You are on page 1of 20

Debt and Seniority:

An Analysis of the Role of Hard Claims


in Constraining Management

By OLIVER HART AND JOHN MOORE*

We argue that long-term debt has a role in controlling management's ability to


finance future investments. Companies with high (widely held) debt will find it
hard to raise capital, since new security-holders will hate low priority relative to
existing creditors; conversely for companies with low debt. We show that there is
an optimal debt -equity ratio and mix of senior and junior debt if management
undertakes unprofitable as well as profitable investments. We derive conditions
under which equity and a single class of senior long-term debt work as well as
more complex contracts for controlling investment behavior. (JEL D23, G23)

Since the time of Franco ModigUani and 1988); and as an attempt to raise funds
Merton Miller's famous irrelevance theo- without diluting the value of equity (see
rem, economists have devoted much effort Stewart Myers and Nicholas Majluf, 1984).'
to relaxing the theorem's assumptiotis in While each of these approaches has pro-
order to understand the real-world trade- vided important insights, none has been en-
offs among debt, equity, and other corpo- tirely successful in explaining the choice of
rate financial instruments. In particular, lit- financial structure. In particular, these ap-
eratures have developed that explain the proaehes cannot explain the types of debt
issuance of debt by public companies as an claims observed in praetiee. As one of us
attempt to reduee taxes (see Modlgliani and has argued elsewhere (see Hart, 1993), un-
Miller. l%3; Miller, 1977); as a signaling der the maintained hypothesis of most of
device (see Hayne Leiand and David Pyle, the literature that management is not self-
1977; Stephen Ross, 1977); as a way of interested, the first-best ean be achieved by
completing markets (see Joseph Stiglitz, making all of a firm's debt soft; that is, all
1974; Franklin Allen and Douglas Gale, debt should be junior (management should
be given the right to issue unlimited amounts
of additional debt senior to existing debt)
and postponable (all debt should be in the
* Departmenl of Economics, Harvard LIniversity, form of payment-in-kind [PIK] bonds, which
Cambridge, MA 02138, and Department of Economics, give management the right to postpone debt
London School of Economics, Houghton Street, Lon- payments at management's direction). The
don. WC2 2AE. Uniled Kingdom, respectively. This is
a major revision of a previous paper, "A Theory of
Corporate Financial Structure Based on the Seniority
of Claims.•• We are particularly grateful to Ian Jewitt
for simplifying the proof of the Key Lemma in Section
III. We also thank Rabindran Abraham, Abhijit Baner- 'Milton Harris and Artur Raviv (1991) survey these
jec. Dick Brualey, Lucian Bebchuk, Siu Myers, Fausto theories. A more recent literature has viewed debt as a
Panunzi, David Wfbb, and two anonymous referees for way of shifting control rights from corporate insiders to
helpful comments. They are, of course, not responsible security-holders in certain (bankruptcy) states of the
for the views expressed here. Finally, we acknowledge world (see Philippe Aghion and Patrick Bolton, 1992;
financial support from Ihe National Science Founda- Hart and Moore, 19S9, 1994). Control-based theories
tion, Ihe LSF. Suntory-Toyota International Centre for seem more applicable to smallish, entrepreneurial firms
Economics and Relaled Discipline-S. the Olin Founda- Ihan to public companies (the focus of this paper); in
tion, and the Center for Energy Policy Research at the latter, managers or directors rarely have voting
MIT. control even when the company is solvent.
567
S6S THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1995

reason Is that, by issuing sueh soft elaims, ment itself in response to a hostile takeover
the firm can take advantage of all the bid.
tax and market-completion benefits of The role of short-term debt in forcing
debt without incurring any bankruptcy or management to disgorge free eash flow has
financial-distress costs. Efficient investment been stressed by Jensen (1986), although he
ehoices ean be ensured by putting manage- does not analyze it formally.* In addition,
ment on an incentive scheme that rewards it Jensen emphasizes the benefits of debt but
according to the firm's total (net) market has little to say about the COST:S. The role of
value, rather than just the value of equity. long-term debt in constraining self-inter-
Such an incentive scheme also avoids con- ested management from raising new capital
fliets of interest between shareholders and has not been analyzed at all, as far as we
creditors (of the type stressed by Michael know. The purpose of this paper is to pro-
Jensen and William Meckling [1976]).^ vide an analysis of the costs and benefits of
In reality, firms issue considerable debt, with a partieular emphasis on long-
amounts of "hard" (senior, nonpostpon- term debt.
able) debt."* That is, we do not appear to We consider a public company, consisting
live in the idealized world described above. of assets in plaee and new investment op-
Presumably, the reason is that managers are portunities (along the lines of Myers [1977];
self-interested in practice (in this paper, we in Myers's work, however, management is
do not distinguish between management and not self-interested). The company's security
the board of direetors). Among other things, structure is ehosen at date 0, an investment
managers have goals, such as the pursuit of decision is made by management at date 1,
power and perquisites, that are not shared and funds are paid out to investors at date 2
by investors. "Hard" debt then has an im- (there is symmetrie information throughout).
portant role to play in curbing managerial We assume that management's empire-
excess (see Sanford Grossman and Hart, building tendencies are sufficiently strong
1982). First, nonpostponable, short-term that it will always undertake the new invest-
debt forces managers to disgorge funds that ment if it can, even if the investment has
they might otherwise use to make unprof- negative net present value. In order to foeus
itable but empire-building investments, and on the role of long-term debt, we assume
to trigger liquidation in states of the world that the firm's going-eoneern value exceeds
where the firm's assets are more valuable its liquidation value, and that the company's
elsewhere. Second, senior long-term debt date-1 earnings are insufficient to finance
prevents managers from finaneing unprof- the investment internally. Under these as-
itable investments by borrowing against fu- sumptions, we show that the optimal level
ture earnings. Hard debt may be put in of short-term debt is zero. However, (senior)
place either by the company's founders be- long-term debt is important in constraining
fore the company goes publie or by manage- management's ability to raise new funds.
The trade-off for investors is the following.
If the company has little or no long-term
debt, management will find it easy to fi-
nanee some negative-net-present-value proj-
ects by borrowing against (i.e., diluting) fu-
For details, see Hart (1993). A related point has
been made by Philip Dybvig and Jaime Zender (1991). ture earnings from assets in place. That is,
^Clifford Smith and Jerold Warner (1979) found there will be overinvestment. On the other
that in a random sample of 87 public issues of debt hand, if the eompany has a large amount of
registered with Ihe Securities and Exchange Commis-
sion between January 1974 and December 1975, more
than 90 percent of the bonds contained restrictions on
the issuing of additional debt. Although the strength of
such debt covenants declined during the 1980"s, it is
still very common for new public debt issues to contain
some restrictions on new debt. See Kenneth Lehn and Some formal analysis is provided by Rene Stulz
Annette Poulsen (1991). (1990) and Guozhong Xie (1990).
VOL. 85 NO. 3 HART AND MOORE: DEBT AND SENIORITY 569

senior long-term debt, management will be the form: "If you (the manager) do not pay
unable to finance some positive-net- D, dollars to security-holders at date /, then
present-value projects because earnings the company goes bankrupt (i.e., you lose
from assets in place are overmortgaged your job)." Given this, it is unclear why an
(there is debt-overhang in the sense of ineentive eontraet of this form would not be
Myers [1977]). That is, there will be underin- employed directly. In contrast, in our model,
vestment. debt is not equivalent to a contingent firing.
We use this trade-off to determine the Rather, debt regulates the manager's ability
eompany's optimal debt-equity ratio and to to raise eapital, making this sensitive to new
derive a number of eomparative-staties re- information available to the market at date
sults concerning the relationship between I when investment decisions are made. Sinee
the debt-equity ratio and the mean and we suppose this information to be observ-
ex ante variance of the return on assets in able but not verifiable, there is no standard
plaee and on new investments."^ In faet, it incentive scheme that duplicates the opti-
turns out that it is sometimes optimal for mal debt eontraet.
the company to issue a more sophisticated Second, much of the literature derives
set of claims than just senior debt and eq- the optimal debt-equity ratio under the as-
uity: in particular, to issue classes of debt of sumption that the company can issue only
different seniorities, with covenants allow- standard debt and equity claims. In con-
ing (limited) dilution of each class. This is trast. Section III considers the case in which
observed in practice and is analyzed in the the eompany can issue arbitrary elaims (in
paper. Finally, we show that our theory is some cases we show that the extra degree of
consistent with the "two most striking facts freedom will not be used). Thus the paper
about corporate financing" (see Myers, can be seen as a contribution to the emerg-
1990): profitability and finaneia! leverage are ing literature on optimal security design (see
negatively eorrelated, and inereases in the recent survey by Harris and Raviv
leverage raise market value. [1992]).
It is useful to note some aspects of our The paper is organized as follows. In Sec-
theory of debt that distinguish it from other tion I, we lay out the basic model and
agency theories in the literature. First, in obtain a sufficient condition for the optimal
most of the literature, debt is equivalent to level of short-term debt to be zero. Seetion
an ineentive contract with management of II contains a number of results about the
optimal level of long-term debt. In Section
III, we consider more general security struc-
tures. Finally, Seetion IV presents our con-
clusions and discusses some extensions of
The trade-of! between overinvestment and under-
investment has also heen analyzed recently by Elazar our work.
Berkovitch and E. Han Kim (1990), Stuiz (1990), Xie
(1990), and Robert Gertner and David Scharfstein I. The Model
(1991). Slulz (1990) and Xie (1990) consider models in
which high short-term debl is good in that it forces
management to pay out funds, but bad because il leads We use the following model, first laid out
to inefficient piecemeal liquidation in the event of by Myers (1977). Consider a firm consisting
default (with, in Stulz's case, a loss of investment of assets in place and new investment op-
opportunities); Slulz and Xie do not consider the role
of long-term debt in preventing the firm from raising
portunities, which exists at three given dates
new capital. Berkovitch and Kim (1990) and Gertner (see Fig. 1). At date 0, the firm's financial
and Scharfstein (1991) do consider the role of long-term structure is chosen. At date 1, the assets in
debt, but assume that managers act on behalf of share- place yield a return of y^ and a new invest-
holders; that is. management is (implicitly) assumed
not to be self-interested. As we have noted, if manage-
ment opportunity costing / appears. At this
ment is not self-interested, the first-best can be time, the firm can be liquidated, yielding L
achieved by putting management on an appropriate (in addition to the y, already realized). We
ineentive scheme and making all of the firm's debt take both investment and liquidation to be
junior and postponable.
zero-one decisions. If the firm is not liqui-
THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1995

t=0 t=2
—I

Old assets Old assets yield return y^ Old assets yield


in place return y2
Decision whether to make
new investment of size i New investment
yields return r
Decision whether to liquidate {if undertaken)
and realize L
1. TiMF LINE FOR THE FIRM

dated, at date 2 the assets in place yield a project-financing.^ Until Section III, we shall
further return y,, and the new investment confine attention to the case in which the
opportunity, if it was taken at date 1, yields firm issues short-term debt due at date 1,
r. At this date the firm is wound up, and long-term debt due at date 2, and equity;
receipts are alloeated to security-holders. and for the time being we shall suppose that
The firm is run by a single manager. This both kinds of debt are senior, in the sense
manager decides whether to take the new that any new claims issued by the firm at
investment opportunity. The variables y^ date 1 are entitled to payment only if date-0
y2, f, r, and L are typically uncertain as of debt-holders have been fully paid off. In
date 0; however, their probability distribu- Section III, we will investigate the role of
tion is common knowledge. All uncertainty more sophisticated securities.
about y^, yj, i, r, and L is resolved at date We also assume that it is prohibitively
1, and there is symmetric information costly for the firm to renegotiate with credi-
throughout. However, y^ ^2' '' '"' 3"*^ ^ ' tors at date 1. Thus if the firm defaults on
although observable, are not verifiable. In its short-term debt at date 1, then this trig-
other words, these variables cannot be the gers bankruptcy, which, in turn, leads to
basis of an enforceable, contingent liquidation (i.e.. L is realized.)." (We discuss
contract.'' Assume also, for simplicity, a zero
interest rate and that investors are risk-
neutral.
If project-financing were possible, the new invest-
Although y^, yj, i, r, and L are not ment could be fmanced as a stand-alone entity, whose
verifiable, we suppose that the total amount merit could be assessed by the market at date 1; and
paid out to security-holders is verifiable. debt levels could be set very high to prevent the
manager from using funds from the existing assets to
Thus securities can be issued at date 0 with subsidize investment. There are several reasons for
claims conditional on the amount that is ruling out projeet-financing. First, it may be that i
paid out. However, we do not allow claims represents an incremenlat investment (e.g.. maintaining
to be issued on the return from the invest- or improving the existing assets) and the final return.
ment, r, separately from the return from >-2 + r. is simply tbe overall return from the (single)
project. Second, it may be that tbe same management
the assets in place, ^2; that is, we rule out team looks after both the uld assets and the new
project and can use transfer pricing to reallocate prof-
its between them; hence the market can keep track
only of total profits. Finally, even if project-speeifie
financing is feasible, it is not at all clear that managers
For example, a statement in the corporate charter will want to finance a project that is not part of their
stipulating that management should invest if and only empire since they will not enjoy the private benefits of
if r > / is unenforceable since a disinterested judge or control (see Shan Li. 1993).
jury would nol know whether r>i. A statement that '*We ignore more sophisticated bankruptcy systems
management must pay out all earnings at date 1 (i.e., tbat try to preserve the firm's going-concern value;
all of >',, whatever >•, may be) is unenforceable for examples are U.S. Chapter II or tbe procedure dis-
sitnilar reasons. cussed in Philippe Aghion et al. (1W2).
VOL. 85 NO. 3 HART AND MOORE: DEBT AND SENIORITY 571

the no-renegotiation assumption further in manager is willing to pay out all accumu-
Section IV.) lated funds (one interpretation is that the
As emphasized earlier, we are interested manager retires and the firm is wound up at
in a situation where management may carry date 2).
out some investment projects for power or The financial structure of the firm is cho-
empire-huilding reasons even though they sen at date 0 so as to maximize the aggre-
are unprofitable.'* To simplify, we consider gate expected return of the security-holders
the (admittedly) extreme case in which the (i.e., to maximize the firm's date-0 market
empire-huilding motive is so strong that no value). This may seem an odd assumption
feasible financial incentive payment can given that financial-structure decisions are
persuade the manager not to invest at date typically made by management (or the board
1.'" At the same time we suppose that the of directors), and we have supposed man-
manager's empire-building tendencies are agement to be self-interested. The assump-
limited to a single, indivisible project. That tion can be justified in two ways. First, the
is, once the project is financed, the manager financial-structure choice may be made,
has no further uses for company funds {i.e., prior to a public ofiFering at date 0, by an
he cannot or does not wish to employ such original owner, who wishes to maximize his
funds to make additional investments or to total receipts in the subsequent offering (he
pay for perks or higher salaries—one inter- is about to retire). Second, one can imagine
pretation is that perks and salaries are ade- that the firm is initially all equity, and the
quately controlled by other mechanisms, threat of a hostile takeover at date 0 forces
e.g., incentive schemes)." management to choose a new financial
Given these assumptions about empire- structure which maximizes date-0 market
building behavior, the only way to stop the value (the hostile bidder is present now but
manager from investing in the project is to may not be around at date I, so manage-
prevent the necessary funds from being ment must bond itself now to act well in the
made available at date 1. We also suppose future).'^
that the manager never liquidates the firm Define d^ to be the amount owed at date
voluntarily at date 1, since this involves a 1, and t/j to be the amount owed at date 2
loss of power. In contrast, at date 2 there (i.e., d, and f/j ^""^ I^^e face values of short-
are no investment opportunities, and so the term and long-term debt, respectively). (Of
course, at date 0 these debt claims will
typically trade for less than their face value
because of the risk of default.) In general,
This is in the spirit of the early managerial litera- the instruments d^ and ^/^ have distinct
ture of William Baumol (1959), Robin Marris (1964), roles in curbing the manager's empire-build-
and Oliver Williamson (1964), as well as the later work
of Jensen (19f^()). For empirical support, see ing tendencies. Since the role of short-term
Gordon Donaldson (1984). debt is relatively well understood, in this
We suppose that tbe manager has no (or little) paper we concentrate on the role of long-
initial wealth and so cannot be cbarged up front for
empire-building benefits.
"This distinguishes our model from a "pure free-
cash-flow model" of the Jensen (19X6) variety. In a
pure free-cash-flow model, the manager always has 'Both of these scenarios are of course special. We
further uses of company funds and so will squander believe tbat the thrust of our analysis applies also to
each dollar of investor returns that is not mortgaged to tbe case in wbich management chooses finaneial struc-
ereditors. Thus in a free-cash-flow model the value of ture to maximize its own welfare. In tbe present
equity is zero, ln contrast, in our model, as the reader three-date model, tbis leads to the trivial outcome of
will shortly see, ihe value of equity can be positive. no debt (management clearly prefers not to be under
Note tbat this is not a critical difference between pressure from creditors). However, in a model with
Ihe two analyses since our main results would still hold more periods, management may issue (senior) debt
under the more extreme Jensen assumptions. A more voluntarily, since this may be the only way to raise
important difference between the models is that ours funds from investors concerned that tbeir claims may
explieitly considers the costs as well as the benefits of be diluted if managemeni undertakes bad investments
short- and long-lerm debt. in the future. On tbis, see Jeffrey Zweibel (1993).
572 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1995

term debt. To this end, we now present an If (1) is not satisfied, the manager will be
assumption which implies that it is optimal able to maintain the firm as a going concern
to set c/, = 0. as long as either

ASSUMPTION V. y,<i and with (3) or y, + y, > .:/i +


probability 1.
In the first case, the manager pays the date-1
Assumption 1 says that the manager can debt out of current earnings, while in the
never finance the investment out of date-1 second case, he pays it by borrowing out of
earnings (there is no free cash flow) and future earnings. If (3) but not (1) is satisfied,
that it is never efficient to liquidate the firm the total return to date-0 claim-holders is
at date 1. Assumption 1 may be plausible
for the case of a growth company that, at
least initially, requires an injection of new (4)
capital to prosper.
To understand why Assumption 1 implies Finally, if neither (1) nor (3) is satisfied,
that the optimal d^ is zero, consider the the firm is liquidated at date 1 and
situation facing the manager at date 1. Given
the manager's empire-building tendencies,
his first choice is to invest (if he can raise (5) L.
the funds). His second choice is to maintain
the firm as a going concern (if he cannot It should now be clear why //, ^ 0 is opti-
invest but can pay ofiF his date-1 debts). His mal; that is, why rfj = 0 maximizes the ex-
third choice is to close the firm down (he pected value of R. Only the sum t/, -I- d/2
does this only if he is forced to default at matters in (1) and the second half of (3).
date 1 and go bankrupt). However, a low d^ is good in increasing the
Now the firm's total revenues if the man- chance that the first half of (3) is satisfied,
ager invests are yi + ^2 + '"' of which d^ + d^ that is, minimizing the likelihood of liquida-
is mortgaged to the old (senior) creditors. tion. Liquidation is undesirable since, given
(Recall that all uncertainty is resolved at yi > L, (4) and (5) imply that R is higher
date 1.) Hence the most the firm can bor- when the firm survives than when it is liqui-
row at date 1 is y,-t-y2 + r - ^i - (^2- '^ dated.
follows that the manager will invest if and We have therefore established the follow-
only if ing proposition.

(1) PROPOSITION 1: Given Assumption 1, the


date-0 market value of the firm is maximized
If (1) is satisfied, the total return to date-0 by setting d^ = 0.'^'
claim-holders, R, is
In the next section, we analyze the opti-
mal level of long-term debt.
(2)

of which date-0 creditors receive J, + d2, '"'Notice that we are ruling out the possibility of
negatire debt. For example, a negative d^—in effect a
and shareholders receive the rest. prearranged boost to y,—allows the manager to make
Notice for future reference the two an investment without tbe need to go to the market at
sources of inefficiency here. Sometimes the date 1, even when y, <i. Tbis may be helpful if the
manager will invest even though r < i, be- profitable investments are small ones. A negative t/j
cause y, -I- y2 is big relative to d^ + dj- At may be bard to implement, however. It may be impos-
sible to arrange for dispersed ereditors to pay in money
other times he will be unable to invest even al date 1; and if the manager is given the money at
though r > /, because yi + y2 is small rela- date 0 he may use it to make an unprofitable date-0
tive to d^ + dj- investment.
VOL. 85 NO. 3 HART AND MOORE: DEBT AND SENIORITY 573

II. Long-Term Debt (iv) If i and y, are deterministic, and r =


g(y2) where gi-) is a strictly increasing
For fhe remainder of fhe paper we as- function, then the first-best can be
sume fhaf Assumpfion 1 holds, and so, by achieved by setting d2 equal to y.+
Proposition 1, the optimal d^ is zero. Thus g-\i).
liquidation never occurs af dafe 1, and L is
irrelevanf. Part (i) of Proposifion 2 is immediafe.
Denofe by F{yy,y2,i,r) fhe probability Since there is no danger of fhe manager
disfribution of yj, y2, /, and r, as of date 0. making an unprofitable investment, it is best
The return from the exisfing assefs. fo give him the flexibility to raise as much
money as he can at date 1, by having no
deht. The investment then always goes
ahead, as required in the first-besf. Part (ii)
is fixed, and so in evaluafing fhe effecfs of is the opposite extreme, where no invest-
differenf levels of d2 we can focus on fhe ment is ever profitable. The effect of a large
nef social refurn from the new investment, amount of senior (nondilutable) debt £^2 '^
r-i. From (1), we know that the invest- fhat fhe manager is never able to raise
ment goes ahead if and only if y[ + y2 + further funds at f =-1, and so fhe invesf-
r - i> d2, and so an optimal dj solves ment never goes ahead.
Part (iii) reveals quife a Iof abouf fhe
economics of the model. The difficulty faced
(6) by those designing fhe security strucfure at
dafe 0 is that the uncertain refurns yi -*- y2
from exisfing assefs cannof be disentangled
from the uncertain returns r - / from new
The basic trade-off is the following. The investment. As a result, fhere is a danger
benefit of a high d2 is that the returns from that the manager will be able to finance fhe
the assets in place are mortgaged, which new investment af date 1 by borrowing
sfops management from using them to sub- against y2. However, the danger can be
sidize bad investment projects. The cost of a avoided if the total return yi-l-y2 from
high dj is debf overhang: given fhat new existing assets is fixed, because this return
invesfors' claims are junior fo the debf dj, can be mortgaged away af date 0 by issuing
good projects cannof be underfaken if senior, nondilufable debt. The manager then
refurns from exisfing assets are overmort- invests if and only if r is greater than /. One
gaged. An opfimal d2 sfrikes the righf bal- point to observe here is that fhe debf y | + y2
ance between fhese fwo conflicfing objec- is riskless; however, this does nof mean thaf
fives. it does not play an important role in pre-
There are four eases in which if is possi- venting the manager from making unprof-
ble to obfain the firsf-besf; fhese are grouped itable investments.
in Proposifion 2. Part (iv) is also revealing. If r^giy-^),
and / and y, are deferministic, then if is
PROPOSITION 2: again possible in effect fo disentangle fhe
returns from the exisfing assets and returns
(i) If r is greater than i with probability I, from the new investment. Given d2 = y] +
then the first-best ean be achieved by g~ '(/), the manager invests if and only if
setting ^2 equal to 0 (all equity). y2 + /• exceeds i + g~'(/), fhat is, since r =
(ii) If r is less than i with probability 1, then gCy^), if and only if r is greater than /.
the first-best can be achieied by setting In general the first-best cannot be
(^2 lo''gc enough. achieved. Some insight into fhe second-besf
(iii) If y[ + y2 equals some constant y with can be obtained by differenfiating (6). If F
probability 1, then the first-best can be is a continuous distribufion, we can express
achieved by setting ^2 equal to y. fhe first-order condifion for an interior
574 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1995

Optimum as Proposifion 3 is proved in the Appendix.


The infuifion is straighfforward. An in-
crease in y, gives fhe manager more cash
(7) wifh which fo invest af date 1, and so at fhe
margin his ability to borrow should be con-
Thaf is, ^ is sef af a level such fhaf the strained: fhe debt level should rise. Equally,
marginal invesfment projecf jusf breaks an increase in the mean of y2 implies fhaf
even. the manager can borrow more at date 1
We consider next some comparative- against fhe refurn from the existing assefs,
statics properties. Proposition 3 below shows and so, again, fhe debt level should rise. An
how d. changes with the means of y,, y2, i, increase in fhe mean of /, or a decrease in
and f. Part (ii) of the proposition uses the the mean of r, implies that investments are
following condition. less likely to be profitable, and therefore fhe
manager should be consfrained with higher
debf.
Condition C: The left-hand side of equation
(7), £ [ r - ( | y , + yi + r - / = (/J, is continu- Notice fhat part (i) of Proposifion 3 says
ously differenfiable on an interval [d2,d2i that d2 in fact moves dollar-for-dollar with
Moreover, whenever (7) holds, if is also the increases in y^ or y2- This follows directly
case fhaf from an inspection of program (6): if a
dollar is added fo every realization of yj (or
yj) and a dollar is added to fl'2' ^^en fhe set
(8) of sfafes in which invesfment goes ahead is
oa-,
unchanged (and the refurn from invesfmenf,
r - i, is also unchanged).
There are no comparably general resulfs
Denofe r-i by X and yi + y2 by Y. for how the opfimal d2 changes with fhe
Inequalify (8) says fhaf EiXlX + Y^dj] variances of y,, y2, ', and r. However, if is
increases wifh d2, buf by less fhan fhe easy fo compufe the opfimal c/2 and, fhere-
amounf d2 increases. Nofe fhaf fhe leff- fore, fo see fhe variance effecfs, in fwo
hand inequalify in Condifion C is simply the examples. These examples also illustrate the
second-order condition for d2 in (6), which mean effects from Proposifion 3. For sim-
will hold (albeit weakly) if r-i and y,-I- plicity, in both examples we assume thaf yi
y2 + r - i are affiliated (i.e., in a loose sense, and / are deterministic (wifh y, < / ) .
positively correlated; see theorem 5 in
Paul Milgrom and Roberf Weber [1982]). Example I: Assume fhat y2 and r are inde-
The righf-hand inequality will hold if, in pendently and normally distributed with
addifion, y, + y2 and y, + y2 + r - / are means /i.2 and (Xr and with variances a2
affiliated. and CT^}'^ Then by standard distribution
theory the left-hand side of (7) is simply
PROPOSITION 3: Suppose is an opti-
mum debt level.

(i) If a dollar is added to every realization of


y^, or added to every realization of
then (^ 2 optimum debt level.
(ii) Assume that Condition C holds, and that
d2 is an interior optimum in [d2,d2] (in
which case it is unique). If a small
amount is added to every realization of i,
or subtracted from every realization of r, '"^Strictly speaking, we ougbt to truncate tbe distri-
then the optimum debt level strictly in- butions of yi and r so that they are nonnegative. See
creases. our 1990 working paper for further details.
VOL. 85 NO. 3 HART AND MOORE: DEBT AND SENIORITY 575

* - y.+y^

FIGURE 2. CASE (a) OF EXAMPLE 2

and hence the optimal debt level dy is::''' profitable (/.t^ < /).
In case (a), the optimal debt level d^ is
indicated in Figure 2, where the support of
y, + y2 is the horizontal of the rectangle,
(9) and the support of r - / is the vertical (note
(T,
that, since s^Ks^-, the rectangle is wider
than it is tall). Notice that conditional on
Example 2: Let y2 and r be independently iy\-^y-2)^{r-i) = d2 (i.e., conditional on
and uniformly distributed on [/ij - ^2' lying along the 135° line intersecting the
fi2 + S2] and [/Xr ~ ^^r'^r + •^fl' Tespectively. rectangular support) the expectation of r - /
Assume that ix, - s^ <i <^i, + s^ [other- is zero, as required by (7). From the figure it
wise, by parts (i) and (ii) of Proposition 2, is clear that the optimal debt level must
the optimal t/j would be either zero or satisfy d^ - ( y , + M2 "-^2)= - ( / i r - ^ ^ r - O ;
infinity]. Also, to simplify the example, we that is.
assume that s^ < .Sj-
There are two cases to consider: (a) the (10) ^2 = + Ms - ^2 - + ^r +
case where on average new investment is
profitable i(x^>i); and (b) where it is un-
In case (b), a similar line of reasoning leads
to
Example 1 is easily generalized to allow for corre- (11) ^2 = y , + /i2 + 52 - /X, - ^, + /
lation between y^ ^nd r. If their correlation coefficient
is p, ttien the optimal ^2 is given by

In both Examples 1 and 2, d^ rises with


yi, rises with the mean of y2, falls with /,
and rises with the mean of r—all as per
Note that the denominator ir^ -f pcr-,o-, is positive from Proposition 3. Also, if new investment is on
the second-order condition. Thus, provided the numer-
ator cr| + p(T2^r is positive—which it will be unless average profitable (i.e., p.^ > i), then d2 falls
( - a-^/dj) < p <,(- a^/a;)—the comparative-statics with the variance of y2 and rises with the
results reported in the text continue to hold. variance of r. However, if new investment is
576 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1995

on average unprofitable t/i^ < i), these vari- ple showing how the extra degrees of free-
ance effects are reversed: rfj "ses with the dom help. The kind of securities we intro-
variance of yj ^'^^ ^^'^^ ^''^^ ^^^ variance duce may af first sight seem rather foreign;
of r. but we go on to show thaf they can be
To understand the variance effects better, approximated by a conventional class of debt
note that, in problem (6), dj i^ ^^^ so that contracts based on seniority. The section
the market's assessment of future total re- ends by considering under what circum-
turn at date 1 screens the quality of new stances one would not need the additional
investment appropriately. If yj and ( are flexibility offered by our general securify
constant (as in Examples 1 and 2), the structure and could instead merely rely on
first-order condition (7) says that the condi- simple debt and equity (as in Section II).
tional expectation of r, E[r\y2 + r = P], Recall that although y,, yj, /, and r are
must equal / when P = d2 + i - yj. Now as not verifiable, the total amount paid out fo
the variance of y;, a-2, rises relative to the security-holders at date 2, denoted by /*, is
variance of r, cr}., the fact that y^-^ r = verifiable. Thus securities can be issued af
^2 + ' ~ yi reveals less information about date 0 with claims conditional on P. The
r — I (we are looking at this from date 0, most general long-term security structure
when r and / are uncertain). In the limit as consists of contingent debt, along the fol-
o-| - » » or cr} -> 0, the left-hand side of (7) lowing lines. The firm issues a single class of
becomes simply /x.^ - ^ and the optimum securities at date 0 wifh an (enforceable)
will not be interior. In the case where new promise that if P dollars are distributed at
investment Is on average profitable (^^ > /), date 2, this class will collectively receive
if is best to give the manager maximum O(P) of them, where 0<O(P)<P. [The
freedom to finance new investment (i.e., to " O " in O(P) denotes fhe old, or original,
set t/j = 0). In the case where new invest- dafe-0 security holders.] In addition, man-
ment is on average unprofitable {\i.^ < i), if agement is given permission to issue any
is best fo give the manager no freedom to new securities it likes at date 1. That is,
finance new investment (i.e., to set dj =<»). management can earmark fhe residual
Put simply, if the manager's ability fo raise amount NiP) = P - OiP) for new investors
fresh capital at date 1 is almost entirely at date 1 in fhe aftempt to finance new
determined by the realized returns from investment. [The ' W in N(P) denotes the
existing assets, fhen fhere is little point in new investors af dafe 1.] Note that a choice
using a security structure fo screen out the of O(P) close to or far away from P af dafe
bad new invesfmenfs. One may as well rely 0 consfrains the firm more or less in its
on prior (date-0) information—thaf is, investment choice at date 1.^''
whether or not new investments are on av-
erage profitable. General long-term securities like O(P)
are not, to our knowledge, observed. How-
Since the above intuition for fhe variance ever, we show shortly that, under two mild
effects does not hinge on fhe particular dis- assumptions, any choice of 0(P) is equiva-
fributional assumptions of Examples 1 or 2, lent to a package of "standard" securities,
we suspect fhaf it may be possible to estab- consisting of equity and various seniorities
lish a general result about the effects of
increasing variance. We do not have such a
result to report at this fime, however.
One can think of even more general securities.
One possibility is that O{P) could be conditioned on
in. General Long-Term Security Structures the amount of money raised at date 1. However, our
preliminary investigations suggest that the extra degree
In this section, we explore fhe possibility of freedom would not help.
thaf more sophisticafed long-ferm securify Another possibility is that OiP) could be sensitive
to Ihe market lvalue of sectirities. The difficulty with
sfructures than simple debt may be optimal. this is that there is a tricky bootstrap efFect: market
We sfart by laying out a quite general class values are affecled by the manager's actions, which are
of securify sfructures, and we give an exam- in turn constrained by the form of O{P).
VOL. 85 NO. 3 HART AND MOORE: DEBT AND SENIORITY 577

of debt. Thus for the moment we stick with NiP ), the manager will raise the i — y^
the genera! specification O(P). We con- dollars necessary to invest by committing
tinue to use Assumption 1 throughout this himself to lower total return from P^ to
section.^^ P-. Thus if /V(P") is raised to M P " ) , the
Given N{ •) [or equivalently O{ •)], con- same investment decisions occur, but total
sider the position of management at date 1 return is generally higher since the manager
once y,, ^2, ', and r are realized. Since y, is not encouraged to engage in wastage. An
is less than /, the manager can invest only if extension of this argument shows that date-0
he can raise ( - y, from the market. If he market value can only increase if NiP) is
does invest, P ^ r + yj, and so the most replaced by sup[NiP~ )\P~ < P) for each P.
he can offer the market at date 2 is P — This yields a monotonically increasing func-
Oir -\- y2)= Nir + yj). It follows that the tion NiP).
manager will be able to finance the invest- A similar argument shows that the slope
ment if and only if N(r + yj) > ( - y^ of N can be set less than or equal to 1, if
As in (6), an optimal security structure at the manager can always raise more funds
date 0 is represented by a function NiP), than he needs for the investment project
which solves and save the rest at the going rate of inter-
est.'** From now on, therefore, when we
solve for the optimal security structure we
(12) max/ {r-i)dF{yi,y2J,r) impose the extra constraint that N has slope
N(-) between 0 and 1:
Mr +

subject to (14)

forall P
(13) 0<N(P)<P.
Is all the flexibility afforded by this gen-
eral security structure useful? Example 3,
So far we have allowed the slope of N(P) which generalizes part (iv) of Proposition 2
to be almost arbitrary. With a minor modi- to the case of uncertain /, shows that indeed
fication in the manager's set of available it is.
actions, however, we can restrict N to have
a slope between 0 and 1. Assume that the Example 3: Suppose y, = 0 and r =
manager can commit himself at date 1 to where g( •) is a strictly increasing function.
lower the return both of the investment Then one can obtain the first-best by putting
project and of the assets in place (e.g., by
selling off some fraction of the assets at an
artificially low price or by hiring extra work-
ers). Suppose that N(p-)> NiF^) for The argument is as follows. Suppose P < P*
some P~ < P'^. Then the firm's date-0 mar- and NiP^)-NiP)> P"" - F". Then (he firm's date-
0 market value will not change if N{P~ ) is raised to
ket value can only increase if N(P^) is N(P' ) - P* + P~. The reason is that, if >'; + r = P~
raised to equal NiP~). The reason is that and N{p-)<i- yi<N{P^)- P*+ p-. the manager
the low value of N{P'^) cannot be effective can raise (i - yi)-^(P'^ - P~ ) dollars from the market,
in deterring management from investing, invest i in the project, and save the remaining
since if y2 + 1" = P^ and N(P*) < i - y, < ( / . - _ p- ) This yields a total date-2 return of P^, out
of which the manager can repay new security-holders
up to NiP' )>i- yi-i-iP^ - P ). Again this argu-
ment can be extended to show that date-0 market value
will be unchanged if NiP) is replaced by
It is straightforward to confirm that Proposition 1
continues to apply, even when more sophisticated
long-term securities are admitted. That is, there is no
role for shorl-term securities (like short-term debt d,) This yields a function NiP) whose slope is less than or
which promise to pay out at date 1. equal to L
578 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1995

NiP)= N, the (unique) solution to claim-holders. For unsecured debt, the free-
dom to issue further debt is often con-
strained by covenants specifying upper lim-
its on the ratio of debt to net worth or to
[It is straightforward to confirm that (13) tangible assets.'"'
and (14) hold.] For a given r [and hence Let us now consider the shape of the
y2 = g~'(r)], the manager can raise up to function NiP) for the above package of
Nir + y2) to finance the investment. But by standard debt and equity. Suppose at date 1
construction, N(r -I- y2) = r. Moreover, since the firm issues all the additional debt
yj = 0, the manager needs to raise the full AD',...,AD",AD" + ' that it is permitted to
cost / to make the investment—which means issue under the date-0 covenants. How much
that he will be in a position to invest if and will these various new issues fetch? Suppose
only if r > i (i.e., the first-best is imple- it is known at date 1 that the firm's date-2
mented). payout will be P. For 0 < / * < D ' - h A D \
Our next task is to show that our general only the most senior class of creditors re-
security structure NiP) can be represented ceives any payment, and the slope of N(P)
by a "standard package" of securities, com- is AD'/(D'+ AD'); the point is that, in
prising equity and noncontingent debt of this region, at date 2 every dollar of P is
various seniorities. divided in the proportions AD':D' be-
A standard package of debt and equity tween new and old cIass-1 creditors. For
consists of n classes of debt and a single D' + AD' < F < D' + AD' f D" + AD^
class of equity. The ;th class of debt, / = the slope of NiP) is A D V ( ^ ^ + A D ^ ) .
l,...,n, is characterized by an amount D^ Here, at date 2 class-1 creditors (old and
collectively owed to class j at date 2 and a new) are fully paid, and every dollar of the
maximum additional amount AD' of in- residual, / ' - D ' - A D ' , is divided in the
debtedness to class j that the firm can take proportions AD^.D^ between new and old
on at date 1 (i.e., a covenant in the initial class-2 creditors; more junior creditors re-
debt contract allows the firm to issue new ceive nothing. And so on (see Fig. 3).
debt at date 1 until the total amount owed It follows from Figure 3 that a standard
class / is D^ + ADO. The classes are ranked debt/equity package yields a particular
by seniority with 1 being the most senior (in function NiP) that satisfies (13) and (14). It
the sense that it must be paid off first) and is also clear from Figure 3 that the converse
n the most junior. The firm can create an holds, at least approximately: given any
(n -+-l)th class of debt of any size at date 1, function NiP) satisfying (13) and (14), we
which is junior to all existing debt, but se- can find a standard debt/equity package
nior to equity; in effect, AD""^' =ao. that approximately implements it. Simply
This description of debt is consistent with approximate the curve NiP) by a piecewise
what we observe in practice. Firms do issue linear graph whose slope always lies be-
securities of different seniorities, the typical tween 0 and 1. Such a piecewise linear
order being secured debt, then various pri- graph is a representation of some .standard
ority claims, then unsecured debt, then sub- debt/equity security package.
ordinated debt, and finally equity. More- The leading example of a standard pack-
over, firms retain the right to issue further age is the case of simple debt/equity, which
securities of comparable or higher seniority, we examined in Section II. Namely, there is
but within prespecified limits. For secured
debt, these limits will be determined by the
amount of collateral still available; and also
possibly by a negative pledge clause, which For a discussion of covenants used in practice, see
prohibits the issuance of any new debt with Smith and Warner (1979) and Lehn and Poulsen (1991).
a superior claim to existing unsecured debt For an example of a bond prospectus (Potomac Elec-
tric Power Co.) with essentially the lorm of our stan-
or which requires that unsecured creditors dard debt/equity package, see Brealey and Myers (1988
be raised to equal status with subsequent pp. 591-99).
VOL. 85 NO. 3 HART AND MOORE: DEBT AND SENIORITY 579

N(P)

^-p

FIGURE 3. THE SHAPE OF THE FUNCTION N(P)

a single class of debt that cannot be diluted: PROPOSITION 4: Ifiandy^ are determin-
n = l, Z)'>0, and A D ' - O . To marry up istic, then simple debt/equity is optimal.
with Section II. let D^ = d-,. Then N{P)
reduces to max(P - d2-, 0). That is, for P < PROOF:
(/,, all of P must be given to senior debt- New investment occurs if and only if
holders, and there is none for new investors. M F ) > ( - y,; that is, in view of (14), if and
On the other hand, for P > dj. the firm can only if P equals or exeeeds some critical
issue junior debt and give P - d2 to new value P'^, say. It follows that the optimum
investors. ean be sustained by a simple debt/equity
In Section II, we proceeded on the as- structure with dj = P" -U - y,)-
sumption that nothing more sophisticated
than simple debt/equity need be consid- Note that Proposition 4 justifies our restric-
ered in many instances. It is time to justify tion to simple debt/equity in Examples 1
that assumption. Obviously, the four special and 2 in Section II.
cases given in Proposition 2 are examples in The lemma below presents a general
which simple debt/equity is optimal, sinee sufficient condition under which simple
in each case we are able to obtain the debt/equity is optimal when / and/or y,
first-best. Another ease in which we can be are stoehastie. We assume that the distribu-
sure that simple debt/equity is optimal is tion function F(y^,y2,i,r) satisfies the fol-
where / and y, are deterministic. lowing condition.
580 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1995

Condition F: Fiy^.yjJ^r) is continuously The lemma is proved in the Appendix. A


distributed, and the joint density function rough intuition is as follows. KiP,N(P)) is
f{P,N) of P = ( r + y . ) a n d N =i i - y^) h the expected value of a marginal date-1
strictly positive everywhere in the set 'T = investment given a total date-2 payout of P.
{{P.N_)\P<P<P; 0<N<P], where P Condition K implies that there is a cutoff
and P are respectively the minimum and value of P, say P*, such that the expeeted
maximum possible value of r + y^. value of a marginal date-1 investment is
negative (respectively, positive) if P < P*
Note that in choosing an optimal security {P>P*). Other things equal, then, one
structure N{P), given the constraint (13), would like to lower N(P) for P < P*, and
set T is the only relevant part of the sup- raise NiP) for P>P*. But we have to
port of Hy,.y2,',''). For ( P , / V ) G T , we contend with constraints (13) and (14). It
define the following conditional expecta- should be clear that a simple security struc-
tion: ture eomprising debt dj^ P* - N{P*) and
equity does a good job of balancing these
goals (sinee N\P)^Q for P < P*, and
N'{P)^\ for P> P*).
= E[r - i\r + yj ^ P and / - y, = N ] .
The result follows from the lemma.
KEY LEMMA: Assume that Condition F PROPOSITION 5: Assume that Condition
holds. A long-term security structure compris- F holds. A long-term security .structure com-
ing simple debt d2 and equity is optimal if the prising simple debt ^2 and equity is optimal
following condition holds. if-
Condition K: For any pair {P*,N*)^r, (i) i is deterministic;
(ii) y^ is distributed independently ofy2 and
K{P*,N'')>0 implies K{P,N) r; and
(iii) E[r\r + y2 = P]_is strictly increasing in
P,forP<P< P.2'
ifO<N-N*\ ^ \P-P'
PROOF:
Conditions (i) and (ii) of the proposition
<0 implies KiP,N)l ^ Jo jointly imply that K(P,N) is independent
of N. Together with condition (iii) they im-
ifQ<N*-N P. ply that K(P,N) is strietly increasing in P.
Hence Condition K is satisfied. Now apply
To help shed light on Condition K, it is the lemma.
useful to rewrite KiP^N) as E[r - i\y^ +
y2 + r — i = P — N and /— y, = A'], the ex- Note tbat condition (iii) of Proposition 5
pected return from the new investment pro- is very natural and will hold (at least weakly)
ject, conditional on the total net profit if r and r + y2 are affiliated. The intuition
equafing P — N and the amount of new behind the result is that, when / is fixed,
finaneing equaling A^. If this conditional ex- new investment should not occur for low
pectation is (strictly) increasing in P - N values of r + y2, sinee this signifies low r,
and (weakly) increasing in N (i.e., if the
project's profit rises with botb tbe total net
profit and the external financing require-
ment), tben Condition K will bold.^"
that there is no inconsistency between
Proposition 5 and Example 3. If / is deterministic and
y, = 0. r = g(y2), then there is indeterminacy in the
We are grateful to a referee for pointing this out. optimal security structure.
VOL. 85 NO. 3 HART AND MOORE: DEBT AND SENIORITY 581

on average; whereas the investment should class. Finally, we have derived sufi^cient
go ahead for high values of r -I- y^. A simple conditions for the additional flexibility af-
debt/equity security structure implements forded by difl'erent classes not to be useful,
this quite well. that is, for simple debt and equity to be
Our final result concerns tbe opposite optimal.
case to Proposition 5. It should be noted that some of our pre-
dictions are novel. For example, a theory
PROPOSITION 6: Assume that Condition whieh trades off the tax benefits of debt
F holds. If (i) r is deterministic, (ii) yj is against the bankruptcy costs of debt would
independent ofy^ and i, and (iii) E[i\i — y^ = not distinguish between assets in place and
N ] is strictly increasing in N, for P < N < P, new investments, and such a theory would
then it is optimal at date 0 to issue two classes predict a positive correlation between prof-
of debt: a negligible amount of senior debt, itability and the debt level. In contrast, our
with an option to borrow a finite amount of theory explains the observed negative corre-
additional debt of the same seniority at date 1 lation between profitability and leverage (see
(dy = 0, Ad, > Q); and a large amount of a Carl Kester, 1986; Myers, 1990), as long as
second class of debt with no option to borrow high profitability is associated with new pro-
any more ft/j ^ "^i ^^i = Oj. jects; this is Myers's (1990) first "striking
fact." Note that we can also explain
In a sense, the optimal security structure Myers's second striking faet. Consider a
in Proposition 6 is the obverse of simple company that for some reason—perhaps
debt/equity: the manager can raise the first historical—has (relatively) little debt, and
Ai/, of any P, but no more [N{P) = suppose the eompany faces the threat of a
min{P, At/,}]. The intuition is that, given a hostile takeover. Then, according to our
fixed r, low (respectively, high) values of / theory, the managers may engage in a
represent good (bad) investment opportuni- debt-equity swap (i.e., borrow and use the
ties and should be eneouraged (discour- proceeds to pay a dividend or buy baek
aged). To this end, the manager is given an equity) in order to commit themselves not
"overdraft facility" of At/,. to undertake future (bad) investments
(thereby persuading shareholders not to
We do not give a formal proof of Proposi-
tender to the raider). Under these condi-
tion 6, since it is similar to the proofs of the
tions, increases in leverage and increases in
lemma and Proposition 5, with Condition K
market value will move together.^^
replaced by K(P,N) independent of P and
strictly decreasing in N, for (P, /V) G T. As noted in the Introduction, however,
perhaps a more important difference be-
IV. Conclusions and Extensions tween our theory and most others in the
literature is that other theories cannot ex-
In this paper, we have explored the role plain the fact that firms issue hard (senior,
of long-term debt in preventing self-inter- nonpostponable) debt claims, whereas our
ested management from financing unprof- theory can explain this.
itable investments. We have shown that, in An important assumption ihat we bave
those cases where simple debt and equity made is that a firm cannot renegotiate with
are optimal, (i) the higher is the average
profitability of a firm's new investment pro-
ject, the lower will be the level of long-term
debt, (ii) the higher is the average prof- Measured profitability reflects the profitability of
itability of a firm's existing assets (assets in assets in place. However, if the profitabilities of assets
place), the higher will be the level of long- in place and new investments are positively correlated,
term debt. We have also shown that, in then measured profitability may serve as a proxy for
general, it is optimal for a firm to issue the profitability of new investments.
classes of debt of different seniorities, with " F o r details, see Hari (1993). Other bonding theo-
ries, such as those in Grossman and Hart (1982) and
eovenants allowing (limited) dilution of each Jensen (1986), can also explain this observation.
582 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1995

its claim-holders at date 1 when a new in- out that the Trust Indenture Act of 1939
vestment project becomes available. Note makes such a provision illegal in the United
that, if renegotiation were costless, there States for public debt. However, even if it
would be no disadvantage in having high were legal, there are strong theoretical rea-
debt since if the new project had positive sons for thinking that it would not solve the
net present value the creditors would always problem. For majority rule to work well,
be prepared to renegotiate their claims so individual investors must keep abreast of
as to allow the project to go ahead. Thus in the firm's progress and have very good in-
a world of costless renegotiation, it would formation about a firm's investment
be optimal to have infinite (or very high) prospects. This is a very demanding require-
debt, in effect forcing the firm to return ment in a complex world where most of
to the capital market—or, to put it an- investors' time is quite properly allocated to
other way, to seek permission from its other activities. In other words, our assump-
creditors—for every new investment. tion that the profitability of new investment
Such an extreme outcome is unrealistic, is public information should not be taken
and there are strong theoretical reasons why. literally; it is meant to apply to the most
Because investors are wealth-constrained sophisticated arbitrageur, rather than to the
and risk-averse, a major corporation will average investor. Thus to make the firm's
typically be financed by a sizable number of investment decision depend on a majority
small investors, rather than just a small vote of average investors would be rather
number of very large ones. But this means like running the firm by a not very well-
that free-rider and holdout problems are informed committee—a procedure whose
likely to make renegotiation difficult. In record of success historically has been less
particular, if the debt level is too high to than outstanding.^''
allow a project with positive net present For these reasons, our assumption that
value to take place, then while it is in the renegotiation is impossible does not seem
collective interest of creditors to forgive a an unreasonable theoretical simplification
portion of the debt, it is in any small credi- for companies with widely held debt.
tor's interest to refuse to forgive his share There are a number of possible exten-
since the chance that his decision will affect sions of the analysis. An obvious one is to
the outcome is very small (see e.g., Gertner increase the number of periods. This raises
and Scharfstein, 1991). Thus in many cases at least two new—and far from straightfor-
one would expect the renegotiation process ward—issues. First, in a multiperiod model,
to break down and investment not to occur; management faces the choice of raising cap-
moreover the evidence of Stuart Gilson ital for investment today or waiting to invest
et al. (1990) suggests that renegotiation fre- until tomorrow. In order to decide which
quently does fail in practice.^'' choice is preferred, one needs to know how
One possible way around the free-rider management trades off different sizes of
problem is to include a provision in the empires at different moments in time. In
initial debt contract that the aggregate debt other words, the multiperiod extension re-
level can be reduced as long as a majority quires the specification of an intertemporal
of creditors approves (i.e., the majority's managerial utility function, whereas the
wishes are binding on the minority). It turns

' T o put it another way, to the extent that (dis-


In a study of the companies listed on the New persed) creditors are poorly informed, any debt for-
York Stock Exchange and the American Stock Ex- giveness is likely to be insensitive to the cx piiU realiza-
change thai were in severe financial distress during tions of >'[, >'2. '•, and i; that is, debt forgiveness will be
197S-1987, Gilson et al. (199U) found that debt renego- approximately a fixed amount </'. Bul then ihe same
tiations failed more often than 50 percent of the time outcome could be achieved by setting the original debt
and were more likely to fail the larger the number of level equal lo (/j ~ ^' ^'•^•. ^^^^ forgiveness serves no
creditors (see also Gilson. 1991). useful role).
VOL. H5 NO. 3 HART AND MOORE: DEBT AND SENIORITY 583

two-period model required only the as- tical argument can be used for the case
sumption that management prefers more where e > 0 is subtracted from every real-
investment to less. ization of r.
A second complication is that the inter-
pretation of seniority becomes less clear-cut. PROOF OF KEY LEMMA:
To give an example, in what sense does a
senior debt claim issued at date 1 with a Let C be the class of admissible security
promise to pay one dollar at date 4 have structures N satisfying (13) and (14), and let
priority over a junior debt claim issued at ViN) denote the integral in (12). Note that
date 2 which promises to pay one dollar at C is convex: \N +{l- \)M ^C for any
date 3? The answer is that it depends on N,M&C and any ( ) < A < I . If N is an
whether the firm goes bankrupt. If it does, optimal security structure, then
the first claim is senior, but if it does not the
second claim may be senior because it is [l-\]M)/dA>0
paid off first. In other words, the notion
at A - I. Carrying out the differentiation,
of seniority that we have analyzed must
be enlarged to encompass seniority in an
intertemporal sense.
(Al) M{P)\K{P,N{P))
^ p
Finally, our analysis has completely ig-
nored the role of shareholder voting and xf(P,N{P))dP
takeovers in a firm's choice of financial
structure. Yet voting and takeovers are im-
portant restraining forces on management. where, by Condition F, the joint density
In future work it is desirable to develop a fiP, NiP)) > 0 for P<P <P.
framework which permits a study of the Let P* = \nf[P\P <P<P; KiP, NiP)) >
interplay between debt and the market for 0). Condition K implies that Ki P, M P)) < 0
corporate control as constraints on manage- for all P<P<P*, and KiP.NiP))>0 (or
rial behavior. all P*<P<P.
Suppose NiP) is not a simple debt/
APPENDIX equity security structure in the relevant do-
main (i.e., P < P < P). Then construct a
In this Appendix, we prove Proposition 3 security structure M comprising simple debt
and the Key Lemma. ^2 and equity, where

PROOF OF PROPOSITION 3:

Part (i) follows immediately from an in- [We know that this f^, ^ 0, since N satisfies
spection of program (6). (13).] That is, M(F*)^=MP*). In the light
If a small f > 0 is added to every realiza- of the fact that N satisfies (13) and (14),
tion of /, the left-hand side of (7) becomes MiP)<NiP) for all P < P < P\ and
MiP)>NiP) for all P* < P < P. Thus the
E[r - i - r - i- E = left-hand side of (Al) is at most zero.
Moreover, since N=AM,jhert must be
= - e -\- E[r - some open interval S^[P,P], not contain-
r ~i = ing P*, such that, for all P e S, both
(i) NiP)=^MiP), and (ii) N{P*)- NiP)¥=
<£[r-/|y, + - / = (/,] - 0 P* ~ P. From Condition K, (ii) implies
Ki P. NiP))^ () for all Pes. But this means
by the right-hand inequality in Condition C that the left-hand side of (Al) is in fact
and by (7). Hence, from the left-hand in- strictly negative, a contradiction. Hence a
equality in Condition C, it follows that the simple debt/equity security structure is
new debt level strictly exceeds d2. An iden- optimal.
584 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW JUNE 1995

REFERENCES of Capital Structure." Journal of Finance,


March 1991, 46(1), pp. 297-355.
Aghion, Philippe and Bolton, Patrick. "An In- _. "Financial Contracting Theory," in
complete Contracts Approach to Finan- J. J. Laffont, ed.. Advances in economic
cial Contracting." Review of Economic theory: Sixth World Congress, Vol. II.
Studies, July 1992, 59(3), pp. 473-94. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
Aghion, Philippe; Hart, Oliver and Moore, John. 1992, pp. 64-150.
"The Economics of Bankruptcy Reform." Hart, Oliver. "Theories of Optimal Capital
Journal of Law, Economics and Organiza- Structure: A Managerial Discretion Per-
tion, October 1992, 5(3), pp. 523-46. spective," in Margaret Blair, ed.. The deal
Allen, Franklin and Gale, Douglas. "Optimal decade: What takeovers and leveraged buy-
Security Design." Review of Financial outs mean for corporate governance.
Studies, Fall 1988, 7(3), pp. 229-63. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution,
Baumol, William. Business behavior and 1993, pp. 19-53.
growth. New York: Macmillan, 1959. Hart, Oliver and Moore, John. "Default and
Berkovitch, Elazar and Kim, E. Han. "Finan- Renegotiation: A Dynamic Model of
cial Contracting and Leverage Induced Debt." Discussion paper, University of
Over- and Under-Investment Ineentives." Edinburgh, August 1989.
Journal of Finance, July 1990, 45i'i), . "A Theory of Corporate Financial
pp. 765-94. Structure Based on the Seniority of
Brealey, Richard and Myers, Stevvart. Principles Claims." Department of Economies
of corporate finance, 3rd Ed. New York: Working Paper No. 560, Massachusetts
McGraw Hill, 1988. Institute of Technology, 1990.
Donaldson, Gordon. Managing corporate . "A Theory of Debt Based on the
wealth. New York: Praeger, 1984. Inalienability of Human Capital." Quar-
Dybvig, Philip and Zender, Jaime. "Capital terly Journal of Economics, November
Structure and Dividend Irrelevance with 1994, 7O9(41X pp. 841-80.
Asymmetric Information." Review of Fi- Jensen, Michael. "Agency Costs of Free Cash
nancial Studies, 1991, 4i\), pp. 201-19. Flow, Corporate Finance, and Take-
Gertner, Rohert and Scharfstein, David. "A overs." American Economic Review, May
Theory of Workouts and the Effects of 1986 (Papers and Proceedings), 76(2), pp.
Reorganization Law." Journal of Finance, 323-29.
September 1991, 46(4), pp. 1189-1222. Jensen, Michael and Meckling, William. "The-
Gilson, Stuart. "Managing Default; Some Ev- ory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior,
idence on How Firms Choose Between Agency Costs and Ownership Structure."
Workouts and Chapter I L " Journal of Journal of Financial Economics, October
Applied Corporate Finance, Summer 1991, 1976, -5(4), pp. 305-60.
4i2\ pp. 62-70. Kester, Carl. "Capital and Ownership Struc-
Gilson, Stuart; John, Kose and Lang, Larry. ture: A Comparison of United States and
"Troubled Debt Restructurings: An Em- Japanese Manufacturing Corporations."
pirical Study of Private Reorganization of Financial Management, Spring 1986, 75(1),
Firms in Default." Journal of Financial pp. 5-16.
Economics, October 1990, 26(2), pp. Lehn, Kenneth and Poulsen, Annette. "Con-
315-53. tractual Resolution of Bondholder-
Grossman, Sanford and Hart, Oliver. "Corpo- Shareholder Conflicts in Leveraged Buy-
rate Financial Structure and Managerial outs." Journal of Law and Economics,
Incentives," in J. J. McCall, ed.. The eco- October 1991, 34(2), pp. 645-74.
nomics of information and uncertainty. Leiand, Hayne and Pyle, David. "Informational
Chicago: University of Chicago Press, Asymmetries, Financial Structure, and Fi-
1982, pp. 107-40. nancial Intermediation." Journal of Fi-
Harris, Milton and Raviv, Artur. "The Theory nance, May 1977, 32(2), pp. 371-87.
. 85 NO. 3 HART AND MOORE: DEBT AND SENIORITY 585

Li, Shan. "Essays on Corporate Governance vestors Do Not Have." Journal of Finan-
and Finance." Ph.D. dissertation, Mas- cial Economics, June 1984, 13(2), pp.
sachusetts Institute of Technology, 1993. 1S7-221.
Marris, Robin. The economic theory of man- Ross, Stephen. "The Determination of Finan-
agerial capitalism. New York: Free Press cial Structure: The Incentive Signalling
of Glencoe, 1964. Approach." Bell Journal of Economics,
Milgrom, Paul and Weber, Robert. "A Theory Spring 1977, 5(1), pp. 23-40.
of Auctions and Competitive Bidding." Smith, Clifford and Warner, Jerold. "On Fi-
Econometrica, September 1982, 50(5), nancial Contracting: An Analysis of Bond
pp. 1089-1112. Covenants." Journal of Financial Eco-
Miller, Merton. *'Debt and Taxes." Journal of nomics, June 1979, 7(2), pp. 117-61.
Finance, May 1977, 32(2), pp. 261-75. Stiglitz, Joseph. "On the Irrelevance of Cor-
Modigliani, Franco and Miller, Merton. ''Cor- porate Financial Policy." American Eco-
porate Income Taxes and the Cost of nomic Review, December 1974, 64(6),
Capital: A Correction." American Eco- pp. 851-66.
nomic Review, June 1963, 53(3), pp. Stulz, Rene. "Managerial Discretion and Op-
433-43. timal Financing Policies." Journal of Fi-
Myers, Stewart. "Determinants of Corporate nancial Economics, July 1990, 26(1),
Borrowing." Journal of Financial Eco- pp. 3-27.
nomics, November 1977, 5(2), pp. 147-75. Williamson, Oliver. The economics of discre-
. "Still Searching for Optimal Capi- tionary behavior Managerial objectives in
tal Structure," in R. Kopcke and E. a theory of the firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ:
Rosengren, eds.. Are the distinctions be- Prentice Hall, 1964.
tween debt and equity disappearing? Fed- Xie, Cuozbong. "Essays on the Theory of the
eral Reserve Bank of Boston Conference Firm." Ph.D. dissertation, Massachusetts
Series No. 33, Boston, MA: Federal Re- Institute of Technology, 1990.
serve Bank of Boston, 1990, pp. 80-95. Zweibel, Jeffrey H. "A Control Theory of
Myers, Stewart and M^luf, Nicholas. "Corpo- Dynamic Capital Structure." Mimeo,
rate Financing and Investment Decisions Stanford University Graduate School of
When Firms Have Information That In- Business, 1993.

You might also like