You are on page 1of 13

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/268986121

Analytics for vaccine economics and pricing: Insights and observations

Article in Expert Review of Vaccines · April 2015


DOI: 10.1586/14760584.2015.985662 · Source: PubMed

CITATIONS READS

12 649

2 authors:

Matthew J. Robbins Sheldon H Jacobson


Air Force Institute of Technology University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign
36 PUBLICATIONS 247 CITATIONS 245 PUBLICATIONS 5,170 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Publishing Ecosystem View project

Dispatching and Locating Military Medical Evacuation Assets View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Sheldon H Jacobson on 27 March 2015.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Review

Analytics for vaccine


economics and pricing:
insights and observations
Expert Rev. Vaccines 14(4), 605–616 (2015)
Expert Review of Vaccines Downloaded from informahealthcare.com by University of Illinois on 03/09/15

Matthew J Robbins1 Pediatric immunization programs in the USA are a successful and cost–effective public health
and endeavor, profoundly reducing mortalities caused by infectious diseases. Two important issues
Sheldon H Jacobson*2 relate to the success of the immunization programs, the selection of cost–effective vaccines
1
and the appropriate pricing of vaccines. The recommended childhood immunization schedule,
Department of Operational Sciences,
Air Force Institute of Technology,
published annually by the CDC, continues to expand with respect to the number of injections
2950 Hobson Way, Wright-Patterson required and the number of vaccines available for selection. The advent of new vaccines to
AFB, OH, USA meet the growing requirements of the schedule results: in a large, combinatorial number of
2
Department of Computer Science, possible vaccine formularies. The expansion of the schedule and the increase in the number
Simulation and Optimization
Laboratory, University of Illinois, of available vaccines constitutes a challenge for state health departments, large city
201 N. Goodwin Avenue (MC258), immunization programs, private practices and other vaccine purchasers, as a cost–effective
Urbana, IL, 61801 2302, USA vaccine formulary must be selected from an increasingly large set of possible vaccine
For personal use only.

*Author for correspondence:


combinations to satisfy the schedule. The pediatric vaccine industry consists of a relatively
Tel.: +1 217 244 7275
shj@illinois.edu small number of pharmaceutical firms engaged in the research, development, manufacture
and distribution of pediatric vaccines. The number of vaccine manufacturers has dramatically
decreased in the past few decades for a myriad of reasons, most notably due to low
profitability. The contraction of the industry negatively impacts the reliable provision of
pediatric vaccines. The determination of appropriate vaccine prices is an important issue and
influences a vaccine manufacturer’s decision to remain in the market. Operations research is
a discipline that applies advanced analytical methods to improve decision making; analytics is
the application of operations research to a particular problem using pertinent data to provide
a practical result. Analytics provides a mechanism to resolve the challenges facing
stakeholders in the vaccine development and delivery system, in particular, the selection of
cost–effective vaccines and the appropriate pricing of vaccines. A review of applicable
analytics papers is provided.

KEYWORDS: analytics • operations research • pediatric vaccines • public health • vaccine pricing

stands at over 70% for the combined vaccine


The US pediatric vaccine market series [3]. The comprehensive success of large-
Vaccination is often lauded as one of the most scale pediatric immunization programs results
important and successful public health endeav- from the collaboration of an interdependent
ors in human history, profoundly reducing system of government and industry stakehold-
mortalities caused by infectious diseases [1]. In ers [4,5]. A stakeholder in this system acts inde-
the USA, among children born during 1994– pendently in pursuit of its own interests;
2013, it is estimated that vaccination will however, the actions of one stakeholder may
prevent 322 million illnesses, 21 million hos- affect the welfare of other stakeholders. It is
pitalizations and 732,000 deaths during their imperative that stakeholders understand the
lifetimes [2]. This success results from a public types of decisions faced by their fellow stake-
health program that fully immunizes nearly holders and how these decisions affect the
three-quarters of the children in the USA entire market. Indeed, the likelihood of sus-
annually. The current national vaccination taining the success of the public health immu-
coverage among children aged 19–35 month nization program increases when stakeholders

informahealthcare.com 10.1586/14760584.2015.985662 Ó 2014 Informa UK Ltd ISSN 1476-0584 605


Review Robbins & Jacobson

are better informed when making their decisions. Of particular financial risk. Moreover, vaccine manufacturers face ongoing
consequence are decisions concerning the selection of cost– regulation of production. The FDA conducts frequent inspec-
effective vaccine formularies [6], the determination of appropri- tions of manufacturing facilities and must approve the release
ate vaccine prices [7] and the implementation of government of individual product batches [19]. Any change in the produc-
vaccination policies that best influence the vaccine industry [8]. tion processes effects expensive product reviews. Finally, despite
These decisions become even more salient given discussions the strict regulatory environment, vaccine manufacturers remain
concerning reductions in federal health spending over the next susceptible to product-liability lawsuits (although, the national
decade [9]. vaccine injury compensation program, funded by a US$ 0.75
A number of stakeholders are involved in the US pediatric per antigen excise tax, greatly mitigates the risk associated with
vaccine market. The CDC acts as the primary federal public vaccine injury claims). Pharmaceutical companies cannot justify
health organization responsible for setting pediatric immuniza- investment in their vaccine manufacturing business units if
tion policy. Based on recommendations from the Advisory their risk-adjusted returns are low. Another important consider-
Expert Review of Vaccines Downloaded from informahealthcare.com by University of Illinois on 03/09/15

Committee on Immunization Practices, the American Academy ation affecting vaccine manufacturing business units is the com-
of Pediatrics and the American Academy of Family Physicians, petition for resources within the larger pharmaceutical
the CDC annually publishes a recommended childhood immu- company’s enterprise. The actual contribution to revenue after
nization schedule (RCIS) (FIGURE 1 from [10]) that provides accounting for the cost of researching, manufacturing and mar-
specific guidance regarding the effective control of vaccine- keting the vaccines may be quite small compared with other
preventable diseases to include the appropriate periodicity and available pharmaceutical endeavors. For example, Advair, a
dosage requirements for each pediatric vaccine. The schedule prescription respiratory product, generated nearly 20% of
serves as the fundamental force driving market demand for vac- GlaxoSmithKline’s revenue in 2013 [20]. As such, Glaxo-
cines [4]; the customers (i.e., healthcare providers, state and SmithKline may have a different perspective regarding the
local government public health officials) purchase vaccines to production of pediatric vaccines compared with other products.
immunize the patients (i.e., the consumers) under their care in Should one of the five vaccine manufacturers decide to cease
accordance with the schedule. Just over 4 million children are production, it would take quite some time before a licensed
For personal use only.

born in the USA each year [11], representing a base annual replacement vaccine became publicly available. This line of rea-
cohort of consumers. Changes in recommendations or require- soning suggests the importance of appropriately pricing vac-
ments from the CDC greatly influence the demand for a par- cines so as to encourage vaccine manufacturers to remain in
ticular vaccine. The CDC also maintains a list of acceptable the market.
pediatric vaccines and negotiates prices [12] at which federal,
state and local governments can purchase the vaccines through Expansion of the schedule
the Vaccines for Children (VFC) program. Pediatric vaccines The CDC has published the RCIS annually since 1995 [21].
purchased at the public sector price, as negotiated by CDC Before 1995, the schedule was updated periodically as new vac-
officials, account for approximately 55% of total pediatric vac- cines became available. In the 1980s, there were seven recom-
cine purchases by volume [4]. The Center for Biologics Evalua- mended vaccines on the schedule: diphtheria, tetanus, pertussis,
tion and Research, a division of the US FDA, licenses new measles, mumps, rubella and polio. As of 2014, there are
vaccines. The FDA ensures manufacturing processes, facilities 14 recommended vaccines on the schedule, with the following
and clinical studies result in the provision of safe and effective seven further additions since the 1980s: Haemophilus influenzae
vaccines. The FDA also maintains a list of vaccines licensed for Type b, hepatitis B, hepatitis A, influenza, varicella, pneumo-
immunization and distribution in the USA [13]. coccal and rotavirus. The rapid appearance of new vaccines
The pediatric vaccine industry consists of a relatively small results from biotechnology improvements within the vaccine
number of pharmaceutical firms (i.e., companies, manufac- industry [4]. The prevention of many more diseases is generally
turers) engaged in the research, development, manufacture and perceived as good news. However, the advent of new vaccines
distribution of pediatric vaccines [4]. The number of firms that poses challenges for public health agencies and health
produce vaccines for the US market has steadily decreased since care providers.
the 1960s. In 1967, 37 vaccine manufacturers operated in the One challenge involves the number of injections required to
USA [14,15]. As of 2014, only five firms manufacture all routine be fully immunize according to the schedule. Another, perhaps
vaccines; many vaccines are manufactured by a single company. more salient challenge involves the number of injections a child
Public health experts [4,16–19] suggest several reasons for the must endure during a single clinical visit. In the 1980s, the
declining number of manufacturers. Participation in the vaccine schedule required children to receive a total of five shots by the
industry is a difficult, costly and risky enterprise. Bringing a time they were 2 years old and not more than one shot at a
new vaccine to market can take up to 30 years and cost in single clinic visit [21]. The low number of injections was due in
excess of US$ 700 million [4,16]. Stringent licensing require- part to the diphtheria, tetanus and pertussis vaccines being
ments by the FDA serve as a barrier to market entry. The combined into a single DTP shot and measles, mumps and
FDA encourages creation of commercial production capacity rubella being combined into a single MMR shot. Moreover, at
before granting a license, placing a company at substantial that time the polio vaccine was given orally. As of 2014, the

606 Expert Rev. Vaccines 14(4), (2015)


Expert Review of Vaccines Downloaded from informahealthcare.com by University of Illinois on 03/09/15
For personal use only.

19–23 11–12 13–15 16–18


Vaccine Birth 1 month 2 months 4 months 6 months 9 months 12 months 15 months 18 months 2–3 years 4–6 years 7–10 years years
months years years

Hepatitis B1 (HepB) 1st dose 2nd dose 3rd dose

informahealthcare.com
Rotavirus2 (RV) Rv1 (2-dose 1st dose See
2nd dose footnote 2
series); RV5 (3-dose series)
Diphtheria, tetanus, and acellular
1st dose 2nd dose 3rd dose 4th dose 5th dose
pertussis3 (DTaP: <7 years)
Tetanus, diphtheria, and acellular
(Tdap)
pertussis4 (Tdap: ≥7 years)
Haemophilus influenzae type See 3rd or 4th dose
1st dose 2nd dose
b5 (Hib) footnote 5 see footnote 5
Pneumococcal conjugate5
1st dose 2nd dose 3rd dose 4th dose
(PCV13)
Pneumococcal polysaccharide6
(PPSV23)
Inactivated poliovirus7 (IPV)
1st dose 2nd dose 3rd dose 4th dose
(<18 years)
Influenza8 (IIV; LAIV) 2 doses Annual vaccination (IIV only) Annual vaccination (IIV or LAIV)
for some: see footnote 8
Measles, mumps, rubella9
1st dose 2nd dose
(MMR)

Varicella10 (VAR) 1st dose 2nd dose

Hepatitis A11 (HepA) 2-dose series, see footnote 11

Human papillomavirus12
(HPV2: females only; HPV4: (3-dose
males and females) series)

Meningococcal13
(Hib-Men-CY ≥6 weeks;
See footnote 13 1st dose
MenACWY-D ≥9 months;
Booster

MenACWY-CRM ≥2 months)

Range of Range of recommended Range of recommended Range of recommended ages Not routinely
recommended ages for ages for catch-up ages for certain high-risk during which catch-up is recommended
all children immunization groups encouraged and for certain
high-risk groups

Figure 1. USA 2014 recommended childhood immunization schedule.


Analytics for vaccine economics & pricing

From [10].
Review

607
Review Robbins & Jacobson

schedule requires children to receive a total of 24 shots by the employs operations research techniques to improve the
time they are 2 years old and up to six shots in a single visit decision-making of client organizations. The emphasis in ana-
(e.g., the 2-month-old well-child visit). The vaccine industry lytics is the improvement of business practices to obtain real,
has responded to this increased complexity by designing and sustainable results.
producing new combination vaccines. A combination vaccine Analytics in the area of vaccine economics examines the pur-
contains antigens for immunization against more than one chase of an optimal set of vaccines from a purchaser’s perspec-
infectious disease. tive. Weniger et al. [6] report the results of a pilot study that
The CDC recognizes a number of advantages for using com- applies operations research methods to the economic analysis of
bination vaccines to reduce the number injections required to vaccine formularies. The authors construct an integer program-
satisfy the schedule [22]. The reasons for using combination vac- ming model of the 1997 RCIS, the analysis of which enables
cines include simplifying the administration process, reducing specification of the vaccine formulary that minimizes the cost
the pain and discomfort experienced by children and increasing to fully immunize a child. Jacobson et al. [28] provide a more
Expert Review of Vaccines Downloaded from informahealthcare.com by University of Illinois on 03/09/15

vaccination compliance rates [23–26]. Combination vaccines also detailed mathematical presentation of the model introduced
help alleviate the issue of vaccine injection overcrowding and in [6]. A sensitivity analysis demonstrates how the model selects
offer economic opportunities with respect to the cost of ship- different vaccine formularies depending on the desired eco-
ping, handling and storage of vaccines. nomic criteria. An important economic criterion featured in
However, when considering the merits of combination vac- the model is the cost of injection. The cost of injection cap-
cines, one must also consider the increased cost to manufac- tures direct and indirect costs associated with delivering a single
turers due to the greater complexity of the formulations. immunization injection. Immunization related-activities include
Although there are advantages to reducing the number of injec- routine nursing activities that occur each time an injection is
tions required to satisfy the recommended schedule, bulk pur- given, nonroutine activities that occur at times other than when
chasers and recommending bodies cannot assume that the costs an injection is given, billing activities, immunization registry
of combining vaccines are simply the sum of their component activities, physician time, supplies and medical waste dis-
vaccines. Indeed, in many circumstances further research and posal [29]. Glazner et al. [29,30] conduct empirical analyses of
For personal use only.

development, as well as formulation changes, are required that actual variable costs of vaccine administration among private
increase the cost of combination vaccines [27]. pediatric practices in the Denver metropolitan area using a
microcosting approach; Glazner et al. [29] report an average cost
Vaccine selection of injection of US$ 11.83. Another important component cap-
The advent of new vaccines results in a large, combinatorial tured by cost of injection is the economic value to parents in
number of possible vaccine formularies. TABLE 1 lists the vaccines avoiding extra vaccine injections [23,25]. Kuppermann et al. [23]
(contract ending 31 March 2015) and prices acceptable for and Meyerhoff et al. [25] report willingness-to-pay values of
purchase by immunization programs that receive CDC immu- approximately US$25 per injection avoided.
nization grant funds [12]. The large number of combination Hall et al. [31] introduce the general vaccine formulary selec-
vaccines available provides a plethora of options, affording pur- tion problem, providing fundamental insights into the structure
chasers with different financial considerations more flexibility of problems concerning minimum cost satisfaction of a routine
when selecting a set of vaccines. The challenge for state health childhood immunization schedule. The authors examine the
departments, large city immunization programs, private practi- simultaneous examination of the economic issue of vaccine for-
ces and other vaccine purchasers is to select a vaccine formulary mulary cost and the medical issue of extraimmunization, where
from this set of vaccines so as to cost–effectively satisfy RCIS. extraimmunization is the event that a child receives antigens
for a given disease in excess of the recommended quantity and
Analytics for vaccine selection timing sequence indicated by the schedule. While combination
Operations research is a discipline that applies advanced analyti- vaccines are an attractive alternative over multiple single-
cal methods to improve decision-making. A myriad of antigen vaccines for reasons previously discussed, the use of
problem-solving techniques and methods can be applied, combination vaccines might result in a child being injected
depending on the nature of the problem being examined, to with antigens that they have already received. The authors’
include: simulation, mathematical optimization, stochastic model provides public health policy makers the means to con-
modeling, queuing theory, Markov decision processes, eco- sider tradeoffs between low-cost formularies and avoiding
nomic methods, data analysis, multivariate statistics and deci- extraimmunization.
sion analysis. Many of these techniques involve the creation of Engineer et al. [32] examine the catch-up scheduling problem.
mathematical models to represent the real system under consid- For a child that misses a dose from the RCIS, the attendant
eration. Operations research emphasizes analyses of the theoret- health care provider must construct a catch-up schedule for that
ical properties of the developed models and/or the solution child. The CDC provides rules and guidelines for the administra-
methodologies used to examine them. Analytics is the applica- tion of the remaining doses. Constructing a catch-up schedule
tion of operations research techniques to problems, with an manually is a difficult and time-consuming endeavor; a model
emphasis on practical implementation using data. Analytics that helps health care providers perform such a task can ensure

608 Expert Rev. Vaccines 14(4), (2015)


Analytics for vaccine economics & pricing Review

Table 1. Vaccine price list, contract ending 31 March 2015.


Vaccine Brandname/ Packaging CDC cost Private sector Manufacturer
tradename per dose cost per
(US$) dose (US$)
DTaP DaptacelÒ 10 pack-1 dose vials 15.38 25.98 Sanofi Pasteur
Ò
DTaP Infanrix 10 pack-1 dose vials 15.76 20.96 GlaxoSmithKline
10 pack-1 dose T-L 15.76 21.44
syringes. No needle
DTaP-IPV KinrixÒ 10 pack-1 dose vials 38.50 48.00 GlaxoSmithKline
10 pack-1 dose T-L 38.50 48.00
Expert Review of Vaccines Downloaded from informahealthcare.com by University of Illinois on 03/09/15

syringes
DTaP-Hep B-IPV PediarixÒ 10 pack-1 dose T-L 53.86 70.72 GlaxoSmithKline
syringes, No needle
DTaP-IP-HI PentacelÒ 5 pack-1 dose vials 52.43 80.43 Sanofi Pasteur
Ò
e-IPV IPOL 10 dose vial 12.46 27.44 Sanofi Pasteur
Hepatitis A pediatric VaqtaÒ 10 pack-1 dose vial 16.17 30.37 Merck
10 pack-1 dose syringes 16.17 31.12
Ò
Hepatitis A pediatric Havrix 10 pack-1 dose vials 16.15 28.74 GlaxoSmithKline
10 pack-1 dose T-L 16.15 28.74
For personal use only.

syringes. No needle
Hepatitis A-hepatitis B 18 only TwinrixÒ 10 pack-1 dose vials 52.26 92.50 GlaxoSmithKline
Ò
Hepatitis B Engerix B 10 pack-1 dose vials 11.08 21.37 GlaxoSmithKline
Pediatric/adolescent 10 pack-1 dose T-L 11.08 21.37
syringes, No needle
Hepatitis B Recombivax 10 pack-1 dose vials 11.00 23.20 Merck
Ò
Pediatric/adolescent HB 10 pack-1 dose syringes 11.75 23.95
Ò
Hib PedvaxHIB 10 pack-1 dose vials 12.34 22.77 Merck
Ò
Hib ActHIB 5 pack-1 dose vials 9.36 26.21 Sanofi Pasteur
Ò
HIBMENCY MENHIBRIX 10 pack-1 dose vials 10.10 23.60 GlaxoSmithKline
Ò
HPV – quadrivalent human Gardasil 10 pack-1 dose vials 121.03 141.38 Merck
papillomavirus types 6, 11,
16 and 18 recombinant
HPV – bivalent human CervarixÒ 10 pack-1 dose syringe, 103.85 128.75 GlaxoSmithKline
papillomavirus types 16 and 18 no needle
Meningococcal conjugate MenactraÒ 5 pack-1 dose vial 82.12 112.93 Sanofi Pasteur
(groups A, C, Y and W-135)
Meningococcal Conjugate MenveoÒ 5 pack-1 dose vial 82.12 117.42 Novartis
(Groups A, C, Y and W-135)
MMR M-M-RÒII 10 pack-1 dose vials 19.91 56.14 Merck
Ò
MMR/Varicella ProQuad 10 pack-1 dose vials 103.16 157.64 Merck
Pneumococcal 13-valent Prevnar 13 TM 10 pack-1 dose syringes, 112.44 135.05 Pfizer
(Pediatric) no needle
MMR: Measles, Mumps and rubella.
From [12].

informahealthcare.com 609
Review Robbins & Jacobson

Table 1. Vaccine price list, contract ending 31 March 2015 (cont.).


Vaccine Brandname/ Packaging CDC cost Private sector Manufacturer
tradename per dose cost per
(US$) dose (US$)
Pneumococcal polysaccharide PneumovaxÒ23 10 pack-1 dose vials 41.49 68.29 Merck
(23 Valent)
Rotavirus, live, pral, pentavalent RotaTeqÒ 10 pack-1 dose 2 ml tubes 63.96 75.20 Merck
25 pack-1 dose 2 ml tubes 63.96 75.20
Ò
Rotavirus, live, oral Rotarix 10 pack-1 dose vials 85.04 106.57 GlaxoSmithKline
Ò
Tetanus and diphtheria toxoids Tenivac 10 pack-1 dose syringes, 17.69 22.34 Sanofi Pasteur
Expert Review of Vaccines Downloaded from informahealthcare.com by University of Illinois on 03/09/15

no needle
10 pack-1 dose vials 17.69 22.34
Ò
Tetanus toxoid, reduced Boostrix 10 pack-1 dose vials 30.64 37.55 GlaxoSmithKline
diphtheria toxoid and acellular
pertussis
10 pack-1 dose syringes 30.64 37.55
Ò
Tetanus toxoid, reduced Adacel 10 pack-1 dose vials 30.25 41.06 Sanofi Pasteur
diphtheria toxoid and acellular
pertussis
5 pack-1 dose BD Leur- 30.25 41.06
Lok syringes
For personal use only.

Varicella VarivaxÒ 10 pack-1 dose vials 78.34 94.14 Merck


MMR: Measles, Mumps and rubella.
From [12].

the construction of accurate and complete schedules, resulting in Hib vaccine complements GlaxoSmithKline’s Pediarix (DTaP–
improved immunization coverage rates. The authors design a HepB–IPV) vaccine. If a vaccine purchaser ignores the Merck
dynamic programming algorithm to construct an optimal sched- Hib special property then the economic value of Pentacel
ule for a child given his or her particular age and history. increases. The schedule indicates that a monovalent hep B birth
Smalley et al. [33] provide a more thorough discussion of the deci- dose should be administered to all newborns before hospital
sion support tools created from the research presented in [32]. discharge. If a vaccine purchaser assumes that the birth dose is
A decision support tool that constructs optimal recommended always given and does not account for its cost when designing
catch-up immunization schedules is available online [34]. a vaccine formulary, then a combination vaccine, such as Pedia-
Behzad et al. [35] examine factors that affect pediatric vaccine rix, which includes an extra dose of hep B is regarded as less
market share. The authors focus on the competition between economically valuable due to the extraimmunization.
Pediarix and Pentacel in the 2009–2012 timeframe. Due to the
structure of the recommended childhood schedule, Pediarix Vaccine pricing
and Pentacel are not compatible for use in a single vaccine The question that most relates to vaccine selection is one of
formulary. TABLE 2 shows two possible vaccine formularies, one vaccine pricing. Consider a single vaccine manufacturer. Given
with Pediarix and one with Pentacel. Notice that significant its own set of vaccines, a set of vaccines manufactured by com-
overlap would occur (as indicated by the crosses) should the peting manufacturers, the current schedule as published by the
two combination vaccines be used in the same formulary, CDC, and the understanding that purchasers seek a cost–
resulting in an expensive formulary with substantial extraimmu- effective vaccine formulary, how should the manufacturer price
nization. For relatively higher costs of injection, the lowest cost its vaccines? The pricing determination is complicated by the
formulary is built with Pentacel or Pediarix as a backbone. The complementary nature of the competing vaccines. Moreover,
authors suggest that competition is driven indirectly by the cost of injection may vary quite substantially. A purchaser with
presence of the Merck H. influenzae Type b vaccine and the a relatively low cost of injection does not value the economic
requirement by the schedule of a hepatitis B birth dose. premium associated with reducing the number of injections
A special property of the Merck Hib vaccine is that the administered to satisfy the schedule. A manufacturer would not
6-month dose is not required if the Merck Hib vaccine is want to set the prices of its combination vaccines too high for
administered in the 2- and 4-month time periods. The Merck fear of being nonselected in favor of monovalents. A purchaser

610 Expert Rev. Vaccines 14(4), (2015)


Analytics for vaccine economics & pricing Review

Table 2. Pediarix- and Pentacel-based formularies.


Pediarix + Merck Hib Pentacel + Engerix B
Disease Time period Disease Time period
2-month 4-month 6-month 2-month 4-month 6-month
Hepatitis B Pediarix Pediarix Pediarix Hepatitis B Engerix B – Engerix B
† † † † †
Diphtheria, tetanus, Pediarix Pediarix Pediarix Diphtheria, tetanus, Pentacel Pentacel Pentacel†
pertussis pertussis
Haemophilus PedvaxHIB PedvaxHIB – H. influenzae Type b Pentacel Pentacel Pentacel
influenzae Type b
Polio Pediarix† Pediarix† Pediarix† Polio Pentacel† Pentacel† Pentacel†
Expert Review of Vaccines Downloaded from informahealthcare.com by University of Illinois on 03/09/15


Doses for which Pediarix and Pentacel would overlap (i.e., extraimmunization) if included in the same vaccine formulary.

with a relatively high cost of injection does value the economic Analytics for vaccine pricing
premium associated with reducing the number of injections Analytics in the area of vaccine economics examines the pricing
and is willing to pay higher prices for such vaccines. of vaccines from a manufacturer’s perspective. Sewell et al. [37]
A manufacturer would not want to set the prices of its combi- investigate a vaccine’s maximum inclusion price (i.e., the maxi-
nation vaccines too low for fear of unrealized profit. mum price at which a vaccine is selected by a customer to be
Consider the pricing of a new vaccine. When a new vaccine part of the minimum cost formulary). The authors employ a
is introduced to the market and no current vaccine exists to reverse engineering scheme to determine the maximum inclu-
compete with the product (i.e., no overlapping antigens), the sion price of four combination vaccines not yet licensed for use
vaccine is priced independent of the existing vaccines with the in the USA (at the time of the study). Such results inform the
For personal use only.

intent of recouping sunk cost investments made by the vaccine pricing decision for vaccine manufacturers, based on the suppo-
manufacturer (e.g., Prevnar 13 is priced at US$ 135.05 per dose sition that the purchaser selects its vaccine formulary using a
for private sector purchase). When a new vaccine is introduced minimum cost criterion. Sewell and Jacobson [38] provide a
to the market and a competitive vaccine exists, then the price of more detailed mathematical presentation of the model intro-
the current vaccine influences the price of the new product. duced in [37]. The results presented in these two articles illus-
When considering incremental price increases for established trate how analytics can provide beneficial economic analyses to
vaccines, manufacturers often face difficulties. Section 13631 of pharmaceutical companies that develop and manufacture vac-
the 1993 Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act establishes the cines and assist in the determination of vaccine prices.
VFC program and enables the CDC to negotiate discounted Consider an analysis that focuses on a particular combina-
vaccine prices (i.e., the federal contract prices) [36]. Increasing tion vaccine; Jacobson et al. [39] investigate the pricing of a
the public sector price of more traditional monovalent vaccines hepatitis B–H. influenzae Type b combination vaccine and
for purchase by entities using VFC program funds is limited by compare the reverse engineered price to its public sector price.
law to no greater than the percentage increase in the consumer Results provide insights into the amount of price premium
prices index. The law effectively places a price control on older that is built into the combination vaccine, thereby enabling
monovalents (i.e., those in existence at the time of the the assessment of whether the vaccine is underpriced or over-
1993 law) sold at public sector prices, where the public sector priced based on the value placed on the cost of an injection.
accounts for 55% of the market by volume [4]. Jacobson et al. [40] investigate the maximum inclusion price of
A related issue germane to the vaccine pricing discussion is two pediatric pentavalents based on the 2003 vaccine market.
one of reimbursement to private practice providers by insurance A maximal price comparison between the DTaP–HBV–IPV
companies. Current policy is to reimburse by injection, which and the DTaP–HIB–IPV vaccines is provided, again indicat-
acts as a disincentive for the adoption of combination vaccines; ing how analytics can be used to gain insights into how com-
a better policy might be to reimburse by antigen. Indeed, this bination vaccines can be best fit into pediatric vaccine
reimbursement deficit issue provides an opportunity to use reg- formularies.
ulatory policies to create a more efficient market. Incentivizing Jacobson and Sewell [41] use Monte Carlo simulation to
healthcare providers to use combination vaccines (e.g., reim- assess and quantify the premium associated with four combina-
bursing by antigen, not injection) benefits the consumer due to tion vaccines. Different populations of parents/guardians, as
time savings and less injections, as well the public due to defined by different cost of injection distributions, are consid-
higher vaccine coverage rates. Higher coverage rates save insur- ered in the analysis. Distributions of maximum inclusion prices
ance providers money over time due to less public illness and for each of the four combination vaccines considered are
avoidance of expensive treatments of diseases. Analytics could reported. Moreover, the authors report that the price premiums
be used to examine such an issue. associated with combination vaccines are based on the cost

informahealthcare.com 611
Review Robbins & Jacobson

assigned to administering an injection and that further develop- Sensitivity analysis with respect to the manufacturers’ assumed
ments in this area by vaccine manufacturers may provide signif- production capacity provides upper and lower bounds for vaccine
icant economic and societal benefits. prices in the public sector of the market. Results indicate the
Robbins et al. [42] present a method to optimally price a sin- importance of several model parameters, such as market demand
gle pediatric vaccine so as to maximize a vaccine manufacturer’s and adverse vaccine events on equilibrium prices.
expected revenue given an uncertain cost of injection parame- The results presented in these studies concerning pricing
ter. The authors analyze pricing strategies of directly compet- strategies in the pediatric vaccine market often suggested that
ing, partially overlapping and mutually exclusive combination Pentacel was overpriced. The 2010 federal contract prices for
vaccines in the US pediatric vaccine market and suggest a Pediarix and Pentacel were US$ 48.75 and US$ 51.49 per
method to maximize a pharmaceutical company’s expected rev- dose [44], respectively, with Pediarix US$ 2.74 less expensive. It
enue. Further analysis determines if a combination vaccine is is interesting to note that the latest 2014 federal contract prices
competitively priced when compared to its competitors, for a for Pediarix and Pentacel are US$ 53.86 and US$ 52.43 per
Expert Review of Vaccines Downloaded from informahealthcare.com by University of Illinois on 03/09/15

given suite of federal contract vaccine prices. The proposed dose [12], respectively, with Pentacel US$ 1.43 less expensive. It
pricing approach suggests an appropriate price for a single is reasonable to conclude that the two combinations are now
given combination vaccine, whereby a substantial increase in much more competitively priced and that perhaps such studies
expected revenue can be realized. Results of the analysis of influenced the vaccine manufacturers’ pricing strategies.
Pediarix and Pentacel pricing under 2009 market conditions
suggest that Pentacel is overpriced and that an even split of the Immunization policy: a holistic view of the market
market occurs at a price difference of approximately US$ 1.03. Although examination of the vaccine selection problem is
The results presented in this article suggest that a smaller price framed from the perspective of a single vaccine purchaser and
difference between these two important combination vaccines is examination of the vaccine pricing problem is framed from the
appropriate. The structure of the schedule and the prices of the perspective of a single or a group of competing vaccine manu-
complementing vaccines affect the equilibrium price difference. facturers, a third, holistic perspective exists. Higher level deci-
Behzad et al. [43] examine pricing strategies for pediatric sion makers, such as federal public health agencies and
For personal use only.

combination vaccines by comparing lowest cost formularies recommending bodies, are concerned about regulatory policies
across 3 years (2009–2011). The analysis emphasizes the exami- affecting the long-term viability of the entire vaccine delivery
nation of Sanofi Pasteur’s DTaP–IPV/HI vaccine (Pentacel). system. In this section, we consider a more comprehensive view
The authors suggest that Pentacel could have been more com- of the market from the perspective of a policy-making body.
petitively priced when compared to the competing vaccine, Many public health policy experts address issues concerning
GlaxoSmithKline’s DTaP–HepB–IPV (Pediarix). Maximal pri- the current vaccine delivery system [17,14,46,18,5,47,19]. Vaccine
ces for Pentacel and the attendant lowest cost formulary are pricing remains an important matter of debate with respect to
reported for Pentacel for a fixed cost of injection. Significant short-term consumer fairness and long-term industry viabil-
cost savings for state public health agencies could be realized if ity [4,7]. The expansion of the RCIS and the advent of more
an agency is not already using its lowest cost formulary, which expensive combination vaccines, developed to satisfy new
is itself conditioned on its own cost of injection. schedule requirements, present challenges to the current vaccine
Robbins et al. [44] analyze pricing in the pediatric vaccine delivery system. There are reasonable arguments on both sides
market by creating a game theoretic model. Vaccine manufac- of the debate concerning appropriate vaccine pricing.
turers satisfy demand by appropriately pricing and selling its Ehreth [48] argues that although vaccination is well regarded as
set of vaccines, where each vaccine contains one or more anti- an important public health endeavor, vaccines remain under-val-
gen. Antigens are used to satisfy the dosage requirements (i.e., ued. The author highlights the benefits of disease eradication and
demand) of the 2010 recommended childhood schedule and it control by vaccination in terms of annual life years saved and
is presumed that purchasers select vaccines by seeking a mini- disability-adjusted life years saved. The direct and indirect cost
mum cost vaccine formulary that satisfies the schedule. Results savings for many vaccine-preventable diseases are computed and
of the repeated game equilibrium prices between Pediarix and reported. Recommendations are for international agencies, gov-
Pentacel suggest a price difference of US$ 0.86, assuming the ernments and health policy makers to keep the public aware of
manufacturers agree to share the market equally with respect to the benefits of vaccination so as to not lose financial support.
volume. These results can inform both manufacturers and pur- Kim [9] discusses the role of cost–effectiveness in evaluating vacci-
chasers on the appropriate pricing of combination vaccines, nation policy. The author defines the cost–effectiveness of an
given the existence of a reasonable set of collusive agreements. intervention (e.g., a single vaccine dose or an entire vaccine pro-
Behzad et al. [45] propose an extended game theoretic model to gram) as the additional cost required per additional unit of health
examine the pediatric vaccine market. The authors consider benefit achieved. The cost–effectiveness of vaccines is affected by
capacity-constrained vaccine manufacturers producing differenti- many factors, including vaccine efficacy and durability, govern-
ated monovalent vaccines. Vaccines are differentiated based upon ment regulatory concerns, severity of disease burden, vaccine
the number of reported adverse medical events for that vaccine. price and the costs of the delivery system. Cost–effectiveness
Equilibrium prices are computed for each monovalent vaccine. analysis indicates whether the health gain is worth the cost

612 Expert Rev. Vaccines 14(4), (2015)


Analytics for vaccine economics & pricing Review

compared with other alternative health care investments. budget, leading to even higher costs to treat the subsequent
Zhou et al. [49,50] conduct analyses demonstrating that despite expected increase in disease incidence rates. O’Leary et al. [61]
increased vaccine and administration costs, the US routine child- report the results of as national survey among private pediatri-
hood immunization program remains one of the most cost–effec- cians and family physicians. The high cost of newer vaccines
tive prevention programs in public health. Postma et al. [51] increases financial risks to private vaccination providers; many
provide an economic evaluation of vaccines in Europe. providers indicate dissatisfaction with payment for vaccine pur-
Meyerhoff et al. [52] conduct an analysis to determine how the chase and administration from third party payers. The report
advent of the combination vaccine DTaP–HepB–IPV impacted suggests that some private providers are considering not provid-
immunization coverage rates, number of injections required to ing childhood vaccines. Freed et al. [62] report the results of a
complete the schedule, and costs. The analysis, based on the survey concerning physicians’ attitudes related to vaccine
medical records of 775 children born in 2001 (who received care financing and their private practice; the authors report dissatis-
from 32 private pediatrics centers), indicates that DTaP–HepB– faction with reimbursement levels and increasing financial bur-
Expert Review of Vaccines Downloaded from informahealthcare.com by University of Illinois on 03/09/15

IPV improves coverage rates, reduces the number of vaccine dens from vaccination. Shen et al. [63] examine the financial
injections and reduces costs. Berge et al. [53], Jacobs et al. [54,55] impact to providers using pediatric combination vaccines.
conduct cost–effectiveness analyses of a single monovalent vac- Using data from a subscription remittance billing service
cine, hepatitis A, under different immunization strategies. employed by private practice healthcare providers, the authors
Chuck et al. [56] conduct cost–effectiveness evaluations of the 10- analyze charge and payment information submitted by pro-
and 13-valent pneumococcal conjugate vaccines. viders to insurance payers over a 2-year horizon (2007–2009).
Newall et al. [57] discuss the methodological challenges in Results indicate that providers who administer combination
implementing cost–effectiveness analyses of vaccine programs to vaccines to children incur a reduced payment due to their use
include estimation of disease changes attributable to vaccination of the combination vaccine. Gidengil et al. [64] conduct a sur-
efforts, evaluation of the hypothetical no vaccination scenario vey of pediatricians, state immunization program managers and
and evaluation of the full benefit achieved by executing a vacci- health insurance plan representatives concerning the use of
nation program. The authors suggest adopting the practice of combination vaccines. Respondents note that high prices, low
For personal use only.

retrospective analyses in which disease surveillance data, the reimbursement for vaccine costs and the loss of fees for vaccine
evolution of vaccine prices over time and vaccine uptake data administration act as financial barriers to the use of combina-
are collected and used to create more robust cost–effectiveness tion vaccines. The common theme pervading such analyses is
analyses. Moreover, the authors suggest that vaccines should be the existence of economic barriers to the ideal execution of an
evaluated on an individual basis so that vaccines that are not immunization program. Lieu et al. [65] discuss overcoming such
cost–effective are not recommended simply because the aggre- economic barriers, suggesting that increased public and private
gate immunization program is cost–effective. sector financing for vaccines is necessary to close the gaps in
Note that cost–effectiveness studies are typically used to vaccine financing and development.
inform the decision making of recommending bodies. Such
studies do not directly inform vaccine selection decisions. Indi- Analytics for informing immunization policy
vidual practice vaccine selection is driven by effectiveness, con- Public health policy studies often argue for the joint consider-
venience, brand loyalty, formulary inertia, financial profit, ation of pediatric vaccine pricing and purchasing in the USA vac-
sustainability, flexibility, risk mitigation of shortages and many cine market. The use of analytics enables the simultaneous
other pertinent issues. treatment of the vaccine selection and pricing issues. Robbins
System stakeholders often provide suggestions regarding the and Jacobson [66] present an operations research approach that
vaccine industry’s viability [58,59]. Such suggestions often entail addresses the issue of the pediatric vaccine industry’s continuing
financial incentives [17] or seek to address regulatory concerns [8]. viability from the perspective of the CDC. The monopsonistic
For example, Hinman [16] advises determining a vaccine’s price market power of the federal government uniquely positions it to
in advance based on its estimated social value. McGuire [60] significantly influence the pediatric vaccine market by negotiating
presents an economic model to determine such prices, reporting contractual agreements that increase the vaccine manufacturers’
that although vaccines have high social value, the vaccine manu- financial incentives to remain in the market. The fundamental
facturers do not receive appropriate financial incentives for par- premise of the analysis is the supposition that the CDC desires to
ticipation in the market. Indeed, many public health experts negotiate pediatric vaccine prices and determine purchase quanti-
contend that vaccine manufacturers should earn higher returns ties to minimize the vaccine system’s delivery costs while also
on their investments to sustain and expand the production of ensuring that the pharmaceutical companies manufacturing the
vaccines. Market contraction negatively impacts the safe, reli- pediatric vaccines each earn a profit that induces them to remain
able provision of vaccines and places public health at risk. in the market. Robbins and Jacobson [66] present a model that
However, viewed from the perspective of the vaccine pur- minimizes the weighted sum of the cost to fully immunize a birth
chasers, lower prices are desired; higher prices may cause large cohort according to a given childhood immunization schedule.
groups of patients in publicly funded programs to go unvacci- The model determines optimal vaccine prices and purchase
nated as fewer vaccines would be purchased for a fixed program quantities while ensuring that each vaccine manufacturer earns at

informahealthcare.com 613
Review Robbins & Jacobson

least a reservation amount of profit, with vaccine production seek formulary pricing. This bundling of products will offer
quotas, capacities and price caps respected. The model can be advantages to both customers and vaccine manufacturers. The
used to design a pricing and purchasing policy for the CDC that challenges facing the pediatric vaccine market are many; signifi-
establishes a sustainable and stable capital investment environ- cantly more collaboration between stakeholders will be neces-
ment in which the reliable provision of pediatric vaccines (so sary to facilitate appropriate pricing. It is in the interest of
essential to public health) can occur. both the pharmaceutical industry and the vaccine purchasers to
pursue a healthy economic relationship in the interests of long-
Expert commentary term market stability.
Analytics can aid market participants in making more informed
decisions regarding the pricing and purchasing of vaccines in Acknowledgements
the US pediatric vaccine market. The compendium of results The authors would like to thank LE Rodewald, Director, Immunization
reviewed in this article provides approaches to understand the Services Division, National Center for Immunization and Respiratory
Expert Review of Vaccines Downloaded from informahealthcare.com by University of Illinois on 03/09/15

impact of vaccine selection and pricing on pediatric vaccine Diseases, CDC (GA, USA), and JA Jokela, Head, Department of Inter-
markets. A meaningful understanding of important issues nal Medicine, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign (IL, USA),
affecting the market can be gained. It is important for stake- for their longstanding encouragement and feedback on this line of
holders to comprehend the consequences of their own actions research. The authors also thank the Commissioning Editor and two
as well the actions of other stakeholders. Such information can anonymous referees for their insightful comments and suggestions, result-
be leveraged to improve a single stakeholder’s position or influ- ing in an improved manuscript.
ence policy decisions that affect the market in its entirety, for
the betterment of all parties involved. Disclaimer
The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and do not
Five-year view reflect the official policy or position of the US Air Force, Department of
Over the next 5 years, new vaccines will be added to the RCIS. Defense, National Science Foundation, or the US Government.
Vaccine manufacturers will attempt to address the congestion
For personal use only.

in the schedule by creating new, more complex combination Financial & competing interests disclosure
vaccines. Such vaccines will be expensive, as vaccine manufac- This research has been supported in part by the National Science Founda-
turers seek a return on their research and development invest- tion (CMMI-1161458). The authors have no other relevant affiliations
ments. The cost to complete the RCIS will continue to grow. or financial involvement with any organization or entity with a financial
The resulting cost burden will challenge public immunization interest in or financial conflict with the subject matter or materials dis-
programs and private practices operating on limited budgets. cussed in the manuscript apart from those disclosed.
Instead of individual vaccine pricing, market participants may No writing assistance was utilized in the production of this manuscript.

Key issues
• Large-scale immunization programs in the USA are a successful and cost–effective public health endeavor, profoundly reducing
mortalities caused by infectious diseases.
• The pediatric vaccine industry consists of a relatively small number of pharmaceutical firms (i.e., companies, manufacturers) engaged in
the research, development, manufacture and distribution of pediatric vaccines.
• The number of firms that produce vaccines for the US market has steadily decreased since the 1960s; in 1967, 37 vaccine
manufacturers operated in the USA, whereas only five vaccine manufacturers operate as of 2014.
• The determination of appropriately priced vaccines is an important issue and influences a vaccine manufacturer’s decision to remain in
the market.
• The recommended childhood immunization schedule, published annually by the CDC, continues to expand with respect to the number
of injections required and the number of vaccines available for selection.
• In the 1980s, the schedule required children to receive a total of five shots by the time they were 2 years old and not more than one
shot at a single clinic visit; as of 2014, the schedule requires children to receive a total of 24 shots by the time they are 2 years old and
up to six shots in a single visit.
• The challenge for state health departments, large city immunization programs, private practices and other vaccine purchasers is to select
a cost–effective vaccine formulary from this set of vaccines so as to cost–effectively satisfy recommended childhood
immunization schedule.
• Operations research is a discipline that applies advanced analytical methods to improve decision-making; analytics is the application of
operations research to a particular problem using pertinent data to provide a practical result.
• Analytics provides a mechanism to resolve the challenges facing stakeholders in the vaccine development and delivery system.

614 Expert Rev. Vaccines 14(4), (2015)


Analytics for vaccine economics & pricing Review

References National center for health statistics; 24. LeBaron CW, Rodewald L, Humiston S.
Hyattsville, MD How much time is spent on well-child care
Papers of special note have been highlighted as:
• of interest 12. Centers for disease control and prevention. and vaccinations? Arch Pediatr Adolesc Med
• of considerable interest Vaccine price list (Contract ending 1999;153(11):1154
31 March 2015. Available from: www.cdc. 25. Meyerhoff AS, Weniger BG, Jacobs RJ,
1. Plotkin SL, Plotkin SA. A short history of
gov/vaccines/programs/vfc/awardees/vaccine- et al. Economic value to parents of reducing
vaccination. Chap. 1 of Plotkin S,
management/price-list/index.html [Last the pain and emotional distress of
Orenstein W, Offit P, eds. Vaccines. 2012.
accessed 23 July 2014] childhood vaccine injections. Pediatr Infect
6 Saunders
13. Food and drug administration. Vaccines Dis J 2001;20(11):S57-62
2. Whitney CG, Zhou F, Singleton J,
licensed for immunization and distribution 26. Pellissier JM, Coplan PM, Jackson LA,
Schuchat A. Benefits from immunization
in the United States. [Accessed 3 September May JE. The effect of additional shots on
during the vaccines for children program
2014] the vaccine administration process: results of
era - United States, 1994-2013. MMWR
14. Lieu TA, Thompson KM, Prosser LA, et al. a time-motion study in 2 settings. Am J
Morb Mortal Wkly Rep 2014;63(16):352-5
Expert Review of Vaccines Downloaded from informahealthcare.com by University of Illinois on 03/09/15

Emerging issues in vaccine economics: Manag Care 2000;6(9):1038


3. Elam-Evans LD, Yankey D, et al. National,
perspectives from the USA. Expert Rev 27. Mahmood K, Pelkowski S, Atherly D, et al.
State, and Selected local area vaccination
Vaccines 2002;1(4):433-42 Hexavalent IPV-based combination vaccines
coverage among children aged
15. Rappuoli R, Miller HI, Falkow S. The for public-sector markets of low-resource
19-35 months- United States, 2013.
intangible value of vaccination. Science countries. Hum Vaccin Immunother 2013;
MMWR Morb Mortal Wkly Rep 2014;
2002;297(5583):937-9 9(9):1894-902
63(34):741-8
16. Hinman AR. Financing vaccines in the 21st 28. Jacobson SH, Sewell EC, Deuson R, et al.
4. Douglas RG, Samant VB. The vaccine
century: recommendations from the national An integer programming model for vaccine
industry. Chap. 3 of Plotkin S, Walter O,
vaccine advisory committee. Am J Prev Med procurement and delivery for childhood
Paul O, editor. Vaccines. 2012. 6th edn
2005;29(1):71-5 immunization: a pilot study. Health Care
Saunders
Manage Sci 1999;2:1-9
5. Orenstein WA, Douglas RG, Rodewald LE, 17. Kaufmann JR, Miller R, Cheyne J. Vaccine
supply chains need to be better funded and 29. Glazner JE, Beaty B, Berman S. Cost of
et al. Immunizations in the United States:
For personal use only.

strengthened, or lives will be at risk. Health vaccine administration among pediatric


success, structure, and stress - a complex
Aff 2011;30(6):1113-21 practices. Pediatrics 2009;124(Suppl 5):
collaboration involving government,
S492-8
industry, providers, academe, professional 18. Offit PA. Why are pharmaceutical
societies, and third-party payers. Health Aff companies gradually abandoning vaccines? 30. Glazner JE, Beaty BL, Pearson KA,
2005;24(3):599-610 Health Aff 2005;24(3):622-30 Berman S. The cost of giving childhood
vaccinations: differences among provider
6. Weniger BG, Chen RT, Jacobson SH, et al. 19. Sloan FA, Berman S, Rosenbaum S, et al.
types. Pediatrics 2004;113(6):1582-7
Addressing the challenges to immunization The fragility of the US vaccine supply. N
practice with an economic algorithm for Engl J Med 2004;351:2443-7 31. Hall SN, Jacobson SH, Sewell EC. An
vaccine selection. Vaccine 1998;16(19): analysis of pediatric vaccine formulary
20. Helfand C. Advair slide, China woes
1885-97 selection problems. Oper Res 2008;56(6):
drop-kick Glaxo profits in Q1. http://www.
1348-65
•• Initial operations research effort to fiercepharma.com/story/advair-slide-china-
inform health care provider vaccine woes-drop-kick-glaxo-profits-q1/2014-04-30 32. Engineer FG, Keskinocak P, Pickering LK.
selection decisions. [Accessed 27 October] 2014 Catch-up scheduling for childhood
vaccination. Oper Res 2009;57(6):1307-19
7. Jacobson SH. Vaccine pricing: how can we 21. Centers for disease control and prevention.
get it right? Expert Rev Vaccines 2012; History of vaccine schedule. Available from: 33. Smalley HK, Keskinocak P, Engineer FG,
11(10):1163-5 http://www.chop.edu/service/vaccine- et al. Universal tool for vaccine scheduling:
education-center/vaccine-schedule/history-of- applications for children and adults.
8. Cox MMJ, Onraedt A. Innovations in
vaccine-schedule.html [Last] [accessed Interfaces 2011;41(5):436-54
vaccine development: can regulatory
authorities keep up? Expert Rev Vaccines 23 July 2014] 34. Catch up immunization scheduler. Available
2012;11(10):1171-3 22. Centers for disease control and prevention. from: www.vacscheduler.org/
9. Kim JJ. The role of cost-effectiveness in US Combination vaccines for childhood 35. Behzad B, Jacobson SH, Jokela JA,
vaccination policy. N Engl J Med 2011; immunization, recommendations of the Sewell EC. The relationship between
365(19):1760-1 Advisory Committee on Immunization pediatric combination vaccines and market
Practices (ACIP), American Academy of effects. Am J Public Health 2014;104(6):
10. Centers for disease control and prevention.
Pediatrics (AAP), and American Academy of 998-1004
Advisory Committee on Immunization
Family Physicians (AAFP). Morbidity and • Examines the market factors that affect
Practices (ACIP) Recommended
Mortality Weekly Report 1999;48(RR-4): pediatric vaccine uptake in the US public
immunization schedules for persons aged
1-15
0 through 18 years- United States, 2014. sector vaccine market with a particular
MMWR Morb Mortal Wkly Rep 2014; 23. Kuppermann M, Nease RF, Ackerson LM, emphasis on Pediarix and Pentacel.
63(5):108-9 et al. Parents’ preferences for outcomes
36. Centers for disease control and prevention.
associated with childhood vaccinations.
11. Hamilton BE, Martin JA, Osterman MJK, Vaccines for children program. Available
Pediatr Infect Dis J 2000;19(2):129
Curtin SC. Births: Preliminary data for from: www.cdc.gov/vaccines/programs/vfc/
2013. National vital statistics reports 2.

informahealthcare.com 615
Review Robbins & Jacobson

about/vac-supply-policy/ [Last accessed vaccine markets with linear demand. Tech 57. Newall AT, Reyes JF, Wood JG, et al.
29 October 2014] report. University of Illinois; USA Economic evaluations of implemented
37. Sewell EC, Jacobson SH, Weniger BG. 46. Lindley MC, Shen AK, Orenstein WA, vaccination programmes: key
Reverse engineering a formulary selection et al. Financing the delivery of vaccines to methodological challenges in retrospective
algorithm to determine the economic value children and adolescents: challenges to the analyses. Vaccine 2014;32(7):759-65
of pentavalent and hexavalent combination current system. Pediatrics 2009; 58. Klein JO, Myers MG. Strengthening the
vaccines. Pediatr Infect Dis J 2001;20(11): 124(Suppl 5):S548-57 supply of routinely administered vaccines in
S45-56 47. Poland GA, Marcuse EK. Vaccine the United States: problems and proposed
• Examines the price premium associated availability in the US: problems and solutions. Clin Infect Dis 2006;42(Suppl 3):
with combination vaccines. solutions. Nat Immunol 2004;5(12):1195-8 S97-S103

38. Sewell EC, Jacobson SH. Using an integer 48. Ehreth J. The global value of vaccination. 59. Shen AK, Rodewald LE, Birkhead GS.
programming model to determine the price Vaccine 2003;21(7):596-600 Perspective of vaccine manufacturers on
of combination vaccines for childhood financing pediatric and adolescent vaccines
49. Zhou F, Santoli J, Messonnier ML, et al.
Expert Review of Vaccines Downloaded from informahealthcare.com by University of Illinois on 03/09/15

immunization. Ann Oper Res 2013;119: in the United States. Pediatrics 2009;
Economic evaluation of the 7-vaccine
261-84 124(Suppl 5):S540-7
routine childhood immunization schedule in
39. Jacobson SH, Karnani T, Sewell EC. the United States, 2001. Arch Pediatr 60. McGuire TG. Setting prices for new
Analyzing the economic value of the Adolesc Med 2005;159(12):1136-44 vaccines (in Advance). Int J Health Care
hepatitis B-Haemophilus influenzae type b Finance Econ 2003;3:207-24
50. Zhou F, Shefer A, Wenger J, et al.
combination vaccine by reverse engineering Economic evaluation of the routine 61. O’Leary ST, Allison MA, Lindley MC,
a formulary selection algorithm. Vaccine childhood immunization program in the et al. Vaccine financing from the perspective
2003;21(17):2169-77 United States, 2009. Pediatrics 2014;133(4): of primary care physicians. Pediatrics 2014;
40. Jacobson S, Sewell EC, Karnani T. 577-85 133(3):367-74
Engineering the economic value of two 51. Postma MJ, Westra TA, Quilici S, 62. Freed GL, Cowan AE, Clark SJ. Primary
pediatric combination vaccines. Health Care Largeron N. Economic evaluation of care physician perspectives on
Manage Sci 2005;8(1):29-40 vaccines: specificities and future challenges reimbursement for childhood
immunizations. Pediatrics 2008;122(6):
For personal use only.

41. Jacobson SH, Sewell EC. Using Monte illustrated by recent European examples.
Carlo Simulation to Deter- mine Expert Rev Vaccines 2013;12(5):555-65 1319-24
Combination Vaccine Price Distributions 52. Meyerhoff AS, Greenberg DP, Jacobs RJ. 63. Shen AK, Sobczyk E, Simonsen L, et al.
for Childhood Disease. Health Care Manag Predicted effects of a new combination Financial impact to providers using pediatric
Sci 2002;5(2):135-45 vaccine on childhood immunization combination vaccines. Pediatrics 2011;
42. Robbins MJ, Jacobson SH, Sewell EC. coverage rates and vaccination activities. Dis 128(6):1087-93
Pricing strategies for combination pediatric Manag Health Outcomes 2005;13(5): 64. Gidengil CA, Rusinak D, et al. Financial
vaccines and their impact on revenue: 317-26 barriers to implementing combination
pediarix or Pentacel? Health Care Manag 53. Berge JJ, Drennan DP, Jacobs RJ, et al. vaccines: perspectives from pediatricians and
Sci 2010;13(1):54-64 The cost of hepatitis a infections in policy makers. Clin Pediatr (Phila) 2009;
48(5):539-47
• Examines vaccine manufacturer pricing American adolescents and adults in 1997.
strategies for pediatric combination Hepatology 2000;31(2):469-73 65. Lieu TA, McGuire TG, Hinman AR.
vaccines. 54. Jacobs RJ, Greenberg DP, Koff RS, et al. Overcoming economic barriers to the
Regional variation in the cost effectiveness optimal use of vaccines. Health Aff 2005;
43. Behzad B, Jacobson SH, Sewell EC. Pricing
of childhood hepatitis a immunization. 24(3):666-79
strategies for combination pediatric vaccines
based on the lowest overall cost formulary. Pediatr Infect Dis J 2003;22(10):904-14 66. Robbins MJ, Jacobson SH. Pediatric vaccine
Expert Rev Vaccines 2012;11(10):1189-97 55. Jacobs RJ, Meyerhoff AS, Zink T. Hepatitis procurement policy: the monopsonist’s
a immunization strategies: universal versus problem. Omega 2011;39(6):589-97
44. Robbins MJ, Jacobson SH, Shanbhag UV,
Behzad B. The weighted set covering game: targeted approaches. Clin Pediatr (Phila) • Introduces model to inform vaccine
a vaccine pricing model for pediatric 2005;44(8):705-9 pricing negotiations between government
immunization. Informs J Comp 2014;26(1): 56. Chuck AW, Jacobs P, Tyrrell G, Kellner JD. and industry.
183-98 Pharmacoeconomic evaluation of 10-and
45. Behzad B, Jacobson SH, Robbins MJ. 13-valent pneumococcal conjugate vaccines.
A symmetric capacity-constrained Vaccine 2010;28(33):5485-90
differentiated oligopoly model for pediatric

616 Expert Rev. Vaccines 14(4), (2015)

View publication stats

You might also like