You are on page 1of 5

DATE DOWNLOADED: Tue Feb 13 08:02:07 2024

SOURCE: Content Downloaded from HeinOnline

Citations:
Please note: citations are provided as a general guideline. Users should consult their preferred
citation format's style manual for proper citation formatting.

Bluebook 21st ed.


Tony Martino, Performing Rights: Are There Realistic Alternatives to the Blanket
License, 9 J. MEDIA L. & PRAC. 20 (1987).

ALWD 7th ed.


Tony Martino, Performing Rights: Are There Realistic Alternatives to the Blanket
License, 9 J. Media L. & Prac. 20 (1987).

APA 7th ed.


Martino, Tony. (1987). Performing rights: are there realistic alternatives to the
blanket license. Journal of Media Law & Practice, 9(1), 20-23.

Chicago 17th ed.


Tony Martino, "Performing Rights: Are There Realistic Alternatives to the Blanket
License," Journal of Media Law & Practice 9, no. 1 (March 1988): 20-23

McGill Guide 9th ed.


Tony Martino, "Performing Rights: Are There Realistic Alternatives to the Blanket
License" (1987) 9:1 J Media L & Prac 20.

AGLC 4th ed.


Tony Martino, 'Performing Rights: Are There Realistic Alternatives to the Blanket
License' (1987) 9(1) Journal of Media Law & Practice 20

MLA 9th ed.


Martino, Tony. "Performing Rights: Are There Realistic Alternatives to the Blanket
License." Journal of Media Law & Practice, vol. 9, no. 1, March 1988, pp. 20-23.
HeinOnline.

OSCOLA 4th ed.


Tony Martino, 'Performing Rights: Are There Realistic Alternatives to the Blanket
License' (1987) 9 J Media L & Prac 20 Please note: citations are
provided as a general guideline. Users should consult their preferred citation
format's style manual for proper citation formatting.

-- Your use of this HeinOnline PDF indicates your acceptance of HeinOnline's Terms and
Conditions of the license agreement available at
https://heinonline.org/HOL/License
-- The search text of this PDF is generated from uncorrected OCR text.
Performing rights: are there realistic
alternatives to the blanket licence?
TONY MARTINO

1. Introduction 2. The nature of the blanket licence


This article examines the legal and economic reali- ASCAP members and BMI affiliates - the com-
ties of performance right licensing. It is limited to posers and publishers of music - grant to their
the 'minor' or 'non-dramatic' performing right to respective organisations the non-exclusive right to
copyright music as licensed to its chief users, the licence non-dramatic public performances of their
broadcasters and to the challenges to its legitimacy copyright musical works. The UK Performing Right
which in recent times have all arisen under the Society (PRS), requires the grant from its members
antitrust laws. Nearly all these challenges have been of the exclusive right of public performance.
mounted in the United States against the American ASCAP, BMI and PRS offer users only blanket
Society of Composers Authors and Publishers licences covering their entire repertoire. They do
(ASCAP) and Broadcast Music Incorporated not licence either individual compositions, or indi-
(BMI). (The Society of European Stage Authors vidual publisher's catalogues. Moreover, they do
and Composers (SESAC) is the smallest of the three not act as agents for composers and publisher who
principal US organisations. Its size has 'permitted it wish to do so.
to work with a "low profile", and its character and By means of a blanket licence, the user is able, in
operations have been relatively unaffected by one transaction, to obtain the right to perform pub-
ASCAP and BMI wars with government and users'. licly any or all of the compositions in the repertoire
Although there are statutory provisions in the of the domestic society, as well as works of affiliated
United Kingdom which control the way in which foreign societies, most of which are linked by means
collecting societies exercise the rights assigned to of reciprocal representation agreements.
them, the Competition Act 1980, s.30, has inserted a In CBS Inc. v. ASCAP the blanket licensing
provision into the Restrictive Trade Practices Act format was subjected to its most 'intensive antitrust
1976, to the effect that the latter statute is not to scrutiny'. The court concluded that the purchaser of
apply to certain licences granted by the owner or a a blanket licence secures a package consisting of the
licensee of any copyright, assignments of copyright, right to use the licensed compositions and the per-
or agreements for such a licence or assignment. forming right organisation's aggregating service.
The activities of performing rights organisations What was licensed, therefore, was the pooled aggre-
have come under the scrutiny of the European gate of the property conglomerate assigned to
Commission.' However, these decisions did not ASCAP by its members. The court emphasised
deal directly with the legality or otherwise of blanket that: 'the whole is truly more than the sum of its
licensing. Nevertheless, the observations are per- parts; it is, to some extent, a different product'.'
tinent to all performing rights organisations since all The court saw ASCAP not as 'a joint sales agency
are similarly constituted and all licence their offering the individual goods of many sellers' but
members' performing rights collectively and in rather a 'separate seller' able to offer a new product
bulk. for the market, the raw material of that product
First, how does broadcast music come to be being the compositions of ASCAP's members.s
selected? This occurs in one of three ways. It may be
selected by the broadcaster himself, or by the pro-
ducer of a programme which is sold to the broad- 2 The blanket licence in its copyright-
caster, or by a performer spontaneously. The antitrust setting
majority of music broadcast is selected by the pro-
ducer of programmes supplied to the companies. In The licensor offering blanket licensing is vulnerable
some instances these are the major television to antitrust attack for four principal reasons:
companies and these programmes are known as First, the blanket licence approach has the effect
'network-produced' programmes. Apart from of precluding competition among its contributors.
these there are 'syndicators' supplying 'syndicated' The licensor is an organisation which, by its nature,
programmes. These are defined as a theatrical is directed towards concerted actions by parties who
motion picture, pre-recorded or live television pro- would otherwise be direct competitors.
gramme which is offered for sale or licence to Secondly, through the agency of the licensor, the
a television company to be broadcast as a 'non- competitors jointly determine the price for their
network programme'. work.

20 MEDIA LAW & PRACTICE, MARCH 1988


Thirdly, the blanket licence forces users to pur- Society (MCPS), this latter acting as agent. PRS
chase music which they neither want nor intend to grants such licences in respect of music composed
use; in effect, a crude tying arrangement.' especially for films. In the US the Harry Fox Agency
Fourthly, it could be used as a significant barrier would act as broker.
to entry into the market. The court in BMI v. Moor- The plaintiff local television broadcasters in
Law Inc.7 pointed out that the user himself had Buffalo Broadcasting Co. Inc. v. ASCAP sought
a considerable incentive to resist the entry of to prove that source licensing was not realistically
new performing rights organisations into the available and would remain so unless the court
market. When the European Commission decided declared blanket licensing unlawful. In the absence
to investigate the position of the West German of blanket licensing, argued the plaintiffs, source
national society, GEMA, it was none other than the licensing would evolve as the most efficient system.'
European Broadcasting Union, the organisation of The plaintiffs sought to establish, by presenting
major music users, which leapt to its support. In a two types of evidence, that source licensing was not
letter of 4 June 1969 to the Commission it said 'if a realistic alternative: first, that they had attempted
competition were to be artificially created in this to obtain performing rights from syndicators with-
sphere it would be to the detriment of broadcasting out success and secondly, by an analysis of the
organisations which, far from deriving benefit from market.
it, would suffer consequences economically harmful Evidence of unavailability was unconvincing
to them'. The alternative to one all-or-nothing for two reasons. First, the plaintiffs had shown no
licence might otherwise be the negotiation of interest in source licensing until they began to col-
several blanket licences at a higher total cost. This late evidence of alleged unavailability some 18
is in fact the position in, among other countries, months after the institution of proceedings. This
Brazil, which has multiple organisations. was so even during the period from 1950 to 1972
when the 'carve-out' provision of the blanket licence
issued by BMI permitted companies to deduct from
4. The alternatives
the revenue base of the blanket licence fee
4.1 'Source licensing' or 'Clearance at the source' the revenue from programmes for which music per-
forming rights were cleared at the source, whether
Source licensing is the process whereby the pro- or not clearance was accomplished by licensing from
gramme producer obtains the music performing BMI.
right from the copyright owner in a one-time buy- Secondly, the plaintiffs' so-called 'offers' to
out before any performances occur and conveys syndicators asking these to undertake the clearance
it to the television company which gives the per- of music performance rights, were made without
formances of the music when the programme is offer of additional payment. In one case, the plain-
broadcast. tiffs simply inserted into the licensing agreement for
Source licensing is probably the most disadvan- syndicated programmes a warranty specifying that
tageous arrangement for composers and authors the producer had obtained music performing rights.
seeking equitable remuneration. In general, no one Whilst the syndicator, unsurprisingly, declined to
can be certain when a film, radio or television pro- agree to the proposed addition, he did not reject the
gramme is made, what the economic returns on the concept but merely indicated that substantial new
whole or its parts will ultimately be. In this state of obligations should be the subject of negotiation.
uncertainty 'at the source', the typically weak bar- The District Court below found as a matter of
gaining position of the composer is at its weakest. fact that the market was weighted heavily in favour
He may be compelled as a practical matter to accept of the syndicator. Yet the court also found that
a lump sum for his work that bears no relation to the there were eight major syndicators distributing
quality or success of the work. Unless the composer approximately half the number of all syndicated
has sufficient power to bargain successfully for fair programmes and that the production of such pro-
residual payments proportioned to actual uses, or grammes was a 'risky business'. o It is difficult on the
for a short, re-negotiable grant of rights, his pros- basis of these findings to concur with the District
pects of obtaining such terms are few. Court's characterisation of the market as uncom-
The availability of source licensing is particularly petitive. Even assuming that the syndicator has the
significant to companies whose programming con- upper hand, would he be as unresponsive as the
sists largely of syndicated programmes, since their companies allege in the face of overwhelming
producer could, if he so desired, convey performing aggregate demand for clearance at the source
rights together with the programme. In keeping coupled with reasonable offers of payment for so
with the consistency of this approach, the producer valuable a commodity?
would have additionally to acquire the mechanical
or synchronisation right colloquially, 'synch right' in 4.2 'Direct licensing'
the copyright musical work. These are rights to Direct licensing provides for direct negotiation
record. The synch right is the right of a film producer between television companies and individual com-
to record in timed relation with audiovisual works. posers.
In the UK this would be granted either by the The District Court stated that direct licensing
publisher or the Mechanical Copyright Protection could not occur without the intervention of some
MEDIA LAW & PRACTICE, MARCH 1988 21
agency to act as broker in the numerous transactions between the two rates lay largely with the television
that would be involved and that the local (i.e. small) companies themselves. In US v. ASCAP - Appli-
television companies lack the market power to cation of Shenandoah Valley Broadcasting Inc.,'s it
induce anyone to come forward and perform that was the companies which decided not to press for a
broking function." The Court of Appeals of the reduction in the programme licence rate and instead
Second Circuit agreed with the first proposition, but to concentrate on the blanket licence rate.
was unable, on the evidence, to concur with the Finally, licence rates and reporting restrictions so
second. The Court of Appeals believed that Judge burdensome as to prevent a company from having a
Gagliardi in the court below had reached the con- genuine choice between the two licensing formats
clusion that no-one would perform the necessary would be subject to review by the District Judge for
broking function, not on the basis of evidence of an the Southern District of New York who supervises
expressed reluctance on anyone's part to broker the operation of the consent decrees.
direct licensing, but because local television com-
panies lacked the necessary market attracting force.
In CBS v. ASCAP, Judge Lasker had found that if 4.4 'Per-piece licensing'
CBS were to seek direct licensing, 'copyright Per-piece licensing represents the antithesis of
proprietors would wait at CBS's door'. Judge blanket licensing. It involves the separation and
Gagliardi in Buffalo Broadcasting found that 'local selection of musical compositions, enabling users to
television stations acting individually and severally select desired compositions and discard undesired
would possess no such awesome power over copy- ones.
right owners." 3 The Court of Appeals said that it is In an objective sense, blanket licensing operates
to disregard the functioning of the market simply as a tying mechanism. Performing rights organisa-
to conclude that one is unable to secure direct licens- tions condition the sale of performance rights to
ing because he is weaker than another; what is users, on the user's purchase of their entire (tied)
important is the perception, either existing or cap- stock of performance rights. Per-piece licensing is
able of stimulation, of aggregate demand. thus not only impractical, but may also serve to lay
Finally, some local television companies were the foundation for a charge of discrimination against
able to obtain direct licences for the bulk of their the performing rights organisation, vis-h-vis its
locally produced programmes and at reasonable members.
pnces.

4.3 'Programme' or 'Per-Programme Licensing' 5. Conclusions


This is a modified form of the blanket licence. It
The local television broadcasters set out to prove
conveys to the television company the music per-
that the blanket licence constituted a restraint on
forming rights to all the music in the repertoire of the
competition. They attempted to do this by arguing
licensor for use in the particularprogramme for
that no other alternative to the blanket licence was
which the licence is issued. ASCAP and BMI are
realistically available to them. Instead, they demon-
required to offer per-programme licences pursuant
strated merely that the lack of use of the alternatives
to the consent decrees under which they operate.
reflected the superiority of the blanket licence. It is
While 748 local companies operated under blanket
purchased because it is less costly than the next best
licences, only two held programme licences. 14
alternative.
The plaintiffs contended that the programme
licence - expressed as a percentage of revenue - was Therefore, what are the precise advantages of the
too costly. The programme licence rate was set at blanket licence? They are as follows:
9%; the blanket licence rate varied between 1% First, they reduce the costs of licensing copyright
and 2%. Also, objection was taken to the onerous musical compositions by eliminating multiple nego-
reporting obligations required by programme tiations of the various rights. Even if the Buffalo
licences. broadcasters could have transferred contractually
The Court of Appeals demonstrated clearly the the obligation of performing right clearance to pro-
falsity of these arguments. With regard to cost, the ducers of syndicated programmes, not only is it
rates are charged on different bases. The blanket reasonable to assume that the necessary costs would
licence rate is applied to a company's total revenue; have been passed on to the broadcasters - albeit in
the programme licence rate is applied to revenue some other guise - but that the broadcasters would
from a particular programme. Since the base for the at some stage have been compelled to revert to
blanket licence fee includes revenue from network direct or programme licensing in respect of their
programmes for which the 'networks' have already locally produced programming. This alternative
acquired performing rights by virtue of their blanket strategy could only reasonably be contemplated by a
licences, as well as some local programmes that use decision to forego the blanket licence lest double-
no music, it is inevitable that the rate for a local payment be incurred.
company's blanket licence will be less than the rate Secondly, the licensor obtains together with his
for a programme licence taken solely to permit use licence the practical assurance that he is not infring-
of music on a particular programme. ing a musical copyright. This protection is qualified
Also, the blame for the degree of difference by the limited extent to which any organisation is not
22 MEDIA LAW & PRACTICE, MARCH 1988
a 100% monopoly and performing rights subsist NOTES
outside its repertoire.
Thirdly, broadcasters must have the immediate 1. Kernochan, Music Performing Rights Organisations, 10
right to use any number of compositions. They COLUM-VLA JL&Arts, 335, 340 [1986].
z. See: Re Gema [1971] CMLR D.35; BRT v. SABAM [1974]
cannot wait for contracts to be drawn up with indivi- 2 CMLR 238; Greenwich Film Production v. SACEM
dual publishers or composers, let alone be forced to [1980] 1 CMLR 629.
locate their heirs or assigns. 3. (1979) 441 US.
4. CBS 111, 441 US at 21-2.
'More recently, the local television broadcasters 5. Ibid. at 22.
have attempted to gain by legislation what they 6. In a conversation with the author, Mr Skip Humphries,
could not gain by litigation. They have procured the Head of Music Services, LWT, to whom gratitude is expres-
introduction of two bills in Congress which would sed, said that since the bulk of music is chosen by pro-
gramme producers, he could not say with certainty which
outlaw the blanket licence and limit the licensing musical compositions his company would not require.
market-place to but one form of so-called "source" 7. 527 F. Supp. 758 (D. Del. 1981).
licensing. One of the arguments the broadcasters 8. 546 F. Supp. 274, (SDNY 1982).
use in advocating this legislation is that the perform- 9. Ibid. at 292.
10. Ibid. at 282.
ing right societies do not negotiate but instead offer 11. Ibid. at 290.
terms on a "take-it-or-leave-it-basis." 6 12. 620 F. 2d 938.
13. 546 F. Supp. 274, at 290.
Thus begins yet another chapter in the history of 14. Ibid. at 288.
antitrust attacks launched against the American 15. Civ. Action No. 13-95 (SDNY) Final Order entered
performing right societies. The prediction of a 28.7.1969.
quietus on this subject is perhaps after all best left to 16. Korman & Koenigsberg. Performing Right Societies'
Journal, Copyright Society of the USA (1986) 332.
the prophets."
17. Rifkind, Music Copyrights and Antitrust: a Turbulent
Tony Martino, formerly ITV Association and PRS; Courtship, 1985 Cardozo Arts and Entertainment LJ 1.
Gamlens, Solicitors in London, England

Ten years of 'neutral reportage' doctrine:


US approach to defamatory republication
KYU HO YOUM, PHD

The US Supreme Court, recognising the general separate tort to republish a defamatory statement of
practices of news publication, observed in 1971: another under its 'republication doctrine" unless
'[A] vast amount of what is published in the daily and the publication is protected by the common law 'fair
periodical press purports to be descriptive of what report' privilege.6 The 'actual malice' rule estab-
somebody said rather than what somebody did. lished by the US Supreme Court in New York Times
Indeed, perhaps the largest share of news concern- Co. v. Sullivan' requires that the media should not
ing the doings of government appears in the form of knowingly publish defamatory falsehoods about
accounts of reports, speeches, press conferences, public officials or public figures, or should not reck-
and the like.' 1 Media attorney Robert Sack, author lessly disregard the truth. Though the Sullivan rule
of the highly acclaimed Libel, Slander, and Related has substantially ameliorated the restrictive impact
Problems, echoed the Supreme Court in stating that of the common law doctrine upon freedom of the
'[w]hat people say, rather than what they do, con- press, the media still should be subject to liability for
stitutes much of the news ... defamation concerning public officials or public
One obvious explanation for dissemination of figures upon a showing of actual malice.
news information by republishing the statements of The common law and constitutional restrictions
others is that either the substance of the statements on the press in republishing newsworthy but
is newsworthy or the act of making the statements defamatory statements have been a continuing
itself is newsworthy, or both.' The news media, concern for the media organisations in that they may
which are expected to strive for 'objectivity' in news be deterred from disseminating some vital infor-
reporting, 4 are merely serving as conveyors of what mation of public concern just because of their fear
they perceive to be newsworthy in republishing such that the media may assume liability for possible
statements. defamation resulting from the publications. Thus,
When it comes to republication of newsworthy it is understandable that the news media have
but false, defamatory statements, however, news clamoured for some way to allow them to republish
media find that their objective reporting by repub- false, defamatory statements of public interest with-
lishing the statements is impractical in terms of out being liable for failing to meet the actual malice
defamation law. The common law makes it a test.
MEDIA LAW & PRACTICE, MARCH 1988
23

You might also like