A.M. Moreno-Menéndez and J.C. Casillas Journal of Family Business Strategy 12 (2021) 100420

Johansson, 2010; Wiklund et al., 2009). Bridging this gap is important, managerial) show lower levels of external fungibility (low versatile re­
not only for academics interested in improving their understanding of sources), which inhibits sales growth.
the antecedents of firm growth, but also for policy makers, owners and Internal fungibility, according to Nason and Wiklund (2018), includes
managers, so that they may improve their firms’ growth promotion “uniquely developed and sticky assets with a broader range of uses” (p.
measures and practices. 37), such as branding and experiential learning. We do expect high
levels of internal fungible resources in family businesses, due to the
2.2. Hypothesis development importance of non-economic dimensions of the business to the owning
family. For example, from the SEW perspective, family businesses pro­
Two complementary theoretical approaches are useful to further vide their members with a strong identity, through well-established
investigate family business growth: the Penrosean theory of the growth brands (sometimes linked to the family name), reputation, or a family
of the firm and the socioemotional wealth perspective (SEW). Edith business image (Binz Astrachan, Botero, Astrachan, & Prügl, 2018;
Penrose (1959) argued that a firm’s growth is based on how managers Berrone et al., 2012; Binz, Hair, Pieper, & Baldauf, 2013; Elsbach &
search new uses for available resources, with managerial resources Pieper, 2019). Other internal fungible resources are related to mana­
being particularly relevant. Resources lie at the heart of the firm growth gerial capabilities, resulting from the close overlap of family members,
literature, as research referring to Penrose’s seminal book illustrates board of directors and TMT. Family directors and managers accumulate
(Davidsson et al., 2009; Naldi & Davidsson, 2014; Wernerfelt, 1984; considerable experiential knowledge, usually tacit knowledge (Leap­
Wiklund et al., 2009). However, as specified above, not all types of re­ trott, 2005) of the firm and the industry, that can be used to expand the
sources necessarily have the same effect on growth. Nason and Wiklund business and its growth (Nason & Wiklund, 2018). We suggest that a
(2018) found that only versatile resources have a significant and positive potential lack of some versatile resources, such as managerial or finan­
influence on firm growth. At the same time, one must acknowledge that cial resources, can be compensated for by other managerial capabilities
firm growth is a multi-dimensional and multi-faceted construct. The that make it easier to put decisions into practice. For example, family
common understanding of growth typically refers to sales versus em­ firms have less formalised structures (Leaptrott, 2005), with more
ployees (Achtenhagen et al., 2010). While sales growth is often a mea­ flexible channels of communication, better circulation of information
sure of performance (output), growth in the number of employees is a and more centralised decision-making (Gomez-Mejía, Cruz, Berrone,
measure of the evolution of a resource (input) that can be used to attain and De Castro, 2012; Kotey & Folker, 2007). Family businesses are less
sales growth or other organizational goals. We propose that family likely to use formal systems (Harris & Reid, 2008), enabling more agile
businesses demonstrate a different orientation towards these two di­ behaviour and growth (Casillas and Moreno-Menendez, 2010).
mensions of growth, primarily because of socioemotional wealth (SEW). In order to reconcile these two contradictory effects (low external
We therefore consider that the SEW perspective can complement the fungibility and high internal fungibility of family businesses resources),
Penrosean approach to explain the differences in growth between family the SEW perspective offers a potential explanation of how family and
and non-family firms. We propose that the orientation towards SEW and non-family firms use their resources differently to achieve growth. The
the preservation of the family business affect the versatility of the SEW perspective argues that family businesses prioritise SEW over
available resources and capabilities in terms of internal and external economic utilities (Gómez-Mejía et al., 2007). The SEW construct is
fungibility (Nason & Wiklund, 2018). Moreover, SEW also affects the manifested in different forms, such as control exercise in family busi­
way in which family firms use their resources and capabilities in order to nesses, family values development, family dynasty evolution, social
grow. More specifically, regarding sales growth, family and non-family capital, or family altruism (Cleary, Quinn, & Moreno, 2019). SEW has
firms experience different effects of SEW on the use of (non)versatile sociological (Kushins & Behounek, 2020) and psychological implica­
resources for growth. Following the differentiation of the internal and tions (Akhmedova, Cavallotti, Marimon, & Campopiano, 2019), and is
external fungibility of resources (as a source of versatility), we propose considered as a multi-dimensional construct (Berrone et al., 2012;
that the difference in growth between family and non-family firms is due Cleary et al., 2019; Debicki, Kellermanns, Chrisman, Pearson, &
to the lower external fungibility and higher internal fungibility of family Spencer, 2016). Most researchers agree that SEW creates a preference in
firms’ resources and capabilities. family firms to take conservative decisions for the sake of their longevity
External fungibility refers to resources with little specificity that are (Souder et al., 2016), avoiding decisions that might threaten the family’s
tradable between firms. Some examples of fungible resources are cash or control and values (Gómez-Mejía, Makri, & Larraza-Kintana, 2010;
generic human resources. In order to preserve family control, family Miller, Le Breton-Miller, & Lester, 2010). In this view, family businesses
businesses are reluctant to seek external capital from capital markets, only take proactive actions to preserve SEW when it is threatened – the
particularly if this requires the incorporation of new partners or loss aversion attitude (Bettinelli et al., 2017; Chrisman & Patel, 2012).
ownership sharing (Hamelin, 2013). As a result, they have fewer ver­ Closely related to these arguments, prior research has assigned a
satile resources such as cash (Nason & Wiklund, 2018). Family firms’ long-term orientation (LTO) to family firms (Lumpkin & Brigham, 2011;
preference for internal financing directly affects their growth capacity in Lumpkin, Brigham, & Moss, 2010). According to this perspective, the
the short term (Carpenter & Petersen, 2002; Cull, Davis, Lamoreaux, & objective of these firms is to prioritise long-term survival over short-term
Rosenthal, 2006). Financial resources are a clear example of versatile profit (Kotlar & De Massis, 2013). As a result of the LTO perspective
resources (Brush et al., 2000) and so we would expect lower levels of (compared to the shorter-term orientation – STO – of non-family firms),
external fungible (financial) resources in family businesses compared to family owners tend to provide patient capital for potential investments
non-family firms. (Pieper, Williams, Manley, & Matthews, 2020; Sirmon & Hitt, 2003).
Regarding managerial resources, family businesses are also reluctant In summary, we argue that family businesses’ growth patterns in
to lose their control of strategic decision-making, as reflected in their terms of sales are expected to be distinct from those of non-family
desire to keep boards and top management teams in the hands of family businesses due to the different levels of specific versatile resources and
members (Basco, 2014; Chrisman, Chua, & Pearson, 2012; Dyer, 1989). different time orientations (family businesses tending toward long-term
Previous literature assumes that family businesses have less access to the orientation and non-family businesses more toward short-term orien­
best human and managerial capabilities (Barbero, Casillas, & Feldman, tation), derived from SEW. We propose that family firms will be more
2012), accompanied by a reluctance to accept non-family expertise reluctant to increase their commercial activities over a relatively short
(Arregle, Duran, Hitt, & van Essen, 2016). Consequently, family man­ time, because of the low level of external fungible resources paired with
agers may act as external non-fungible resources, with a narrow scope of their risk aversion for a potential loss of SEW. Family firms that pursue
knowledge that is not easily transferable to other businesses (Nason & growth strategies will increase their growth slowly in the short term, and
Wiklund, 2018). In summary, family business resources (financial and instead search for growth opportunities in the long term (Bjuggren,

3
A.M. Moreno-Menéndez and J.C. Casillas Journal of Family Business Strategy 12 (2021) 100420

Daunfeldt, & Johansson, 2013). Family businesses’ internal fungible suffer from ‘liabilities of newness’ (Stinchcombe, 1965). Young firms
resources, derived from firm-specific assets (e.g., brands, family man­ tend to use their resource slack less efficiently than older firms, which
agers, share values) are useful for growth, but take longer to achieve the affects the perceptions and expectations relating to the firm’s best per­
desired results (Nason and Wiklund, 2018). In other words, the sales of formance (Correa et al., 2003; Dunne & Hugues, 1994; Mor­
family businesses will grow slower in the short term, compared to the eno-Menéndez & Casillas, 2007; Shafman, Wolf, Chase, & Tansik, 1988).
sales of non-family firms. As a result, overall, we expect that family Second, the entrepreneurship literature generally proposes a negative
businesses will grow more slowly than their non-family counterparts in relationship between age and the entrepreneurial orientation of the firm
order to avoid high risks to SEW. This leads us to the following (Lumpkin, 1998; Lumpkin & Dess, 1996) and considers younger firms to
hypothesis: be more innovative, proactive and risk-orientated (Miller, 2003; Shane
& Venkataraman, 2000). This is due to the learning advantage of
Hypothesis 1a. Within a specific time period, family businesses will
newness (Autio et al., 2000) and the greater organisational agility
grow less than non-family businesses in terms of sales.
ascribed to younger firms (Baumol, 2004; Buckley & Prashantham,
Family businesses tend to have a different approach to dealing with 2016; Kuemmerle, 2006).
employees, due to the role of SEW. As Miller, Le Breton-Miller and In a family business, firm age can be related to the generational
Scholnick (2008, p. 56) propose, family-owned businesses will display involvement of the family. This has a bearing on the development of the
greater stewardship over their community of employees. The SEW firm’s resources and capabilities and affects the way in which SEW in­
perspective argues that there is a stronger connection between family fluences decision-making processes. At the founder stage, family busi­
members and the firm’s employees. One dimension of SEW (Berrone nesses often demonstrate entrepreneurial behaviour, given that most
et al., 2012) suggests that non-family employees are treated as part of founders are per se entrepreneurs (Bettinelli et al., 2017). Only when
the family, promoting an integrative culture and commitment to the family firms evolve, pass through the generations, and develop a more
firm (Miller & Le Breton-Miller, 2005), and creating binding social ties. complex family business system, specific characteristics such as ‘fami­
This close connection between family owners and non-family employees liness’ (Habbershon & Williams, 1999), or socioemotional wealth
develops an orientation towards personnel retention (Miller et al., (Gómez-Mejía et al., 2007) do emerge and grow. Previous research ar­
2008), leading to higher levels of job creation than in non-family gues that while first-generation family businesses are expected to have a
businesses. ‘leadership imperative’ that drives entrepreneurship (Miller, 1983),
According to the SEW perspective, family businesses consider their second-generation family firms tend to be more externally oriented,
employees as long-term versatile (internal fungible) resources and not as following an ‘environmental-structural imperative’ (Cruz & Nordqvist,
mere instruments to achieve short-term performance. In this sense, 2007). In fact, as Zellweger and Sieger (2012) state, the levels of
family businesses will be less focused on immediate increases in pro­ entrepreneurial spirit and innovativeness usually fluctuate over time,
ductivity and be more oriented towards building a long-term community with occasional revolutionary phases; a succession phase acting as a
of interests (Miller et al., 2008). This will especially be the case when the window of opportunity for renewing the family’s involvement (Arsu­
company has a positive performance and there is no risk to survival biaga et al., 2019; Hauck, Suess-Reyes, Beck, Prügl, & Frank, 2016b).
(Casillas, Moreno-Menendez, Barbero, & Clinton, 2019). Prior research Conversely, there is no consensus about how SEW evolves over time
also suggests that compared to their non-family cousins, family busi­ (Chua, Chrisman, & De Massis, 2015; Hasenzagl, Hatak, & Frank, 2018;
nesses often show flatter structures, more informal management models Le Breton-Miller & Miller, 2013; Miller & Le Breton-Miller, 2014;
and less professionalization (Fernández and Nieto, 2006; Stewart & Hitt, Schulze & Kellermanns, 2015; Sciascia et al., 2014). On the one hand,
2012). Family businesses may therefore be positively inclined towards some prior research argues that SEW is strongest in firms managed by
investing in the hiring of new employees with general capabilities to first-generation family members and decreases as the firm evolves
develop a broader community, reinforcing the stock of internal fungible (Gomez-Mejia et al., 2007; Strike, Berrone, Sapp, & Congiu, 2015).
resources (Nason & Wiklund, 2018). In line with this argument, we Contradictory arguments emerge when other FIBER dimensions of SEW
propose that family businesses will increase their number of employees are looked at more closely (Berrone et al., 2012). For example, binding
in the short term as a resource to achieve long-term sales growth. In social ties, the emotional attachment of family members, and the
relation to the growth in employees, therefore, we propose the following renewal of family bonds to the firm through dynastic succession tend to
hypothesis: become stronger as family firms pass through subsequent generations
(Arregle, Batjargal, & Hitt, 2015; Gómez-Mejía et al., 2007). Accord­
Hypothesis 1b. Within a specific time period, family businesses will
ingly, the growth and development of SEW in family businesses, their
grow more than non-family businesses in terms of employees.
risk aversion and the ‘loss mode’ of these firms will be higher in older
These general hypotheses are affected by demographic firm charac­ family businesses. In these cases, more family members are involved and
teristics, such as previous firm size and age of the firm (Wiklund et al., a legacy has been generated over time, compared to younger firms,
2009). As the literature has demonstrated, most SMEs do not grow over which are more closely linked to the founder, and whose behaviour
time and only a small proportion of companies achieve high-growth resembles that of an entrepreneur.
status (Birch, 1987; Henrekson & Johansson, 2010; Storey, 1994). We In terms of resources, we expect that, as time goes by, external
will therefore treat firm size and firm age as independent dimensions, fungible resources will decrease more intensively in family businesses,
and propose different effects on sales/employee growth than previous due to the avoidance of integrated external (financial and managerial)
papers that studied variables such as profitability (Yazdanfar, 2013), resources. Older family firms have more wealth to lose from a risky
strategic decisions (Sarangee & Echambadi, 2014) or intra- and inter­ decision than entrepreneurial family firms, where a legacy has not yet
cultural trust (Jiang, Chua, Kotabe, & Murrat, 2011). been generated, and there are fewer family members depending on the
business. Older family businesses may protect their SEW through less
2.3. The moderating role of firm age development of more versatile resources, such as external financial re­
sources (cash) or external managers/directors, inhibiting sales growth.
There is general agreement that younger firms experience higher For all these reasons, we propose the following hypothesis:
growth than older ones (Henrekson & Johansson, 2010) as most prior
Hypothesis 2a. Firm age will moderate the negative effect of the
research has found a negative relationship between firm age and firm
family nature of the firm on sales growth, in such a way that the negative
growth (Wiklund et al., 2009). This finding has been explained by two
relationship between this characteristic and sales growth will be more
theories. First, the organisational learning perspective (Jovanovic,
intense in older businesses than in younger ones.
1982) argues that young firms tend to be resource-constrained and

4
A.M. Moreno-Menéndez and J.C. Casillas Journal of Family Business Strategy 12 (2021) 100420

When it comes to the relationship between family nature of firms and growth-oriented family firms show a more entrepreneurial behaviour
employee growth, we propose a negative moderating effect of firm age than non-family businesses (Nordqvist & Melin, 2010). At the same
for two different reasons. As firms increase their experiences, they can time, larger family firms are also able to gradually incorporate external
better adjust their correct size to the real activity of the business. fungible resources, such as professional managers and certain financial
Younger family businesses do not have enough information to interpret resources (bank loans, greater self-financing, incorporation of small
their past results, commonly suffering from interpretation problems capital partners, etc.), promoting sales growth. These highly fungible
(Zajac & Bazerman, 1991). As family firms age and subsequent gener­ resources, together with the flexible structure of family businesses
ations succeed the founder, they are increasingly able to adjust the mentioned above, increase the potential for sales growth as the firms
number of employees to match their real needs, as a result of their increase in size. For this reason, we propose the following hypothesis:
accumulated experience. Additionally, the second and following gen­
Hypothesis 3a. Firm size will moderate the negative effect of the
erations change their way to preserve SEW (Berrone et al., 2012; Zell­
family nature of the firm on sales growth, in such a way that the negative
weger & Dehlen, 2012). After the founder generation, family managers
relationship between this characteristic and sales growth will be less
from further generations will have fewer emotional ties to employees,
intense in larger businesses than in smaller ones.
promoting professionalization. For this reason, as family firms get older,
passing from generation to generation, we expect a lower expansion of Finally, in relation to employment growth, we expect larger family
the number of workers in the company. We therefore propose: businesses to be more selective in their hiring of personnel as their
professionalism increases. Greater size used to be associated with a more
Hypothesis 2b. Firm age will moderate the positive effect of the
professional structure (task divisions, non-family management, less
family nature of the firm on employee growth, in such a way that the
nepotism, more formal routines, etc.), allowing businesses to be more
positive relationship between this characteristic and employee growth
productive and efficient (Dekker, Lybaert, Stejvers, & Depaire, 2013). In
will be less intense in older businesses than in younger ones.
this context, as family firms grow, their decisions tend to be more
comparable to non-family firms (Stewart & Hitt, 2012), decreasing the
2.4. Firm size, growth and family firms intensity of the positive effect of the family nature of the firm on
employment growth. This leads us to our final hypothesis:
Past research offers inconclusive findings on the basic assumption of
Hypothesis 3b. Firm size will moderate the positive effect of the
Gibrat (1931), showing a positive, neutral and negative relationship
family nature of the firm on employee growth, in such a way that the
between size and growth (Bechetti & Trovato, 2002; Correa et al., 2003;
positive relationship between this characteristic and employee growth
Dunne & Hugues, 1994; Evans, 1987; Henrekson & Johansson, 2010;
will be less intense in larger businesses than in smaller ones.
Knudsen, Levinthal, & Winter, 2017; Moreno-Menéndez & Casillas,
2007; Wiklund et al., 2009). The Penrosean perspective explains the
3. Methodology
higher growth rates of smaller firms, arguing that they seek a more
efficient use of existing idle resources and capabilities (Penrose, 1959).
3.1. Sample
Small businesses work with highly versatile resources; they are partic­
ularly reluctant to incorporate external (e.g., financial or managerial)
The data source of our study is the Spanish Government’s Survey of
resources, allowing the owners and managers to develop highly diver­
Business Strategies (SBS). This is a firm-level database and a represen­
sified skill sets (Nason & Wiklund, 2018). We therefore argue that, in
tative sample of Spanish manufacturing firms with more than 10 em­
terms of internal fungibility, small family firms are particularly rich in
ployees. The validity of the sample was achieved by adopting a
highly versatile resources.
combination of exhaustive criteria and random sampling. Two groups
The way that family businesses manage their resources differs from
were established by the database creators: In the first group, all firms
non-family firms. Family firm management tends to be based on high
with over 200 employees were invited to participate, while the second
levels of internal fungible resources and capabilities, using informal
group consisted of firms with 10–200 employees, selected through
procedures and more centralised decision-making processes (Daily &
stratified sampling. This survey has been used in prior studies, since it
Dollinger, 1992). Family businesses are managed based on tacit
encompasses various aspects of Spanish firms’ strategic behaviour and
knowledge (Leaptrott, 2005), it is clearer within family firms who the
international activities (Fernández and Nieto, 2006; Golovko & Valen­
strategic decision-makers are, and formal routines are less developed
tini, 2011). Given the availability of some of the variables in our
(Fernández and Nieto, 2006). More informal management allows in­
research (such as family versus non-family firms), information was taken
formation to flow rapidly, improving communication and coordination
from the 2006–2014 period. The average number of firms per year was
activities and making the implementation of strategies easier. Family
1973 (ranging from 1330 in 2014 to 2023 in 2006), with a total of 15,
businesses usually show a more entrepreneurial management style
790 firm-year observations.
across generations (Jaskiewicz, Combs, & Rau, 2015). Other research
also suggests that entrepreneurship is supported by family members’
sense of unity with the firm (Eddleston, Kellermanns, & Zellweger, 3.2. Variables
2012), which can be carried across generations. Accordingly, some re­
searchers have considered imprinting theory to explain why some family Dependent variables: Due to the potentially spurious determinants of a
businesses remain entrepreneurial across multiple generations (Keller­ single-year measure of growth (e.g., accounting accrual, yearly contex­
manns, Eddleston, Barnett, & Pearson, 2008). As Jaskiewicz et al. state tual factors, among others), we measured growth over three-year pe­
(2015, p. 32), “Conditions and features that supported earlier generations’ riods, instead of annual growth rates, susceptible to greater variability
entrepreneurship, or lack thereof, might become imprinted on firms and from spurious causes. In doing so, we attempt to measure the growth
support continuous entrepreneurship”. trend of the firms, reducing contingent variability. Three years is also
Family businesses work with fewer –albeit very versatile (internally the time span used to identify high-growth or gazelle firms (Any­
fungible)– resources than non-family SMEs, and develop less bureau­ adike-Danes et al., 2009; Daunfeldt, Johansson, & Halvarson, 2015;
cracy, clearer leadership and greater owner involvement. Besides, the OECD, 2000). However, we also measured growth at years 1 and 2 to
founder’s entrepreneurship imprints its culture (Schein, 1983). More­ evaluate the robustness of our results. We used two measures for the
over, these characteristics facilitate organisational agility (Hatum & continuous variable firm growth: (a) sales growth: the percentage of sales
Pettigrew, 2004), which in turn can foster growth strategies for those growth over a three-year period (salesn+3 – salesn / salesn); and (b)
family firms that make the deliberate choice to grow. As a result, employee growth: the percentage growth in the number of employees

5
A.M. Moreno-Menéndez and J.C. Casillas Journal of Family Business Strategy 12 (2021) 100420

(full-time) over a three-year period (employeesn+3 – employeesn / problems with heteroscedasticity.


employeesn). Given the continuous nature of firm growth, heteroscedasticity
Independent variable: Family firm status. The survey asked the firm problems can be resolved by using the generalised method of moments
whether a family group is actively involved in the company, as con­ (GMM) to control for the potential risk of endogeneity, which is
trolling owner or participating in management. These are the two main appropriate for cases with endogenous variables and potential reverse
characteristics used to identify a family business in the academic liter­ causality (Jean, Deng, Kim, & Yuan, 2015; Yi, Wang, & Kafouros, 2013).
ature (Astrachan & Shanker, 2003; Boellis, Mariotti, Minichilli, & Pis­ Referring to the earlier work by Arellano and Bover (1995), Blundell and
citello, 2016; Fernández and Nieto, 2006). Similar to previous studies Bond (1998) used additional moment restrictions to improve the per­
(Fernández and Nieto, 2006; Nieto, Santamaría, & Fernández, 2015), we formance of the Arellano and Bond GMM estimator when there is a low
used a binary variable, where the value ‘1’ indicates a family firm and ‘0’ number of time series observations, and when there is only a few years’
a non-family firm. Applying this distinction, there were 9240 (58.52 per worth of data (xtdpdsys command). The Sargan tests (Blundell & Bond,
cent) non-family business observations and 6550 (41.48 per cent) family 1998) confirmed the validity of the instruments. We considered two
business observations in the overall sample. This variable was captured possible dependent variables: sales growth and growth in the number of
each year (from 2006 to 2014), and is not a time-invariant variable, employees.
since some companies may cease trading or become a family business as
a result of processes such mergers, acquisitions/sales, or changes in 4. Results
ownership structure, corporate government, etc.
Moderator variables: (1) Firm age was measured by the logarithm of Table 1 describes the variables for the whole sample and using the
the the difference between previous to current year and founding year same variables, with the sample split into two groups: family and non-
(Log Age i), which was previously standardised in order to be included family businesses. In this table, we did not convert any of the vari­
as a moderator variable (Thornhill & Amit, 2003; Wilson, Wright, & ables into logarithm form, in order to allow a clear understanding of the
Scholes, 2013); and (2) Firm size was measured through the number of characteristics of the firms. The firms have an average of over 250 em­
employees in the year before the growth (Revilla, Pérez-Luño, & Nieto, ployees, and family firms are relatively smaller than non-family firms
2016; Zahra, 2010), measured by the dependent variable – firm growth. (157 versus 322 employees). Consequently, this is not a study of SMEs,
In order to satisfy the normality condition for regression analysis, we but of medium and large manufacturing family businesses. Both sub-
used this number as the logarithm (Log Size i). samples are homogeneous with regard to firm age, with an average of
Control variables: We controlled for leverage, in the form of the ratio of 29 years. Sales growth over the 2006–2014 period reached nearly 30
long-term debt to total assets (Brannon, Wiklund, & Haynie, 2013; Lim, percent, with a considerable difference between family and non-family
Celly, Morse, & Rowe, 2013) and idle resources capacity, measured as the businesses (6 percent versus 44 percent), but the data also revealed a
“percentage of the firm’s manufacturing capacity that is not currently negative growth in the number of employees (-2.7 % — -2.2 % in family
being used”1 in each of the years analysed. Idle resources are key de­ businesses versus -3.0 % in non-family businesses). Table 1 also provides
terminants of growth according to the resourced-based view of the firm the correlation matrix, using the converted version of the variables
(Penrose, 1959). It has been also considered in previous research about (standardised logarithm for size and age).
firm growth (Bradley, Wiklund, & Shepherd, 2011). This information Table 2 shows the regression models. Models 1 and 2 show the
was explicitly requested from the companies in the survey question. regression results of the GMM, using sales growth (Model 1) and
Furthermore, in order to evaluate industry and time (years) effects and employee growth (Model 2) as dependent variables. The first columns
considering that we are using panel data, depending on the final sta­ (Models 1a and 2a) form the baseline, including only firm age, firm size
tistical model used, time-invariant variables should be eliminated, and family as explanatory variables. The next models incorporate the
especially for fixed-effects estimations. Therefore, we did not use sec­ interaction effect of firm age (Models 1b and 2b) and size (Models 1c and
tor/year dummies, given that firms typically do not change sector over 2c) separately, while in the final model (Models 1d and 2d) the joint
time. However, we used an alternative method to consider industry and interaction effect of both moderators with family business was added.
year effects: We introduced the mean values of the dependent variable After several estimations, the best model estimated the two-step esti­
for each sector, as an explanatory variable, that is, the average growth of mator and two lags of the dependent variable. The Cumby-Huizinga test
the industry sector in the focal year –industry growth– (Cassiman & suggested that potential autocorrelation is only present with a one-year
Veugelers, 2002; Surroca, Tribo, & Waddock, 2010). lag, but not with two lags. Variance inflation factors were all under 2.63,
well below the threshold level of 10 (Hair, Anderson, Tatham, & Black,
3.3. Statistical modelling 1995) and even below the more restrictive value of 5 (Ringle, Wende, &
Becker, 2015), suggesting that the estimated models did not suffer from
We calculated several regression models to ensure rigorous testing of problems of multicollinearity. The eight models were significant, with
the statistical analysis of the evolution of sales and employment. Given the Wald Chi-squared statistic of both models demonstrating statistical
the nature of the data, we adopted a panel data approach, based on significance (p-value<0.001).
dynamic models that use lagged dependent variables as explanatory Hypotheses 1a and 1b proposed a negative influence of family
variables (Franco, 2013; Li, Li, & Tsay, 2012). The first test carried out business status on sales growth and a positive relationship with
was the Breusch-Pagan Lagrange Multiplier, to decide between a employee growth. Considering the final models, Table 2 shows a nega­
random effects model and a pooled least squares regression. We also tive effect of the family nature of the business on sales growth (Model
carried out an F-test, which compared the fixed effects model with the 1d: β = -0.305; p-value<0.005), and presents a positive effect on
pooled least squares regression. Results of these two tests showed that employment growth (Model 2d: β = 0.105; p-value<0.005). Interme­
the pooled least squares regression was inefficient, given the possible diate models were consistent with these results. Hypothesis 2 refers to
unobserved heterogeneity associated with each firm. Based on the pre­ the moderator effect of firm age on the family-growth relationship. Our
vious tests, a panel model was selected as the most appropriate. The next results show a negative interaction effect when the dependent variable is
step therefore was to choose between a fixed effects model and a random sales growth (Model 1d: β = -0.131; p-value < 0.05), and we find the
effects model. The Hausman test recommended the use of the random same negative effect when growth is ascribed to employees (Model 2d: β
effects model and the Pagan-Hall test indicated that there were some = -0.075; p-value<0.001). Finally, Hypothesis 3 considered that firm
size moderates the effect of the family nature of the firm on growth. In
this case, the results showed a positive coefficient when the dependent
1
A single question in the survey used the exact phrase in quotation marks. variable is sales growth (Model 1d: β = 0.222; p-value<0.01), while it

6
A.M. Moreno-Menéndez and J.C. Casillas Journal of Family Business Strategy 12 (2021) 100420

Table 1
Descriptors and Correlation Matrix.
Mean s.d. Family Non-family 1 2 3 4 5 6 7

1. Sales growth 0.295 18.96 0.061 0.447 1.0000


2. Employee growth − 0.027 0.450 − 0.022 − 0.030 0.0233 1.0000
3. Family 0.396 0.489 – – − 0.0100 0.0090 1.0000
4. Idle capacity 0.152 0.203 0.139 0.161 0.0321 0.0293 − 0.0126 1.0000
5. Leverage 0.235 6.201 0.219 0.339 0.0123 0.0227 -0.2183 0.0360 1.0000
6. Size 257.3 816.3 157.2 322.2 0.0075 ¡0.0392 ¡0.1300 0.0155 0.1841 1.0000
7. Age 28.96 20.24 29.47 28.63 − 0.0065 ¡0.0324 0.0467 0.0329 0.2934 0.3971 1.0000

Italic, p-value>0.01; Bold. P-value<0.001.

Table 2
Regression Models.
Dependent variable: Sales Growth (GMM) 3 year Dependent variable: Employees Growth (GMM) 3 year

Model 1a Model 1b Model 1c Model 1d Model 2a Model 2b Model 2c Model 2d

Intercept − 0.557*** − 0.537*** − 0.558*** − 0.542*** 0.764*** 0.760*** 0.757*** 0.757***


(0.148) (0.148) (0.152) (0.150) (0.095) (0.095) (0.097) (0.097)
Leverage 0.104+ 0.104+ 0.105+ 0.104 − 0.050*** − 0.050*** − 0.050*** − 0.050***
(0.059) (0.059) (0.059) (0.059) (0.017) (0.017) (0.017) (0.017)
Idle resources 0.003*** 0.003*** 0.003*** 0.003*** 0.004 0.004 0.003 0.003
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Industry growth 0.087** 0.084** 0.085** 0.087** 0.088** 0.087** 0.090** 0.090**
(0.052) (0.050) (0.056) (0.063) (0.074) (0.073) (0.079) (0.079)
1-Lag dep. variable 0.224*** 0.224*** 0.223*** 0.223*** 0.661*** 0.661*** 0.661*** 0.661***
(0.017) (0.017) (0.017) (0.017) (0.031) (0.031) (0.031) (0.031)
2-Lags dep. variable. − 0.133*** − 0.134*** − 0.134*** − 0.113*** − 0.083*** − 0.083*** − 0.085*** − 0.085***
(0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.018) (0.018) (0.018) (0.018)
LnAge 0.489** 0.434** 0.492** 0.436* − 0.854*** − 0.838*** − 0.843*** − 0.843***
(0.175) (0.176) (0.178) (0.173) (0.119) (0.120) (0.120) (0.120)
LnSize 0.836*** 0.832*** 0.836*** 0.840*** − 0.990*** − 0.991*** − 0.992*** − 0.992***
(0.224) (0.225) (0.233) (0.232) (0.140) (0.140) (0.145) (0.145)
Family − 0.050* − 0.351* − 0.076** − 0.305** 0.012* 0.136** 0.105** 0.105**
(0.026) (0.157) (0.114) (0.176) (0.015) (0.113) (0.071) (0.071)
Age x family − 0.119* − 0.131* − 0.044** − 0.075***
(0.048) (0.052) (0.024) (0.097)
Size x family 0.179* 0.222* − 0.043** − 0.070***
(0.128) (0.129) (0.017) (0.017)
# Observations 9,466 9,466 9,494 6,702 6,702 6,702 6,702 6,702
# Groups 1,941 1,941 1,941 1,687 1,687 1,687 1,687 1,687
Wald Chi (p-value) 402,2*** 410,7*** 410,8*** 409,9*** 641,3*** 641,4 *** 679,1*** 681,6***

+ p-value<0.05; * p-value<0.01; ** p-value<0.005; *** p-value<0.001.

becomes negative when the endogenous variable is growth in the businesses possess different types of resources (Sirmon & Hitt, 2003)
number of employees (Model 2d: β = -0.070; p-value<0.001). –with different levels of versatility (internal and external fungibility
In order to test the robustness of these results, we repeated the —Nason & Wiklund, 2018)– that have potential positive and negative
analysis, measuring growth for 2-year periods and single-year intervals. effects on the different dimensions of firm growth in terms of sales and
The final results are presented in Table 3. Model 3a (1-year) and 3b (2- employees (Discua, Howorth, & Hamilton, 2013; Naldi, Nordqvist,
year) refer to sales growth as dependent variables and Models 3c (1- Sjöberg, & Wiklund, 2007; Stenholm et al., 2016).
year) and 3d (2-year) represent the results for the growth in employment In the first two hypotheses, we proposed that family firms display
as an explained variable. After several estimations, for models with 1- lower growth than non-family firms in terms of sales (H1a), and the
year growth as the dependent variable, the models only included a opposite (a positive effect) when growth is measured in terms of em­
one-year lag for growth as an explanatory variable. The results did not ployees, proposing a positive effect of the family nature of the firm and
differ significantly from the main results shown in Table 2. We only growth in the number of employees (H1b). The empirical results did
found differences in the level of significance of some coefficients, but confirm both hypotheses, with a negative significant coefficient in
none of the significant relationships cease to be so in the new models Model 1d (Table 2) and a positive significant coefficient in Model 2d
(Table 3). (Table 2). These findings suggest that, in a similar time period, family
firms seem to grow less than non-family firms in term of sales (output/
5. Discussion performance), but increase their number of employees (input/resources)
more than non-family firms. These apparently contradictory results may
Our paper sought to explore family business growth. Based on SEW be explained through the long-term orientation of family businesses
and Penrosean perspectives of growth, we proposed that the growth (Lumpkin & Brigham, 2011). These businesses seem to be more involved
pattern among family firms is different from the one in non-family firms. in developing internal resources (such as a long-term investments),
One potential explanation for these differences may be due to the fact although the effect on their performance may be deferred over time.
that family businesses tend to prioritise long-term non-economic goals This result is consistent with the SEW approach that posits the desire of
and avoid potential risks to SEW (Berrone et al., 2012; Gómez-Mejía family businesses to build an internal community of interests, thereby
et al., 2007; Vazquez & Rocha, 2018). At the same time, from a Penro­ integrating non-family employees.
sean perspective of growth, previous literature suggests that family Hypothesis 2 pertained to the age of family/non-family firms and

7
A.M. Moreno-Menéndez and J.C. Casillas Journal of Family Business Strategy 12 (2021) 100420

Table 3
Robustness tests.
1 year 2 year 1 year 2 year
Sales Sales Employees Employees
Model 3a Model 3b Model 3a Model 3b

Intercept − 0.575*** − 0.609*** 0.535*** 0.448***


(0.079) (0.094) (0.488) (0.082)
Leverage − 0.045+ 0.034 − 0.064*** − 0.018
(0.022) (0.041) (0.012) (0.022)
Idle resources 0.003*** 0.005*** 0.005+ 0.000*
(0.000) (0.000) (0.005) (0.000)
Industry growth 0.079** 0.073** 0.051** 0.067**
(0.068) (0.053) (0.040) (0.054)
1-Lag dep. variable 0.022** 0.292*** − 0.049*** 0.499***
(0.007) (0.012) (0.012) (0.025)
2-Lags dep. variable. − 0.324*** − 0.359***
(0.016) (0.027)
LnAge 0.446*** 0.610*** − 0.380*** − 0.447***
(0.100) (0.136) (0.066) (0.096)
LnSize 0.939*** 0.845*** − 0.968*** − 0.667***
(0.126) (0.152) (0.075) (0.125)
Family − 0.138* − 0.176** 0.053* 0.111**
(0.115) (0.186) (0.084) (0.108)
Age x family − 0.011* − 0.006* − 0.022+ − 0.049*
(0.034) (0.053) (0.026) (0.029)
Size x family − 0.045* − 0.043* − 0.032** − 0.073*
(0.022) (0.027) (0.011) (0.015)
# Observations 10,960 7,662 10,960 7,662
# Groups 2,264 1,884 2,264 1,884
Wald Chi (p-value) 524,9*** 1154,0*** 582,3*** 816,9***

firm growth in terms of sales (H2a) and employees (H2b). In relation to


sales growth, we proposed that the negative effect of the family char­
acteristics of a firm on its growth increases with company age. We found
a negative relationship between firm age and firm growth, in line with
the majority of previous research (Henrekson & Johansson, 2010;
Wiklund et al., 2009). In order to better interpret the interaction effects,
these are represented in Figs. 1 and 2. A simple slope test (Cohen, Cohen,
West, & Aiken, 2003) in relation to Fig. 1 indicated that the negative
Fig. 1. Moderator effect of family business on Age-Growth relationship.
effect of the family nature of the firm on sales growth is slightly more
1a. Dependent variable: Sales Growth (with 95 % CI).
intense when firms are older (simple slope = 0.17, SE = 0.21, p < 0.05), 1b. Dependent variable: Employee Growth (with 95 % CI).
according to Hypothesis 2a (which was confirmed). However, in the case
of employee growth (as a dependent variable), Fig. 1b shows, first, that
0.–10; SE = 0.07; p = 0.38). In summary, this result suggests that larger
firm age negatively influences the increase in the number of employees,
family businesses demonstrate similar behaviour to non-family busi­
and second, that this effect is less intense for family firms than
nesses in relation to potentially increasing or decreasing the number of
non-family firms, as proposed (and confirmed) in Hypothesis 2b. We
employees. One possible reason for this result is that larger family firms
verified that this relationship is significant using a simple slope test
tend to have more professional management and more formal decision-
(simple slope = -0.13, SE = -0.11, p < 0.05).
making processes, especially in areas that involve increasing amounts of
Finally, Hypothesis 3 proposed that firm size moderates the effect of
resources that may negatively impact the risk level assumed by the
family ownership and control and growth (sales growth in H3a and
owner family (Basco, 2014; Stewart & Hitt, 2012).
employee growth in H3b). The results for sales growth showed a positive
interaction effect in Model 1d (Table 2). Fig. 2a illustrates this moder­
ation effect (simple slope = 0.27; SE = 0.19; p < 0.05), indicating that 6. Conclusion
the positive influence of the firm’s size on sales growth is more intensive
in smaller firms than for larger companies. Fig. 2a shows that there are One of the main challenges of family business is growth (Campo­
no significant differences between larger family and non-family business piano et al., 2019; Stenholm et al., 2016). Previous literature shows that
in terms of sales growth. This finding supports Hypothesis 3a, which family firms tend to be smaller than non-family firms (Casillas et al.,
proposed that any negative influence of the family nature of the firm on 2015), and this characteristic implies several liabilities associated with
sales growth will be less intense for larger business. However, when we small size. However, until this study, we did not know so much about
look at employment growth, Table 3 shows a negative (significant) co­ how this smaller size of family businesses may influence their growth
efficient of the joint effect of firm size and its family nature on growth. pattern. With few exceptions, growth differences between family and
Fig. 2b graphically represents this interaction effect, showing nearly non-family companies are still under-investigated and our research
parallel lines for family and non-family businesses, with no differences findings offer three main contributions to both the firm growth and
in the effect of larger companies on employment growth. Among smaller family business literature.
firms only, there is a slight difference between family and non-family First, our research indicates that family and non-family businesses
businesses, showing more intense growth for family firms compared to differ in terms of sales growth and employment growth in the short-
their non-family counterparts, rejecting Hypothesis 3b. The simple slope term. We found differences in the growth development of family and
test indicated that there are no significant differences between small and non-family firms, suggesting there are differences in their time orien­
big family businesses in terms of growth in employees (simple slope = tation and the role of SEW (Pieper et al., 2020). First, our results support
the idea of the long-term orientation of family businesses (Lumpkin &

8
A.M. Moreno-Menéndez and J.C. Casillas Journal of Family Business Strategy 12 (2021) 100420

and family business, showing that conventional theories, such as Pen­


rosean perspective of business growth, must be complemented by spe­
cific theories of family businesses, in order to consider non-economic
goals and the role of preserving socioemotional wealth in the long term
(Astrachan, 2010; Gómez-Mejía et al., 2007).
Our research also offers several contributions to practitioners. First,
we show that growth is not a one-dimensional construct and that it is
possible to grow more in one dimension and less in others. Our research
finds that family businesses are able to grow more in employees but less
in sales, in comparison to non-family firms. This finding suggests that
family business may tend to invest into fungible resources in the short
term in order to grow more in the long term. At the same time, this result
underlines the social dimension of family firms, which can be considered
a community of interests. Second, managers should evaluate the results
of this study in relation to the potential impact of a higher growth in the
number of employees than in sales, especially in the case of smaller and
younger family firms. In these companies, increasing employment more
than sales may result in a decrease in efficiency and productivity,
compared to non-family business, which can make these firms less
competitive. Third and finally, managers should also consider the stage
of the company in the family-firm lifecycle (Gersick, Davis, McCollon, &
Lansberg, 1997). We find that firm age and firm size influence the
growth pattern of the family firms, and reiterate the findings of recent
studies that illustrate the role of entrepreneurial behaviour of the family
business in growth (Campopiano et al., 2019; Brumana, Minola, Garrett,
& Digan, 2017; Minola, Brumana, Campopiano, Garrett, & Cassia,
2016).
Our study does have a number of limitations, which point the way for
future research on the topic. The first limitation is the lack of informa­
tion regarding the direction and intensity of the family’s involvement in
the TMT and/or the board of directors (Casillas et al., 2011; Sciascia,
Mazzola, Astrachan, & Pieper, 2012, 2013). We only had demographic
characteristics of the companies at our availability, rather than internal
information regarding the proportion and distribution of ownership,
family involvement on the board and top management team, genera­
tional involvement, and so on. This information would be helpful in
delving deeper into how family members make decisions regarding
growth and shaping resources for future growth. A second limitation is
Fig. 2. Moderator effect of family business on Size-Growth relationship.
the sample selection. Our sample pertains to a single country (Spain) and
2a. Dependent variable: Sales Growth (with 95 % CI).
only includes medium and large companies from manufacturing in­
2b. Dependent variable: Employee Growth (with 95 % CI).
dustries (both private and public entities). Bjuggren et al. (2013) found
that there is likely to be a difference in the influence of family control on
Brigham, 2011; Lumpkin et al., 2010), showing a slower sales growth
firm growth between SMEs and larger companies. Therefore, subsequent
compared to non-family businesses. Furthermore, we find that family
studies should include firms of all sizes to cover a broader spectrum of
firms prefer to invest in versatile resources, such as employees, devel­
organizations. In relation to sample selection, our database is unbal­
oping a community of people, as argued by the SEW perspective. At the
anced (not all data were available for every firm/year). Although GMM
same time, we provide further evidence of how differences in the nature
(Generalized Method of Moments) is appropriate for this kind of data,
of resources (versatility and/or fungibility) may impact sales and
the database does not contain information about the reasons for a firm’s
employment growth in different ways (Sirmon & Hitt, 2003). In this
exit from the database (no information, acquisition, failure, and so on).
regard, our findings stress the importance of devising a series of mea­
Moreover, our analysis covered a nine-year period (2006–2014), during
sures with which to assess family and non-family business outcomes to
which time there was a severe economic crisis (2008). It would therefore
effectively capture their idiosyncrasies (see also Wagner, Block, Miller,
be interesting to explore our hypotheses using different time and
Schwens, and Xi (2015)) for similar findings on financial firm
geographical contexts; perhaps in the context of an expanding economy.
performance).
Finally, we have not considered nor measured the potential underlining
Second, we tested the role of the age and size of family firms in the
drivers of family business growth, such as the role of the different di­
context of firm growth. Here, our findings suggest that the lower growth
mensions of SEW, for example. Future studies could assess the valence of
of family firms is more pronounced among older firms, showing that the
SEW in its various dimension directly, using readily available scales to
potential negative influence of family owners and managers (risk aver­
operationalize SEW (e.g., Debicki et al., 2016; Hauck, Suess-Reyes, Beck,
sion and slack resources) may develop over time, as younger generations
Prügl, & Frank, 2016a).
become involved in the firm. This finding is consistent with the idea of
In conclusion, while previous research recognised the comparatively
an erosion of entrepreneurial orientation across generations in family
smaller size of family businesses (Bjuggren et al., 2011; Casillas et al.,
companies (Cruz & Nordqvist, 2007; Habbershon & Williams, 1999). In
2015; Shanker & Astrachan, 1996), few works have explicitly investi­
relation to the effect of firm size, our results support the idea of a greater
gated the drivers of growth among these firms. This article opens a door
similarity in the decision-taking process between large family and
for future research in relation to how economic and non-economic issues
non-family firms.
mutually influence growth strategies in family business and how het­
And finally, our findings contribute to the literature on firm growth
erogeneity of family firms, may affect to their decision-taking process.

9
A.M. Moreno-Menéndez and J.C. Casillas Journal of Family Business Strategy 12 (2021) 100420

Apart from firm size and age, analysed in our paper, future research Bradley, S. W., Wiklund, J., & Shepherd, D. A. (2011). Swinging a double-edged sword:
The effect of slack on entrepreneurial management and growth. Journal of Business
should investigate other sources of heterogeneity.
Venturing, 26(5), 537–554.
Brannon, D. L., Wiklund, J., & Haynie, J. M. (2013). The varying effects of family
Funding relationships in entrepreneurial teams. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 37(1),
107–132.
Brumana, M., Minola, T., Garrett, R. P., & Digan, S. P. (2017). How do family firms
This manuscript has been financed by Santander Family Business launch new businesses? A developmental perspective on internal corporate
Chair of the University of Seville, and the Ministry of Economy and venturing in family business. Journal of Small Business Management, 55, 594–613.
Competitiveness (ECO2017-84364-R Project). Brush, T. H., Bromiley, P., & Hendrickx, M. (2000). The free cash flow hypothesis for
sales growth and firm performance. Strategic Management Journal, 21(4), 455–472.
Buckley, P. J., & Prashantham, S. (2016). Global interfirm networks: The division of
Declaration of Competing Interest entrepreneurial labor between MNEs and SMEs. Academy of Management Perspectives,
30(1), 40–58.
Campopiano, G., de Massis, A., & Kotlar, J. (2019). Environmental jolts, family-centered
The authors report no declarations of interest. non-economic goals, and innovation: A framework of family firm resilience. The
Palgrave handbook of heterogeneity among family firms (pp. 773–789). Springer.
References Campopiano, G., Brumana, M., Minola, T., & Cassia, L. (2020). Does growth represent
chimera or Bellerophon for a family business? The role of Entrepreneurial
orientation and family influence nuances. European Management Review, 17(3),
Achtenhagen, L., Naldi, L., & Melin, L. (2010). ‘Business growth’: Do practitioners and
765–783.
scholars really talk about the same thing? Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 34(2),
Carpenter, R. E., & Petersen, B. C. (2002). Is the growth of small firms constrained by
289–316.
internal finance? The Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(2), 298–309.
Akhmedova, A., Cavallotti, R., Marimon, F., & Campopiano, G. (2019). Daughters’
Casillas, J. C., & Moreno-Menendez, A. M. (2010). The relationship between
careers in family business: Motivation types and family-specific barriers. Journal of
entrepreneurial orientation and growth: The moderating role of family involvement.
Family Business Strategy. In press.
Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, 22(3-4), 265–291.
Almus, M., & Nerlinger, E. A. (2000). Testing “Gibrat”s Law’ for young firms – Empirical
Casillas, J. C., Moreno-Menendez, A. M., Barbero, J. L., & Clinton, E. (2019).
results for West Germany. Small Business Economics, 15, 1–12.
‘Retrenchment strategies and family involvement: the role of survival risk’. Family
Anderson, R. C., & Reeb, D. M. (2003). Founding-family ownership and firm
Business Review, 32(1), 58–75.
performance: Evidence from the S&P 500. Journal of Finance, 58, 1301–1328.
Casillas, J. C., Moreno-Menendez, A. M., & Barbero, J. L. (2011). Entrepreneurial
Anyadike-Danes, M., Bonner, K., Hart, M., & Mason, C. (2009). Measuring Business
orientation of family firms: Family and environmental dimensions. Journal of Family
Growth: High-growth firms and their contribution to employment in the UK London.
Business Strategy, 2(2), 90–100.
NESTA.
Casillas, J. C., López-Fernández, C., Meroño, A., Pons, A., & Beiges, R. (2015). Family
Aparicio, G., Iturralde, T., & Sanchez-Famoso, V. (2019). Innovation in family firms: a
businesses in Spain. Madrid: Instituto de la Empresa Familiar.
holistic bibliometric overview of the research field. European Journal of Family
Cassiman, B., & Veugelers, R. (2002). R&D cooperation and spillovers: Some empirical
Business, 9(2), 83–97.
evidence from Belgium. The American Economic Review, 92(4), 1169–1184.
Arellano, M., & Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of
Chang, E. P. C., Chrisman, J. J., Chua, J. H., & Kellermanns, F. W. (2008). Regional
error-components models. Journal of Econometrics, 68, 29–51.
economy as a determinant of the prevalence of family firms in the United States: A
Arregle, J. L., Batjargal, B., & Hitt, M. A. (2015). Family ties in entrepreneurs’ social
Preliminary Report. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 32(3), 559–573.
networks and new venture growth. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 39(2),
Chrisman, J. J., & Patel, P. (2012). Variations in R&D investment in family and non-
313–344.
family firms: Behavioral agency and myopic loss aversion perspectives. The Academy
Arregle, J. L., Duran, P., Hitt, A., & van Essen, M. (2016). Why is family firms’
of Management Journal, 55, 976–997.
internationalization unique? A meta-analysis. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice,
Chrisman, J. J., Chua, J. H., & Pearson, A. W. (2012). Family involvement, family
41(5), 1–31.
influence, and family-centered non-economic goals in small firms. Entrepreneurship
Arsubiaga, U., Maseda, A., Uribarri, & Palma, J. M. (2019). Collaborative innovation in
Theory and Practice, 36(2), 267–293.
the family SME: Conceptualization, goals, and success factors. European Journal of
Chua, J. H., Chrisman, J. J., & De Massis, A. (2015). A closer look at socioemotional
Family Business, 9(2), 113–121.
wealth: Its flows, stocks, and prospects for moving forward. Entrepreneurship Theory
Astrachan, J. H. (2010). Strategy in family business: Toward a multidimensional research
and Practice, 39(2), 173–182.
agenda. Journal of Family Business Strategy, 1(1), 6–14.
Cirillo, A., Huybrechts, J., Mussolino, D., Sciascia, S., & Voordeckers, W. (2020).
Astrachan, J. H., & Shanker, M. C. (2003). Family businesses contribution to the U.S.
Researching family business growth. European Management Review, 17(3), 733–746.
economy: A closer look. Family Business Review, 16(3), 1–220.
Cleary, P., Quinn, M., & Moreno, A. (2019). Socioemotional wealth in family firms: A
Autio, E., Sapienza, H. J., & Almeida, J. G. (2000). Effects of age at entry, knowledge
longitudinal content analysis of corporate disclosures. Journal of Family Business
intensity, and imitability on international growth. The Academy of Management
Strategy, 10(2), 119–132.
Journal, 43(5), 909–924.
Cohen, J., Cohen, P., West, S. G., & Aiken, L. S. (2003). Applied multiple regression/
Barbero, J. L., Casillas, J. C., & Feldman, H. D. (2012). Managerial capabilities and paths
correlation analysis for the behavioral sciences (3rd ed.). Mahwah, NJ: Erlbaum.
to growth as determinants of high-growth small and medium-sized enterprises.
Correa, A., Acosta, M., González, A. L., & Medina, U. (2003). Size, age, activity sector on
International Small Business Journal, 29(6), 671–694.
the growth of the small and medium firm size. Small Business Economics, 21,
Basco, R. (2014). Exploring the influence of the family upon firm performance: Does
289–307.
strategic behavior matter? International Small Business Journal, 32(8), 976–995.
Covin, J. G., & Slevin, D. P. (1990). New venture strategic posture, structure, and
Baumol, W. J. (2004). Entrepreneurial enterprises, large established firms and other
performance: An industry life cycle analysis. Journal of Business Venturing, 5,
components of the free- market growth machine. Small Business Economics, 23, 9–21.
123–135.
Bechetti, L., & Trovato, G. (2002). The determinants of growth for small and medium
Cruz, C., & Nordqvist, M. (2007). Environmental factors and entrepreneurial orientation in
sized firms. The role of the availability of external finance. Small Business Economics,
family business: A generational perspective. Jonkoping, Sweden: Paper presented at the
19, 291–306.
3rd Workshop on Family Firms Management Research.
Berrone, P., Cruz, C., & Gomez-Mejia, L. R. (2012). Socioemotional wealth in family
Cull, R., Davis, L., Lamoreaux, N., & Rosenthal, J. L. (2006). Historical financing of small-
firms: Theoretical dimensions, assessment approaches, and agenda for future
and-medium-size enterprises. Journal of Banking & Finance, 30, 3017–3042.
research. Family Business Review, 25(3), 258–279.
Daily, C., & Dollinger, M. (1992). An empirical examination of ownership structure in
Bettinelli, C., Sciascia, S., Randerson, K., & Fayolle, A. (2017). Researching
family and professionally managed firms. Family Business Review, 5, 117–136.
entrepreneurship in family firms. Journal of Small Business Management, 55(4),
Daunfeldt, S.-O., Johansson, D., & Halvarson, D. (2015). Using the eurostat- OECD
506–529.
definition of high-growth firms: a cautionary note. Journal of Entrepreneurship and
Binz Astrachan, C., Botero, I., Astrachan, J. H., & Prügl, R. (2018). Branding the family
Public Policy, 4(1), 50–56.
firm: A review, integrative framework proposal, and research agenda. Journal of
Davidsson, P., Steffens, P., & Fitzsimmons, J. (2009). Growing profitable or growing from
Family Business Strategy, 9(1), 3–15.
profits: Putting the horse in front of the cart? Journal of Business Venturing, 24,
Binz, C., Hair, J., Pieper, T. M., & Baldauf, A. (2013). Exploring the effect of distinct
388–406.
family firm reputation on consumers’ preferences. Journal of Family Business Strategy,
Davidsson, P., Achtenhagen, L., & Naldi, L. (2010). Small firm growth. Foundations and
4(1), 3–11.
Trends in Entrepreneurship, 6, 69–166.
Birch, D. L. (1987). Job creation in America. New York: Free Press.
De Massis, A., Audretsch, D., Uhlaner, L., & Kammerlander, N. (2018). Innovation with
Bjuggren, C. M., Daunfeldt, S. O., & Johansson, D. (2013). High-growth firms and family
Limited Resources: Management Lessons from the German Mittelstand. The Journal
ownership. Journal of Small Business & Entrepreneurship, 26(4), 365–385.
of Product Innovation Management, 35(1), 125–146.
Bjuggren, C. M., Johansson, D., & Sjögren, H. (2011). A note on employment and gross
Debicki, B. J., Kellermanns, F. W., Chrisman, J. J., Pearson, A. W., & Spencer, B. A.
domestic product in Swedish family-owned businesses: A descriptive analysis. Family
(2016). Development of a socioemotional wealth importance (SEWi) scale for family
Business Review, 24(4), 362–371.
firm research. Journal of Family Business Strategy, 7(1), 47–57.
Blundell, R., & Bond, S. R. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic
Dekker, J., Lybaert, N., Stejvers, T., & Depaire, B. (2013). The effect of family business
panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87, 115–143.
professionalization as a multidimensional construct on firm performance. Journal of
Boellis, A., Mariotti, S., Minichilli, A., & Piscitello, L. (2016). Family involvement and
Small Business Strategies, 53(2), 516–538.
firms’ establishment mode choice in foreign markets. Journal of International Business
Studies, 47(8), 1–22.

10
A.M. Moreno-Menéndez and J.C. Casillas Journal of Family Business Strategy 12 (2021) 100420

Discua, A., Howorth, C., & Hamilton, E. (2013). Intra-family entrepreneurship: The Kotlar, J., & De Massis, A. (2013). Goal setting in family firms: Goal diversity, social
formation and membership of family entrepreneurial teams. Entrepreneurship Theory interactions, and collective commitment to family-centered goals. Entrepreneurship
and Practice, 37, 17–46. Theory and Practice, 37, 1263–1288.
Dolz, C., Iborra, M., & Safon, V. (2019). Improving the likelihood of SME survival during Kraus, S., Clauss, T., Breier, M., Gast, J., Zardini, A., & Tiberius, V. (2020). The
financial and economic crises: The importance of TMTs and family ownership for economics of COVID-19: Initial empirical evidence on how family firms in five
ambidexterity. Business Research Quarterly, 22(2), 119–136. European countries cope with the corona crisis. International Journal of
Dunne, P., & Hugues, A. (1994). Age, size, growth and survival: UK companies in the Entrepreneurial Behavior & Research. Forthcoming.
1980s. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 42, 115–138. Kuemmerle, W. (2006). Innovation in large firms. In M. Casson, B. Yeung, A. Basu, &
Duran, P., Kammerlander, N., van Essen, M., & Zellweger, T. (2016). Doing more with N. Wadeson (Eds.), Oxford handbook of entrepreneurship (pp. 311–331). New York:
less: Innovation input and output in family firms. The Academy of Management Oxford University Press.
Journal, 59(4), 1224–1264. Kushins, E. R., & Behounek, E. (2020). Using sociological theory to problematize family
Dyer, W. G., Jr (1989). Integrating professional management into a family owned business research. Journal of Family Business Strategy. In press.
business. Family Business Review, 2(3), 221–235. Leaptrott, J. (2005). An institutional theory view of the family business. Family Business
Eddleston, K. A., Kellermanns, F. W., & Zellweger, T. M. (2012). Exploring the Review, 18(3), 215–228.
entrepreneurial behavior of family firms: Does the stewardship perspective explain Le Breton-Miller, I., & Miller, D. (2013). Socioemotional wealth across the family firm life
differences? Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 36(2), 347–367. cycle: A commentary on Family Business Survival and the Role of Boards.
Elsbach, K. D., & Pieper, T. M. (2019). How psychological needs motivate family firm Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 37(6), 1391–1397.
identifications and identifiers: A framework and future research agenda. Journal of Li, G., Li, Y., & Tsay, C. (2012). Quantile correlations and quantile autoregressive modeling.
Family Business Strategy, 10(3). forthcoming. SSRN working paper. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2153697.
European Commission. (2010). Europe 2020: A strategy for smart, sustainable and inclusive Lim, D. S. K., Celly, N., Morse, E. A., & Rowe, W. G. (2013). Rethinking the effectiveness
growth. Brussels: Communication From the Commission, European Commission. of asset and cost retrenchment: The contingency effects of a firm’s rent creation
Eurostat-OECD. (2007). Eurostat-OECD manual on business demography statistics. mechanism. Strategic Management Journal, 34(1), 42–61.
Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities. Lumpkin, G. T., & Brigham, K. H. (2011). Long-term orientation and intertemporal
Evans, D. S. (1987). The relationship between firm growth, size, and age: estimates for choice in family firms. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 35(6), 1149–1169.
100 manufacturing industries. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 35, 567–581. Lumpkin, G. T., & Dess, G. G. (1996). Clarifying the entrepreneurial orientation construct
Fernández, Z., & Nieto, M. J. (2006). Impact of ownership on the international and liking it to performance. The Academy of Management Review, 21, 135–172.
involvement of SMEs. Journal of International Business Studies, 37, 340–351. Lumpkin, G. T., Brigham, K. H., & Moss, T. W. (2010). Long-term orientation
Franco, C. (2013). Exports and FDI motivations: Empirical evidence from U.S. foreign implications for the entrepreneurial orientation and performance of family
subsidiaries. International Business Review, 22, 47–62. businesses. Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, 22, 241–264.
Gersick, K., Davis, J., McCollon, M., & Lansberg, I. (1997). Generation to generation: Life Miller, D. (1983). The correlates of entrepreneurship in three types of firms. Management
cycles of the family business. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press. Science, 29, 770–791.
Gibrat, R. (1931). Les inequalites economiques. Paris: Libraire du Recueil Sirey. Miller, D. (2003). An asymmetry-based view of competitive advantage. Strategic
Golovko, E., & Valentini, G. (2011). Exploring the complementarity between innovation Management Journal, 24, 961–976.
and export for SMEs’ growth. Journal of International Business Studies, 42, 362–380. Miller, D., & Le Breton-Miller, I. (2005). Managing for the long run: Lessons in competitive
Gómez-Mejía, L. R., Haynes, K. T., Núñez-Nickel, M., Jacobson, K. J. L., & Moyano- advantage from great family businesses. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School
Fuentes, J. (2007). Socioemotional Wealth and Business Risks in Family-Controlled Press.
Firms: Evidence from Spanish Olive Oil Mills. Administrative Science Quarterly, 52, Miller, D., & Le Breton-Miller, I. (2014). Deconstructing socioemotional wealth.
106–137. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 38(4), 713–720.
Gómez-Mejía, L. R., Makri, M., & Larraza-Kintana, M. (2010). Diversification decisions in Miller, D., Le Breton-Miller, I., & Scholnick, B. (2008). Stewardship vs. stagnation: An
family-controlled firms. Journal of Management Studies, 47(2), 223–252. empirical comparison of small family and non-family businesses. Journal of
Gomez-Mejía, L., Cruz, C., Berrone, P., & De Castro, J. (2012). The Bind that Ties: Management Studies, 45, 51–78.
Socioemotional Wealth Preservation in Family Firms. The Academy of Management Miller, D., Le Breton-Miller, I., & Lester, R. H. (2010). Family ownership and acquisition
Annals, 5(1), 653–707. behavior in publicly-traded companies. Strategic Management Journal, 31, 201–223.
Habbershon, T. G., & Williams, M. L. (1999). A resource-based framework for assessing Minola, T., Brumana, M., Campopiano, G., Garrett, R. P., & Cassia, L. (2016). Corporate
the strategic advantages of family firms. Family Business Review, 12(1), 25. venturing in family business: A developmental approach of the enterprising family.
Hair, J. F., Jr., Anderson, R. E., Tatham, R. L., & Black, W. C. (1995). Multivariate data Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, 10(4), 395–412.
analysis (3rd ed). New York: Macmillan. Miroshnychenko, I., De Massis, A., Miller, D., & Barontini, R. (2020). Family business
Hamelin, A. (2013). Influence of family ownership on small business growth. Evidence growth around the world. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, Article
from French SMEs. Small Business Economic, 41, 563–579. 1042258720913028.
Harris, R., & Reid, R. (2008). Barriers to growth in family-owned smaller businesses. In Moreno-Menéndez, A. M., & Casillas, J. C. (2007). High-growth SMEs versus Non-high-
R. Barrett, & S. Mayson (Eds.), International handbook of HRM entrepreneurship (pp. growth SMEs: A Discriminant Analysis. Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, 19
260–284). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. (1), 69–88.
Hasenzagl, R., Hatak, I., & Frank, H. (2018). Problematizing socioemotional wealth in Moreno-Menéndez, A. M., & Casillas, J. C. (2008). Entrepreneurial Orientation and
family firms: a systems-theoretical reframing. Entrepreneurship and Regional Growth of SMEs: A Causal Model, 32(3): Entrepreneurship. The Police Journal,
Development, 30(1–2), 199–223. 507–528.
Hatum, A., & Pettigrew, A. (2004). Adaptation under environment turmoil: Naldi, L., & Davidsson, P. (2014). Entrepreneurial growth: the role of international
organizational flexibility in family-owned firms. Family Business Review, 17, knowledge acquisition as moderated by firm age. Journal of Business Venturing, 29(5),
237–258. 687–703.
Hauck, J., Suess-Reyes, J., Beck, S., Prügl, R., & Frank, H. (2016a). Measuring Naldi, L., Nordqvist, M., Sjöberg, K., & Wiklund, J. (2007). Entrepreneurial orientation,
socioemotional wealth in family-owned and-managed firms: A validation and short risk taking, and performance in family firms. Family Business Review, 20, 33–47.
form of the FIBER Scale. Journal of Family Business Strategy, 7(3), 133–148. Nason, R. S., & Wiklund, J. (2018). An assessment of resource-based theorizing on firm
Hauck, J., Suess-Reyes, J., Beck, S., Prügl, R., & Frank, H. (2016b). Measuring growth and suggestions for the future. Journal of Management, 44(1), 32–60.
socioemotional wealth in family-owned and -managed firms: A validation and short Nieto, M. J., Santamaría, L., & Fernández, Z. (2015). Understanding the innovation
form of the FIBER scale. Journal of Family Business Strategy, 7, 133–148. behavior of family firms. Journal of Small Business Management, 53(2), 382–399.
Henrekson, M., & Johansson, D. (2010). Gazelles as job creators: a survey and Nordqvist, M., & Melin, L. (2010). Entrepreneurial family firms. Entrepreneurship and
interpretation of the evidence. Small Business Economics, 35, 227–244. Regional Development, 22(3–4), 211–239.
IFERA. (2003). Family business dominate. Family Business Review, 16(4), 235–240. OECD. (2000). High-growth enterprises: What governments can do to make a difference.
Jaskiewicz, P., Combs, J. G., & Rau, S. B. (2015). Entrepreneurial legacy: Toward a available at: OECD Studies on SMEs and Entrepreneurship, OECD Publishing
theory of how some family firms nurture transgenerational entrepreneurship. https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264048782-en.
Journal of Business Venturing, 30(1), 29–49. Penrose, E. (1959). The theory of the growth of the firm. New York: Wiley.
Jean, R. J., Deng, Z., Kim, D., & Yuan, Y. (2015). Assessing endogeneity issues in Pettus, M. L. (2001). The resourced-based view as a developmental growth process:
international marketing research. International Journal of Sales & Marketing evidence from the deregulated trucking industry. The Academy of Management
Management Research and Development, 33(3), 483–512. Journal, 44, 878–896.
Jiang, C., Chua, R., Kotabe, M., & Murrat, J. (2011). Effects of cultural ethnicity, firm Pieper, T. M., Williams, R. I., Jr., Manley, S. C., & Matthews, L. M. (2020). What time
size, and firm age on senior executives’ trust in their overseas business partners: may tell: An exploratory study of the relationship between religiosity, temporal
Evidence from China. Journal of International Business Studies, 42, 1150–1173. orientation, and goals in family business. Journal of Business Ethics, 163, 759–773.
Jovanovic, B. (1982). Selection and evolution of industry. Econometrica, 50, 508–523. Revilla, A. J., Pérez-Luño, A., & Nieto, M. J. (2016). Does family involvement in
Kellermanns, F. W., Eddleston, K. A., Barnett, T., & Pearson, A. (2008). An exploratory management reduce the risk of business failure? The moderating role of
study of family member characteristics and involvement: effects on entrepreneurial entrepreneurial orientation. Family Business Review, 29(4), 365–379.
behavior in the family firm. Family Business Review, 21, 1–14. Ringle, C. M., Wende, S., & Becker, J. M. (2015). SmartPLS 3. Retrieved from.
Knudsen, T., Levinthal, D. A., & Winter, S. G. (2017). Systematic Differences and Random Bönningstedt: SmartPLS http://www.smartpls.com.
Rates: Reconciling Gibrat’s Law with Firm Differences. Strategy Sicnece, 2(2), Sarangee, K., & Echambadi, R. (2014). Firm-specific determinants of product line
83–139. technology strategies in high technology markets. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal,
Kotey, B., & Folker, C. (2007). Employee training in SMEs: Effect of size and firm type – 8, 149–166.
Family and nonfamily. Journal of Small Business Management, 45(2), 214–238. Schein, E. H. (1983). The role of the founder in creating organizational culture.
Organizational Dynamics, 12(1), 13–28.

11
A.M. Moreno-Menéndez and J.C. Casillas Journal of Family Business Strategy 12 (2021) 100420

Schulze, W. S., & Kellermanns, F. W. (2015). Reifying socioemotional wealth. Strike, V. M., Berrone, P., Sapp, S. G., & Congiu, L. (2015). A socioemotional wealth
Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, (May), 447–459. approach to CEO career horizons in family firms. Journal of Management Studies, 52,
Sciascia, S., Mazzola, P., Astrachan, J. H., & Pieper, T. M. (2012). The role of family 555–583.
ownership in international entrepreneurship: Exploring nonlinear effects. Small Surroca, J., Tribo, J. A., & Waddock, S. (2010). Corporate responsibility and financial
Business Economics, 38(1), 15–31. performance: The role of intangible resources. Strategic Management Journal, 31,
Sciascia, S., Mazzola, P., & Chirico, F. (2013). Generational involvement in the top 463–490.
management team of family firms: Exploring non-linear effects of entrepreneurial Thornhill, S., & Amit, R. (2003). Learning about failure: Bankruptcy, firm age, and the
orientation. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 37, 69–85. resource-based view. Organization Science, 14, 497–509.
Seibold, L. K. (2021). Patterns of family enterprise’s growth. Topics of family business Vazquez, P., & Rocha, H. (2018). On the goals of family firms: A review and integration.
governance (pp. 79–86). Cham: Springer. Journal of Family Business Strategy, 9(2), 94–106.
Shafman, M., Wolf, G., Chase, R., & Tansik, D. (1988). Antecedents of organizational Wagner, D., Block, J. H., Miller, D., Schwens, C., & Xi, G. (2015). A meta-analysis of the
slack. The Academy of Management Review, 13, 601–614. financial performance of family firms: Another attempt. Journal of Family Business
Shane, S., & Venkataraman, S. (2000). The promise of entrepreneurship as a field of Strategy, 6(1), 3–13.
research. The Academy of Management Review, 25, 217–226. Wernerfelt, B. (1984). A resource-based view of the firm. Strategic Management Journal, 5
Shanker, M. C., & Astrachan, J. H. (1996). Myths and realities: Family businesses’ (2), 171–180.
contribution to the US economy—A framework for assessing family business Wiklund, J., Patzelt, H., & Shepherd, D. A. (2009). Building an integrative model of small
statistics. Family Business Review, 9(2), 107–123. business growth. Small Business Economics, 32(4), 351–374.
Sirmon, D. G., & Hitt, M. A. (2003). Managing resources: linking unique resources, Wilson, N., Wright, M., & Scholes, L. (2013). Family business survival and the role of
management, and wealth creation in family firms. Entrepreneurship Theory and boards. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 37(6), 1369–1389.
Practice, 27(4), 339–358. Yazdanfar, D. (2013). Profitability determinants among micro firms: evidence from
Souder, D., Zaheer, A., Sapienza, H., & Ranucci, R. (2016). How family influence, Swedish data. International Journal of Managerial Finance, 9(2), 150–160.
Socioemotional-Wealth, and competitive conditions shape new technology adoption. Yi, J., Wang, C., & Kafouros, M. (2013). The effects of innovative capabilities on
Strategic Management Journal, 38(9), 1774–1790. exporting: Do institutional forces matter? International Business Review, 22, 392–406.
Stenholm, P., Pukkinen, T., & Heinonen, J. (2016). Firm growth in family Zahra, S. (2010). Harvesting family firms’ organizational social capital: A relational
businesses—The role of entrepreneurial orientation and the entrepreneurial activity. perspective. Journal of Management Studies, 47(2), 345–366.
Journal of Small Business Management, 54(2), 697–713. Zajac, E. J., & Bazerman, M. H. (1991). Blind spots in industry and competitor analysis:
Stewart, A., & Hitt, M. A. (2012). Why can’t a family business be more like a nonfamily Implications of interfirm (mis)perceptions for strategic decisions. The Academy of
business? Modes of professionalization in family firms. Family Business Review, 25(1), Management Review, 16(1), 37–56.
58–86. Zellweger, T. M., & Dehlen, T. (2012). Value is in the eye of the owner: Affect infusion
Stinchcombe, A. L. (1965). Social structure and organizations. In J. G. March (Ed.), and socioemotional wealth among family firm owners. Family Business Review, 25(3),
Handbook of organizations (pp. 142–193). Chicago: Rand McNally and Co. 280–297.
Storey, D. J. (1994). Understanding the small business sector. London: Routledge. Zellweger, T., & Sieger, P. (2012). Entrepreneurial orientation in long-lived family firms.
Small Business Economics, 38(1), 67–84.

12

You might also like