You are on page 1of 36

Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

Accepted Manuscript
The Singapore Economic Review
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

Article Title: Wage Discrimination in India’s Formal and Informal Labour markets

Author(s): Bhaskar Jyoti Neog, Bimal Kishore Sahoo

DOI: 10.1142/S021759081950019X

Received: 18 July 2018

Accepted: 13 February 2019


Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

To be cited as: Bhaskar Jyoti Neog, Bimal Kishore Sahoo, Wage Discrimination in India’s
Formal and Informal Labour markets, The Singapore Economic Review,
doi: 10.1142/S021759081950019X

Link to final version: https://doi.org/10.1142/S021759081950019X

This is an unedited version of the accepted manuscript scheduled for publication. It has been uploaded
in advance for the benefit of our customers. The manuscript will be copyedited, typeset and proofread
before it is released in the final form. As a result, the published copy may differ from the unedited
version. Readers should obtain the final version from the above link when it is published. The authors
are responsible for the content of this Accepted Article.
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER
Manuscript (no author info) Click here to access/download;Manuscript (no author
info);01_02_2019_Discrimination_No_Author.pdf

IP
Wage Discrimination in India's Formal and Informal Labour markets

CR
Abstract

The study examines the extent of gender and caste-based discrimination among the formally and

informally employed in India using the National Sample Survey Office (NSSO) Employment-
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
Unemployment Survey (EUS) data for the four major rounds from 1999-00 to 2011-12. Oaxaca-

Blinder decomposition results corrected for self-selection show wage discrimination to be

significantly higher in informal employment compared to the formally employed. Similarly,

caste-based discrimination is found to be lower compared to gender-based discrimination. The


AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

quantile decomposition results show discrimination to vary across the quantiles. Our results

highlight the need for better regulation of the informal labour market in India.

Keywords: Gender; Caste; Discrimination; Decomposition; Quantile; Informal; Regulation.


DM

JEL: J31, J38, J71, J78.

1. Introduction

The Indian economy embarked on a process of major economic reforms in the early

1990s. Although such reforms have markedly improved economic growth rates, they were also
TE

accompanied by rising socio-economic inequalities (Ahluwalia, 2011; Subramanian & Jayaraj,

2015). Gender and caste-based discrimination can be a major factor influencing these trends 1. In
EP

1
Caste is an English word that translates into two concepts- varna and jati. Under the varna system, the society is
divided broadly into five distinct sub-groups characterized by endogamy, hereditary membership and specific
occupations. These are brahmins (priests), kshatriyas (warriors), vaisyas (traders), sudras (those engaged in menial
works) and the Ati Sudras (the formerly untouchables). Jatis are the thousands of narrower sub-groups which forms
the operative code in everyday lives. The varnas provide the broader classification system to which the jatis try to
align although the relation between the two is much more complex (Deshpande, 2000). Additionally, there is a 50-
million strong tribal population in India which have lifestyles, habitats and languages quite distinct from other
C

known languages in India (Kijima, 2006). After Independence, the Constitution of India ratified affirmative action
and statutory reservations for Scheduled Castes (SCs, primarily composed of the lower varnas such as Sudras and
the Ati Sudras) and Scheduled Tribes (STs, chiefly consisting of the tribal population). In the 1990s, after much

1
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
other words, discrimination can be an important reason that results in high inequality across

CR
social groups. Therefore, it is critical to examine the extent of gender and caste-based

discrimination in the labour market in India. Further, it is necessary to understand how the

process of liberalisation has shaped the scenario of discrimination in the Indian labour market

over the years. The present study is a modest endeavour towards this.
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
Although the literature discusses a number of factors influencing such discrimination, an

issue that has received much attention in the recent literature is the role of wage setting

institutions and regulations in explaining wage discrimination (Arulampalam, Booth, & Bryan,
AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

2007; Blau & Kahn, 2003; Weichselbaumer & Winter-Ebmer, 2007). In this regard, Peetz (2015)

stresses on the role of ‘regulation proximity’ or the extent to which the terms of employment of

particular workers are regulated, including by collective agreements, legislation or other


DM

instruments, in influencing discrimination. He concludes that workers in jobs with low regulation

proximity would be likely to suffer more discrimination by increasing “the likelihood that norms

and cultures that favour those in power (men) will dominate outcomes”. As such, in societies

where discriminatory social norms prevail, discrimination would be higher the greater the

market-orientation of the economy. At the other end of the spectrum, proponents of globalisation
TE

argue that more liberalisation and competition would loosen the hitherto monopolies and reduce

the dominance of those hitherto in power (men and upper-castes), leading to lesser

discrimination and more equal outcomes (Becker, 1957; Neetha, 2014).


EP

Most of the relevant literature on this is related to the comparison of discrimination in the

public sector and the private sector (Arulampalam et al., 2007; Duraisamy & Duraisamy, 2016;
C

debate and deliberations, a third group called the Other Backward Class (OBC, consisting of a heterogeneous group
of socially, economically and educationally backward sections of the society) was made eligible for reservations
(Vaid, 2014).

2
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
Gornick & Jacobs, 1998; Hoffnar & Greene, 1996; Miller, 2009). A majority of such studies

CR
have found wage discrimination to be higher in the sector with low regulation proximity, i.e. the

private sector. However, a public sector vs private sector comparison in developing countries

like India is flawed as a large and rising proportion of the public sector jobs are informal in

nature (Table 1). Hence their wages are more likely to be influenced by social norms and
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
competition rather than statutory rules and regulations. Similarly, many jobs in the private sector

are likely to be formal in nature. Similar problems arise in comparing the wages of regular vs

casual workers, as is done in Duraisamy & Duraisamy (2016). Other studies concentrating on

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

cross-country experiences have similarly found that countries with a largely regulated labour

market, characterised by highly centralised and unionised wage setting mechanisms have lower

gender wage gaps (Arulampalam et al., 2007; Blau & Kahn, 2003).
DM

Our study aims to shed more light on the issue by examining wage discrimination

separately in the formal and informal economy. The extent of discrimination is likely to vary in

the formal and the informal employment due to the markedly different wage-setting mechanism

in the two labour markets. Within formal employment, we find that anti-discrimination and equal

treatment laws and regulations play a major role. On the other hand, such regulations and wage
TE

bargaining processes are completely absent in informal employment; and it is mainly

competition as well as social norms favouring the dominant groups, that play the upper hand

(Carrington, McCue, & Pierce, 2000; International Labour Office, 2003; Saget, 2006). Such stark
EP

differences in the wage setting mechanism of the two segments thus enable us to empirically

study the role of regulation as well as liberalisation in shaping discrimination. Further, studying

the trend in wage discrimination in informal employment is important in itself given the large
C

and burgeoning size of the informal workforce.

3
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
The paper is divided into five sections. Section 2 discusses the theory and empirical

CR
evidence relating to labour market discrimination. Section 3 presents the data and the

methodology. Sections 4 presents a discussion on the results of the paper. Finally, Section 5

concludes the study and makes some policy prescriptions.


by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
2. Theoretical Literature and Empirical Evidence

2.1.Theoretical Literature

Within the ‘mainstream’ economics literature, theoretical models have mainly focused on

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

three broad factors- human capital differences; prejudice and imperfect information. The first of

these mainly focus on differences in the characteristics of workers in explaining the gender wage

gap. The second of these emphasise the taste for discrimination “by at least some members of the

majority group against interacting with members of the minority group" (Altonji & Blank, 1999;
DM

Becker, 1957). Becker (1957) models such ‘taste-based’ discrimination separately from the

alternative perspectives when the prejudiced agent is the employer, employees or the consumers.

The third factor emphasize the role of imperfect information as firms with imperfect information

about the skills and productivity of workers use easily observable traits such as gender or caste

(under the assumption that such traits are correlated with productivity), to distinguish between
TE

high and low productivity workers (Arrow, 1971; Phelps, 1972).

Theoretical perspectives on discrimination outside the mainstream economics have

mainly come from the sociological as well as the Marxist literature. Prominent among the
EP

sociological theories is the conflict theory which posits discrimination as a ploy used by the

dominant group members to monopolise and exclude the access of valuable economic and social

resources away from out-of-group members (Blumer, 1958).


C

4
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
Tilly (1999) similarly attributes discrimination due to the institutionalisation of

CR
categorical differences (based on ‘rigid’ markers such as sex or race). Another important theory

from the sociology discipline due to Reskin (2000), counter Blumer's (1958) assertion of a

conscious categorisation of individuals into in-group and out-of-group members. The author

rather argues that much of the categorisation is automatic and sub-conscious based on social and
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
cultural markers such as sex and race (Reskin, 2000). Within the Marxist tradition, Reich (1978)

asserts that feelings of prejudice among one group of employees against other groups is a tool

used by capitalists to ‘divide-and-conquer’ the labour force and extract the maximum profits.

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

The existing theoretical understanding of the relationship between liberalisation and

discrimination is heavily influenced by Becker (1957). Becker (1957) argues that increased

competition from international trade and liberalisation would make taste-based discrimination
DM

costly and would ultimately eliminate it. However, Borjas & Bronars (1989) and others

extending the Becker (1957) model for the presence of search costs, show that such

discrimination can persist in the long run even in a competitive labour market (Altonji & Blank,

1999). Other theoretical models, similarly, do not offer any unambiguous conclusion on the

effect of liberalisation on discrimination.


TE

On the other hand, Menon & Rodgers (2009) and Rosén (2003) show that discrimination

can increase with rising liberalisation. In their models, discriminatory employers, faced with

rising competition, lower the wages of women relative to men. Non-discriminatory employers
EP

earn lower profits compared to discriminatory employers leading to the exit of non-

discriminatory employers from the market. As such, discrimination against women is likely to

rise with increasing competition in the labour market.


C

5
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
2.2. Empirical Evidence

CR
Numerous studies have empirically tried to study the extent of wage discrimination in the

labour market. A number of studies have also attempted to analyse the impact of rising

competition and liberalisation on labour market discrimination (Berik, Rodgers, & Zveglich,
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
2004; Black & Brainerd, 2004; Hazarika & Otero, 2004; Menon & Rodgers, 2009). While there

is an ongoing debate on the impact of globalisation on discrimination (Weisskopf, 2010),

existing empirical evidence has failed to provide a coherent picture on the issue.

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

Studies also find evidence of significant gender discrimination in the Indian labour

market across various segments (Agrawal, 2013; Duraisamy & Duraisamy, 2016; Jacob, 2006;

Kingdon & Unni, 2001; Sengupta & Das, 2015). In this context, studies have noted a general

trend of rising gender discrimination over time as well as the presence of a sticky floor effect
DM

over the wage distribution. Discrimination based on caste has also been the subject of a number

of decomposition and experimental studies in India (A. Banerjee, Bertrand, Datta, &

Mullainathan, 2009; B. Banerjee & Knight, 1985; Jacob, 2006; Madheswaran, 2006;

Madheswaran & Attewell, 2007; Siddique, 2011). Decomposition-based studies show that the

extent of caste-based discrimination, though significant, is found to be significantly smaller than


TE

gender discrimination.

Further, many studies on gender and caste-based discrimination in India report a complex

picture reporting discrimination to vary with several other factors such as religion, gender, caste
EP

and employer characteristics (A. Banerjee et al., 2009; Duraisamy & Duraisamy, 2016; Sengupta

& Das, 2015; Siddique, 2011). Our study complements this literature by comparing

discrimination in India’s formal and informal economies. Such an exercise would extend our
C

6
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
understanding of how wage setting structure and institutions influence the extent of

CR
discrimination in the labour market.

Although, the study by Duraisamy & Duraisamy (2016) explore a similar issue by

comparing discrimination between private (casual) and public (regular) labour market segments,
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
as argued Section 1, a formal vs. informal dichotomy offers a much starker and clearer contrast

to study the role of institutions and regulations on labour market discrimination. Additionally,

Duraisamy & Duraisamy (2016) do not control for self-selection which might significantly bias

their results. Similarly, although Deininger, Jin, & Nagarajan (2013) study discrimination in
AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

India’s casual labour market, their analysis is restricted to rural areas and as such neglects a large

segment of the urban workforce. Further, they do not provide comparable estimates of

discrimination in the formal (or regular) jobs in India.


DM

The few studies that have looked into the issue of wage discrimination in the formal and

informal employment have found mixed results. While some studies find evidence of higher

discrimination in informal employment (Funkhouser, 1996), others find evidence to the contrary

(Ben Yahmed, 2018; Pignatti, 2010; Tansel, 2001). However, to the best of our knowledge, there

is no study in India which provides a systematic comparison of discrimination in the formal and
TE

informal economies.

3. Data and Methodology

3.1. Data Description


EP

The study uses unit level data from the National Sample Survey Organisation (NSSO)

Employment-Unemployment Survey (EUS) for four years 1999-2000, 2004-05, 2009-10 and
C

2011-12. The sample size is representative at both national and sub-national (state) level. The

7
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
EUS for the four rounds contains information on the enterprise size and type, employment status

CR
and the availability of social security benefits to workers. We have utilised this information to

distinguish between formal and informal employment. We have used the NCEUS methodology

modifying it suitably for our purpose of classifying workers into formal and informal

employment. Details are provided in Appendix-1 to the paper Sahoo & Neog, (2017). Further, it
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
provides individual and household level information that we have used for further analysis. We

carry out our analysis excluding the cultivators as information on the availability of social

security benefits as well as enterprise type, or the number of workers in the enterprise is not

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

available for such workers.

NSSO also provides information on the wages of the workers in the last week. We divide

the weekly wages of the workers by the number of days worked over the week to arrive at the
DM

daily wages of the workers. A problem with deriving wages for formal and informal workers

arises because information on firm size, social security benefits etc. used to determine

informality status is collected for a longer recall period of the last 365 days whereas information

on wages is available for a shorter recall period of the last seven days. Hence, information on

informality status and wages are not strictly compatible. The study attempts to overcome this
TE

problem by restricting the sample to individuals whose usual status codes, 5-digit NIC codes as

well as the 3-digit NCO codes are the same for the 365 recall period as well as the seven-day

recall period.
EP

3.2. Methodology

We perform the decomposition methodology proposed by Oaxaca (1973) and Blinder

(1973) to analyse the gender and caste-based wage gaps among formal and informal workers.
C

8
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
However, Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition would give us unbiased decomposition estimates only

CR
under the assumption of Conditional Independence or Ignorability, which assume that once we

control for observable worker characteristics, selection into labour market segments is random

i.e. workers do not self-select into labour market segments based on their unobservable

characteristics (Fortin, Lemieux, & Firpo, 2011).


by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
If the assumption of Ignorability is violated, i.e. there is selection on unobservables, we

need to correct the decomposition results using a correction method proposed initially by

Heckman (1979). Since our sectoral choice decision is not limited to two choices as in the
AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

Heckman (1979) model but is extended to more than two choices, we follow a methodology

proposed by Lee (1983) to correct for possible selection on unobservables.

𝑗
Formally, suppose 𝐼𝑁𝑖 be the index of benefits to individual 𝑖 from the choice of 𝑗𝑡ℎ sector
DM

𝑗 𝑗
which depends on both observables 𝑍𝑖 and unobservables 𝑣𝑖 ,

𝑗 𝑗 𝑗
or, 𝐼𝑁𝑖 = 𝑍𝑖 𝛾 𝑗 + 𝑣𝑖 … … … … . . (1)

𝑗
In terms of this function, sectorial allocation depends on the index of benefits 𝐼𝑁𝑖 .
TE

i.e. 𝐷𝑖 = 𝑓(𝐼𝑁𝑖 ), where 𝐷𝑖 indexes the sectorial choice of the individual and 𝐷𝑖 = 𝑗, if the 𝑗𝑡ℎ

sector is chosen, 𝑗 = 1,2, . . 𝑘.

Since wages are observed for a particular sector, the conditional wage function is given by,
EP

𝐸(𝑤𝑖 ⎸𝐷 = 𝑗) = 𝑥𝑖 𝛽 + 𝐸(𝑢𝑖 ⎸𝐷 = 𝑗) … … . (2)

Here, 𝑤𝑖 represents wage earnings, 𝑥𝑖 is a vector of covariates and 𝛽 is the corresponding


C

coefficient vector. 𝑢𝑖 represents the error term.

9
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
If the assumption of Ignorability is violated, 𝐸(𝑢𝑖 ⎸𝐷 = 𝑗) ≠ 0, and the coefficient

CR
estimates from OLS would be inconsistent. To produce unbiased estimates of the 𝛽′𝑠, we include

the 𝐸(𝑢𝑖 ⎸𝐷 = 𝑗) as an additional regressor in our wage function.

Hence, our corrected wage function becomes,


by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
𝐸(𝑤𝑖 ⎸𝐷 = 𝑗) = 𝑥𝑖 𝛽 + 𝐸(𝑢𝑖 ⎸𝐷 = 𝑗) = 𝑥𝑖 𝛽 + 𝛿𝑗 𝜆𝑗 … … . (3)

Here, the selection term 𝜆𝑗 is an estimate of 𝐸(𝑢𝑖 ⎸𝐷 = 𝑗) and is analogous to the inverse

Mill’s ratio in the Heckman (1979) selection model and has been computed using the method
AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

proposed by Lee (1983) and Trost & Lee (1984). The implementation of the above procedure is

done in two stages. In the first stage, a multinomial logit model is run which models the sectorial

choice of the workers.


DM

[Insert Figure 1 here]

In our study of gender wage gaps in informal employment, the selection model has the

alternatives depicted in Model 1 (Figure 1). Similarly, the selection process for the formal

economy wage gaps as well as the caste-based wage gaps in the formal and informal economy

are depicted in Model 2, 3 and 4 respectively (Figure 1). The null hypothesis of the poolability of
TE

any two alternatives (choices) in the multinomial logit model is rejected at 1 per cent level of

significance 2. A crucial assumption of the multinomial logit selection model is the Independence

of Irrelevant Alternatives (IIA). However, Bourguignon, Fournier, & Gurgand (2006) has shown
EP

the Lee (1983) methodology to be quite robust to possible violation of the IIA assumption.
C

2
We check for this using STATA’s mlogtest command.

10
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
As a further check for the robustness of the results to a possible violation of IIA

CR
assumption, we model our participation decision using a binomial probit model as in Heckman

(1979). Formally, selection depends on the index function given by Eq. (1). Wages for a

𝑗 𝑗
particular sector 𝑗 is observed only if, 𝐼𝑁𝑖 > 0. Also, let 𝐵 𝑗 = 1, if 𝐼𝑁𝑖 > 0 and zero otherwise

Accordingly, our conditional wage function is given by,


by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
𝐸(𝑤𝑖 ⎸𝐵 𝑗 = 1) = 𝑥𝑖 𝛽 + 𝐸(𝑢𝑖 ⎸𝐵 𝑗 = 1) … … . . (4)

The selection corrected wage regression is given by,

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

𝑗
𝐸(𝑤𝑖 ⎸𝐵 𝑗 = 1) = 𝐸(𝑤𝑖 ⎸𝐼𝑁𝑖 > 0) = 𝑥𝑖 𝛽 + 𝛿𝑗 𝜆𝑗 … … . . (5)

Here, the selection term, 𝜆𝑗 , also called the inverse Mill’s ratio, is an estimate of

𝐸(𝑢𝑖 ⎸𝐵 𝑗 = 1) and computed following Heckman (1979).


DM

Identification: For the proper identification of the model we need to include at least one

variable in the selection equation which is not there in the wage regression. The additional

variables, also called the selection instrument, should be such that it influences sectoral choice

but not the wages of the worker (Puhani, 2000). For our study, we have considered a dummy
TE

depicting whether there is any relative within the household who is formally employed.

We argue that the presence of a formally employed relative within the household

increases the probability of formal employment for the individual through networking effects
EP

(Ben Yahmed, 2018; Pratap & Quintin, 2006). Further, wages in the formal sector are generally

high and as such household incomes would be higher for households with a formal sector

employee. This reduces the probability of distress-driven employment among other household
C

11
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
members. This is especially likely to be so for women who are likely to be driven into

CR
employment due to distress-driven factors (Dubey, Olsen, & Sen, 2017).

Secondly, we consider another dummy variable depicting whether there is any female

relative who is employed in wage employment. The role of cultural factors in influencing labour
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
force participation in India has been amply highlighted in the literature on, especially among

women (Dubey et al., 2017; Neetha, 2014). The presence of a female relative engaged in wage

employment within the household is likely to imply that cultural environment within the

household is not so inimical to labour force participation of women. Finally, we interact the two
AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

dummy variables to derive a third selection instrument.

However, the above instruments are unlikely to likely to influence the productivity and

wages of the workers. Additionally, Puhani (2000) points out that the selection bias correction
DM

procedure is likely to be affected by high multicollinearity in the outcome equation. Leung & Yu

(1996) finds that if the condition number3 is less than 20, OLS results from the outcome equation

are not adversely affected. The predicted probabilities of the multinomial logit model are then

used to create the selection term. In the second stage, the wage regressions for formal and

informal workers are estimated including the selection term as an additional regressor.
TE

Decomposition at mean: Given the above selection bias correction for the wage

functions, Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition can be applied to the wage equations to study the wage

gap between the male and female workers. The same procedure applies for the analysis of wage
C EP

3
The condition number is defined as the square root of the ratio of the largest and the smallest eigenvalue from the
moment matrix X’X.

12
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
gaps between SC/ST and Non-SC/ST castes. Suppose the selection bias corrected wage function

CR
for male and female workers are given by-

𝑙𝑛𝑤𝑖𝑙 = 𝑋𝑖𝑙′ 𝛽 𝑙 + 𝜆𝑙𝑖 𝛿 𝑙 + 𝑢𝑖𝑙 … … . (6)

where, 𝑙 = {𝑀, 𝐹} denotes the two categories for whom the wage gap is being analyzed, 𝑖
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
indexes individuals. 𝑙𝑛𝑤𝑖𝑙 is the log daily wages, 𝑋𝑖𝑙 is a vector of explanatory variables, 𝛽 𝑙 is the

corresponding coefficient estimates and 𝑢𝑖𝑙 ∼ 𝑁(0, 𝜎 2 ) is the error term. Also, 𝜆𝑙𝑖 is the selection

term and 𝛿 𝑙 is its estimated coefficient. The above equation is estimated using Ordinary Least

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

Square (OLS) method.

Now, 𝐸(𝑙𝑛𝑤𝑖𝑙 ) = 𝑋𝑖𝑙′ 𝛽 𝑙 + 𝜆𝑙𝑖 𝛿 𝑙 … … . (7), since 𝐸(𝑢𝑖𝑙 ) = 0 by definition.

We define a vector 𝑋𝑖𝑙∗ such that 𝑋𝑖𝑙∗ includes 𝑋𝑖𝑙 in addition to 𝜆𝑙𝑖 . Similarly, the corresponding
DM

coefficient vector is 𝛽 ∗𝑙 which includes 𝛿 𝑙 in addition to 𝛽 𝑙 .

Accordingly, Eq. (7) can be written as,

𝐸(𝑙𝑛𝑤𝑖𝑙 ) = 𝑋𝑖∗𝑙′ 𝛽 ∗𝑙
TE

The wage gap between the two categories of workers is given by,

𝐺 = 𝐸(𝑙𝑛𝑤𝑖𝐹 ) − 𝐸(𝑙𝑛𝑤𝑖𝑀 )

′ ′
= 𝐸(𝑋𝑖∗𝐹 𝛽 ∗𝐹 ) − 𝐸(𝑋𝑖∗𝑀 𝛽 ∗𝑀 )
EP

′ ′
= 𝐸(𝑋𝑖∗𝐹 𝛽 ∗𝐹 − 𝑋𝑖∗𝑀 𝛽 ∗𝑀 )

Replacing the expected values of covariates by sample averages, we have,


C

13
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
𝐺 = (𝑋̅ ∗𝐹′ 𝛽 ∗𝐹 − 𝑋̅ ∗𝑀′ 𝛽 ∗𝑀 )

CR
Suppose there is a non-discriminatory coefficients vector 𝛽̃. Following Fortin et al., (2011), we

take 𝛽̃ to be the coefficient vector from a pooled model, with a group membership dummy as an

additional regressor, so that our expression for decomposition becomes,


by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
′ ′
𝐺 = (𝑋̅ ∗𝐹 − 𝑋̅ ∗𝑀 )′ 𝛽 ∗ + [(𝛽̃ − 𝛽 ∗𝑀 )𝑋̅ ∗𝑀 + (𝛽 ∗𝐹 − 𝛽̃)𝑋̅ ∗𝐹 ] … . . (8)

The first term on the right-hand side corresponds to the endowment effect or the explained wage

gap; the second term within square bracket corresponds to the discrimination effect or the
AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

unexplained wage gap4.

Quantile Decomposition: The above method allows us to study the wage gap at the mean

of the wage distribution. However, to investigate further about the wage gap between formal and
DM

informal workers over the entire wage distribution we employ the Oaxaca-Blinder

decomposition method on the RIF-regression estimates. The RIF for a statistic (e.g., a quintile) is

a transformation of the outcome variable so that it aggregates back to the statistic of interest. A

RIF-regression is similar to a standard regression, except that the dependent variable, in our

case 𝑙𝑛𝑤𝑖𝑙 , is replaced by the (recentered) influence function of the statistic of interest (e.g., a
TE

quintile) (Firpo, Fortin, & Lemieux, 2009).

Following Fortin et al. (2011), the method comprises of two steps- In the first step, the

RIF of the dependent variable is estimated which is then used to run regressions of the RIF on
EP

the vector of covariates. We run two separate regressions for the two categories of workers,

separately for each quintile. In the second step, the corresponding coefficient vector can then be
C

4
Computations are conducted using STATA’s oaxaca command.

14
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
used to perform a standard Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition yielding decomposition results for the

CR
selected quintiles as follows:

′ ′
𝐺𝑞 = (𝑋̅ 𝐹 − 𝑋̅ 𝑀 )′ 𝛽𝑞 + [(𝛽̃𝑞 − 𝛽𝑞 𝑀 )𝑋̅ 𝑀 + (𝛽𝑞 𝐹 − 𝛽̃𝑞 )𝑋̅ 𝐹 ] … … (9)

where 𝑞 indexes the quintiles. Here, 𝐺𝑞 is the wage gap at the selected quintile 𝑞 and 𝛽 𝑙 , 𝑙 =
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
{𝐹, 𝑀} are the coefficient estimates from the RIF-regression performed in the first step, at the

selected quintiles 𝑞. 𝛽̃𝑞 is defined as in Eq. (8). The first term on the right hand side represents

the endowment effect or the explained wage gap whereas the second term within square brackets

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

denotes the discrimination effect or the unexplained wage gap5. However, the above

methodology cannot be extended to correct for any selection bias in our model (Firpo et al.,

2009; Fortin et al., 2011).


DM

3.3. Variable Description

The literature suggests a number of determinants of the earnings function. Apart from the

standard variables such as age, education (general and technical), gender, caste, religion, marital

status, rural-urban location and industrial affiliation, we also include additional job-specific and

firm-specific variables in our model. The role of age is captured using a continuous variable. The
TE

impact of education (general and technical) on wages is captured through a continuous variable

measuring years of general education and a dummy variable for the presence of technical

education of the worker6. The role of gender is studied through a dummy indicating that the
EP

5
Computations are conducted in STATA using the codes available at Prof. Nicole Fortin’s website:
(http://faculty.arts.ubc.ca/nfortin/datahead.html). Detailed methods are available upon request.
6
To derive our continuous variable for years of general education, we consider the years of education completed by
an individual. For example, a person having completed primary school would have five years of schooling whereas a
C

person with graduate degree will have 15 years of education. For ‘Below Primary’ education, we take the expected
years of education i.e. the average of four (max) and zero (min) years of completed education by the person.

15
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
worker is male. Similarly, separate dummies are generated for Scheduled Castes (SCs),

CR
Scheduled Tribes (STs) and Other Backward Castes (OBCs) while we exclude the ‘Other castes’

group (consisting of General castes) taking it as the reference category.

The impact of religion on informality is explored by including separate dummies for


by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
Muslims and ‘Other religions’ (consisting of all other religions except Hindus and Muslims),

considering Hindus as the reference group. Similarly, we generate separate dummies for being

married/divorced/widow and residing in a rural area to capture marital status and rural-urban

residence respectively. Finally, we include six separate dummies representing broad industrial
AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

groups viz. ‘agriculture’ (excluding cultivators); ‘mining, electricity & water supply’;

‘manufacturing’; ‘construction’; ‘community, social & personal services’; and ‘finance,

insurance & real estate’, with ‘trade, hotels & transportation’ acting as the reference category.
DM

Further, the literature also stresses the role of firm-specific and job-specific variables in

the wage determination process (Chatterji, Mumford, & Smith, 2011). We thus include separate

dummy variables for full-time work, whether the job is permanent and whether the job is a

regular job. Given the important role of unions in the wage determination process (Elvira &

Saporta, 2001), our study includes a dummy for union membership in the wage function. Further,
TE

the literature highlights the spatially concentrated nature of industrialisation as well as the

variation in the political and economic climate across states (Sanyal & Menon, 2005). We

control for such variation by including 24 dummies representing state-regions in our model.
EP

Further, using a methodology proposed in Ministry of Labour and Employment (Ministry

of Labour and Employment, n.d.), we divide the occupations titles of the workers into four

groups depending on the skill content of the job. We include dummy variables for three skill
C

16
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
groups, excluding the fourth group as the reference category. We also include dummy variables

CR
depicting whether the firm is a public sector entity and whether the firm is in the unorganised

sector. Finally, a variable depicting the dependency ratio7 of the household is used in the

earnings equation.
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
4. Results and Discussion

4.1. Descriptive Statistics

Descriptive statistics related to the entire sample as well as the different labour market

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

segments are discussed below. We only present the results for the years 2004-05 and 20011-12

here (Table 2). Results for the years 1999-00 and 2009-10 portray a similar picture and are

available upon request. A look at Table 2 reveals that the percentage of SC/ST population in

formal employment is significantly lower than in informal employment 8. Further, we see that the
DM

mean years of education is significantly higher in formal employment compared with the

informally employed across all categories. Also, educational levels are higher for the

OBC/General workers and male workers compared to the SC/ST workers and female workers

respectively. Similarly, we find heterogeneities in the age profile and MPCE levels of workers

across labour market segments (Table 2). Finally, in line with our earlier contention on the
TE

unregulated nature of the informal economy, we find unionisation rates to be significantly lower
EP

7
An individual is considered to be a dependent if he is less than 5 years old or an elderly aged more than 59 years
who is not in the workforce. Dividing the number of dependents by the household size gives us the dependency
ratio.
8
Although NSSO provides caste affiliation on four groups (SC, ST, OBC and General), we combine the SC/ST
C

groups and the OBC/General groups to form two distinct broad groups on which we make our comparison. This is
partly influenced by sample size considerations. Additionally, we find that wages and other characteristics are also
largely similar within our two broad groups.

17
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
among the informally employed compared to the formally employed. The unionisation rate is

CR
also seen to be declining over time (Table 2).

[Insert Table 2 here]

Looking at the daily wages of workers, we see that wages differ considerably between
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
different groups across formal and informal employment. Mean wages are significantly higher in

formal employment compared to the informally employed. Further, wages are comparatively

higher for males and the OBC/General groups. In general, informal employees, as well as SC/ST

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

workers, are found to have significantly lower education levels, age, MPCE levels as well as

wages. Although wages and other endowments are also different between males and females, the

difference is comparatively lower than that between the SC/ST vs the OBC/General groups

(Table 2).
DM

4.2. Decomposition Results

Before looking at the decomposition results, we check whether the additional terms in the

selection model significantly influence the participation decision. We find that our selection

instruments significantly influence the participation decision. Additionally, as discussed in


TE

Section 3.2, the Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition results hinges on the fact that the outcome

equation does not suffer from collinearity issues. We find that the condition number in the

outcome equations are well below the threshold of 20 suggested by Leung & Yu (1996). The
EP

results for the above contentions are not presented here but is available upon request.

We take a look at the mean wage gaps as well as its breakdown into explained and

unexplained components for gender and caste in formal and the informal employment.
C

18
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
[Insert Table 3 here]

CR
Looking at the Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition results, we find that absolute wage gaps

have declined over the period in informal employment whereas wage gaps have increased

marginally in formal employment. Wage gaps are also quite larger in informal employment
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
compared to the formally employed. Looking further at the selection-bias corrected

decomposition results show that within the informally employed a large part of the wage gap is

unexplained and is attributable to the discrimination effect whereas in formal employment,

endowment effect plays a much bigger role. Further, we find gender discrimination to have
AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

increased in informal employment so that in 2009-10 and 2011-12 it explains more than 100 per

cent of the gender wage gaps (Table 3). Our results tally with the findings reported in Deininger,

Jin, & Nagarajan (2013) who find significant gender discrimination in the Indian casual rural
DM

labour market. Our results are also similar to Duraisamy & Duraisamy (2016) who report higher

discrimination in the comparatively unregulated casual (private economy) labour market relative

to the regular (public economy) labour market. The uncorrected decomposition results depict a

similar picture.

[Insert Table 4 here]


TE

Looking at the Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition results for caste-based wage gaps, we find

overall wage gaps in the formal and informal employment to be positive and more or less stable

over time. Interestingly overall wage gaps are higher in formal employment compared to the
EP

informally employed. Within the informally employed, we find that the endowment effect and

the discrimination effect both play an important role in explaining the overall wage gap. Looking

at the formally employed, our results, in fact, indicate that the endowment effect explains almost
C

19
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
the entire wage gap and the discrimination effect is insignificant or negative across the years

CR
(Table 4). This may be, in large part, due to the reservation policy of the government for the

SC/ST groups. Our results are quite similar to that of Siddique (2011) who find that caste-based

discrimination though absent in larger more established firms is evident in smaller firms. The

decomposition results without selection-bias correction give us a similar picture.


by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
The results of our study unambiguously show discrimination to be higher in the informal

economy compared to the formal economy. Such a result highlight the importance of

psychological constructs and prejudice (as embedded in social norms and customs) in facilitating
AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

discrimination as argued in the theories of Blumer, (1958), Reskin, (2000), Tilly, (1999), and

Becker, (1957). However, contrary to what was argued by Becker (1957), our study fails to find

any positive impact of liberalisation on reducing discrimination. In fact, discrimination seems to


DM

be higher in the less regulated (more liberalised) informal economy. Our results concur more

with the theoretical arguments of Rosén (2003) and Menon & Rodgers (2009) who posit

discrimination to increase with rising liberalisation in the economy.

4.3. Quantile Decomposition Results


TE

We next look at the extent of wage gaps and its constituents across quantiles. Given our

focus on the study of discrimination, we only present the results for unexplained wage gaps

across quantiles, to make our interpretation more concise and to the point (Table 5 and 6).

Results for the overall wage gaps as well as the endowment effects is available on request.
EP

[Insert Table 5 and Figure 2 here]

Looking at the quantile decomposition results for gender for the informally employed, we
C

find that the unexplained wage gap starts from a high level and falls as we move towards the

20
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
higher quantiles indicating the presence of sticky floor effect (Table 5; Figure 2). The results for

CR
gender discrimination in formal employment, on the other hand, show that the unexplained wage

gap is very high in the 10th quantile and then falls drastically as we move to the 70th quantile

before stabilizing or rising slightly in the 90th quantile (Figure 2; Table 5). This pattern is broadly

consistent with a sticky floor effect. Our results are similar to Duraisamy & Duraisamy (2016)
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
who report a sticky floor effect in both the public and the private economies.

[Insert Table 6 here]

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

Quantile decomposition results for the caste-based wage gaps for the informally

employed, on the other hand, show discrimination effect to be generally low and insignificant

across the quantiles for the informally employed (Table 6; Figure 2). In case of the formally

employed, our results find the unexplained wage gap to rise drastically in the initial quantiles
DM

before stabilising or even rising marginally in the later quantiles (Table 6; Figure 2). This pattern

is broadly consistent with a glass ceiling effect.

4.4. Interacting the formal-informal employment dichotomy with the public-private sector

dichotomy
TE

The discussion above provides vital insights into the impact of competition and

regulations in influencing discrimination. Although we argue that the formal-informal

employment dichotomy provides a more useful distinction compared to the public sector vs.
EP

private sector dichotomy in understanding such a mechanism, it would still be interesting to

study how the extent of discrimination varies when we interact the formal-informal employment

dichotomy with the public-private sector dichotomy.


C

Accordingly, we run a regression as in Eq. (6), as follows,

21
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
𝑙𝑛𝑤 = 𝛼1 𝐷 + 𝛼2 𝑆 + 𝛼3 𝐷 ∗ 𝑆 + 𝑋𝛽 + 𝑢 … … (10)

CR
Here, 𝑙𝑛𝑤 is the logarithm of daily wages, 𝐷 is the gender dummy equalling 1 if the

worker is male and else 0. Similarly, 𝑆 is the sector dummy equalling 1 if the worker works in

the public sector and else 0. 𝑋 is a vector of other control variables including the constant and the
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
selection term and 𝛽 is the corresponding coefficient vector. We have made corrections for

possible selection on unobservables through the inclusion of the selection term using the method

of Lee, (1983). 𝛼2 is the coefficient of the sector dummy 𝑆 and 𝑢 is the error term. The co-

efficient 𝛼1 can be interpreted as the extent of gender-based discrimination in the private sector
AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

i.e. when 𝑆 equals 0. Similarly, the co-efficient 𝛼3 gives us the extent by which gender-based

discrimination differs between the public and the private sector. Finally, 𝛼1 + 𝛼3 gives us the

extent of gender-based discrimination in the public sector. Similarly, we can estimate the extent
DM

of variation in caste-based discrimination between the public and the private sectors. Table 7

reports the estimates of the coefficients 𝛼1 , 𝛼1 + 𝛼3 and 𝛼3 .

We prefer the single equation framework over the decomposition-based framework as the

later entails a significant reduction of sample size as we further sub-divide the sample between

the public and private sectors within the formal and informal economy. However, the single
TE

equation approach can be flawed9. As such the results in Table 7 should be interpreted with

caution. In line with our earlier results, Table 7 show discrimination across sectors to be higher

in the informal economy compared to the formal economy. Similarly, gender-based


EP

discrimination is found to be higher than caste-based discrimination across sectors.

Discrimination is not found to differ significantly between the public and private sectors in most
C

9
Madheswaran & Attewell, (2007) point out that the single equation framework can yield biased results as it
assumes the wage structure to be identical for both the gender (or caste) groups.

22
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
cases. However, we cannot completely rule out the hypothesis of no significant difference in

CR
discrimination between the public and the private sectors.

[Insert Table 7 here]

One such interesting case is caste-based discrimination in the formal economy where
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
discrimination is significantly higher in the private sector compared to that in the public sector.

This result could be because SC/ST formal employees in the public sector enjoy the benefits of

reservation policy adopted by the government of India, whereas such policies are not applicable

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

to formal employees in the private sector. Such a picture fits well with our earlier arguments on

discrimination being lower in jobs with high regulation proximity. We conclude that although the

formal-informal employment dichotomy offers a useful device to understand discrimination,

extending the framework by interacting the formal-informal employment dichotomy with the
DM

public-private sector dichotomy can provide us with further useful insights.

5. Conclusion

The study finds significant differences by gender and caste groups in the characteristics

of the workers in both formal and informal employment. The decomposition results at the mean
TE

show gender and caste-based discrimination to be significantly higher in informal employment

compared to the formally employed. Gender-based discrimination is also found to be higher than

caste-based discrimination for the formally and informally employed. The quantile
EP

decomposition results show discrimination to vary across the quantiles for the different labour

market segments. Studying discrimination through the public-sector vs. private-sectors

dichotomy among the formally and informally employed also offers interesting insights.
C

23
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
Given the large proportion of the workforce engaged in informal employment in India,

CR
such large-scale wage discrimination among the informally employed needs urgent policy

attention. It points to the fact that increasing liberalisation and globalisation accompanied by the

withdrawal of the state from many sectors have been unable to lessen the discriminatory

practices in informal employment. As such the benefits of non-discriminatory regulations are


by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
being restricted to a small section of the workers engaged in formal employment.

Hence a blind faith in market forces may not be enough to reduce the extent of

discrimination in the economy. Urgent policy steps need to be put in place to bring the
AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

informally employed under the regulatory mechanism to arrest the rising trend of gender wage

discrimination (International Labour Office, 2003). We also find evidence of significantly large

wage gaps at the bottom of the wage distribution in informal employment. This calls for policy
DM

efforts for the legislation and strict implementation of minimum wage laws, especially in the

informal economy. Finally, steps need to be taken to improve the endowment set of the female

and SC/ST workers especially in the direction of gaining more vocational training and skills.

References
TE

Agrawal, T. (2013). Are There Glass-Ceiling and Sticky-Floor Effects in India? An Empirical

Examination. Oxford Development Studies, 41(3), 322–342.

https://doi.org/10.1080/13600818.2013.804499
EP

Ahluwalia, M. S. (2011). Prospects and Policy Challenges in the Twelfth Plan. Economic and

Political Weekly, XLVI(21), 88–105.

Altonji, J. G., & Blank, R. M. (1999). Race and Gender in the labour market. In Handbook of
C

Labour Economics, Vol. 3 (pp. 3143–3259). Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North Holland.

24
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
Arrow, K. (1971). The Theory of Discrimination. In Discrimination in Labor Markets (pp. 3–

CR
33).

Arulampalam, W., Booth, A. L., & Bryan, M. L. (2007). Is There a Glass Ceiling over Europe?

Exploring the Gender Pay Gap across the Wage. Industrial and Labor Relations Review,
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
60(2), 163–186.

Banerjee, A., Bertrand, M., Datta, S., & Mullainathan, S. (2009). Labor market discrimination in

Delhi: Evidence from a field experiment. Journal of Comparative Economics, 37(1), 14–27.

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2008.09.002

Banerjee, B., & Knight, J. B. (1985). Caste discrimination in the Indian urban labour market.

Journal of Development Economics, 17(3), 277–307. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-

3878(85)90094-X
DM

Becker, G. S. (1957). The Economics of Discrimination. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Ben Yahmed, S. (2018). Formal but Less Equal. Gender Wage Gaps in Formal and Informal

Jobs in Urban Brazil. World Development, 101, 73–87.

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2017.08.012
TE

Berik, G., Rodgers, Y. V. D. M., & Zveglich, J. E. (2004). International trade and gender wage

discrimination: Evidence from East Asia. Review of Development Economics, 8(2), 237–
EP

254. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9361.2004.00230.x

Black, S. E., & Brainerd, E. (2004). Importing Equality? The Impact of Globalization on Gender

Discrimination. Industrial & Labor Relations Review, 57(4), 540–559.


C

https://doi.org/10.2307/4126682

25
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
Blau, F. D., & Kahn, L. M. (2003). Understanding International Differences in the Gender Pay

CR
Gap. Journal of Labor Economics, 21(1), 106–144. https://doi.org/10.1086/344125

Blinder, A. S. (1973). Wage Discrimination : Reduced Form and Structural Estimates. The

Journal of Human Resources, 8(4), 436–455.


by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
Blumer, H. (1958). Race Prejudice as a Sense of Group Position. Pacific Sociological Review,

1(1), 3–7. https://doi.org/10.2307/1388607

Borjas, G. J., & Bronars, S. G. (1989). Consumer Discrimination and Self-Employment. Journal

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

of Political Economy, 97(3), 581–605.

Bourguignon, F., Fournier, M., & Gurgand, M. (2006). Selection bias corrections based on the

multinomial logit model : Monte Carlo comparisons. Journal of Economic Surveys, 21(1),
DM

174–205.

Carrington, W. J., McCue, K., & Pierce, B. (2000). Using Establishment Size to Measure the

Impact of Title VII and Affirmative Action. Journal of Human Resources, 35(3), 503–523.

https://doi.org/http://jhr.uwpress.org/archive/
TE

Chatterji, M., Mumford, K., & Smith, P. N. (2011). The public-private sector gender wage

differential in Britain: evidence from matched employee-workplace data. Applied

Economics, 43(26), 3819–3833. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036841003724452


EP

Deininger, K., Jin, S., & Nagarajan, H. (2013). Wage Discrimination in India’s Informal Labor

Markets: Exploring the Impact of Caste and Gender. Review of Development Economics,

17(1), 130–147. https://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12020


C

Deshpande, A. (2000). Recasting Economic Inequality. Review of Social Economy, 58(3), 388–

26
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
399. https://doi.org/10.2753/JEI0021-3624440403

CR
Dubey, A., Olsen, W., & Sen, K. (2017). The Decline in the Labour Force Participation of Rural

Women in India: Taking a Long-Run View. The Indian Journal of Labour Economics.

https://doi.org/10.1007/s41027-017-0085-0
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
Duraisamy, M., & Duraisamy, P. (2016). Gender wage gap across the wage distribution in

different segments of the Indian labour market, 1983–2012: exploring the glass ceiling or

sticky floor phenomenon. Applied Economics, 48(43), 4098–4111.

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

https://doi.org/10.1080/00036846.2016.1150955

Elvira, M. M., & Saporta, I. (2001). How Does Collective Bargaining Affect the Gender Pay

Gap? Work and Occupations, 28(4), 469–490.


DM

Firpo, S., Fortin, N. M., & Lemieux, T. (2009). Unconditional Quantile Regressions.

Econometrica, 77(3), 953–973. https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA6822

Fortin, N., Lemieux, T., & Firpo, S. (2011). Decomposition methods in economics. In Handbook

of Labour Economics Vol. 4 (pp. 1–102). Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North Holland.
TE

Funkhouser, E. (1996). The urban informal sector in Central America: Household survey

evidence. World Development, 24(11), 1737–1751. https://doi.org/10.1016/0305-

750X(96)00074-5
EP

Gornick, J. C., & Jacobs, J. A. (1998). Gender, the Welfare State, and Public Employment: A

Comparative Study of Seven Industrialized Countries. American Sociological Review,

63(5), 688–710.
C

Hazarika, G., & Otero, R. (2004). Foreign Trade and the Gender Earnings Differential in Urban

27
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
Mexico. Journal of Economic Integration, 19(2), 353–373.

CR
Heckman, J. J. (1979). Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error. Econometrica, 47(1),

153–161. https://doi.org/10.1007/S10021-01

Hoffnar, E., & Greene, M. (1996). Gender discrimination in the public and private sectors: A
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
sample selectivity approach. Journal of Socio-Economics, 25(1), 105–114.

https://doi.org/10.1016/S1053-5357(96)90056-6

International Labour Office. (2003). The Scope of the Employment Relationship. Geneva.

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

Jacob, M. (2006). Changes in the Wage Gap of Gender and Caste Groups in India. University of

Maryland.

Kijima, Y. (2006). Caste and Tribe Inequality: Evidence from India, 1983–1999. Economic
DM

Development and Cultural Change, 54(2), 369–404. https://doi.org/10.1086/497008

Kingdon, G., & Unni, J. (2001). Education and Women’s Labour Market Outcomes in India.

Education Economics, 9(2), 173–195. https://doi.org/10.1080/09645290110056994

Lee, L. (1983). Generalized Econometric Models with Selectivity. Econometrica, 51(2), 507–
TE

512.

Leung, S. F., & Yu, S. (1996). On the choice between sample selection and two-part models.

Journal of Econometrics, 72, 197–229.


EP

Madheswaran, S. (2006). Caste Discrimination in the Indian Urban Labour Market: Evidence

from the National Sample Survey. RISEC, 53(3), 349–372.


C

Madheswaran, S., & Attewell, P. (2007). Caste discrimination in the Indian urban labour market:

28
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
Evidence from the National Sample Survey. Economic and Political Weekly, 42(41), 4146–

CR
4154. https://doi.org/10.2307/40276549

Menon, N., & Rodgers, Y. V. D. M. (2009). International Trade and the Gender Wage Gap: New

Evidence from India’s Manufacturing Sector. World Development, 37(5), 965–981.


by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2008.09.009

Miller, P. W. (2009). The gender pay gap in the US: Does sector make a eifference? Journal of

Labor Research, 30(1), 52–74. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12122-008-9050-5

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

Ministry of Labour and Employment. (n.d.). National Classification of Occupations-2004.

Retrieved from http://www.dget.nic.in/upload/uploadfiles/files/publication/1 preface.pdf

Neetha. (2014). Crisis in Female Employment: Analysis across Social Groups. Economic and
DM

Political Weekly, XLIX(47).

Oaxaca, R. (1973). Male-Female Wage Differentials in Urban Labor Markets. International

Economic Review, 14(3), 693–709.

Peetz, D. (2015). Regulation distance, labour segmentation and gender gaps. Cambridge Journal
TE

of Economics, 39(2), 345–362. https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/beu054

Phelps, E. S. (1972). The Statistical theory of Racism and Sexism. American Economic Review,

62(4), 659–661. https://doi.org/10.2307/1806107


EP

Pignatti, N. (2010). Labor Market Segmentation and the Gender Wage Gap in Ukraine

(ESCIRRU No. 17). Berlin, Germany.


C

Pratap, S., & Quintin, E. (2006). Are labor markets segmented in developing countries? A

29
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
semiparametric approach. European Economic Review, 50(7), 1817–1841.

CR
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.euroecorev.2005.06.004

Puhani, P. (2000). The Heckman Correction for Sample Selection and Its Critique. Journal of

Economic Surveys, 14(1), 53–68. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-6419.00104


by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
Reich, W. (1978). Who Benefits from Racism? The Distribution among Whites of Gains and

Losses from Racial Inequality. The Journal of Human Resources, 13(4), 524–544.

Reskin, B. F. (2000). The Proximate Causes of Employment Discrimination. Contemporary

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

Sociology, 29(2), 319–328.

Rosén, Å. (2003). Search, Bargaining, and Employer Discrimination. Journal of Labor

Economics, 21(4), 807–829. https://doi.org/10.1086/377018


DM

Saget, C. (2006). Wage fixing in the informal economy: Evidence from Brazil, India, Indonesia

and South Africa. Geneva. https://doi.org/10.1086/261023

Sahoo, B. K., & Neog, B. J. (2017). Heterogeneity and participation in informal employment

among non-cultivator workers in India. International Review of Applied Economics, 31(4),


TE

437–467. https://doi.org/10.1080/02692171.2016.1257584

Sanyal, P., & Menon, N. (2005). Labor Disputes and the Economics of Firm Geography: A

Study of Domestic Investment in India. Economic Development and Cultural Change,


EP

53(4), 825–854. https://doi.org/10.1086/429304

Sengupta, A., & Das, P. (2015). Gender Wage Discrimination across Social and Religious

Groups in India. Economic and Political Weekly, XLIX(21), 71–76.


C

30
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
Siddique, Z. (2011). Evidence on Caste Based Discrimination. Labour Economics, 18(SUPPL.

CR
1), S146–S159. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.labeco.2011.07.002

Subramanian, S., & Jayaraj, D. (2015). Growth and Inequality in the Distribution of India’s

Consumption Expenditure: 1983 to 2009–10. Economic and Political Weekly, 50(32), 39–
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
47.

Tansel, A. (2001). Wage Earners, Self Employed and Gender in the Informal Sector in Turkey

(No. 0102). ERF Working Paper Series. Cairo, Egypt.

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

Tilly, C. (1999). Durable Inequality. Oakland, USA: University of California Press.

Trost, R. P., & Lee, L. (1984). Technical training and earnings: a polychotomous choice model

with selectivity. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 66(1), 151–156.


DM

https://doi.org/10.2307/1924708

Vaid, D. (2014). Caste in Contemporary India: Flexibility and Persistence. Annual Review of

Sociology, 40(1), 391–410. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-soc-071913-043303

Weichselbaumer, D., & Winter-Ebmer, R. (2007). The Effects of Competition and Equal
TE

Treatment Laws on Gender Wage Differentials. Economic Policy, 22(50), 235–287.

Weisskopf, T. E. (2010). Reflections on Globalization, Discrimination, and Affirmative Action.

In M. A. Centeno (Ed.), Discrimination in an Unequal World. New York: Oxford


EP

University Press.

TABLES
C

Table 1: Informality rates in public and private sectors among the wage employees in non-cultivation work
1999-00 2004-05 2009-10 2011-12

31
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
Public Sector 17.13 18.32 29.98 37.41
Private Sector 82.29 87.61 87.32 87.41

CR
Note: The table shows the percentage of workers employed as informal employees in public and private sectors
among the wage employees in non-cultivation work.
Sampling weights have been used in the calculation of the results.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on NSSO data

Table 2: Descriptive Statistics


by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
Informal Employment Formal Employment
Year Total Male Female SC/ST OBC/ Male Female SC/ST OBC/
Gen Gen
2004-05 27.57 29.64 34.40 100 0 20.63 19.63 100 0
% SC/ST
2011-12 28.23 30.35 33.22 100 0 20.36 21.05 100 0
2004-05 18.21 0 100 21.17 17.74 0 100 16.12 16.98
% Females
2011-12 17.53 0 100 18.52 16.60 0 100 19.03 18.40

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

Mean Years of 2004-05 7.29 5.83 4.40 4.03 6.24 11.42 11.53 9.17 12.02
Education 2011-12 7.85 6.39 5.41 5.04 6.74 12.67 12.74 10.89 13.14
2004-05 34.12 31.02 33.68 31.70 31.45 40.90 37.67 40.24 40.39
Mean Age
2011-12 35.26 33.48 35.47 33.84 33.81 40.07 37.25 39.71 39.50
2004-05 989.1 718.3 745.3 567.9 791.9 1620.3 1660.3 1042.9 1777.4
Mean MPCE
2011-12 1991.4 1549.9 1672.3 1265.7 1207.1 3141.3 3656.2 2430.9 3444.3
2004-05 4.51 4.22 3.67 4.00 4.17 5.45 5.13 5.20 5.45
Mean of Log Wages
2011-12 5.35 5.13 4.62 4.95 5.09 6.25 5.99 6.01 6.25
DM

Unionization Rates 2004-05 25.05 7.91 6.02 5.81 8.32 67.59 64.58 73.29 65.48
(%) 2011-12 19.33 7.88 6.67 6.56 8.17 54.38 51.85 59.21 52.55
2004-05 55870 27856 6941 10747 24037 17557 3516 6101 14956
No. of Observations
2011-12 55094 29453 6407 11513 24347 15824 3410 5862 13372
Note: Sampling weights have been used in the calculation of the estimates.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on NSSO data

Table 3: Oaxaca-Blinder Decomposition results by gender


TE

Informal Employment Formal Employment


1999-00 2004-05 2009-10 2011-12 1999-00 2004-05 2009-10 2011-12
a
Overall Wage Gap 0.588 0.552a 0.506a 0.510a 0.230a 0.318a 0.282a 0.261a
Controlling for observables and self-selection (Lee method)
Explained Wage Gap 0.095a 0.001 -0.095a -0.085a 0.056a 0.114a 0.110a 0.139a
a a a
Unexplained Wage Gap 0.493 0.552 0.602 0.595a 0.174a 0.204a 0.172a 0.122a
Controlling for observables and self-selection (Heckman method)
EP

Explained Wage Gap 0.075a -0.027c -0.099a -0.083a 0.023 0.077a 0.091b 0.134a
a a a
Unexplained Wage Gap 0.513 0.579 0.605 0.593a 0.207a 0.241a 0.191a 0.127a
Controlling for observables only (without selection bias correction)
Explained Wage Gap 0.149a 0.117a 0.059a 0.044a 0.030a 0.063a 0.021c 0.047a
a a a
Unexplained Wage Gap 0.439 0.435 0.448 0.466a 0.200a 0.255a 0.261a 0.214a
Source: Authors’ calculations based on NSSO data
C

Note: Significance levels are denoted by c 10%, b 5%, a 1%.

32
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
Sampling weights have been used in the calculation of the estimates.
Wage gaps refer to male wages minus female wages in case of gender-based discrimination and General/OBC

CR
wages minus SC/ST wages in case of caste-based discrimination.

Table 4: Oaxaca-Blinder Decomposition results by caste


Informal Employment Formal Employment
1999-00 2004-05 2009-10 2011-12 1999-00 2004-05 2009-10 2011-12
a
Overall Wage Gap 0.173 0.169a 0.189a 0.138a 0.170a 0.256a 0.276a 0.249a
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
Controlling for observables and self-selection (Lee method)
Explained Wage Gap 0.112a 0.050a 0.102a 0.070a 0.192a 0.241a 0.245a 0.242a
a a a
Unexplained Wage Gap 0.061 0.119 0.088 0.068a -0.022 0.015 0.031 0.007
Controlling for observables and self-selection (Heckman method)
Explained Wage Gap 0.115a 0.050a 0.102a 0.075a 0.233a 0.290a 0.288a 0.296a
a a a
Unexplained Wage Gap 0.058 0.119 0.088 0.063a -0.063a -0.034 -0.012 -0.047c
Controlling for observables only (without selection bias correction)

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

Explained Wage Gap 0.140a 0.087a 0.123a 0.102a 0.169a 0.205a 0.222a 0.211a
a a a
Unexplained Wage Gap 0.033 0.082 0.066 0.036a 0.001 0.051a 0.054b 0.038b
Source: Authors’ calculations based on NSSO data
See Notes in Table 3.

Table 5: Gender discrimination across quantiles


Informal Employment Formal Employment
DM

Quantil 10th 30th 50th 70th 90th 10th 30th 50th 70th 90th
e
Unexplained 1999-00 0.45a 0.48a 0.48a 0.39a 0.40a 0.88a 0.13a 0.02 0.04b 0.11a
a a
Wage Gap 2004-05 0.58 0.40 0.38a 0.42a 0.38a 0.78a 0.26a 0.12a 0.04b 0.16a
2009-10 0.73a 0.52a 0.38a 0.35a 0.44a 0.55a 0.29a 0.15a 0.04c 0.11a
a a
2011-12 0.69 0.39 0.50a 0.41a 0.47a 0.48a 0.41a 0.13a 0.08a 0.05c
See Notes in Table 3.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on NSSO data
TE

Table 6: Caste-based discrimination across quantiles


Informal Employment Formal Employment
Quantil 10th 30th 50th 70th 90th 10th 30th 50th 70th 90th
e
Unexplained 1999-00 0.10a -0.07a -0.05a 0.01 0.07a -0.05 -0.02 -0.01 0.03c 0.08a
EP

a
Wage Gap 2004-05 0.03 0.09 0.02 0.06a 0.20a 0.31a 0.02 0.08a 0.03c 0.07a
2009-10 0.03 0.09a 0.08a 0.07a 0.01 -0.11 0.04 0.06a 0.05a 0.02
2011-12 0.03 0.04b -0.06a -0.05a 0.06a 0.18b 0.01 0.02 0.04b 0.06b
See Notes in Table 3.
Source: Authors’ calculations based on NSSO data
C

Table 7: Discrimination across sectors in formal and informal employment

33
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
Informal Employment Formal Employment
1999-00 2004-05 2009-10 2011-12 1999-00 2004-05 2009-10 2011-12

CR
Gender-based discrimination
Private sector 0.48a 0.55a 0.59a 0.59a 0.27b 0.26a 0.17c 0.12c
Public sector 0.78a 0.60a 0.67a 0.64a 0.09b 0.15a 0.17a 0.12a
a
Difference -0.30 -0.04 -0.08 -0.05 0.18b 0.11 0.001 -0.001
Caste-based discrimination
Private sector 0.05a 0.12a 0.09a 0.07a -0.05 0.08b 0.1 0.06
a a
Public sector 0.27 0.14 0.07c 0.02 -0.01 -0.01 0.001 -0.02
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
b
Difference -0.22 -0.02 0.02 0.05 -0.04 0.09b 0.10b 0.08c
Source: Authors’ calculations based on NSSO data
Standard errors are clustered on state/province level
See Notes in Table 3.

FIGURES

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

Figure 1: Simultaneous decision process of the worker


Informal Male Wage Employed Formal Male Wage Employed

Informal Female Wage Employed Formal Female Wage Employed


Participation decision

Participation decision
choices (Model 1)

choices (Model 2)

Formal Wage Employed Informal Wage Employed


DM

Cultivators Cultivators

Self-Employment Self-Employment

Outside the workforce Outside the workforce

Not Matching Not Matching

Informal Gen/OBC Wage Employed Formal Gen/OBC Wage Employed


TE

Informal SC/ST Wage Employed Formal SC/ST Wage Employed


Participation decision

Participation decision
choices (Model 3)

choices (Model 4)

Formal Wage Employed Informal Wage Employed

Cultivators Cultivators
EP

Self-Employment Self-Employment

Outside the workforce Outside the workforce


C

Not Matching Not Matching

34
AC
T
Accepted manuscript to appear in SER

IP
Note: The ‘Not Matching’ category includes the set of wage-employed in whose case the usual status codes, 5-digit
NIC codes or 3-digit NCO codes are not the same for the 365-day and seven-day recall period. See Section 3.1 for

CR
further details.
Model 1 and 2 shows the choices in the participation decision in case of gender-based discrimination in
informal and formal employment respectively. Similarly, Model 3 and 4 shows the choices in the participation
decision in case of caste-based discrimination in informal and formal employment respectively.
The above classification of workers into different activity status is based on the 365-day recall period.
Source: Authors calculations
by LA TROBE UNIVERSITY on 03/18/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles.

US
Figure 2: Gender and caste-based discrimination across quantiles in formal and informal employment

AN
Singapore Econ. Rev. Downloaded from www.worldscientific.com

DM
TE

Source: Authors’ calculations based on NSSO data.


EP

See Notes in Table 3.


C

35
AC

You might also like