You are on page 1of 17

Module 2: Marginal analysis and Marginal analysis Analytical technique for

Consumer behavior solving optimization problems that involves


changing values of choice variables by small
2.1 Marginal Analysis for Optimal
amounts to see if the objective function can
Decisions
be further improved.
3.1 CONCEPTS AND TERMINOLOGY
3.2 UNCONSTRAINED
Making optimal decisions about the levels of MAXIMIZATION
various business activities is an essential
Any activity that decision makers might
skill for all managers, one that requires
wish to undertake will generate both benefits
managers to analyze benefits and costs to
and costs. Consequently, decision makers
make the best possible decision under a
will want to choose the level of activity to
given set of circumstances.
obtain the maximum possible net benefit
Objective function The function the from the activity, where the net benefit (NB)
decision maker seeks to maximize or associated with a specific amount of activity
minimize. (A) is the difference between total benefit
(TB) and total cost (TC) for the activity
Maximization problem An optimization
problem that involves maximizing the
objective function. NB = TB - TC
Minimization problem An optimization
problem that involves minimizing the
objective function. Net benefit, then, serves as the objective
function to be maximized, and the amount of
Activities or choice variables Variables activity, A, represents the choice variable.
that determine the value of the objective Furthermore, decision makers can choose
function. any level of activity they wish, from zero to
infinity, in either discrete or
Discrete choice variables A choice variable
continuous units. Thus, we are
that can take only specific integer values.
studying unconstrained maximization in this
Continuous choice variables A choice section.
variable that can take any value between two
end points.
Unconstrained optimization An
optimization problem in which the decision
maker can choose the level of activity from
an unrestricted set of values.
Constrained optimization An optimization
problem in which the decision maker
chooses values for the choice variables from
a restricted set of values.
Optimal level of activity The level of
activity that maximizes net benefit (A*)
In Panel A of Figure 3.1, net benefit at any
particular level of activity is measured by
the vertical distance between the total
benefit and total cost curves. At 200 units of
activity, for example, net benefit equals the
length of line segment CC', which happens
to be $1,000 as shown in Panel B at point c”.
Panel B of Figure 3.1 shows the net benefit
curve associated with the TB and TC curves
in Panel A. As you can see from examining
the net benefit curve in Panel B, the optimal
level of activity, A*, is 350 units, where NB
reaches its maximum value. At 350 units in
Panel A, the vertical distance between TB
Figure 3.1. Total benefit increases with and TC is maximized, and this maximum
higher levels of activity up to 1,000 units distance is $1, 225 (= NB*).
of activity (point G); then total benefit Two important observations can now be
falls beyond this point. Total cost begins made about A* in unconstrained
at a value of zero and rises continuously maximization problems.
as activity increases. These “typical”
curves allow us to derive general rules 1) The optimal level of activity does not
for finding the best solution to all such generally result in maximization of total
unconstrained problems, even though benefits.
specific problems encountered in later
In Panel A of Figure 3.1, you can see that
chapters sometimes involve benefit and
total benefit is still rising at the optimal
cost curves with shapes that differ
point B. As we will demonstrate later in this
somewhat from those shown in Panel A.
book, for one of the most
For example, total benefit curves can be important applications of this technique,
linear. Total cost curves can be linear or profit maximization, the optimal level of
even S-shaped. And, as you will see in later production occurs at a point where revenues
chapters, total cost curves can include fixed are not maximized.
costs when they take positive values at zero
2) The optimal level of activity in an
units of activity. In all of these variations,
unconstrained maximization problem
however, the rules for making the best
does not result in minimization of total
decisions do not change. By learning how to
cost.
solve the optimization problem as set forth
in Figure 3.1, you will be prepared to solve In Panel A, you can easily verify that total
all variations of these problems that come cost isn’t minimized at A* but rather at
later in the text. zero units of activity.
Marginal Benefit and Marginal Cost
Marginal benefit (MB) The change in total
benefit caused by an incremental change in
the level of an activity.
Marginal cost (MC) The change in total
cost caused by an incremental change in the
level of an activity.
Marginal benefit and marginal cost can be
expressed mathematically as

MB = Change in total The two panels in Figure 3.2 show how


benefit/Change in activity
the total curves in Figure 3.1 are related
=ΔTB/ΔA to their respective marginal curves.
Panel A in Figure 3.2 illustrates the
procedure for measuring slopes of total
and curves at various points or levels of
activity. Recall from your high school
math classes or a pre-calculus course in
MC = Change in total
college that the slope of a curve at any
cost/Change in activity
particular point can be measured by first
=ΔTC/ΔA
constructing a line tangent to the curve
at the point of measure and then
computing the slope of this tangent line
where the symbol “ΔΔ” means “the change by dividing the “rise” by the “run” of the
in” and A denotes the level of an activity. tangent line.
Since “marginal” variables measure rates of
change in corresponding “total” variables, Consider, for example, the slope of TB at
marginal benefit and marginal cost are also point C in Panel A. The tangent line at point
slopes of total benefit and total cost curves, C rises by 640 units (dollars) over a 100-unit
respectively. run, and total benefit’s slope at point C is
$6.40 (= $640/100). Thus the marginal
benefit of the 200th unit of activity is $6.40,
which means adding the 200th unit of
activity (going from 199 to 200 units) causes
total benefit to rise by $6.40.
You should understand that the value of
marginal benefit also tells you that
subtracting the 200th unit (going from 200
to 199 units) causes total benefit to fall by
$6.40. Because the slope of TB at point C is
$6.40 per unit change in activity, marginal
benefit at point c in Panel B is $6.40. You marginal cost) or decreased (if marginal
can verify that the same relation holds for cost exceeds marginal benefit) to reach the
the rest of the points shown on total benefit highest net benefit. The optimal level of the
(B, D, and G), as well as for the points activity—the level that maximizes net
shown on total cost (C', B', and D'). We benefit—is attained when no
summarize this important discussion in a further increases in net benefit are possible
principle: for any changes in the activity, which occurs
at the activity level for which marginal
Principle: Marginal benefit (marginal cost)
benefit equals marginal cost: MB = MC.
is the change in total benefit (total cost) per
unit change in the level of activity. The Maximization with Discrete Choice
marginal benefit (marginal cost) of a Variables
particular unit of activity can be measured
by the slope of the line tangent to the total
benefit (total cost) curve at that point of
activity.
Finding Optimal Activity Levels with
Marginal Analysis

To make optimal decisions for discrete


choice variables, decision makers must
increase activity until the last level of
activity is reached for which marginal
benefit exceeds marginal cost. We can
Notice in Figure 3.3 that, at 200 units of explain this rule for discrete choice
activity (point c”), net benefit is rising at variables by referring to Table 3.2, which
a rate of $3 (= $300/100) per unit shows a schedule of total benefits and
increase in activity, as it must since MB total costs for various levels of some
equals $6.40 and MC equals $3.40. activity, A, expressed in integers
between 0 and 8.

Let’s suppose the decision maker is


currently doing none of the activities and
wants to decide whether to undertake the
first unit of activity. The marginal benefit of
the first unit of the activity is $16, and the
Principle: If, at a given level of activity, a
marginal cost is $2.
small increase or decrease in activity causes
Undertaking the first unit of activity adds
net benefit to increase, then this level of the
$16 to total benefit and only $2 to total cost,
activity is not optimal. The activity must then
so net benefit rises by $14 (from $0 to $14).
be increased (if marginal benefit exceeds
The decision maker would choose to
undertake the first unit of activity to gain a
higher net benefit. Applying this reasoning
to the second and third units of activity leads
again to a decision to undertake more
activity. Beyond the third unit, however,
marginal cost exceeds marginal benefit for
additional units of activity, so no further
increase beyond three units of activity will
add to net benefit. As you can see, the
optimal level of the activity is three units
because the net benefit associated with three
units ($29) is higher than for any other level
of activity. These results are summarized in
the following principle:
Principle: When a decision maker faces an
unconstrained maximization problem and
must choose among discrete levels of an
activity, the activity should be increased if
MB >MC and decreased if MB < MC. The
optimal level of activity is reached—net
benefit is maximized—when the level of
activity is he last level for which marginal
benefit exceeds marginal cost. Sunk Costs, Fixed Costs, and Average
Costs Are Irrelevant
A. Sunk costs Costs that have previously
been paid and cannot be recovered.
B. Fixed costs Costs are constant and must
be paid no matter what level of the activity
is chosen.
Such costs are totally irrelevant in decision
making. They either have already been paid
and cannot be recovered, as in the case of
sunk costs, or must be paid no matter what a
manager or any other decision maker
decides to do, as in the case of fixed costs.
In either case, the only relevant decision
variables—marginal cost and marginal
revenue—are in no way affected by the
levels of either sunk or fixed costs.
Example: C. Average (unit) cost Cost per unit of
activity computed by dividing total cost by
Suppose you head your company’s
the number of units of activity.
advertising department and you have just
paid $2 million to an advertising firm for In order to make optimal decisions, decision
developing and producing a 30-second makers should not be concerned about
television ad, which you plan to air next whether their decision will push average
quarter on broadcast television networks costs up or down. The reason for ignoring
nationwide. The $2 million one-time average cost is quite simple: The impact on
payment gives your company full ownership net benefit of making an incremental change
of the 30-second ad, and your company can in activity depends only on marginal benefit
run the ad as many times as it wishes and marginal cost (ΔΔNB = MB - MC), not
without making any further payments to the on average benefit or average cost. In other
advertising firm for its use. Under these words, optimal decisions are made at the
circumstances, the $2 million payment is a margin, not “on the average.”
sunk cost because it has already been paid
To illustrate this point, consider the decision
and cannot be recovered, even if your firm
in Table 3.2 once again. The average cost of
decides not to use the ad after all.
two units of activity is $3 (=$6/2) and
During the meeting, the company’s media average cost for three units of activity is
buyer informs you that 30-second television $3.67 (= $11/3). Recall from our earlier
spots during American Idol will cost discussion, the decision to undertake the
$250,000 per spot. The marketing research third unit of activity is made because the
experts at the meeting predict that the 24th marginal benefit exceeds the marginal cost
time the ad runs it will generate $270,000 of ($10 > $5), and net benefit rises. It is
additional sales, while running it a 25th will completely irrelevant that the average cost
increase sales by $210,000. of three units of activity is higher than the
average cost of two units of activity.
Using the logic of marginal analysis, the
Alternatively, a decision maker should not
marketing team decides running the new ad
decrease activity from three units to two
24 times next quarter is optimal because the
units just to achieve a reduction in average
24th showing of the ad is the last showing
cost from $3.67 to $3 per unit of activity;
for which the marginal benefit exceeds the
such a decision would cause net benefit to
marginal cost of showing the ad:
fall from $29 to $24.
MB = $270,000 >$ 250,000 = MC
The following principle summarizes the role
It would be a mistake to go beyond 24 of sunk, fixed, and average costs in making
showings because the 25th showing would optimal decisions:
decrease net benefit; the change in net
Principle: Decision makers wishing to
benefit would be -$40,000 (= $210,000 -
maximize the net benefit of an activity
$250,000).
should ignore any sunk costs, any fixed
Another type of cost that should be ignored costs, and the average costs associated with
in finding the optimal level of an activity is the activity because none of these costs
the average or unit cost of the activity. affect the marginal cost of the activity and
so are irrelevant for making optimal
decisions.
3.3 CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION
Retailers frequently advertise that their Even though machine B provides a higher
products give “more value for your money.” marginal benefit, its marginal benefit per
People don’t usually interpret this as dollar spent is lower than that for machine
meaning the best product in its class or the A. Machine A is a better deal than machine
one with the highest value. Neither do they B because it yields higher marginal benefit
interpret it as meaning the cheapest per dollar. The third copy machine produces
580,000 copies over its useful life and costs
The three brands do differ, however, in price $2,600. Machine C is neither the best
and in the number of copies the machines machine (580,000 , 600,000 copies) nor is it
will make before they wear out. Brand A’s the cheapest machine ($2,600 . $2,500), but
copy machine costs $2,500 and will produce of the three machines, machine C provides
about 500,000 copies before it wears out. the greatest marginal benefit per dollar
The marginal benefit of this machine is spent:
500,000 (MBA = 500,000) since the
machine provides the law office with the
ability to produce 500,000 additional copies.
To find the marginal benefit per dollar
spent on copy machine A, marginal benefit
is divided by price (PA = 2,500): On a bang per buck basis, you would rank
machine C first, machine A second, and
machine B third.
When choosing among different activities, a
decision maker compares the marginal
You get 200 copies for each of the dollars benefits per dollar spent on each of the
spent to purchase copy machine A. activities. Marginal benefit (the “bang”), by
itself, does not provide sufficient
Now compare machine A with machine B, information for decision-making purposes.
which will produce 600,000 copies and costs Price (the “buck”), by itself, does not
$4,000. The marginal benefit is greater, but provide sufficient information for making
so is the price. To determine how “good a decisions. It is marginal benefit per dollar
deal” you get with machine B, compute the spent (the “bang per buck”) that matters in
marginal benefit per dollar spent on machine decision making.
B:
Constrained Maximization
In the general constrained maximization
problem, a manager must choose the levels
of two or more activities in order to
maximize a total benefit (objective) function
subject to a constraint in the form of a
budget that restricts the amount that can be purchasing two less units of activity B
spent. causes total benefit to fall by 20 units. The
combined total benefit from activities A and
Consider a situation in which there are two
B rises by 20 units (= 40 - 20) and the new
activities, A and B. Each unit of activity A
combination of activities (A = 21 and B = 8)
costs $4 to undertake, and each unit of
costs the same amount, $100, as the old
activity B costs $2 to undertake. The
combination. Total benefit rises without
manager faces a constraint that allows a total
spending any more than $100 on the
expenditure of only $100 on activities A and
activities.
B combined. The manager wishes to allocate
$100 between activities A and B so that the Naturally, the manager will continue to
combined total benefit from both activities is increase spending on activity A and reduce
maximized. spending on activity B as long as
MBA/PA exceeds MBB/PB. In most
The manager is currently choosing 20 units
situations, the marginal benefit of an activity
of activity A and 10 units of activity B. The
declines as the activity increases.
constraint is met for the combination 20A
and 10B since ($4 x 20) + ($2 x10) = $100. Consequently, as activity A is increased,
For this combination of activities, suppose MBA gets smaller. As activity B is
that the marginal benefit of the last unit of decreased, MBB gets larger. Thus as
activity A is 40 units of additional benefit spending on A rises and spending on B falls,
and the marginal benefit of the last unit of B MBA/PA falls and MBB/PB rises. A point is
is 10 units of additional benefit. In this eventually reached at which activity A is no
situation, the marginal benefit per dollar longer a better deal than activity B; that is,
spent on activity A exceeds the marginal MBA/PA equals MBB/PB. At thispoint,
benefit per dollar spent on activity B: total benefit is maximized subject to the
constraint that only $100 is spent on the two
activities.
If the original allocation of spending on
Spending an additional dollar on activity A
activities A and B had been one, where
increases total benefit by 10 units, while
spending an additional dollar on activity B
increases total benefit by 5 units. Because
the marginal benefit per dollar spent is
greater for activity A, it provides “more
bang per buck” or is a better deal at this the manager would recognize that activity B
combination of activities. is the better deal. In this case, total benefit
could be increased by spending more on
To take advantage of this fact, the manager
activity B and less on activity A while
can increase activity A by one unit and
maintaining the $100 budget. Activity B
decrease activity B by two units (now, A =
would be increased by two units for every
21 and B = 8). This combination of activities one-unit decrease in activity A (in order to
still costs $100 [($4 x 21) +($2 x 8) = $100].
satisfy the $100 spending constraint) until
Purchasing one more unit of activity A
causes total benefit to rise by 40 units, while
the marginal benefit per dollar spent is equal this situation, the marginal benefit per dollar
for both activities: spent on activity A exceeds the marginal
benefit per dollar spent on activity B:

If there are more than two activities in the


objective function, the condition is expanded Because the marginal benefit per dollar
to require that the marginal benefit per dollar spent is greater for activity A than for
spent be equal for all activities. activity B, activity A gives “more for the
money.”
Principle: To maximize total benefits subject
to a constraint on the levels of activities, To take advantage of activity A, the
choose the level of each activity so that the manager can reduce activity B by one unit,
marginal benefit per dollar spent is equal for causing total benefit to fall by 60 units and
all activities reducing cost by $20. To hold total benefit
constant, the 60 units of lost benefit can be
made up by increasing activity A by two
units with a marginal benefit of 30 each. The
two additional units of activity A cause total
cost to rise by $10. By reducing activity B
and at the same time, the chosen level of by one unit and increasing activity A by two
activities must also satisfy the constraint. units, the manager reduces total cost by $10
Constrained Minimization (= $20 - $10) without reducing total benefit.

Constrained minimization problems involve As long as MBA/PA . MBB/PB, the


minimizing a total cost function (the manager will continue to increase activity A
objective function) subject to a constraint and decrease activity B at the rate that holds
that the levels of activities be chosen such TB constant until
that a given level of total benefit is achieved.
Consider a manager who must minimize the
total cost of two activities, A and B, subject
to the constraint that 3,000 units of benefit
are to be generated by those activities. The If there are more than two activities in the
price of activity A is $5 per unit and the objective function, the condition is
price of activity B is $20 per unit. Suppose expanded to require that the marginal
the manager is currently using 100 units of benefit per dollar spent be equal for all
activity A and 60 units of activity B and this activities.
combination of activity generates total Principle: In order to minimize total costs
benefit equal to 3,000. At this combination subject to a constraint on the levels of
of activities, the marginal benefit of the last activities, choose the level of each activity so
unit of activity A is 30 and the marginal that the marginal benefit per dollar spent is
benefit of the last unit of activity B is 60. In equal for all activities
consists of 20X and 40Y, bundle C
consists of 40X and 20Y, and so on. Two
important assumptions must be made
about how people rank bundles of goods:
and at the same time, the chosen level of consumer preferences must be complete
activities must also satisfy the constraint. and transitive.
2.2 Theory of Consumer Behavior Complete preference ordering Consumers
Understanding consumer behavior is the first are able to rank all conceivable bundles of
step in making profitable pricing, commodities.
advertising, product design, and production For example, a consumer who is confronted
decisions. Firms spend a great deal of time with bundles A and B in Figure 5.1 must be
and money trying to estimate and forecast able to make one of the following three
the demand for their products. possible responses:
Some of the information needed by the 1. I prefer bundle A to bundle B (denoted as
company are: A > B).
How are consumer preferences used to 2. I prefer bundle B to bundle A (denoted as
determine demand? B > A).
How do consumers allocate income to the 3. I am indifferent between bundles A and B
purchase of different goods? (denoted as A ~ B).
How do consumers with limited income Transitive preference ordering Consumer
decide to buy? preferences are transitive if A > B, and B >
5.1 BASIC ASSUMPTIONS OF C, then it follows that A > C.
CONSUMER THEORY The Utility Function
Consumption bundle A particular Utility Benefits consumers obtain from the
combination of specific quantities of goods goods and services they consume.
or services.
Utility function An equation that shows an
individual’s perception of the level of utility
that would be attained from consuming each
conceivable bundle of goods:

U = f (X, Y)

where X and Y are, respectively, the


Figure 5.1 shows a number of typical amounts of goods X and Y consumed, f
consumption bundles for two goods, X means “a function of” or “depends on,” and
and Y. Bundle A consists of 10 units of
U is the amount of utility the
good X and 60 units of good Y, bundle B
person receives from each combination of X
and Y. Thus, utility depends on the make the consumer indifferent between
quantities consumed of X and Y. the two combinations.

The actual numbers assigned to the levels of Indifference curves are downward sloping
utility are arbitrary. We need only say that if Because the consumer obtains utility from
a consumer prefers one combination of both goods, when more X is added, some Y
goods, say, 20X and 30Y, to some other must be taken away in order to maintain the
combination, say, 15X and 32Y, the amount same level of utility. Consequently,
of utility derived from the first bundle is indifference curves must be downward
greater than the amount from the second sloping.
U = f (20 , 30) > U =f (15, 32) Indifference curves are convex. A convex
shape means that as consumption of X is
5.2 INDIFFERENCE CURVES
increased relative to consumption of Y, the
Indifference curve A set of points consumer is willing to accept a smaller
representing different bundles of goods and reduction in Y for an equal increase in X in
services, each of which yields the same level order to stay at the same level of utility.
of total utility.
Begin at point A, with 10 units of X and 60
units of Y. In order to increase the
consumption of X by 10 units, to 20, the
consumer is willing to reduce the
consumption of Y by 20 units, to 40. Given
indifference curve I, the consumer will be
indifferent between the two combinations
represented by A and B.
Next begin at C, with 40X and 20Y. From
this point, to gain an additional 10 units of X
(move to point D), the consumer is willing
Figure 5.2 shows a representative to give up only 5 units of Y, much less than
indifference curve with the typically the 20 units willingly given up to obtain 10
assumed shape. All combinations of more units at point A. The convexity of
goods X and Y along indifference curve I indifference curves implies a diminishing
yield the consumer the same level of
marginal rate of substitution, to which we
utility. In other words, the consumer is
now turn.
indifferent among all points, such as
point A, with 10 units of X and 60 units Marginal Rate of Substitution A measure
of Y; point B, with 20X and 40Y; point C, of the number of units of Y that must be
with 40X and 20Y; and so on. At any given up per unit of X added so as to
point on I, it is possible to take away maintain a constant level of utility.
some amount of X and add some amount
of Y and leave the consumer with the
same level of utility. Conversely, we can
add X and take away just enough Y to The marginal rate of substitution is 2,
meaning that the consumer is willing to give smaller, the (absolute value of the)
up two units of Y for each unit of X added. tangent line becomes a better and better
Because it would be cumbersome to have approximation of the MRS at that point.
the minus sign on the right side of the
Indifference Maps
equation, the marginal rate of substitution is
defined as

For the movement from C to D along I, the


marginal rate of substitution is

In this case the consumer is willing to give The indifference map in Figure 5.4
up only ½ unit of Y per additional unit of X consists of only four indifference curves.
added. We could have drawn many, many more.
Therefore, the marginal rate of substitution Relation: An indifference map consists of
diminishes along an indifference curve. several indifference curves. The higher (or
When consumers have a small amount of X further to the right) an indifference curve,
relative to Y, they are willing to give up a the greater the level of utility associated
lot of Y to gain another unit of X. When with the curve. Combinations of goods on
they have less Y relative to X, they are higher indifference curves are preferred to
willing to give up less Y in order to gain combinations on lower curves.
another unit of X.
A Marginal Utility Interpretation of MRS
The addition to total utility that is
attributable to the addition of one unit of a
good to the current rate of consumption,
holding constant the amounts of all other
goods consumed.
The change in total utility that results when
both X and Y change by small amounts is
related to the marginal utilities of X and Y
Figure 5.3 shows, if the movement is as
along the indifference curve, only a little
less than 0.75 unit of Y must be
sacrificed to remain indifferent. ΔU = (MUx × ΔX) + (MUy ×
Nevertheless, the (absolute value of the) ΔY)
slope of the tangent line is a fairly close
approximation of the exact MRS. As the
changes in X and Y become smaller and
where MUx and MUy are the marginal 5.3 THE CONSUMER’S BUDGET
utilities of X and Y, respectively. To CONSTRAINT
illustrate this relation, suppose a consumer
If consumers had unlimited incomes or if
increases consumption of X by 2 units (ΔΔX
goods were free, there would be no problem
= 2) and decreases consumption of Y by 1
of economizing. People could buy whatever
unit (ΔΔY = -1).
they wanted and would have no problem of
the marginal utility of X is 25 for each choice. But this is not generally the case.
additional unit of X, and the marginal utility Consumers are constrained as to what
of Y is 10. The amount by which utility bundles of goods they can purchase based on
changes is computed as the market determined prices of the goods
and on their incomes. We now turn to an
ΔU = (25 × 2) + (10 × −1) = 40
analysis of the income constraint faced by
Consuming 2 more X and 1 less Y causes consumers.
total utility to rise by 40 units of utility.
Budget Lines
For points on a given indifference curve, all
Consumers normally have limited incomes
combinations of goods yield the same level
and goods are not free. Their problem is how
of utility, so ΔΔU is 0 for all changes in X
to spend the limited income in a way that
and Y that would keep the consumer on the
gives the maximum possible utility. The
same indifference curve. From the above
constraint faced by consumers can be
equation, if ΔΔU = 0, it follows that
illustrated graphically.
Suppose the consumer has a fixed income of
ΔU = 0 = (MUx × ΔX) + (MUy × $1,000, which is the maximum amount that
ΔY) can be spent on the two goods in a given
period. For simplicity, assume the entire
income is spent on X and Y. If the price of
Therefore, solving for −ΔYΔX−ΔYΔX, X is $5 per unit and the price of Y is $10 per
unit, the amount spent on X ($5 ×× X) plus
the amount spent on Y ($10 ×× Y) must
−ΔY/ΔX= Mux /MUy equal the $1,000 income
$5X+$10Y=$1,000$5X+$10Y=$1,000
where−ΔYΔX−ΔYΔX is the negative of the
Alternatively, solving for Y in terms of X,
slope of the indifference curve, or the
marginal rate of substitution. Thus, the
marginal rate of substitution can be
interpreted as the ratio of the marginal utility The graph of this equation, shown in Figure
of X divided by the marginal utility of Y 5.5, is a straight line called the budget line.

MRS = Mux/MUy
The slope of the budget line, -1/2
(= ΔΔY/ΔΔX), indicates the amount of Y
that must be given up if one more unit of X
is purchased.
For every additional unit of X purchased, the
consumer must spend $5 more on good X.
To continue meeting the budget constraint,
$5 less must be spent on good Y; thus the
consumer must give up 1/2 unit of Y.

A budget line is the set of all combinations To illustrate this point, suppose the
or bundles of goods that can be purchased at consumer is currently purchasing bundle D
given prices if the entire income is spent. but wishes to move to bundle E, which is
Bundles costing less than $1,000 lie below composed of 1 more unit of X and 1/2 unit
AB. All bundles above budget line AB cost less of Y (see the blowup in Figure 5.5).
more than $1,000. Bundles D and E both cost $1,000 to
purchase, but the consumer must trade-off
Thus, the budget line divides the commodity 1/2 unit of good Y for the extra unit of good
space into the set of attainable bundles and X in bundle E.
the set of unattainable bundles.
The rate at which the consumer can trade-off
• To purchase any one of the bundles Y for one more unit of X is equal to the
of X and Y on the budget line AB in price of good X (here $5) divided by the
Figure 5.5, the consumer spends price of good Y (here $10); that is,
exactly $1,000.
• If the consumer decides to spend all
$1,000 on good Y and spend nothing Slope of the budget line =
on good X, 100 (= $1,000/$10) units −Px/Py
of Y can be purchased (point A in
Figure 5.5).
• If the consumer spends all $1,000 on where Px and Py are the prices of goods X
X and buys no Y, 200 (= $1,000/$5) and Y, respectively. In Figure 5.5, the slope
units of X can be purchased (point of the budget line is -1/2, which equals -
B). $5/$10.
• In Figure 5.5, consumption bundles
The relation between income (M) and the
C, with 40X and 80Y, and D, with
amount of goods X and Y that can be
120X and 40Y, represent two other
purchased can be expressed as
combinations of goods X and Y that
can be purchased by spending
exactly $1,000, because (80 x $10) + M = PxX + PyY
(40 x $5) = $1,000 and (40 x $10) +
(120 x $5) = $1,000.
This equation can also be written in the form Begin as before with the original budget line
of a straight line: AB and then let the price of X fall from $5
to $4 per unit.
Since M/Py does not change, the vertical
intercept remains at A (100 units of Y).
However, when Px decreases, the absolute
The first term, M/Py, gives the amount of Y value of the slope (Px/Py) falls to 4/10 (5
the consumer can buy if no X is purchased. $4y$10).
As noted, -Px/Py is the slope of the budget
line and indicates how much Y must be In this case, the budget line becomes less
given up for an additional unit of X. steep. After the price of X falls, more X can
be purchased if the entire income is spent on
The general form of a typical budget line is X. Thus the horizontal intercept increases
shown in Figure 5.6. from 200 to 250 units of X (= 1,000/$4).
In Panel B, the budget line pivots (or rotates)
from AB to AD. An increase in the price of
good X to $8 causes the budget line to pivot
backward, from AB to AC. The intercept on
the horizontal axis decreases to 125
(=$1,000/$8). When Px increases to $8, the
absolute value of the slope of the line,
The line AB shows all combinations of X Px/Py, increases to 8/10 (=$8/$10). The
and Y that can be purchased with the given budget line becomes steeper when Px rises,
income (M) and given prices of the goods while the vertical intercept remains constant.
(Px and Py). The intercept on the Y-axis, A,
Relation :An increase (decrease) in income
is M/Py; the horizontal intercept, B, is M/Px.
causes a parallel outward (inward) shift in
The slope of the budget line is -Px/Py.
the budget line. An increase (decrease) in
Shifting the Budget Line the price of X causes the budget line to pivot
inward (outward) around the
Panel A of Figure 5.7 shows the effect of original vertical intercept.
changes in income. Panel B shows the effect
of changes in the price of good X. 5.4 INDIVIDUAL DEMAND AND
MARKET DEMAND CURVES
We can now use the theory of consumer
utility maximization to derive a demand
curve for an individual consumer and, by
aggregating individual demand curves, we
can derive market demand curves.
An Individual Consumer’s Demand
Curve
Demand Schedule for Good X
In Table 5.1, the quantities demanded by
each consumer at each price in column 1
are shown in columns 2, 3, and 4. Column
5 shows the sum of these quantities
demanded at each price and is therefore
the market demand. Because the demand
for each consumer is negatively sloped,
market demand is negatively sloped also.
Quantity demanded is inversely related
to price.

Relation: The market demand curve is the


horizontal summation of the demand curves
Figure 5.9 to show how an individual of all consumers in the market. It therefore
consumer’s demand curve is obtained. shows how much all consumers demand at
Begin with income of $1,000 and prices of each price over the relevant range of prices.
good X and good Y both equal to $10. The
corresponding budget line is given by
budget line 1, from 100Y to 100X, in the
upper panel of the figure.
The consumer maximizes utility where
budget line 1 is tangent to indifference curve
I, consuming 50 units of X.
Thus when income is $1,000, one point on
this consumer’s demand for X is $10 and 50
Figure 5.10 shows graphically how a
units of X.This point is illustrated on the
market demand curve can be derived
price–quantity graph in the lower panel of
from the individual demand curves.
Figure 5.9.
The individual demands of consumers 1, 2,
Market Demand and Marginal Benefit
and 3 from Table 5.1 are shown graphically
Market demand A list of prices and the as D1, D2, and D3, respectively. The market
quantities consumers are willing and able to demand curve DM is simply the sum of the
purchase at each price in the list, other quantities demanded at each price. At $6,
things being held constant. consumer 1 demands 3 units. Because the
others demand nothing, 3 is the quantity
demanded by the market.
At every other price, DM is the horizontal
summation of the quantities demanded by
the three consumers. And if other consumers
came into the market, their demand curves
would be added to DM to obtain the new
market demand.
As explained in Chapter 2, the market
demand curve gives demand prices for any
quantity demanded of the good. Because the
demand price for a specific quantity
demanded is the maximum price consumers
will pay for that unit of a good, demand
price measures, in dollars, the economic
value or benefit to consumers of
that unit.
Thus, for any particular quantity demanded,
the price on the vertical axis of the market
demand curve measures two things:
(1) the maximum price consumers will pay
to buy that quantity of the good, and
(2) the dollar value of the benefit to buyers
of that particular unit of the good. A market
demand curve, then, gives the marginal
benefit (value) individuals place on the last
unit consumed.
Relation: The demand prices at various
quantities along a market demand curve
give the marginal benefit (value) of the last
unit consumed for every buyer in the market,
and thus market demand can be interpreted
as the marginal benefit curve for a good.

You might also like