You are on page 1of 11

CORPORATE TAX AVOIDANCE AND FIRM VALUE

Author(s): Mihir A. Desai and Dhammika Dharmapala


Source: The Review of Economics and Statistics , August 2009, Vol. 91, No. 3 (August
2009), pp. 537-546
Published by: The MIT Press

Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/25651357

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms

The MIT Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
Review of Economics and Statistics

This content downloaded from


202.43.95.117 on Sat, 06 Feb 2021 01:20:48 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
CORPORATE TAX AVOIDANCE AND FIRM VALUE
Mihir A. Desai and Dhammika Dharmapala*

Abstract?Do corporate tax avoidance activities advance shareholder of tax avoidance as a transfer of value to shareholders. First,
interests? This paper tests alternative theories of corporate tax avoidance
using unexplained differences between income reported to capital markets
corporate expatriations?transactions where U.S. firms in
and to tax authorities. OLS estimates indicate that the effect of tax vert their corporate structure so that a subsidiary in a tax
avoidance on firm value is a function of firm governance, as predicted by
haven becomes the parent entity?provide significant cor
an agency perspective on corporate tax avoidance. Instrumental variables
estimates based on exogenous changes in tax regulations yield larger porate tax savings with limited, if any, operational changes.
overall effects and reinforce the basic result, as do several robustness However, markets do not react in a strongly positive fash
checks. The results suggest that the simple view of corporate tax avoid ion?and often react negatively?to U.S. firms' announcing
ance as a transfer of resources from the state to shareholders is incomplete
given the agency problems characterizing shareholder-manager relations. such moves (e.g., Desai & Hines, 2002). Second, an event
study of an episode of increased tax enforcement in Russia
indicates that these enforcement actions are associated with
I. Introduction
positive market reactions (Desai, Dyck, & Zingales, 2007).
These small sample studies are provocative but leave open
WHILE tax
manyconsequences
corporate decisions, are a motivating
managerial actions de factor in questions about the nature of corporate tax avoidance ac
signed solely to minimize corporate tax obligations are tivity generally and in larger samples.
thought to be an increasingly important feature of U.S. This paper investigates the degree to which corporate tax
corporate activity.1 Do such activities advance shareholder avoidance activity is valued by investors in a large sample
interests? If avoidance activities are costless to investors, of U.S. firms. While the traditional view of corporate tax
the question is trivial, as avoidance activity results in a avoidance suggests that shareholder value should increase
transfer of value from the state to shareholders. Indeed, this with tax avoidance activity, an agency perspective on cor
has been the presumption in the large literature on the porate tax avoidance provides a more nuanced prediction.
effects of taxes on financial decision making. Corporate tax Specifically, firm governance should be an important deter
avoidance activity, however, may be costly on several mar minant of the valuation of purported corporate tax savings.
gins. Aside from the direct costs of engaging in such While tax avoidance per se should increase the after-tax
activities, managers typically have to ensure that these value of the firm, this effect is potentially offset, particularly
actions are obscured from tax authorities. In the process, in poorly governed firms, by the increased opportunities for
such machinations may afford managers increased latitude rent diversion provided by tax shelters. Thus, the net effect
to pursue self-serving objectives. Can the latter effect be on firm value should be greater for firms with stronger
significant enough to change the simple answer that inves governance institutions.
tors fully capture the value of corporate tax avoidance The relative merits of these two views of tax avoidance
activity? are evaluated using a data set with 4,492 observations on
Two small sample studies indicate that the valuation of 862 firms over the period 1993-2001. This panel is drawn
tax avoidance activities may not conform to the simple story from the Compustat and Execucomp databases, merged
with data on institutional ownership of firms from the
Received for publication October 24, 2005. Revision accepted for CDA/Spectrum database. Firm value is measured using
publication February 22, 2008. Tobin's q, and governance quality is proxied for by the level
* Desai: Harvard University and NBER; Dharmapala: University of
Connecticut. of institutional ownership, reflecting the ability of institu
We thank the editor (Daron Acemoglu), two anonymous referees, Ro tional owners to monitor managerial performance more
sanne Altshuler, Alan Auerbach, Amy Dunbar, Ray Fisman, Sanjay Gupta,
aggressively. Tax avoidance is measured by inferring the
Michelle Hanlon, Jim Hines, Peter Katuscak, Mark Lang, Lillian Mills,
John Phillips, George Plesko, Dan Shaviro, Joel Slemrod, and John Wald difference between income reported to capital markets and
for helpful discussions and comments. We also thank Sanjay Gupta and tax authorities?the book-tax gap?and controlling for ac
Jared Moore for kindly providing the data used in section III on firms
cruals and other measures of earnings management. The
involved in tax shelter litigation. M.D. acknowledges the financial support
of the Division of Research of Harvard Business School, and D.D. analysis demonstrates that this measure takes on higher
acknowledges the financial support of the University of Connecticut values when a firm is involved in litigation relating to
Research Foundation.
aggressive tax sheltering activity.
1 See, for example, U.S. Department of the Treasury (1999), Bankman
(2004), and Slemrod (2004). The extensive literature on the effects of OLS results indicate that controlling for a variety of other
taxes on firms' behavior, as surveyed in Auerbach (2002) and Graham relevant factors including firm and year fixed effects, the
(2003), does not typically consider corporate tax avoidance. The literature
effect of the tax avoidance measure on q is positive but not
on individual tax avoidance and evasion, as surveyed in Slemrod and
Yitzhaki (2002), is extensive. Despite the differences between the indi significantly different from 0. As predicted by the agency
vidual and corporate contexts stressed by Slemrod (2004), there has been perspective on corporate tax avoidance, the effect is positive
relatively little theoretical modeling of tax compliance decisions by
corporations. Chen and Chu (2005) and Crocker and Slemrod (2005)
for those firm-years with high levels of institutional owner
analyze the distinct question of the nature of the optimal incentive contract ship. The interpretation of these results, however, is com
when managers can engage in tax evasion on behalf of the firm. plicated by the possibility of measurement error in the proxy

The Review of Economics and Statistics, August 2009, 91(3): 537-546


? 2009 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology

This content downloaded from


202.43.95.117 on Sat, 06 Feb 2021 01:20:48 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
538 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

for tax avoidance and by the potential endogeneity of tax The paper proceeds as follows. Section II presents the
avoidance activity. Specifically, it is possible that firms that alternative views of corporate tax avoidance. Section III
are performing worse for exogenous reasons may be more describes the data and the measure of corporate tax avoid
likely to engage in tax avoidance.2 Fortunately, a 1997 ance. Section IV presents the OLS results, while section V
regulatory change unintentionally and significantly changed describes the IV methodology and results. Section VI con
the costs of tax sheltering differentially across firms. This cludes.
source of exogenous variation permits the implementation
of an instrumental variables strategy that can be used to II. Theories of Corporate Tax Avoidance
address these concerns and to investigate the causal effect of
tax avoidance on firm value. The purported growth in corporate tax avoidance activity
has given rise to two alternative perspectives on the moti
The check-the-box regulations were designed to enable
vations and effects of this activity. Several studies investi
small firms to choose their organizational form for tax
gate corporate tax avoidance as an extension of other
purposes. Altshuler and Grubert (2005) and various practi
tax-favored activity, such as the use of debt. In particular,
tioners have observed that these regulations also had the
Graham and Tucker (2006) construct a sample of firms
unintended consequence of lowering the costs of tax avoid
involved in 44 corporate tax shelter cases over the period
ance for firms. Specifically, hybrid entities became increas
1975-2000. By comparing these firms with a matched
ingly common. These entities are classified as separately sample of firms not involved in such litigation, they identify
incorporated subsidiaries under the tax rules of one country characteristics (such as size and profitability) that are pos
while simultaneously being treated as unincorporated itively associated with the use of tax shelters and argue that
branches under the tax rules of another country. This flex tax shelters serve as a substitute for interest deductions in
ibility in entity classification creates a sizable tax avoidance determining capital structure. This paper is representative of
opportunity for firms with incentives to capitalize on these the common view that corporate tax shelters are merely
regulatory changes. The central idea underlying the identi tax-saving devices without any other agency dimensions.
fication strategy is that for a given incentive to engage in tax An alternative theoretical approach emphasizes the inter
avoidance, a firm will engage in more actual tax avoidance action of these tax avoidance activities and the agency
after the check-the-box regulations were adopted. A crucial problems inherent in publicly held firms. According to this
determinant of the incentives to engage in tax avoidance is view, obfuscatory tax avoidance activities can create a
the availability of tax shields. Thus, instruments for tax shield for managerial opportunism and the diversion of
avoidance are constructed by interacting a dummy variable rents. This perspective underlies several recent studies,
for the period after the check-the-box regulations with including Desai and Dharmapala (2006) and Desai et al.
variables (at the firm-year-level) that proxy for the avail (2007), and forms part of an emerging paradigm that em
ability of tax shields: net operating loss (NOL) carryfor phasizes the links between firms' governance arrangements
wards and two different measures of debt. and their responses to taxes.3 In this view, corporate tax
Instrumental variables (IV) estimates using the instru avoidance not only entails distinct costs, but these costs may
ments described above lead to results that are in the same outweigh the benefits to shareholders, given the opportuni
direction as the OLS results but are considerably stronger. ties for diversion that these vehicles provide. Desai and
The interaction between institutional ownership and tax Dharmapala (2009) discuss examples of the interaction
avoidance is positive and significant, as predicted by the between tax shelters and various forms of managerial op
agency perspective on tax avoidance. This result is robust to portunism, illustrating that straightforward diversion and
the inclusion of various additional control variables and a subtle forms of earnings manipulation can be facilitated
variety of extensions to the model. The exclusion restriction when managers undertake tax avoidance activity.
While the traditional view of corporate tax avoidance
underlying the IV results may be invalid if the effect on firm
value of the tax shield variables changed over time for suggests that shareholder value should increase with tax
reasons unrelated to the check-the-box regulations. Reas avoidance activity, the alternative view provides a more
suringly, the basic result is robust to including interactions nuanced prediction. Specifically, firm governance should be
between these variables and time trends in the model. an important determinant of the valuation of purported
Overall, the substantially larger effects found using the IV corporate tax savings. While the direct effect of tax avoid
ance is to increase the after-tax value of the firm, these
approach suggest that the OLS results are significantly
affected by attenuation bias due to measurement error in the
3 For example, Chetty and Saez (2005) show that increases in dividend
tax avoidance proxy or by the endogeneity of tax avoidance.
payments in response to the 2003 dividend tax cut were most pronounced
among firms with high levels of managerial ownership, as well as those
2 Unlike the study of tax evasion by Fisman and Wei (2004), where with high levels of institutional ownership. Managers with large stock
prices of goods are observed more directly, the measure employed here is option holdings, however, were less likely to respond to the tax change
indirect. While the validation check provides reassuring evidence, con (Brown, Liang, & Weisbenner, 2004). Each of these papers indicates that
trolling for various measures of accruals may not sufficiently isolate tax tax incentives interact with ownership and governance institutions in
avoidance from earnings management. important ways.

This content downloaded from


202.43.95.117 on Sat, 06 Feb 2021 01:20:48 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
CORPORATE TAX AVOIDANCE AND FIRM VALUE 539

_Table 1.?Summary Statistics_ correlation between the dependent variable and the measure
Standard Number of of tax avoidance.4 While q is the primary dependent vari
Mean Deviation Observations
able used in the analysis, alternative measures of firm value
Tobin's q (excluding deferred tax lead to consistent results, as discussed in section V.
expense) 2.3537 2.2885 4,492 In addition to drawing on financial statement data, the
Tobin's q (including deferred tax
expense) 2.3123 2.0011 4,062 analysis here requires a measure of firm governance. The
Market value (scaled) 1.7825 2.2881 4,470 primary measure of governance used in testing the paper's
Book-tax gap (scaled) -0.0074 0.1077 4,492 main hypothesis is the fraction of the firm's shares owned
Total accruals (scaled) -0.0432 0.0787 4,492
Ratio of value of stock option grants by institutional investors (from the CDA Spectrum data
to total compensation for top five base, based on Schedule 13F filings with the SEC by large
executives 0.4066 0.2542 4,492
Value of stock option exercises by
institutional investors). This fraction (which is reported
top five executives (scaled) 0.0061 0.0257
quarterly) is 4,492
averaged over each firm-year and is denoted by
Sales (millions of $) 3.5831 8.3074 4,492
Iit E [0, 1] for firm i in year t. The basic motivation
Volatility (Black-Scholes measure) 0.4021 0.1864 4,492
NOL carryforwards (scaled) 0.0351 0.2074 4,492underlying this proxy is that institutional investors have
Foreign income or loss (absolute greater incentives and capacity to monitor managerial per
value; scaled) 0.0327 0.0401 4,492 formance. Thus, the higher is Iit, the greater the degree of
R&D expenditures (scaled) 0.0475 0.0666 4,492
Long-term debt (scaled) 0.1748 0.1537 scrutiny to which managerial actions are subjected, and the
4,492
Debt in current liabilities (scaled) 0.0387 0.0608 4,492 are agency problems between managers and
less important
Deferred tax expense (scaled) 0.0256 0.0345 4,062 In addition, a different measure?the index of
shareholders.
Future sales growth (fraction) 0.1077 0.2984 4,328
Capital expenditures (scaled) 0.0674 0.0505 4,433provisions constructed by Gompers et al. anti-takeover
Pretax income (scaled) 0.0544 0.1363 4,492 (2003)?is used in robustness checks. While this captures a
Governance Index, 1998 9.2650 2.8387 3,906 quite different aspect of governance than does Iit (namely,
Institutional ownership (fraction) 0.5853 0.1768 4,492
managerial entrenchment rather than the quality of moni
Note: These variables are defined as in the text. Scaled variables are deflated by the contemporaneous
book value of assets. toring), its use leads to highly consistent results, as dis
cussed in section V.
Given the efforts undertaken to obscure such activities,
tax avoidance is difficult to measure. The analysis in this
effects are potentially offset, particularly in poorly governed
firms, by the increased opportunities for managerial rent paper adopts an indirect approach, constructing a measure
diversion. Thus, the net effect on firm value should of becorporate tax avoidance that takes as its starting point the
gap between financial and taxable income. The difference
greater for firms with stronger governance institutions.
between income reported to capital markets, using Gener
III. Measuring Firm Value, Governance, and Corporate ally Accepted Accounting Principles (GAAP) and to the tax
Tax Avoidance authorities?the so-called book-tax gap?has attracted con
siderable interest in recent years and has been related to
The data used to test the hypothesis described above are
measures of corporate tax avoidance (Manzon & Plesko,
drawn from three sources. Financial accounting data are
2002; Desai, 2003, 2005). Given that tax returns are confi
drawn from Standard and Poor's Compustat database, ex
dential, income reported to tax authorities cannot be ob
ecutive compensation data (and certain other control vari
served directly and must be inferred using financial account
ables) from Standard and Poor's Execucomp database, and
ing data, as described in Manzon and Plesko (2002) and
data on institutional ownership of firms from the CDA/
implemented
Spectrum database. Merging these variables leads to a data in Desai and Dharmapala (2006). This ap
proach uses firms' reported current federal tax expense and
set with 4,492 observations at the firm-year level on 862
firms over the period 1993-2001. The variables are de "grosses up" this tax liability by the U.S. federal corporate
tax rate.5 For firms with positive current federal tax expense,
scribed in detail below; summary statistics are reported in
table 1.
4 Using the Compustat data item numbers, qit for firm i in year t is
In emphasizing the value implications of corporate tax defined as follows:
avoidance, this paper builds on the extensive literature in
corporate finance on the determinants of firm value. Within _(#6)<f+((#24)*(#25)ft)-(#60)ft
this literature, it has become standard since Demsetz and qit (#6),
Lehn (1985) to use Tobin's q to measure firm value. The Note, however, that using the standard definition (Kaplan
definition of q used in Kaplan and Zingales (1997) and 1997) that includes deferred taxes leads to consistent results,
in section V.
Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick (2003) is employed in the 5 The exclusion of foreign taxes and income from this calcula
analysis below, with one modification: deferred tax expense problems associated with inferring the applicable foreign tax
is not included in the definition of q used in the basic results ever, foreign activities can affect U.S. tax liability under th
system of taxation that applies to U.S. corporations. Thus, th
below, as current tax avoidance activity may result in analysis includes a control variable that proxies for foreign
changes to future tax liabilities and thus create a mechanical absolute value of foreign income or loss, as described below

This content downloaded from


202.43.95.117 on Sat, 06 Feb 2021 01:20:48 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
540 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

the graduated structure of corporate tax rates is used in this cruals proxy isolates the component of the
calculation. For firms with negative current federal tax tax avoidance. In the regressions report
expense, the top statutory rate of 35% is used. used as a proxy for tax avoidance activi
Given this inferred value of the firm's taxable income, the management is controlled for by incl
book-tax gap can be estimated by simply subtracting in total accruals (denoted TAit for firm / in
ferred taxable income from the firm's reported pretax (do variable.9
mestic U.S.) financial income.6 To control for differences in Given the confidentiality of tax returns, this procedure
firm scale and because the dependent variable is deflated by yields the best measure of corporate tax avoidance that can
the book value of assets, the inferred book-tax gap is also be obtained using publicly available data. However, in view
scaled by the book value of assets. This yields the measure of the limitations associated with inferring taxable income,
of the book-tax gap used in the analysis below (denoted BTit and as there are alternative explanations for book-tax gaps,
for firm / in year t).1 it is useful to implement a validation check of the book-tax
gap as a measure of corporate tax sheltering activity before
The book-tax gap does not necessarily reflect corporate
proceeding to determine its valuation effects.
tax avoidance activity, so any measure of tax avoidance
Graham and Tucker (2006) construct a sample of firms
must control for other factors. In particular, the overreport
involved in 44 cases of tax shelter litigation over the period
ing of financial income (known in the accounting literature
1975-2000, using publicly available court records and press
as earnings management) may contribute to the measured articles. The validation check undertaken here uses a data
book-tax gap.8 Studies of earnings management (e.g., Healy,
set compiled using a similar methodology. This information
1985) have argued that such manipulation is most likely to can be used to construct a variable that indicates whether tax
occur through the exercise of managerial discretion in sheltering activity was alleged in any given firm-year. Spe
determining accounting accruals (i.e., adjustments to real cifically, let the indicator variable Lit be equal to 1 if firm /
ized cash flows that are used in calculating the firm's net was alleged to have used a tax shelter in year r, and 0
income). The basic intuition underlying the measure of tax otherwise. This variable is merged with data on the
avoidance used here is that book-tax gaps are attributable to book-tax gap and a set of control variables from the
either earnings management or tax avoidance activity. Ac merged Compustat-Execucomp data set in order to ex
cordingly, adjusting for earnings management with an ac amine the relationship between involvement in tax shelter
litigation and book-tax gaps. The regression specification
6 One particular concern with this approach may be the following. A (for the case of a linear probability model) is
firm's taxable income is reduced by the value of the compensation at the
time that employees exercise stock options. However, under the applicable
accounting rules, the reported tax expense is unaffected. It should be Lit = ^BTit + $2TAit + X,yy + e, + vit9 (1)
remembered, though, that reported financial income is not reduced by
employees' stock option exercises either. Thus, the exclusion of stock where et is a year fixed effect and vit is the error term. Xit
option exercises from both tax expense and financial income does not bias
the measure of the book-tax gap (see Manzon & Plesko, 2002, or Desai is a vector of control variables that includes measures of
and Dharmapala, 2006, for more details). Nonetheless, some concerns firm size (assets, sales, and market value) and the structure
may remain that the valuation of tax avoidance may be affected by the tax
of executive compensation.
shield available to a firm from stock option exercises. This issue is
addressed by including the value of observed stock option exercises as a Estimating this relationship using a logit model results in
control in robustness checks. a positive coefficient on BTit, as reported in column 1 of
7 Using the Compustat data item numbers, BTit, for firm i in year t is table 2: the book-tax gap tends to be larger, other things
defined as follows:
equal, in firm-years in which tax sheltering is alleged.10
(#63), Probit and linear probability models also yield positive
(#272), t
coefficients. Any conclusions from this validation check are
BTit= (#6h, '
9 Some component
where t is the U.S. federal corporate tax rate. of TAit mayhere,
As defined be positive even in the absence of
BTit
includes elements that are innocuous fromearnings management. Severalof
the perspective alternative measures of "abnormal" or
the gover
"discretionary"
nance issues analyzed in this paper, such as book-tax accruals (e.g., Jones, 1991; Dechow,
differences arising Sloan, and Sweeney,
from the treatment of depreciation or from 1995;
theDechow, Richardson, & tax
investment Tuna, credit.
2003) have been
The developed to better
isolate the factors
extent to which BTit can be corrected for these components of is
accruals that are truly
limited by under
the managerial control.
unavailability of information (e.g., on tax Using these alternative proxies
depreciation) in for earnings management instead of TAit
Compustat.
However, controlling for depreciation expenseleads to very investment
and similar results. An alternative
tax credits approach to calculating
accruals (Hribar
in robustness checks leads to consistent results (see &section
Collins, 2002)
V).usesNote
information
also on cash flows; this
approach
that tax deductions (such as those for interest also givesor
expense consistent
pension results.expense)
The results are also robust to
that are treated symmetrically for book including
and a tax
controlpurposes
for another measure of earnings
(i.e., alsomanagement, pro
posed by Phillips, Pincus,
deducted from financial income) do not mechanically affectand Rego (2003), namely deferred tax expense
BTit.
(see section
8 Lev and Nissim (2004) and Hanlon (2005) V).
investigate how book-tax
10 Note that firm fixed effects cannot be used in table 2, because the
gaps predict the quality of future earnings, essentially interpreting the
fixed-effects
entire book-tax gap as being due to earnings logit model doesactivity.
management not use for identification
They any observations
analyze the consequences of these managed for firms for which Lit isfor
earnings always subsequent
0 or always 1. Thus, given that the vast
accounting and market outcomes, but do notmajority of firmson
focus are never
thealleged to use shelters, the remaining sample
contemporane
in a fixed-effects
ous valuation of the tax avoidance component of themodel would be extremely
book-tax gap.small.

This content downloaded from


202.43.95.117 on Sat, 06 Feb 2021 01:20:48 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
CORPORATE TAX AVOIDANCE AND FIRM VALUE 541

Table 2.?Book-Tax Gaps and Tax Shelter Litigation


(2006). To control for changes over time in the risk associ
Indicator (=1) for Alleged ated with a firm's stock price, a measure of volatility is also
Dependent Variable Tax Shelter Activity included.13 As NOL carryforwards are not taken into ac
Book-tax gap (scaled) 3.7185* count in the measure of tax avoidance (and because NOLs
(1.9377) can affect the incentives to engage in tax avoidance), NOL
Accruals measure (scaled) ?5.6702***
(0.9005) carryforwards scaled by assets (with missing values treated
Controls for changes in sales, assets, market Y as zeroes) are also included.
value, and the ratio of the value of stock The tax avoidance measure is restricted to domestic U.S.
option grants to total compensation for
top 5 executives? tax expense and U.S. federal taxes, but tax liabilities and the
Number of firms 1,018 incentives for tax avoidance may be influenced by foreign
Number of observations 4,985
Pseudo-tf2 0.0671 activity under the U.S. system of worldwide taxation. Thus,
a proxy for foreign activity?the absolute value of foreign
Note: The dependent variable is an indicator variable = 1 in any firm-year in which the firm was
subsequently alleged to be engaging in aggressive tax sheltering. The sample includes all firms in the income or loss?is included in Xff. As tax shields can affect
merged Compustat and Execucomp databases for which the required data are available. The estimates use
a logit model. The sample period is 1993-2001. The specifications include year effects and the set of the value of engaging in tax avoidance, changes in firms'
controls specified. Robust standard errors that are clustered at the firm level are presented in parentheses;
* and *** denote significance at the 10% and 1% levels, respectively.
leverage are controlled for by including measures of long
term debt and debt in current liabilities. Changes in intan
gibles that affect q but are imperfectly measured in the book
necessarily tentative, given the small number of firms that value of assets are proxied for by research and development
have been involved in tax shelter litigation. Nonetheless, it (R&D) expenditures. A number of additional control vari
appears that the measure of tax avoidance employed below ables are used in robustness checks, as described below.
captures a critical element of tax sheltering activity, as it Note also that because firm fixed effects are employed in the
takes on higher values for those firm-years for which there specification described below, many of the sources of cross
is some independent evidence for alleged tax shelter activ sectional variation in q across firms that have been dis
ity. cussed in the literature are effectively controlled for here.
The specification used to test whether the valuation of
IV. OLS Approach and Results corporate tax avoidance is dependent on firm governance
While the central hypothesis of the paper concerns the extends equation (2) as follows:
interaction of governance institutions and tax avoidance
activity, the question of whether tax avoidance tends to be qit = $xBTit + ?2TAit + fo/,, + Ml%BTit) + Xity
associated with increases or decreases in firm value is also (3)
of considerable interest. This is addressed using the follow + p.,- + e, + vit,
ing specification:
where Iit is the measure of institutional ownership defined
qit = ^BTit + $2TAit + Xity + ^ + e, + vit, (2) above. The hypothesis in section II implies that p$4 > 0: the
effect of tax avoidance on q is greater in firm-years in which
where the variables BTit and TAit are as defined above, |X/ institutional ownership is higher (and governance is stron
and are firm and year fixed effects, respectively, and vit is ger).
the error term (note that all regressions reported in this The results using OLS estimation on equations (2) and (3)
paper use both firm and year fixed effects).
are reported in table 3; note that all results reported in this
Xit is a vector consisting of the following control vari paper use robust (White, 1980) standard errors clustered at
ables. Changes in firm size over time are controlled for the firm level. Column 1 presents the results from the
using sales.11 The value of stock option grants to executives estimation of equation (2).14 The overall effect on firm value
as a fraction of total compensation12 is included because a of the proxy for tax avoidance is positive but insignificant.
substantial literature (e.g., Morck, Shleifer, & Vishny, 1988; The test of the hypothesis using equation (3) is reported in
Mehran, 1995) finds stock-based compensation to be a column 2. Here, the coefficient on the interaction term
determinant of firm value, presumably through incentive (I*BTit)?p4 in equation (3)?is positive, consistent with
alignment effects. In addition, the structure of executive
the paper's hypothesis, and is of borderline statistical sig
compensation plays a central role in Desai and Dharmapala nificance. The intuition can be reinforced by running equa
tion (2) separately for firm-years with high and low levels of
11 Assets and market value enter into the definition of q and so would be
mechanically correlated with the dependent variable.
institutional ownership (columns 3 and 4, respectively),
12 This is calculated from data at the manager-year level in the Execu
comp database and is defined as the ratio of the Black-Scholes value of 13 Using a firm's beta (calculated using CRSP monthly data for the
stock option grants to total compensation (i.e., the sum of the value of preceding five years) instead of the volatility measure has no effect on the
stock options, salary, and bonus). This is similar to the stock-based results.
compensation measures used in Mehran (1995) and in a large subsequent 14 The sample is restricted to firm-years for which the CDA/Spectrum
literature. Adding a measure based on stock option exercises (defined data on institutional ownership are available (although that variable is not
analogously) does not affect the results. used in equation (2)), for comparability with the other columns of table 3.

This content downloaded from


202.43.95.117 on Sat, 06 Feb 2021 01:20:48 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
542 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

Table 3.?Tax Avoidance, Firm Value, and Governance Institutions: OLS Results

Tobin's q
(1) (2) (3) (4)
Firm-Years with Hig
Dependent Variable All Firms All F
Book-tax gap (scaled) 0.5776 -2.1655 2.7624* 0.2718
(0.5590) (1.4957) (1.5394) (0.3678)
Book-tax gap interacted with institutional 5.6687*
ownership (3.3307)
Institutional ownership 0.7706**
(0.3287)
Total accruals (scaled) 1.3267** 1.2689** 0.5313 1.1159*
(0.3811) (0.3613) (0.5676) (0.5892)
Ratio of value of stock option grants to total 0.4391** 0.4371** 0.5627** 0.2253
compensation for top 5 executives (0.1208) (0.1202) (0.2004) (0.1745)
Sales 0.0442* 0.0471* 0.0195 0.0592
(0.0249) (0.0250) (0.0158) (0.0404)
Volatility -2.114006** -1.9465** -3.8771** -1.0303*
(0.6682) (0.6466) (1.2553) (0.5697)
Controls for tax shields (NOLs, long-term
debt, and current debt) Y Y Y Y
Controls for foreign income/loss and R&D Y Y Y Y
Year and firm effects? Y Y Y Y
Number of firms 862 862 583 614
Number of observations 4,492 4,492 2,324 2,168
R2 0.6483 0.6500 0.7765 0.6213
Note: The dependent variable is Tobin's q, as defined in section III. The sa
which CDA/Spectrum data on institutional ownership are available. All specific
ownership > 0.6. In column 4, the sample is restricted to firm-years with in
significance at the 10% and 5% levels, respectively.

where "high" institutional ownership


in the proxy for taxis av
d
fraction that exceeds 0.6, which is
measurement approxi
error dif
of the sample. For well-governed
example, if the firm-yea
proxie
tax avoidance on q incomplete,
is positive and of bo
the remain
cance. For less well-governed firm-years (w
may be mischaracteriz
ownership below 0.6), the effect
represents is also ma
earnings po
tically insignificant that
and considerably
the results are small
driv
Thus, while the estimated
earningsoverall effect of
management
firm value is indistinguishable
erned firms. The0,
from the
secon
be more positive for well-governed
avoidance activity.firm-
For
poorly governed firm-years.
worse for This finding
other reason i
the hypothesis that agency problems
avoidance. mitigat
shareholders of th corporate tax to
In order avoidance.
address
of variation in firms'
V. Instrumental Variables Approach an
required. Fortunately,
A. Instrumental Variables
lated objectives lowere
subset of firms. In lat
OLS estimation of equations
known as (2) and
the (3) gi
check-th
types of potential problems.15 The first is m
ulations enable firms to
tax purposes?for exa
15 Another alternative explanation for the paper's fin
corporation
entirely addressed by the or is
IV approach) asthat
a pass-
the
or between
valuation of tax avoidance sole proprietorship?
the well-gover
erned subsamples relate to differences in the types of
they simply check t
these firms. It is possible that the smaller effect for po
complex
is due to these firms' investing set of
in riskier rules th
shelters b
higher rates or in shelters tax status,
with shorterthe CTB liv
expected re
explanation is true, thethe
tax avoidance measurebu
administrative wo
exhibit lower autocorrelation for poorly governed f
governed firms. However, computing simple autocor
shelters of
for BTi t in the two subsamples with shorter expecte
firm-years show
autocorrelation is actuallytest, the (more
larger available evidence
positive) for
explanation.
firm-years. This is not consistent with poorly gover

This content downloaded from


202.43.95.117 on Sat, 06 Feb 2021 01:20:48 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
CORPORATE TAX AVOIDANCE AND FIRM VALUE 543

Table 4.?Book-Tax Gaps, Tax Shields, and the Check-the-Box


studying international taxation argue that the CTB regula
tions also had the unintended consequence of facilitating tax _Regulations: First-Stage IV Results_

avoidance by large U.S.-based multinational firms through Book-Tax Gap


the use of what are known as hybrid entities (see in partic Dependent Variable (1) (2)
ular Altshuler & Grubert, 2005). Hybrid entities are classi PostCTB X (NOL carryforwards) -0.0349** -0.0162
fied in two distinct ways: as separately incorporated subsid (0.0139) (0.0356)
iaries under the tax rules of one country and as PostCTB X (long-term debt) -0.0127 -0.0474
(0.0160) (0.0384)
unincorporated branches under the tax rules of another PostCTB X (current debt) -0.0879* -0.3103**
country.16 (0.0507) (0.1197)
The instruments for tax avoidance involve interacting a PostCTB X (NOL carryforwards) X -0.0579
(institutional ownership) (0.1341)
dummy variable for the post-CTB time period (the years PostCTB X (long-term debt) X 0.0548
since 1997) with firm-year-level variables that capture the (institutional ownership) (0.0570)
PostCTB X (current debt) X 0.4149**
incentive to engage in tax avoidance. The central idea
(institutional ownership) (0.1644)
underlying the identification strategy is that for a given F-statistic for joint significance of 3.33** 3.00***
incentive to engage in tax avoidance, a firm will engage in the instruments (p-value) (0.0189) (0.0063)
Controls for total accruals, executive
more actual tax avoidance after the CTB regulations were
compensation, sales, volatility,
adopted than it would have before, other things equal. A foreign income/loss, and R&D Y Y
crucial determinant of the incentives to engage in tax Controls for tax shields (NOLs, long
term debt, and current debt) Y Y
avoidance is the availability of tax shields (tax deductions
Control for institutional ownership N Y
from other sources, such as interest deductions or NOL Year and firm effects? Y Y
carryforwards resulting from losses in previous years). For Number of firms 862 862
instance, Graham and Tucker (2006) emphasize the substi Number of observations 4,492 4,492
R2 0.5993 0.6009
tutability of tax shelters and other kinds of tax shields. Note: The dependent variable is the book-tax gap, as defined in the text. "PostC
Instruments for tax avoidance can thus be constructed by variable for years after the check-the-box regulations were introduced (1997-2001). T
period 1993-2001) is drawn from the merged Compustat and Execucomp databases
interacting a dummy variable for the period after the CTB firm-years for which CD A/Spectrum data on institutional ownership are availabl

regulations with each of the following variables: NOL include year effects, firm fixed effects, and the controls listed. Robust standard erro
at the firm level are presented in parentheses. *, **, and *** denote significance at t
carryforwards and two different measures of debt (long levels, respectively.

term debt and debt in current liabilities).


The IV approach involves instrumenting for the endoge
nous variable BTit in equation (2) using as the set of In equation (3), there are effectively two e
instruments the variables listed above, each interacted with variables?BTit and (I*BTit)?and the set of in
a dummy variable for the post-CTB period. Let Pt be the thus includes interactions with Iit. In particular
dummy for the post-CTB period, NOLit be the NOL carry ments for BTit and (I*BTit) are the following:
forwards for firm / in year t, DLit be long-term debt for firm (P*DLit), (P*DC/r), (I%P*NOLit), (/f,P*D
/ in year t, and DCit be debt in current liabilities for firm / (I*P*DCit). The first-stage results (presented in
in year t. Then the instruments for BTit are {P^NOLit), of table 4) show the expected negative relationsh
(P*DLit), and (P?DC/f). The first-stage regression (reported each of the first three of these instruments and BT
in column 1 of table 4) shows that these instruments are set of instruments is also strongly jointly signific
indeed strongly related to BTit. Specifically, the coefficients The basic rationale for this IV approach is th
are negative, as expected: lower values of tax shields (which incentive to engage in tax avoidance should lea
imply a greater incentive to engage in tax avoidance) are actual tax avoidance after the CTB regulations t
associated with larger values of BTit after the CTB regula The crucial exclusion restriction underlying the
tions than before, controlling for other factors. The instru instruments is the following. The underlying
ments are jointly significant at the 5% level. variables (NOLs and the debt measures) used in
ing the instruments may directly affect firm
16 The following is a simple example of how these entities can be used direct effect is controlled for by including th
to reduce tax liabilities. Suppose that a U.S.-based multinational (A) sets
variables in the specification. However, the tax
up a tax haven subsidiary (B) that provides loans to another subsidiary (C)
in a high-tax foreign country. The interest on these loans is tax deductible ables should not affect firm value differently afte
in the high-tax foreign country, to the government of which B is reported regulations other than through their influence on
to be a separately incorporated entity from C. Prior to 1997, the interest for tax avoidance. This restriction is conditi
received by B (while untaxed by its tax haven location) would have been
subject to immediate U.S. taxation under the Subpart F rules relating to controls included in the model. For example, e
interest payments from one Controlled Foreign Corporation (CFC) to valuations were in general higher in the late 199
another. However, the CTB regulations made it possible for A to elect (for
U.S. tax purposes) to have B treated as an unincorporated branch of C.
dummies included in the specification would ac
This makes the interest payments received by B "invisible" to the U.S. tax
system and so facilitates the avoidance (or at least deferral until repatri 17 The instruments are also of borderline significance in th
ation) of U.S. tax on the interest income paid by C to B. regression for {I*BTit).

This content downloaded from


202.43.95.117 on Sat, 06 Feb 2021 01:20:48 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
544 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

Table 5.?Tax Avoidance, Firm Value, and Governance Institutions: Second-Stage IV Results
Market Value
Tobin's q Tobin's q (scaled) Tobin's q
Dependent Variable (1) (2) (3) (4)
Book-tax gap (scaled) 14.523 -5.8710 -6.9313 -4.2465
(12.288) (5.1474) (4.9001) (4.0640)
Book-tax gap interacted with institutional ownership 32.8204** 31.
(13.0267) (12.8540) (10.8603)
Institutional ownership 1.0331** 1.0593** 0.9614**
(0.4376) (0.4250) (0.3976)
Total accruals (scaled) -2.8305 -1.3588 -0.4447 -0.2585
(3.6467) (2.3935) (2.3651) (1.8085)
Ratio of value of stock option grants to total 0.3495 0.4839** 0.5532** 0.4732***
compensation for top 5 executives (0.3092) (0.2142) (0.1919) (0.1609)
Sales 0.0434 0.0473* 0.0581 0.0418
(0.0276) (0.0264) (0.0245) (0.0255)
Volatility -1.0221 -1.2096 -1.2202 -1.5364**
(0.9795) (0.7703) (0.7869) (0.7227)
Controls for tax shields (NOLs, long-term debt, and
current debt) Y Y Y Y
Controls for foreign income/loss and R&D Y Y Y Y
Interactions between tax shield variables and time trends N N N Y
Year and firm effects? Y Y Y Y
Number of firms 862 862 862 862
Number of observations 4,492 4,492 4,470 4,492
Note: The dependent variable in columns 1, 2, and 4 is Tobin's q, as defined in section iii. The dependent vari
sample (over the period 1993-2001) is drawn from the merged Compustat and Execucomp databases and is res
specifications include year effects, firm fixed effects, and the controls listed. The book-tax gap variable and the
the text. Robust standard errors that are clustered at the firm level are presented in parentheses. *, **, and ***

tivity
this. Of course, the validity of the will continue
exclusion in the future
restriction
depends on there being no otherrates used, the
changes overestimated coeffi
time in the
effect of the tax shield variables on firm
governed value. To
sample in test for
the OLS sp
possible violations of this exclusion restriction,
table 3) interactions
would correspond to an ex
between the tax shield variables and to
of seven time
ninetrends are well-go
years for in
cluded in the model as a robustness check.
interpreting this OLS coefficient
cated by the identification concer
B. Instrument Variables Results
marginal significance of the coeff
The IV estimate in column 3 o
The second-stage results from the IV analysis are pre
overcome these difficulties. For a
sented in table 5. Column 1 reports the results from esti
institutional ownership, these coe
mating equation (2), using the instruments for BTit de
market interprets
scribed above. The overall estimated effect an increase i
of tax avoidance
quasi-permanent change in tax
on firm value is substantially larger than in the OLS results
in table 3. Column 2 reports changes in the
the results book-tax
from gap are not
estimating
items associated with
equation (3), using the instruments for BTit and (I*tBTit) particular
described above. The coefficientgeneral
(34 tax planning
of the ability.18
interaction be The l
approach
tween governance and tax avoidance suggest that
is positive measureme
and highly
significant, consistent with theance proxy
paper's main may lead to
hypothesis. attenua
The
IV results thus support themates.notion Alternatively, the OLS
that the benefits to esti
shareholders from corporate tax avoidance
avoidanceon firmon
depend value may be b
firms'
governance institutions. form of endogeneity noted abov
The results in table 5 are in the same direction
performing poorlyas the
for OLS
other r
engage instronger.
results in table 3 but are considerably tax avoidance.19
The coeffi
cients from tables 3 and 5 can be interpreted as reflecting an
expected duration of a particular18 In shelter
tax the data or
set the
on corporate tax shelt
ability to
and Tucker (2006, table 1), the active life
engage in tax planning for a to
given period. Suppose a firm
10 years. The active life in the Graham-T
unexpectedly increases its book-tax
longevity of gap bytax
specific $1.00. Thestrat
sheltering
current-year tax benefit (including
imply that federal
current and
tax state taxactivit
avoidance
ability, which may be expected to persi
benefits) would be approximately $0.40. Market reactions
particular strategy.
are given by the coefficient on19the
It isbook-tax gap
possible that and
the should
apparent effect
incorporate an expectation of attributable
how longto managerial
tax incentives
sheltering ac (no

This content downloaded from


202.43.95.117 on Sat, 06 Feb 2021 01:20:48 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
CORPORATE TAX AVOIDANCE AND FIRM VALUE 545

C. Robustness of the IV Results While the baseline specification in table 5 includes an


extensive set of controls, it is possible that unobserved
These IV results appear to be robust to concerns regard
changes in firms' investment opportunities or expected fu
ing the measurement of the book-tax gap, governance, and ture performance may affect q. To address these concerns, it
firm value. For instance, the basic result in column 2 of table
is possible to include capital expenditures and future reve
5 is robust to the (unreported) inclusion of additional vari nue growth as additional controls; including these controls
ables?specifically, deferred tax expense,20 depreciation ex leads to consistent results. Furthermore, although Tobin's q
pense, investment tax credits, interest expense, pension is a standard measure of firm value in the literature, it is
expense, and a proxy for employees' stock option exercis nonetheless important to consider alternative proxies. As q
es21?that control for the potential mismeasurement of the takes account of the book as well as market value of equity
book-tax gap. It is also robust to adding lagged tax avoid and the value of debt, a simpler measure is the market value
ance activity to the model; this does not change the effect of of common stock (Execucomp variable MKTVAL, the clos
contemporaneous tax avoidance (interacted with Iit), and ing share price for the fiscal year multiplied by the number
the effect of the lagged variable is small and insignificant. of common shares outstanding). This is scaled by the book
Thus, there is no evidence to suggest a substantial delayed value of assets in order to conform to the scaling of the
market reaction to firms' tax avoidance activity. independent variables. As shown in column 3 of table 5,
The results are also robust to using alternative measures using this variable instead of q leads to essentially identical
results.
of governance. Specifically, the findings are unaffected
when Iit is replaced by the index of anti-takeover provisions Finally, the identification strategy used depends on the
constructed by Gompers et al. (2003). This index represents validity of the exclusion restrictions. In particular, it re
a count of anti-takeover provisions that apply to a firm quires that there are no changes over time in the effect on
(through either its corporate charter or state law).22 It takes
firm value of the tax shield variables used in constructing
on values up to 18, with lower values indicating better the instruments (other than the change due to the impact of
the CTB regulations on tax avoidance activity). This as
governance. As the cardinal properties of this index are
sumption may be violated if there are trends unrelated to the
unclear, the robustness check involves constructing an in
CTB regulations in the effect of the tax shield variables on
dicator variable for better-governed firms by dividing the
q. This possibility can be tested for by adding to the model
sample at the mean (with values of 9 or lower corresponding interactions between a time trend and each of the tax shield
to "well-governed" firms). The interaction between this
variables. Specifically, these additional control variables are
indicator variable for well-governed firms and BTit is very (NOL%(t - 1997)), (DL%(t - 1997)), and (DCt(t -
similar in magnitude and significance to that in column 2 of 1997)), where t is the year (1997, the midpoint of the
table 5. This suggests that the results are robust to alterna sample period, is used as the base year). The second-stage
tive notions of governance, as the Gompers et al. (2003) IV results with the addition of these controls are presented
index measures managerial entrenchment rather than the in column 4 of table 5. While the coefficient of the interac
quality of monitoring. Moreover, this also indicates that the tion term of interest is somewhat smaller, it remains signif
results are unaffected by the potential endogeneity of Iit, icant at the 5% level. Thus, it does not appear that the effect
where institutional investors may choose to buy firms that of the instrumental variables is driven by time trends in the
are expected to increase in value. This is less applicable to impact of the tax shield variables on firm value. Rather, the
the Gompers et al. index, as its values were predominantly results seem to depend on only the discontinuous change in
determined in the 1980s and generally do not change during the effect of tax shields on firm value associated with the
the sample period. CTB regulations.

2006, find a relationship between managerial incentives and tax avoidance VI. Conclusion
activity). However, adding an interaction term between the executive
compensation measure and tax avoidance to the model leaves the results
essentially unchanged.
Although there is an extensive literature on how firms
20 Recall that deferred tax expense was omitted from the computation of respond to taxes, little analysis of activities has been de
q, while taxable income was inferred using only current tax expense. This signed solely or primarily to reduce tax liabilities. This
omission could be important because current tax sheltering activity may
take the form of deferring tax liabilities to the future. Also, a focus on paper contributes to the emerging literature on this topic by
current tax avoidance ignores current actions by the firm that reduce its investigating whether such activities advance shareholder
future tax liabilities, and hence increase the present value of the firm. Note interests, using evidence on how markets capitalize these
that adding deferred tax expense to the definition of q, as in Kaplan and
Zingales (1997), leads to results that are highly consistent with those in
activities. The simple presumption that corporate tax avoid
table 5. ance represents a transfer of value from the state to share
21 The value of stock option exercises by the top five executives (scaled holders does not appear to be validated in the data. Rather,
by the book value of assets) is used as a proxy for these deductions. On
the importance of stock option deductions for certain firms, see Graham,
the patterns in the data are more consistent with the agency
Lang, and Shackelford (2004). perspective on corporate tax avoidance, which emphasizes
22 See Gompers et al. (2003, appendix 1) for more details. the mediating role of governance. The basic result that

This content downloaded from


202.43.95.117 on Sat, 06 Feb 2021 01:20:48 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms
546 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS

higher-quality firm governance leads to a larger effect of tax- "The Degradation of Reported Corporate Profits," Journal of
Economic Perspectives 19 (2005), 171-192.
avoidance on firm value is reinforced by using an exoge Desai, Mihir A., Alexander Dyck, and Luigi Zingales, "Theft and Taxa
nous source of variation due to changes in tax regulations to tion," Journal of Financial Economics 84 (2007), 591-623.
construct instrumental variables for tax avoidance activity. Desai, Mihir A., and Dhammika Dharmapala, "Corporate Tax Avoidance
and High Powered Incentives," Journal of Financial Economics 79
The results are robust to a wide variety of tests for alterna (2006), 145-179.
tive explanations. - "Earnings Management, Corporate Tax Shelters, and Book-Tax
The findings of this paper shed new light on what Weis Alignment," National Tax Journal 62 (2009), 169-186.
Desai, Mihir A., and James R. Hines Jr., "Expectations and Expatriations:
bach (2002) terms the "undersheltering puzzle": why firms Tracing the Causes and Consequences of Corporate Inversions,"
do not engage in sheltering activity more extensively, given National Tax Journal 55 (2002), 409-441.
the widespread availability of shelters and the low risk of Fisman, Raymond, and Shang-Jin Wei, "Tax Rates and Tax Evasion:
Evidence from 'Missing Imports' in China," Journal of Political
penalties. Undersheltering may not be as puzzling as it first Economy 112 (2004), A1X-A96.
appears, given that investors doubt the value of such activ Gompers, Paul A., Joy Ishii, and Andrew Metrick, "Corporate Governance
ities in the absence of good governance. More generally, the and Equity Prices," Quarterly Journal of Economics 118 (2003),
107-155.
result that the valuation of tax avoidance is a function of
Graham, John R., "Taxes and Corporate Finance: A Review," Review of
firm governance suggests that tax avoidance and managerial Financial Studies 16 (2003), 1074-1128.
efforts to divert value from shareholders may be inter Graham, John R., Mark H. Lang, and Douglas A. Shackelford, "Employee
Stock Options, Corporate Taxes, and Debt Policy," Journal of
twined. This paper thus shows that incorporating agency Finance 59 (2004), 1585-1618.
issues into the analysis of corporate tax avoidance leads to Graham, John R., and Alan Tucker, "Tax Shelters and Corporate Debt
theoretical and empirical conclusions that are substantially Policy," Journal of Financial Economics 81 (2006), 563-594.
Hanlon, Michelle, "The Persistence and Pricing of Earnings, Accruals, and
different from those that would be predicted by a model Cash Flows When Firms Have Large Book-Tax Differences,"
where managers are perfect agents. These findings open up Accounting Review 80 (2005), 137-166.
several lines of inquiry, including the implications of this Healy, Paul, "The Effect of Bonus Schemes on Accounting Decisions,"
Journal of Accounting and Economics 1 (1985), 85-107.
agency perspective for the analysis of tax policy, which we Hribar, Paul, and Daniel W. Collins, "Errors in Estimating Accruals:
leave for future research. Implications for Empirical Research," Journal of Accounting Re
search 40 (2002), 105-134.
Jones, Jennifer, "Earnings Management During Import Relief Investiga
REFERENCES tions," Journal of Accounting Research 29 (1991), 193-228.
Kaplan, Steven N., and Luigi Zingales, "Do Investment-Cash Flow
Altshuler, Rosanne, and Harry Grubert, "The Three Parties in the Race to Sensitivities Provide Useful Measures of Financing Constraints?"
the Bottom: Host Governments, Home Governments, and Multi Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (1997), 169-216.
national Companies," Florida Tax Review 1 (2005), 137-209. Lev, Baruch, and Doron Nissim, "Taxable Income, Future Earnings, and
Auerbach, Alan J., "Taxation and Corporate Financial Policy" (pp. 1251? Equity Values," Accounting Review 19 (2004), 1039-1074.
1292), in A. J. Auerbach and M. Feldstein (Eds.), Handbook of Manzon, Gil B., Jr., and George A. Plesko, "The Relation between
Public Economics, vol. 3 (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 2002). Financial and Tax Reporting Measures of Income," Tax Imw
Bankman, Joseph, "The Tax Shelter Problem," National Tax Journal 57 Review 55 (2002), 175-214.
(2004), 925-936. Mehran, Hamid, "Executive Compensation Structure, Ownership, and
Brown, Jeffrey R., Nellie Liang, and Scott Weisbenner, "Executive Finan Firm Performance," Journal of Financial Economics 38 (1995),
cial Incentives and Payout Policy: Firm Responses to the 2003 163-184.
Dividend Tax Cut," NBER working paper no. 11002 (2004). Morck, Randall, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny, "Management Own
Chen, Kong-Pin, and C. Y. Cyrus Chu, "Internal Control vs. External ership and Corporate Performance: An Empirical Analysis," Jour
Manipulation: A Model of Corporate Income Tax Evasion," RAND nal of Financial Economics 20 (1988), 293-315.
Journal of Economics 36 (2005), 151-164. Phillips, John, Morton Pincus, and Sonja Olhoft Rego, "Earnings Man
Chetty, Raj, and Emmanuel Saez, "Dividend Taxes and Corporate Behav agement: New Evidence Based on Deferred Tax Expense," Ac
ior: Evidence from the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut," Quarterly Journal counting Review 78 (2003), 491-521.
of Economics 120 (2005), 791-833. Slemrod, Joel, "The Economics of Corporate Tax Selfishness," National
Crocker, Keith J., and Joel Slemrod, "Corporate Tax Evasion with Agency Tax Journal 51 (2004), 877-899.
Costs," Journal of Public Economics 89 (2005), 1593-1610. Slemrod, Joel, and Shlomo Yitzhaki, "Tax Avoidance, Evasion and Ad
Dechow, Patricia, Scott Richardson, and Irem Tuna, "Why Are Earnings ministration" (pp. 1423-1470), in A. J. Auerbach and M. Feldstein
Kinky? An Examination of the Earnings Management Explana (Eds.), Handbook of Public Economics, vol. 3 (Amsterdam: North
tion," Review of Accounting Studies 8 (2003), 355-384. Holland, 2002).
Dechow, Patricia, Richard Sloan, and Amy Sweeney, "Detecting Earnings U.S. Department of the Treasury, "The Problem of Corporate Tax Shelters:
Management," Accounting Review 70 (1995), 193-225. Discussion, Analysis and Legislative Proposals" (Washington, DC:
Demsetz, Harold, and Kenneth Lehn, "The Structure of Corporate Own U.S. Government Press Office, 1999).
ership: Causes and Consequences," Journal of Political Economy Weisbach, David, "Ten Truths about Tax Shelters," Tax Law Review 55
93 (1985), 1155-1177. (2002), 215-253.
Desai, Mihir A., "The Divergence Between Book and Tax Income" (pp. White, Halbert, "A Heteroskedasticity-Consistent Covariance Matrix Es
169-206), in J. M. Poterba (Ed.), Tax Policy and the Economy, vol. timator and a Direct Test for Heteroskedasticity," Econometrica 48
17 (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2003). (1980), 817-830.

This content downloaded from


202.43.95.117 on Sat, 06 Feb 2021 01:20:48 UTC
All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like