You are on page 1of 6

ISSN 1392-1258.

EKONOMlKA 2004 68

TAX COMPETITION AND ASYMMETRIC COUNTRIES

Anton Jevcak
Research Assistant, University of Dortmund
LS Offentliche Finanzen, Vogelpothsweg 87,
44221 Dortmund, Germany
jevcak@gmx.de
Tel: +49 231 755 3440,
Fax: +49 231 755 5404

This paper explores the consequences of a difference in the levels of public inputs accumulated over
time in a small open economy model where capital tax revenues are used exclusively for the provision
of public inputs, while the government sets the capital tax rate in way to maximise its country's natio-
nal income. It is shown that in this case the optimal capital tax rate in a country is a decreasing func-
tion of its stock of accumulated public inputs. The model thus implies that capital tax harmonisation
could actually be detrimental to the so-called core EU member states as it could fix their capital tax
rates at an in-optimally high levels and thus hinder their ability to dampen undesirable capital out-
flows.
Keywords: tax competition; public inputs; capital mobility; asymmetric countries

Introduction more difficult to find a single tax rate or a lo-


wer bound on corporate tax rates suitable for
The latest enlargement of the EU brought to-
the whole EU.
gether a group of countries which are more Krogstrup (2004, p. 14) in one of the latest
heterogeneous sthan ever before. Apart from surveys of the capital tax competition literatu-
having significantly different levels of per ca- re notices that only a few papers have so far
pita GDP these countries offer potential fo- analysed tax competition among asymmetric
reign investors different levels of the so-cal- countries. Moreover, the source of asymmet-
led industrial public goods/publicly provided ry in the countries' factor endowments has un-
inputs while charging diverse tax rates. This til now been only restricted to the private fac-
increased heterogeneity might be seen as a re- tors of production, notably capital and labour
ason for corporate tax harmonisation in the (Bucovetsky, 1991; Wilson, 1991).
EU, as it might be argued that the need for a The main implication of these models is
"fair" framework for capital investment com- that a country with a larger population expe-
petition within the internal market has increa- riences a lower elasticity of capital to the tax
sed. On the other hand, it might also be argu- rate, that is a lower marginal cost of public
ed that the increased heterogeneity makes it funds, and thus sets a higher tax rate than does

56
the country with a smaller population. Both puts accumulated over time in a small open
models, however, are based on the assumption economy model, where capital tax revenues are
that governments levy taxes on capital in or- used exclusively for the provision of public in-
der to finance the provision of public goods puts, while the government sets the capital tax
which only benefit their countries' populations rate in way to maximise its country's national
and have no impact on capital productivity. income. It is shown that in this case the opti-
Hence, the models' conclusions are driven by mal capital tax rate in a country is a decrea-
the discrepancy between the government's sing function of its stock of accumulated pub-
budget revenue and expenditure side, or in ot- lic inputs.
her words, only the revenue side of public sec- The paper can be viewed as a contribution
tor plays a role in these models. to the debate about capital tax harmonisation
Tax systems designed in this way have be- in the enlarged EU where the new member
en criticised, among others, by McLure (1986) states offer both significantly lower levels of
or Salin (1990) who suggested that the tax re- accumulated public inputs and lower capital
venue structure in a country should more clo- tax rates than the old member states while ne-
sely reflect the expenditure structure. That is, eding to attract as much FDI as possible. Con-
public goods provided to increase the welfare trary to the traditional view, the model offe-
of citizens should be paid for by taxation of red here implies that capital tax harmonisa-
citizens, while the supply of public inputs that tion could actually be detrimental to the so-
enhances capital productivity should be finan- called core EU member states as it could fix
ced by capital taxation. their capital tax rates at sub-optimally high le-
Furthermore, governmentally provided in- vels and thus hinder their ability to dampen
puts like infrastructure, education, national undesirable capital outflows.
defence or effective police and legal system, This interpretation is supported by the Ap-
which also influence the locational decisions ril 2004 World Economic Outlook (WEO)
of capital investments, have to be built up over which analysed structural reforms in 20 indust-
many years and thus their levels cannot be ad- rial countries (13 elder EU member states + 7
justed instantaneously. There is therefore in non-EU countries) over the past three deca-
the given period no perfect correlation betwe- des. It showed that contrary to the financial
en the total public revenues and the overall le- sector, selected product markets and interna-
vels of provided public inputs, as these are also tional merchandise trade, labour markets and
determined by history and geography. tax systems underwent only minor reforms in
Nevertheless,' although countries differ in this period. Furthermore, the WEO offered
the levels of government-provided inputs, the empirical evidence in favour of the "back-
models of tax competition with public inputs, against-the-wall" argument which states that
to my knowledge, have so far always assumed difficult economic conditions stimulate the re-
identical jurisdictions (see, for instance, Zod- form process (IMF, 2004).
row and Mieszkowski, 1986; Fuest, 1995; Bay- It can thus be argued that because of the
indir-Upmann, 1998, or Rauscher, 1997). significantly worse economic conditions over
Hence, this paper explores the consequen- the last decade the new member states have
ces of a difference in the levels of public in- been forced to adjust their capital tax rates clo-

57
ser to the optimal levels, while the capital tax after-tax profit per unit of capital has to equal
rates in the older member states still need to the world rate of interest, R > 0, that is
be substantially corrected. As a result, harmo-
nising capital tax rates at the levels currently (2)
observed in the so-called core EU member sta-
tes would only induce unwanted capital out- Differentiating this capital market arbitra-
flows from the whole enlarged EU, while allo- ge condition with respect to the tax rate while
wing for tax competition could finally force the substituting for G from equation (1) reveals that
older member states to cut their capital tax ra-
tes closer to the optimal levels.

A simple model Solving equation (3) for KT gives

A small open economy is modelled. It offers


the capital located at its territory (K) an in-
(4)
dustrial public good (G) which consists of a
stock of public inputs accumulated over time
(as > 0) and of public inputs financed through Equation (4) indicates that if the govern-
capital taxation (G1). Setting GT = TK, where ment provided public inputs at the level whe-
T > 0 is a tax rate on a unit of capital invested re the marginal decrease in capital income in-
in the country, implies that in the given period duced by a higher capital tax rate (dTK) is exac-
tly equal to the increase in the capital income
G = GS + TK. (1) generated by a marginal increase in the public
input provision (YKcJ<dTK), then a marginal
The stock of public inputs accumulated change in Twould have no impact on the stock
over time, as, stands for publicly provided in- of capital located in the small open economy
puts like infrastructure, educated workforce, (KT = 0).
national defence and effective police and le- The national income of a country is in this
gal system which have been built up over the model given by its domestic production (Y) mi-
years and are thus independent of the current nus the tax revenues (TK) and minus the inco-
tax revenues. me earned by the foreign capital invested the-
There is a single aggregate good which can
re R(K - K) , where K denotes the stock of
be either consumed or used as a production
capital owned by the home country's citizens.
input. The aggregate good is produced accor-
Suppose that the government sets the capital
ding to a neoclassical production function Y
tax rate T as to maximise its country's national
(K, G) exhibiting non-increasing returns to sca-
income, that is
le in the two production inputs K and G, with
YIl' YG > 0, YKK' YGG < 0 and YKG > 0, where the
MaxT Y -TK -R(K -K) ,
subscripts indicate the respective derivatives.
As capital is perfectly mobile between the hence YK(KT)+YG(K+TK T )-
small open economy and the rest of the world, - K - TK T - RK T = 0 . (5)

58
Substituting for YK from equation (2) then vision through a positive tax rate levied on the
implies that capital invested at its territory. This is assumed
to be the case, since in the dynamic context
(which is ignored here for the sake of analyti-
cal tractability) with a positive depreciation ra-
Using a production function of the form Y te of the stock of public inputs, a capital tax
= KaGIl, with a + ~ < 11, rearranging equa- rate equal to zero could not be sustained in
tion (4) and subsequently substituting for G the long run as eventually aGs < ~RK would
and YKfrom equations (1) and (2) leads to be fulfilled for aT> O.

Differentiating equation (9) with respect to


GS then shows that
(7)

(10)

In order to determine K os , the capital


Equation (6) can in this case be rewritten as market arbitrage condition has to be differen-
tiated with respect to GS which implies that

~K(R+T) (K +
a(G s + TK) (11)

s
+ T(l-13(G +TK)-I(R+T)K) )=K and thus that
(a-l)(R+T)K-1 +13(G s +TK)-l(R+T)T .

(8)
(12)
Solving equation (8) for T gives

Using again the production function of the


form Y = KaGIl, with a + ~ < 1, equation (12)
T (9)
can be rearranged so that

Equation (9) reveals that if the country's


stock of accumulated public inputs is relative-
ly small compared to the level of capital inves-
ted there (aGs < ~RK), then the government
~K
has an incentive to increase public input pro- (13)
(a-1)(G S +KT)+~KT·

1 As discussed in Rauscher (1997), the upper limit of Equation (13) demonstrates that Kos is
unity should be well above any reasonable estimates of
a+l3· always positive as the denominator of the ra-

59
tio on the RHS of equation (13) is always ne- ases in the amount of public inputs already of-
gative for a + P < 1. This is an intuitive result, fered by the given country.3 Therefore, a coun-
as a higher stock of accumulated public inputs try with a higher stock of accumulated public
makes the given country a more attractive lo- inputs should have a lower incentive to incre-
cation for capital investment. ase capital tax rates.
Finally, substituting equation (13) into equ-
ation (10) gives Conclusion
This paper is an attempt to complement the
rather scarce literature on capital tax compe-
(a-l)G+pKT)K tition among asymmetric countries. It focused
on the so far ignored aspect of the asymmetry
among the countries that differ in the levels of
public inputs accumulated over time, while as-
suming that the public expenditure structure
closely reflects the public revenue structure,
The expression in brackets can be shown
i.e. is that capital tax revenues are used exclu-
to be always positive as
sively on the provision of public inputs.
The simple model offered in this paper de-
pG S monstrates that a less developed country (a
{ + 1> 0 (15)
\(a-l)G s +(a+p-l)KT) country with a smaller stock of public inputs)
trying to maximise its national income should
set a higher capital tax rate than a more deve-
can be rewritten as
loped country (a country with a larger stock of
public inputs) which is also trying to maximise
pG S < ((l-a)G s +(l-a-p)KT) (16) its national income. This is caused by the fact
that the positive impact of public input provi-
which holds for all a + p < 1,2 Hence, equa- sion on capital productivity decreases in the
tion (14) implies that the optimal capital tax overall level of public inputs provided.
rate of a small open economy is a decreasing This conclusion is in direct contradiction
function of its stock of accumulated public in- to the situation currently observed in the en-
puts. larged EU and to the usual arguments for tax
This result is induced by the concave as- harmonisation in the EU. If, however, the
pect of the production function (YKGG < 0) "back-against-the-wall" argument is accepted,
which implies that the positive impact of a ca- that is if one believes that the harsher econo-
pital tax financed marginal increase in public mic conditions forced the new member states
input provision on capital productivity decre-

3 This concave aspect disappears in the case of a +13 = 1,


as a decrease in the marginal productivity of public input
2In the case of a +13 = 1, the RHS of equation (14) is
implied by its larger accumulated stock is in this case exac-
equal to zero and thus the optimal capital tax rate of a
tly offset by a capital inflow induced by a larger provision
small open economy in this case does not depend on its
of public input.
stock of accumulated public inputs.

60
to adjust their capital tax rates closer to the sing capital tax rates at the sub-optimally high
optimallevels while the capital tax rates in the levels presently observed in the so-called core
elder inember states do not reflect efficien- EU member states would not only further hin-
cy consideration, then the model's implica- der the ability of these countries to drive down
tions for the enlarged EU become more ap- the unwanted capital outflows, but it would al-
parent. so dampen the economic development in the
In this case, it can be argued that harmoni- new member states.

REFERENCES

Bayindir·Upmann, T. (1998) 1\vo games of inter- Rauscher, M. (1997) lntetjurisdiclional competition


jurisdictional compelition when local governments and. the efficiency of the public seeIor: the triumph of
provide induslrial public goods, InterntJtiofllJl Tax and. the markeI over the slate? London: The Centre for
Public Finance 5: 471-487. Economic Policy Research, CEPR Discussion Paper
Bucovetsky, S. (1991) Asymmetric tax competi- No. 1624.
lion, JoumtJl of Ulban Economics 30: 167-81. Salin, P. (1990) Comment on Vito Thnzi and
Fuest, C. (1995) Interjurisdictional competition A. Lan. Bovenberg "I. There a Need for Harmoni-
and public expenditure: is tax co-ordination counter- zing Capital Income Taxes within EC Countries?",
productive?, Finanzarchiv NF 52: 478-496. in: H. Siebert (ed.) Reforming Capital Income Taxa-
IMF (2004), World economic outlook analysis: how lion, Tūbingen·Mohr, pp.198-205.
can industrial countries overcome obstacles to struc- WIlson, J.D. (1991) Thx competition with interre-
tural reform?, IMF Survey 33: 104-106. gionai differences in factor endowments, Regionai
Krogstrup, S. (2004) A syntbesis of recent deve· Science and Ulban Economics 21: 423-52.
lopments in the theory of capital tax competition, Zodrow, G.R. and P. Mieszkowski (1986) Pigou,
EPRU Worlcing Paper Series 2004-02. Tiebout, property taxation, and the underprovision
McLure, C.E. (1986) Tax competition: is what's of local public goods, JoumtJl of Ulban Economics
good for the private goose also good for the public 19(3): 356-70.
gander? National Tax JourntJl 39: 341-348.

MOKESČIŲ KONKURENCIJA IR ASIMETRIŠKOS ŠALYS

AllIon Je\'tak
Santrauka

Straipsnyje nagrinėjami klausimai, susij~ su pa- mą gali būtinustatyti neoptimaliai dideli jų turto
darniais, esant skirtingiems visuomeninių indėlių, su- mokesčio tarifai ir taip trukdoma jų galimybėm••u·
kauptų per tam tikrą laiką mažos atviros ekonomi- mažinti nepageidaujamus turto nuotėkius. Straips-
kos atveju, lygiams, kai turto mokesčių jplaukos yra niu bandoma papildyti litera turą apie nesimetriškų
panaudojamos tik visuomeninių indėlių aprūpinimui, šalių turto mokesčio palyginimą. Publikacijoje susi·
o vykdomoji valdžia nustato turto mokesčio tarifą, teikta ties mažai paisomu aspektu dėl asimetrijos
kad padidintų savo šalies nacionalines pajamas. Tai- tarp šalių, joms per laiką sukaupiant skirtingo dydžio
gi optimalus turto mokesčio tarifas šalyje yra mažė­ visuomeninių indėlių, tariant, kad visuomeninių
janti sukaupto kiekio visuomeninių indėlių funkcija. sąnaudų struktūra gerai atspindi visuomeninių pa·
Modelis parodo, kad turto mokesčio suderinimas gali jamų struktūrą, t. y. kad turto mokesčio jplaukos
iš tikrųjų būti nuostolingas vadinamosioms ES šer- yra naudojamos tik visuomeniniams indėliams ap·
dies šalims narėms, kadangi atliekant harmonizavi- rūpinti.

{teikta 2004 m. rugpjūčio mėn.

61

You might also like