You are on page 1of 6

The text discusses the origins of modern social science in the late nineteenth and twentieth centuries,

primarily driven by European attempts to understand the unique economic development of western
Europe. However, despite extensive efforts, there is no consensus on the factors that made Europe's
economic path distinctive. The focus of much literature has been on explaining Europe's early
development of large-scale mechanized industry, often attributing it to unique ingredients within Europe
or its freedom from certain impediments.

Various explanations, such as colonial extraction and overseas resources, have been proposed, but these
have not gained widespread acceptance. The text challenges the notion of "primitive accumulation" of
capital through dispossession, arguing that Europe's investible surplus grew through retained earnings
within its own borders. It emphasizes the exploitation of non-Europeans and access to overseas resources
but asserts that internal European growth also played a vital role.

The book contends that while western Europe may have had effective institutions for mobilizing capital
and early adoption of labor-saving technologies, differences existed, and the great transformation of the
nineteenth century occurred in the context of Europe's privileged access to overseas resources. It argues
against an either/or framework, advocating for an integrated approach that considers both internal and
external factors, combining comparative analysis and a global perspective.

Furthermore, the text criticizes existing literature for maintaining an either/or framework, either focusing
on a Europe-centered world system or attributing almost everything to endogenous European growth.
Recent scholarship in European economic history tends to reinforce an exclusively internal focus,
emphasizing market dynamics and downplaying the role of government policies and overseas coercion.

The author proposes a reciprocal comparative method, comparing regions like the Yangzi Delta, Kantó
plain, Britain, and the Netherlands directly, rather than relying on arbitrary continental units. This
approach aims to uncover similarities in agricultural, commercial, and proto-industrial development
among various parts of Eurasia until 1750 and to explain the rupture of further growth in western Europe
during the nineteenth century. The text argues for considering absences, accidents, and obstacles that
diverted Europe from other paths and for examining blockages that kept non-European areas from
reproducing European paths.

In summary, the text challenges prevailing narratives about the uniqueness of Europe's economic
development, advocating for a nuanced understanding that incorporates both internal and external factors
and employs reciprocal comparisons to shed light on historical processes.
Variations on the Europe-Centered Story: Demography, Ecology, and Accumulation

The text explores arguments proposing that western Europe possessed a unique capacity for industrial
transformation, mainly falling into two clusters. The first cluster, exemplified by E. L. Jones, contends
that Europe, between the sixteenth and eighteenth centuries, had surpassed the rest of the world in
accumulating both physical and human capital. This perspective attributes Europe's unique success to
demographic and economic behaviors that allowed it to adjust fertility, increase per capita capital stock,
and support a larger non-farming population.

However, recent research on birthrates, life expectancy, and demographics in China, Japan, and Southeast
Asia challenges this view, suggesting that what was once considered unique European achievements may
be more ordinary. The recognition of economic booms and rising living standards in preindustrial settings
outside Europe is acknowledged but often treated as temporary, susceptible to political shifts or
population growth outpacing productivity-enhancing innovations.

The text critiques these narratives for two anachronisms. First, it argues that they read contemporary
ecological disasters in Asia back into earlier periods, portraying eighteenth-century Asian societies as
having exhausted their possibilities. Second, they often internalize the ecological bounty gained by
Europe from the New World, overlooking the exceptional scale of this windfall, the coercive aspects of
colonization, and the global dynamics that facilitated European expansion.

To move beyond oversimplified claims, the text suggests a systematic comparison of ecological
constraints in key areas of China and Europe. It challenges the notion that Europe had plenty of room to
grow, arguing that if Europe's internal processes brought it close to a crisis, it was rescued by overseas
resources and England's breakthrough in using subterranean energy stores. The text also questions the
idea that high population growth in China, Japan, and India was a pathology blocking development,
proposing instead that it was an economic achievement comparable to Europe's industrialization.

The argument parallels the work of Sugihara Kaoru, emphasizing the high standard of living in
eighteenth-century Japan and China, as well as the sophistication of institutions supporting economic
achievements. It challenges Sugihara's suggestion that Europe was on a capital-intensive path while East
Asia was on a labor-intensive path, contending that Europe could have followed a labor-intensive path,
but discontinuities, including fossil fuels and New World resources, steered it in a different direction.

The text concludes by highlighting that population growth after 1750 in China and Japan was
concentrated in less-developed regions, with smaller surpluses to trade with resource-hungry cores. In
contrast, Europe experienced population increases in already advanced and densely populated areas. The
differences, rooted in political-economic and ecological factors, are not indicative of a greater overall
strain on resources in Asia compared to Europe. The text anticipates further exploration of these
differences and their significance for industrialization in subsequent chapters.
Other Europe-Centered Stories: Markets, Firms, and Institutions

The text presents a second group of arguments regarding the factors influencing Western Europe's
economic development during the early modern period. Scholars such as Fernand Braudel, Immanuel
Wallerstein, K. N. Chaudhuri, and Douglass North focus less on levels of wealth and more on the
emergence of institutions deemed conducive to economic development. These arguments highlight the
importance of efficient markets and property-rights regimes that rewarded productivity in utilizing land,
labor, and capital. A common assertion in these arguments is that economic development in other regions,
particularly China and India, was hindered either by a strong and anti-private property state or a weak
state incapable of protecting entrepreneurs from local customs, clergy, or strongmen.

Robert Brenner offers a distinct perspective, explaining divergent development paths within Europe
through class struggles that altered property-rights regimes. According to Brenner, Western European
peasants won the first round of struggles with their lords, gaining freedom from forced labor. In Eastern
Europe, peasants lost, and the ruling class continued to exploit them without modernizing agriculture.
Brenner further argues that a second round of struggle occurred within Western Europe, with English
lords winning the battle, investing in innovations that reduced labor costs, and leading to the expulsion of
unneeded workers from the land. Dispossessed farmers eventually became England's industrial
workforce.

Brenner's argument, emphasizing class struggle as the motor of the story, converges with Douglass
North's perspective, which emphasizes increasingly competitive markets for commodified land, labor,
capital, and intellectual property as drivers of economic development.

While North and Brenner focus on institutions shaping the majority's daily economic activities, another
set of institutionalist arguments represented by Braudel and his school concentrates on the profits
accumulated by a few wealthy individuals. These scholars emphasize institutions facilitating wealth
accumulation, often involving special privileges that interfere with neoclassical markets. They pay
attention to profits derived from coercion and collusion, particularly in long-distance trade. Wallerstein
sees the growth of trade between feudal Eastern Europe and capitalist Western Europe as the beginning of
a world economy, highlighting the role of western Europe's combination of relatively free labor,
productive urban populations, and supportive merchants and governments in facilitating long-distance
trade and profit reinvestment.

Despite variations in emphasis, these institutionalist arguments collectively underscore the role of
institutions, be they market-oriented or profit-driven with special privileges, in shaping Western Europe's
unique economic development during the early modern period. The international division of labor
resulting from this development increased wealth disparities between Western Europe and other regions,
with the core's specialization in goods requiring cheap, often coerced, labor contributing to this
divergence.
Problems with the Europe-Centered Stories

The text argues against the notion of a unique European economic advantage before 1800 and challenges
the idea of a distinct "European miracle" leading to industrialization. It suggests that industrial capitalism,
marked by the large-scale use of inanimate energy sources, only emerged in the 1800s. The author
contends that there is little evidence to support the belief that western Europe had decisive advantages in
capital stock or economic institutions that made industrialization probable there and unlikely elsewhere.

In Part 1 of the book, the author questions various claims about Europe's internal economic edge before
1800 and presents a perspective of broad similarities among the most densely populated and
commercialized parts of the Old World. Chapter 1 argues that Europe did not possess a crucial advantage
in physical capital before 1800 and was not freer of Malthusian pressures compared to other large
economies. The chapter also explores the technological edge in early modern Europe, acknowledging
differences but emphasizing the significance of geographic factors and access to overseas resources in
shaping the outcomes.

Chapter 2 focuses on markets and related institutions, particularly comparing western Europe and China.
The analysis suggests that, even as late as 1789, western European markets were probably further from
perfect competition than those in most of China. The chapter examines laws and customs related to land
ownership, agricultural output sales, labor practices, compulsory labor, migration, and changes in
occupations. The text concludes by discussing household relationships and labor allocation, asserting that
core regions in China and Japan circa 1750 resembled the most advanced parts of western Europe,
challenging the notion of a unique European trajectory. The author proposes that explanations for
subsequent divergence must be sought outside these core regions.

Building a More Inclusive Story

In Part 2 (chapters 3 and 4), the focus shifts from survival-oriented activities to new consumer demands,
exploring cultural and institutional changes associated with them. Chapter 3 examines differences in
consumer behavior between China, Japan, and western Europe, finding small and uncertain distinctions in
quantities and consumerist attitudes. The chapter suggests that Europe's favorable consumer behavior was
influenced by extra-European elements, such as the extraction of New World silver and the demand for it
in Asia. Chapter 4 explores merchants and manufacturers who brought new "luxuries" to market, moving
beyond typical households to examine factors of production like capital. It challenges arguments about
European merchants having a crucial advantage in amassing and deploying capital, emphasizing that
capital was not a scarce factor in the 18th century.

The chapter rejects claims that Europe's financial institutions gave it a significant edge, emphasizing the
importance of capital abundance, energy constraints, and the necessity of land in production. It challenges
the link between capital accumulation and industrialization, citing examples of capital-rich but late-
industrializing areas in Europe. The text argues that the abundance of capital before 1800, as highlighted
by Braudel, did not necessarily make Europe a better environment for productive activity.

Part 3 (chapters 5 and 6) introduces a new framework for understanding Europe's development. Chapter 5
addresses ecological obstacles to further growth in densely populated Eurasian areas, highlighting
shortages in fuel, building materials, and threats to soil fertility. It examines attempts to address these
shortages through long-distance trade, arguing that such trade had limitations. Chapter 6 explores
Europe's land constraint during industrialization, discussing the shift from wood to coal and the
ecological relief provided by relations with the New World. It emphasizes the role of slavery in creating a
new kind of periphery and how Europe used labor and capital to overcome land shortages.

Chapter 6 also discusses how core-periphery relations and the colonial period shaped proto-
industrialization, emphasizing the significance of differing long-term relations. It introduces the concept
of "pseudo-surplus labor" and discusses the limitations of proto-industrial growth, linking it to population
increases and ecological bottlenecks. The chapter concludes by comparing the ecological significance of
the Atlantic trade to England's turn to coal, suggesting that overseas exploitation was crucial in relieving
Europe's fundamental physical constraints until well into the 19th century.
Comparisons, Connections, and the Structure of the Argument

In Part 1, the text explores comparative analyses, contending that factors like accumulation levels,
demographic patterns, and specific markets might identify certain regions, such as western Europe, China,
and Japan, as potential settings for an economic shift. However, these factors alone cannot explain why
the shift occurred first in western Europe or why it happened at all. Technological differences are deemed
insufficient until the nineteenth century, when Europe's global interactions become integral to the story.

Moving into Part 2, intercontinental comparisons persist, with a growing emphasis on the importance of
intercontinental connections. The argument suggests that as economic activities become less tied to
physical necessity and involve a smaller population share, some distinctions in culture and institutions
emerge in western Europe compared to other "core" regions. However, these differences are seen as
matters of degree rather than kind and are limited in strength and scope. Claims of a unique "capitalist
mode of production" or "consumer society" for western Europe alone are challenged. Notably, discernible
differences often relate to deviations from simple market dynamics, such as state-licensed monopolies,
privileges, armed trade, and colonization.

In Part 3, the text returns to comparison, demonstrating that Europe's advantages, whether in "capitalism,"
"consumerism," or technological innovations, were insufficient to overcome shared ecological constraints
in various "core" areas of the Old World. Consensual trade with less densely populated regions had
limited potential for easing resource bottlenecks. The New World, influenced by global conjunctures,
emerges as more promising. Epidemics weakened resistance to European appropriation, and transatlantic
relations, including mercantilism and the African slave trade, facilitated the self-catalyzing flow of
needed resources to Europe. This dynamic, anticipating the modern world's division of labor between
primary product exporters and manufacturing regions, contributed to the creation of the world's first
"modern" core and periphery. The concluding idea is that connections and interactions, beyond mere
comparison, play a crucial role in explaining the uniqueness of western Europe's economic development.

A Note on Geographic Coverage

In outlining the book's main ideas, a cautionary note is issued regarding its geographic coverage. The
treatment of world regions is uneven, with a focus on China, western Europe, Japan, and south Asia,
while eastern Europe, southeast Asia, the Americas, Africa, the Middle East, central Asia, and Oceania
receive less attention. The approach involves both comparisons and connections for the former regions
and emphasizes interactions with other regions for the latter.

The author justifies this emphasis by highlighting the historical significance of China as the "other" in
Western narratives and the need to reconsider both Chinese and European development freed from this
juxtaposition. Furthermore, the narrative aligns with processes that spotlight densely populated parts of
the world and their trading interactions. Ongoing specialization is linked to high population density,
emphasizing the need for many people within an accessible distance to support elaborate economic
activities.

The argument's ecological dimension, central to the narrative, is closely tied to demography, making
densely populated areas more relevant. The author introduces the concept of "fully populated" areas,
where extensive growth is constrained without technological change, institutional improvements, or
increased access to land-intensive commodities through external trade. This criterion directs attention to
western Europe, China, Japan, and, to a lesser extent, India.

The author acknowledges limitations in his own training, making him better equipped to write about
certain regions, and emphasizes the empirical nature of exploring the applicability of "uniformitarianism"
across Afro-Eurasia. The emphasis on certain geographic areas is defended, considering available
literature and the need to put new questions on the agenda for rethinking the origins of the current
industrialized era. The focus on specific regions is not intended to diminish the importance of the rest of
the world but is deemed a reasonable distribution for the book's central theme.
 Conventional approaches

- Capital accumulation (creation of surplus, necessary to invest in industrialization), due to:

1. Overseas trade (colonial expansion).


2. Improvements in agriculture.
3. Institutions (who set rules to regulate social or economic activity) Such as:
contract enforcement, banks and capitalists’ institutions (private property).

- Capitalists’ markets

- Fertility, reduce in the levels of fertility to escape the Malthusian trap, increasing GDP per
capita.

 Pomeranz’s criticism

He doesn’t agree to the previous bc they were not that much unique in Europe, it also existed in other
parts of Asia. You find similar conditions in other parts of Eurasia.

Criticizing nation-states as units of analysis, bc for example China is as big as Europe, and inside China
there were different parts with different evolutions. Taking into comparison Europe with China is stupid,
for example, industrialization started in Britain, not Europe.

European societies were not special, there were areas in Eurasia that had similar technological growth.

Limitation in China: problems to being self sufficient foodwise. There wasn’t enough food. Availability
of land to produce food.

- Europe had not accumulated a crucial advantage in physical capital and was not freer of
Malthusian pressures.
- Availability of coal, Britain.
- Possibility of importing from New World, especially food.

Britain didn’t need land to produce energy or food, that’s what led to industrialization.

 Alternative approaches

You might also like