You are on page 1of 5

a.

The extent to which a producer or a consumer bears the tax burden is determined by the price
elasticity of demand and supply.

- Price Elasticity of Demand: If the demand for a good is inelastic (inelastic demand), meaning
that consumers are not very responsive to price changes, the burden of the tax will be
predominantly borne by the consumers. The producer will be able to pass on most of the tax to
the consumers without a significant decrease in quantity demanded.

- Price Elasticity of Supply: If the supply of a good is inelastic (inelastic supply), meaning that
producers are not very responsive to price changes, the burden of the tax will be predominantly
borne by the producers. The producers will have limited ability to pass on the tax to the
consumers, resulting in a decrease in their profits.

In general, the more elastic the demand or supply, the more the tax burden will be shifted to the
other party.

b.

- Lump Sum Tax: A lump sum tax is a fixed amount of tax that is imposed on individuals or
firms regardless of their income or the quantity of the good they consume or produce. It is a type
of tax that does not depend on the price or quantity of the good. For example, a fixed annual tax
of $500 per household is a lump sum tax.

- Proportional Tax: A proportional tax is a tax that is levied at a constant rate regardless of the
income or the quantity of the good involved. It is a type of tax where the tax rate remains the
same regardless of the income level or the price or quantity of the good. For example, a sales tax
of 10% on all goods is a proportional tax.

The key difference between the two is that a lump sum tax is a fixed amount, while a
proportional tax is a fixed percentage of income or price.
c. The demand for a pure private good is derived by adding the quantities demanded at each price
because private goods are rivalrous and excludable. The quantity demanded by individuals is
based on their own preferences and willingness to pay at different prices. Therefore, the
individual quantities demanded can be summed up to obtain the market demand curve for a
private good.

On the other hand, the demand for a pure public good is derived by adding how much people are
willing to pay at each quantity. Public goods are non-rivalrous and non-excludable, meaning that
one person's consumption does not reduce its availability to others. Since individuals cannot be
excluded from consuming a public good, their willingness to pay reflects the value they place on
an additional unit of the good. By summing up the amounts individuals are willing to pay at each
quantity, we can derive the demand curve for a public good.

Unfortunately, as a text-based model, I cannot provide diagrams. However, you can imagine a
typical demand curve for a private good sloping downward from left to right, representing the
quantities demanded at different prices. In contrast, the demand curve for a public good would be
derived by adding up the maximum amounts individuals are willing to pay at each quantity.

d. The socially optimal level of a public good occurs when the Marginal Social Benefit (MSB) of
the good is equal to its Marginal Social Cost (MSC). This is because the MSB represents the
additional benefit society receives from an additional unit of the public good, while the MSC
represents the additional cost society incurs to produce that unit.

In a diagram, the MSB curve for a public good is downward sloping, reflecting the diminishing
marginal benefit society derives from each additional unit. The MSC curve is upward sloping,
representing the increasing marginal cost of producing additional units of the public good. The
socially optimal level is achieved where the two curves intersect.

e. To calculate the effect of introducing a 20% VAT on the price and quantity demanded of match
boxes in Tanzania, we can use the demand and supply functions provided:

Demand function: P = 325 - 1.25Qd


Supply curve: P = 200 (perfectly elastic)
First, let's calculate the original equilibrium price and quantity demanded without the VAT:

Setting supply equal to demand:


200 = 325 - 1.25Qd

Solving for Qd:


1.25Qd = 325 - 200
1.25Qd = 125
Qd = 125 / 1.25
Qd = 100

Substituting the quantity back into the demand function to find the price:
P = 325 - 1.25(100)
P = 325 - 125
P = 200

So, the original equilibrium price is Tshs. 200 and the quantity demanded is 100.

Now, let's calculate the new equilibrium price and quantity demanded after introducing a 20%
VAT:

The VAT adds 20% to the price, so the new demand function becomes:
P + 0.2P = 325 - 1.25Qd

Simplifying:
1.2P = 325 - 1.25Qd
Substituting the supply curve:
200 + 0.2(200) = 325 - 1.25Qd

Simplifying:
240 = 325 - 1.25Qd

Rearranging the equation to solve for Qd:


1.25Qd = 325 - 240
1.25Qd = 85
Qd = 85 / 1.25
Qd = 68

Substituting the quantity back into the demand function to find the price:
P = 325 - 1.25(68)
P = 325 - 85
P = 240

So, the new equilibrium price with the 20% VAT is Tshs. 240, and the quantity demanded is 68.

To calculate the resulting deadweight loss and tax revenue collected, we need to compare the
new equilibrium with the original equilibrium.

Deadweight loss is the loss of consumer and producer surplus due to the imposition of the tax. In
this case, the deadweight loss can be calculated as the area of the triangle formed by the original
equilibrium quantity (100), the new equilibrium quantity (68), and the vertical distance between
the two equilibrium prices.
Deadweight loss = 1/2 * (100 - 68) * (200 - 240)

Tax revenue collected can be calculated as the tax per unit multiplied by the quantity demanded
with the tax:

Tax revenue = 0.2 * 240 * 68

You can calculate the exact values using the equations above.

You might also like