You are on page 1of 3

PERSPE C T I V E Contraceptive Drugs may cause political headaches

public space: whether every reli- Disclosure forms provided by the author sionalism and conscience. Washington, DC:
are available with the full text of this arti- American Constitution Society for Law and
gious institution and adherent is cle at NEJM.org. Policy, 2007 (http://www.acslaw.org/sites/
free to act to the point of impos- default/files/Charo_-_Health_Care_Refusals
ing on others, or whether every From the School of Law and the School of
.pdf).
3. Bolstad E. Florida’s Rubio pushes back at
individual is free from being im- Medicine and Public Health, University of
contraception rules under health care law.
posed upon to the point of sti- Wisconsin, Madison.
McClatchy Newspapers Washington Bureau.
fling some who would act. This February 5, 2012.
This article (10.1056/NEJMp1202701) was 4. Uttley L, Pawelko R. No strings attached:
debate deserves more than parti- published on March 14, 2012, at NEJM.org. public funding of religiously-sponsored hos-
san sound bites and slogans. Per- pitals in the United States. MergerWatch
haps Friess wasn’t too far off, 1. Equal Employment Opportunity Commis-
Project, 2002 (http://www.mergerwatch.org/
mergerwatch-publications).
and the best cure for today’s con- sion. Decision on contraception (http://www
5. Abelson R. Catholic hospitals expand, re-
traceptive headache is for the en- .eeoc.gov/policy/docs/decision-contraception
ligious strings attached. New York Times.
.html).
tire country to take two aspirin 2. Charo RA. Health care provider refusals
February 20, 2012:A1.
and lay off until after the election. to treat, prescribe, refer or inform: profes-
Copyright © 2012 Massachusetts Medical Society.

Medicare’s Readmissions-Reduction Program —


A Positive Alternative
Robert A. Berenson, M.D., Ronald A. Paulus, M.D., M.B.A., and Noah S. Kalman, B.A.

H ospital readmissions are re-


ceiving increasing attention
as a largely correctable source of
30-day readmission rate did not
change appreciably between 2004
and 2009. Unless they are at full
for patients with myocardial in-
farction, pneumonia, or heart fail-
ure using claims data. If a hospi-
poor quality of care and exces- capacity, hospitals have no eco- tal’s risk-adjusted readmission rate
sive spending. According to a 2009 nomic incentive to reduce readmis- for such patients exceeds that av-
study, nearly 20% of Medicare sions under Medicare’s di­ag­nosis- erage, CMS penalizes it in the
beneficiaries are rehospitalized related group (DRG) payment following year for all Medicare
within 30 days after discharge, approach. The Affordable Care admissions in proportion to its
at an annual cost of $17 billion.1 Act (ACA) therefore created a fi- rate of excess rehospitalizations
Causes of avoidable readmissions nancial penalty for “excessive” of patients for the target condi-
include hospital-acquired infec- readmissions at hospitals that tions. Although the maximum
tions and other complications; are paid for DRGs. Unfortunately, penalty is set at 1% for 2013,
premature discharge; failure to this approach may be too weak eventually reaching 3% of a hos-
coordinate and reconcile medica- to overcome the substantial coun- pital’s Medicare payments, the
tions; inadequate communication terincentives inherent in DRG- CMS implementation reduces the
among hospital personnel, pa- based payments It also tries to potential penalties in aggregate
tients, caregivers, and community- change hospitals’ behavior with to only 0.2% of national Medicare
based clinicians; and poor plan- a stick but no carrot, failing to payments in 2013.3 Payments for
ning for care transitions. reward hospitals that improve. hospitals with below-average re-
Although studies have shown We propose an alternative ap- hospitalization rates for all three
that specific interventions, par- proach — a “warranty” payment conditions won’t change. Eventu-
ticularly among patients with — that provides a stronger busi- ally, CMS plans to expand this
multiple medical conditions, can ness case for hospitals to get program to include other com-
reduce readmission rates by 25 to with the program. mon diagnoses for which read-
50%,2 the Centers for Medicare Under the ACA, CMS calcu- missions are theoretically pre-
and Medicaid Services (CMS) lates the average risk-adjusted, ventable, boosting the financial
found that Medicare’s national 30-day hospital-readmission rates effects.

1364 n engl j med 366;15 nejm.org april 12, 2012

The New England Journal of Medicine


Downloaded from nejm.org at CALIF INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY on August 10, 2015. For personal use only. No other uses without permission.
Copyright © 2012 Massachusetts Medical Society. All rights reserved.
PERSPECTIVE Medicare’s Readmissions-Reduction Program

The CMS readmissions-penalty desirable outcomes for patients related services for 90 days, in-
policy has drawn the attention of and payers, they detrimentally cluding any rehospitalizations —
hospitals and stimulated similar affect hospitals’ finances. in essence, a warranty. In adapt-
approaches among other payers, If a penalty is more than off- ing this approach to focus on
with readmission rates emerging set by program costs and lost readmissions, Medicare could
as a quality marker in public re- rehospitalization revenue, hospi- eliminate or reduce payment (per-
porting programs. Nevertheless, tals would be better off finan- haps to the variable cost for the
for most hospitals, the financial cially if they maintained the sta- admission) for many or perhaps
case for aggressively reducing re- tus quo. Reductions of as much all readmissions within a desig-
hospitalizations may remain elu- as 10% in admissions from any nated interval after discharge —
sive, especially given declining cause could result if hospitals say, 15 or 30 days — thereby re-
utilization related to the eco- aggressively tried to reduce re- moving entirely the perverse
nomic downturn, advances in admissions, given the success of incentives associated with pay-
ambulatory care, and growing programs offering limited finan- ments for avoidable readmissions.
pressure on reimbursement rates. cial incentives.4 Regardless, fail- In essence, hospitals could re-
Hospitals with lower-than-average ing to provide a positive econom- ceive an increase in their base
readmission rates for all three ic incentive for hospitals with payment for each index admis-
targeted conditions will face no readmissions rates near or below sion, although somewhat less
financial penalty; for them, the the national average means miss- than projected payments for their
implementation of readmissions- ing an opportunity to increase the readmissions — perhaps 90 or
reduction programs would only benefit to patients and to Medi- 95% of that estimate. Medicare
increase costs and decrease reve- care. At best, under the ACA would thus be guaranteed im-
nues. Furthermore, because the ­readmissions provision, the busi- mediate savings (5 or 10%, in this
benchmark readmission rate is ness case for mounting a multi- example) and have the opportu-
initially based on only three con-
ditions, which account for just
12% of all Medicare admissions, Unless they are at maximum capacity,
hospitals that implement transi-
tion programs and improve care hospitals face two major economic disincentives
for patients with other conditions
will see only net increases in to reducing readmissions for the specified
costs and reductions in revenues.
Unless they are at maximum diagnoses: the direct costs of the program itself
capacity, hospitals face two ma- and decreased revenues resulting from
jor economic disincentives to re-
ducing readmissions for the spec- successful interventions.
ified diagnoses: the direct costs
of the program itself and de-
creased revenues resulting from pronged readmissions-reduction nity to garner additional savings
successful interventions. Interven- program is a close call; at worst, over time as it gradually reduced
tions to create and sustain re- it’s overtly negative in Medicare’s the percentage of projected re-
ductions in readmissions typi- volume-based payment system. admission payments loaded into
cally average $100 to $200 per There is a simple alternative hospitals’ base payments. As hos-
discharge2 and often have spill- approach. Geisinger Health Sys- pitals reduced readmissions, Medi-
over effects, decreasing hospital- tem’s ProvenCare program creat- care could reduce payment bench-
izations for nontargeted diagno- ed a single-episode price for all marks in accordance with lower
ses and reducing readmissions services associated with a surgi- projected readmission rates —
from any cause even outside the cal procedure, such as coronary- and probably a lower index-admis-
30-day window and across pay- artery bypass grafting, including sion rate, thanks to the spillover
ers. Although these effects are the initial hospitalization and all effect described above. All hospi-

n engl j med 366;15 nejm.org april 12, 2012 1365


The New England Journal of Medicine
Downloaded from nejm.org at CALIF INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY on August 10, 2015. For personal use only. No other uses without permission.
Copyright © 2012 Massachusetts Medical Society. All rights reserved.
PERSPE C T I V E Medicare’s Readmissions-Reduction Program

tals would then have a direct in- readmissions within a specified Disclosure forms provided by the authors
are available with the full text of this article
centive to invest in reducing re- period. at NEJM.org.
admissions, and Medicare would We acknowledge that this ap-
benefit from immediate savings proach has the perverse effect of From the Urban Institute, Washington, DC
(R.A.B.); and Mission Health System, Ashe-
and progressively lower rates. further rewarding all admissions ville (R.A.P.), and the Fuqua School of Busi-
Our approach would measure other than readmissions that fall ness, Duke University, Durham (N.S.K.) —
a hospital’s readmissions perfor- within the 15- or 30-day window; both in North Carolina.
mance against its own historical a recent study showed a strong This article (10.1056/NEJMp1201268) was
record and population, avoiding association between rehospitaliza- published on March 28, 2012, at NEJM.org.
the need for complex risk adjust- tion rates and overall admission
1. Jencks SF, Williams MV, Coleman EA. Re-
ment or adjustments for readmis- rates.5 Only fundamentally dif- hospitalizations among patients in the Medi-
sions to nonindex hospitals, since ferent payment methods, such care fee-for-service program. N Engl J Med
they would already be included as population-based, global pay- 2009;360:1418-28. [Erratum, N Engl J Med
2011;364:1582.]
in each hospital’s baseline rate. ments, would avoid the volume- 2. Chollet D, Barrett A, Lake T. Reducing
Medicare would provide extra pay- generating incentives of episode- hospital readmissions in New York State:
ment in accordance with a hos- based approaches. We doubt that a simulation analysis of alternative payment
incentives. Princeton, NJ: Mathematica Policy
pital’s historical (perhaps 3-year the marginally higher payment Research, September 2011.
rolling average) readmission rate, rates would substantially alter the 3. Medicare Payment Advisory Commission.
for either all cases or a large already strong incentive for hospi- Public meeting. December 15, 2011 (http://
www.medpac.gov/transcripts/1215162011
subgroup of diagnoses in which tals to fill beds. Increasing pen- .pdf).
readmissions are potentially avoid- alties for readmissions, but not 4. Hansen LO, Young RS, Hinami K, Leung A,
able. Britain, Germany, and Mary- all admissions, provides a clearer Williams MV. Interventions to reduce 30-day
rehospitalizations: a systematic review. Ann
land, which runs its own all-payer incentive for hospitals to pursue Intern Med 2011;155:520-8.
hospital rate-setting program, readmissions-reduction programs 5. Epstein AM, Jha AK, Orav EJ. The relation-
have all adapted the DRG pay- and enhance quality and efficien- ship between hospital admission rates and
rehospitalizations. N Engl J Med 2011;365:
ment approach in this way, so cy, while more fundamental pay- 2287-95.
they pay nothing for many or all ment reform is being explored. Copyright © 2012 Massachusetts Medical Society.

Thirty-Day Readmissions — Truth and Consequences


Karen E. Joynt, M.D., M.P.H., and Ashish K. Jha, M.D., M.P.H.

R educing hospital readmission


rates has captured the imag-
ination of U.S. policymakers be-
Medicaid Services (CMS) to penal-
ize hospitals with “worse than
expected” 30-day readmission
First, the metric itself is problem-
atic: only a small proportion of
readmissions at 30 days after ini-
cause readmissions are common rates. This part of the law has tial discharge are probably pre-
and costly and their rates vary — stimulated hospitals, professional ventable, and much of what drives
and at least in theory, a reason- societies, and independent orga- hospital readmission rates are
able fraction of readmissions nizations to invest substantial re- patient- and community-level fac-
should be preventable. Policymak- sources in finding and implement- tors that are well outside the hos-
ers therefore believe that reduc- ing solutions for the “readmissions pital’s control. Furthermore, it is
ing readmission rates represents problem.” unclear whether readmissions al-
a unique opportunity to simulta- Although a focus on readmis- ways reflect poor quality: high re-
neously improve care and reduce sions may have good face validi- admission rates can be the result
costs. As part of the Affordable ty, we believe that policymakers’ of low mortality rates or good
Care Act (ACA), Congress direct- emphasis on 30-day readmissions access to hospital care. Second,
ed the Centers for Medicare and is misguided, for three reasons. although improving discharge

1366 n engl j med 366;15 nejm.org april 12, 2012

The New England Journal of Medicine


Downloaded from nejm.org at CALIF INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY on August 10, 2015. For personal use only. No other uses without permission.
Copyright © 2012 Massachusetts Medical Society. All rights reserved.

You might also like