You are on page 1of 17

Vol. 23, No. 1, January 2014, pp. 19–35 DOI 10.1111/poms.

12030
ISSN 1059-1478|EISSN 1937-5956|14|2301|0019 © 2013 Production and Operations Management Society

Vertical Integration under Competition: Forward,


Backward, or No Integration?
Yen-Ting Lin
School of Business Administration, The University of San Diego, San Diego, California 92110, linyt@sandiego.edu

Ali K. Parlakt€
urk, Jayashankar M. Swaminathan
Kenan-Flagler Business School, The University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, Chapel Hill, North Carolina 27599,
pturk@unc.edu, msj@unc.edu

e consider two competing supply chains, each consisting of supplier, a manufacturer, and a retailer. The suppliers
W exert effort to improve product quality, and the retailers sell products competitively. Each manufacturer chooses
one of the three strategies: forward integration, backward integration, or no vertical integration. We seek for a subgame
perfect Nash equilibrium and study the resulting market structure. Moreover, we characterize the effect of vertical inte-
gration on profitability, product price, and quality in a competitive setting. Existing literature has shown that, when man-
ufacturers consider only forward integration, they may choose not to vertically integrate in equilibrium. In contrast, we
find that, when both forward and backward integration options are considered, disintegration cannot be an equilibrium
outcome. In this case, both manufacturers either forward or backward integrate, and the degree of product perishability,
cost of quality, and how much consumers value quality are critical for the chosen direction of integration. Furthermore,
competition increases attractiveness of backward integration relative to forward integration. We show that, while integrat-
ing backward unilaterally is always beneficial, unilateral forward integration can harm a manufacturer’s profitability.
Finally, vertical integration can result in a better quality product sold at a lower price.
Key words: vertical integration; competition; supply chain; quality; pricing
History: Received: December 2011; Accepted: November 2012 by Eric Johnson, after 2 revisions.

control over the distribution of its growing product


1. Introduction offerings (Collier 2009). Conversely, backward inte-
Many manufacturers pursue vertical integration to gration stretches a manufacturer’s operations toward
gain competitive edge. Examples of vertical conglom- the source of raw materials, strengthening its control
erates who govern the entire supply chain are, how- on the supply side. For instance, steelmaker Arcelor-
ever, less common. In practice, diversity in the Mittal is moving deeper into the mining business to
direction of vertical integration occurs instead: some ensure stable material supply (Worthen et al. 2009);
manufacturers choose to forward integrate retail oper- likewise, the Chinese apparel manufacturer Esquel
ations, while others opt to backward integrate supply backward integrates supply functions by engaging in
activities. This observation immediately leads to an cotton farming (Peleg-Gillai 2007).
important question: When should a manufacturer What is driving manufacturers to vertically inte-
choose to forward integrate, backward integrate, or grate? Obviously, vertical integration eliminates the
stay disintegrated? Furthermore, how do supply adverse effect of double marginalization. However,
chain competition and other market and operational forward and backward integrations provide some
factors affect this decision? These questions motivate additional benefits. Forward integration allows a
this paper. manufacturer to better control its retail price, enabling
Forward integration extends a manufacturer’s oper- it to respond to changes in demand more effectively.
ational reach to product retailing, tightening its grip The value of this benefit increases with the degree of
on the demand side. For example, European fashion product perishability, the rate at which product popu-
giant Zara and Los Angeles-based apparel retailer larity changes over time. Such a benefit of forward
American Apparel manufacture products and sell integration is quite significant for a fashion apparel
them through their own retail channels. Tainan Enter- manufacturer, for example, as it deals with quickly
prise, a Taiwan-based manufacturer, established its changing consumer trends. On the other hand, back-
own brand, Tony Wear, in China in the late 1990s (Ho ward integration allows a manufacturer to seize a
2002). Similarly, Pepsi purchased its bottlers for better stronger control over its quality of material supply
19
urk, and Swaminathan: Vertical Integration under Competition
Lin, Parlakt€
20 Production and Operations Management 23(1), pp. 19–35, © 2013 Production and Operations Management Society

and, thereby, its quality of final products. This occurs In equilibrium, both manufacturers choose to verti-
because quality of raw materials is one of the impor- cally integrate in the same direction. The chosen
tant determinants of a final product’s quality. For direction depends on how benefits of more closely
instance, the quality of fabrics used in its production managing demand and supply side compare to each
determines the texture quality of apparel. other. When demand (supply) side dynamics domi-
Forward and backward integrations benefit firms in nate, manufacturers choose forward (backward) inte-
different ways, and each of these benefits is well gration. On the one hand, when the product is highly
understood in isolation. But we want to understand perishable, which implies a significantly lower second
when the benefits of forward integration dominate period demand, controlling retail price becomes more
those of backward integration, and vice versa. How important. This in turn makes forward integration
these benefits interact with competitive dynamics in a more attractive. On the other hand, when return from
supply chain is also not clear. These issues lead to a a quality investment is low due to either high cost of
number of research questions. When do firms benefit improving quality or low consumer sensitivity, an
from vertical integration in a competitive market? independent supplier would underinvest in quality
How does the choice between forward and backward too much. Therefore, backward integration, which
integration depend on the competitor’s supply chain allows directly controlling quality, becomes more
structure? What is the resulting equilibrium supply attractive.
chain structure when firms competitively choose their We find that the equilibrium exhibits a prisoner’s
integration strategies? Furthermore, how do product dilemma: both manufacturers choose to vertically
perishability, consumer sensitivity to quality (market integrate (either backward or forward) in equilibrium,
factors), and cost of quality (an operational factor) and they both suffer. Furthermore, competition
affect answers to these questions? increases the attractiveness of backward integration
To address these questions, we consider a model of relative to forward integration. Specifically, for the
two competing supply chains, each consisting of a same demand and cost parameters, a manufacturer is
supplier, a manufacturer, and a retailer. The supplier more likely to choose backward integration in duop-
can exert effort to improve the quality of material it oly than in monopoly.
supplies to the manufacturer. The manufacturer then Moving from disintegration to backward integra-
makes the product and sells it through its retailer tion always benefits a manufacturer regardless of its
exclusively. The product is sold in two periods, and competitor’s integration strategy. In contrast, integrat-
its popularity, and thereby the size of its potential ing forward unilaterally can hurt a manufacturer
market, decreases over time. Endogenizing quality because it intensifies the retail competition, which in
investment and product perishability in our demand turn drops the retail price and hurts the manufac-
model allows us to capture the benefits of vertical turer’s margin. Such a drop is less severe when the
integration besides eliminating double marginaliza- competing supply chain has fewer intermediaries.
tion. Each manufacturer in our model chooses one of Therefore, when its competitor vertically integrates, a
the three strategies: (i) forward integration, (ii) back- manufacturer becomes more likely to choose forward
ward integration, and (iii) no integration. We seek a over backward integration.
Subgame Perfect Nash Equilibrium (SPNE) in this Controlling the retail end of the supply chain can
model. enable improving brand perception. This improve-
We find that not to vertically integrate at all cannot ment may increase consumer willingness to pay in
be an equilibrium outcome when manufacturers com- some settings. Thus, we also study what happens
petitively choose their integration strategies. This when forward integration results in pricing advan-
result is in sharp contrast to the celebrated result of tage by reducing consumer price sensitivity. In this
McGuire and Staelin (1983), in which disintegration, case, a forward-integrated manufacturer can make
that is, not to vertically integrate at all, can be an equi- even the backward integration option unprofitable for
librium outcome. The key difference in our model that the competing manufacturer.
leads to this contrast is that we consider a three-tier Finally, we show that vertical integration (either
supply chain; the manufacturer can choose to either forward or backward) results in a higher quality
forward or backward integrate in our model, whereas product sold at a lower retail price. Vertical integra-
prior studies allow only forward integration in a two- tion lowers the retail price of a product because it
tier supply chain. In other words, we show that the reduces the number of intermediaries profiting from
result of prior studies (e.g., Gupta and Loulou 1998, it. This benefit alleviates double marginalization and
McGuire and Staelin 1983, Trivedi 1998) is incom- encourages more investment in quality improvement.
plete: not to vertically integrate at all can be an equi- In the remainder of this article, section 2 presents
librium strategy only when a backward integration our literature review. Section 3 describes our model.
option is not available. Section 4 characterizes the equilibrium decisions and
urk, and Swaminathan: Vertical Integration under Competition
Lin, Parlakt€
Production and Operations Management 23(1), pp. 19–35, © 2013 Production and Operations Management Society 21

discusses the value of vertical integration. Section 5 less likely to drop when the merger occurs in down-
presents extensions to the base model. Finally, section stream rather than upstream of a supply chain. Pun
6 offers our concluding remarks. and Heese (2010) consider two competing manufac-
turers who sell two complementary products through
retailers, and they find that manufacturers can benefit
2. Related Literature from staying disintegrated, as this mitigates their
A number of papers in Operations Management and competition. Boyaci and Gallego (2004) consider two
Marketing literature study the structure of competing supply chains who compete on fill-rate assuming an
supply chains. In their seminal work, McGuire and exogenously determined retail price. In contrast firms
Staelin (1983) consider two competing supply chains, compete on price and quality in our model. They
and they show that staying disintegrated can be an identify a prisoner’s dilemma: both supply chains
equilibrium for manufacturers. A number of papers prefer having coordination among its manufacturer
have extended this result, confirming that vertically and retailer even though both achieve a lower profit.
integrating with a downstream retailer may not be the There is a stream of papers addressing when a firm
profit-maximizing strategy for a manufacturer under should outsource production or keep it in-house,
various settings. For example, Moorthy (1988) finds which is essentially a form of backward integration.
that manufacturers may not vertically integrate even Cachon and Harker (2002) and Gilbert et al. (2006)
when competing products are complements. Cough- show that competing firms may benefit from out-
lan (1985) extends the linear demand model of sourcing production to a common supplier as this
McGuire and Staelin (1983) to a more general demand dampens the price competition. In our model, each
model. Trivedi (1998) allows retailers to carry prod- manufacturer has a distinct supplier instead of a com-
ucts of multiple competing manufacturers. In Gupta mon one. Van Mieghem (1999) and Kostamis and
and Loulou (1998), manufacturers can invest in Duenyas (2009) allow firms to continue producing
research and development to reduce unit production in-house while outsourcing a part of their production.
cost. In Gupta (2008), a manufacturer’s cost reduction Our paper differs from the aforementioned papers
investment also helps its competitor reduce its cost in three critical aspects. First, while we study a three-
due to involuntary technology spillovers. In Liu and tier supply chain, they all consider vertical integration
Tyagi (2011), retailers determine their competitive in two-tier supply chains, and therefore they cannot
product position on a Hotelling line. Wu et al. (2007) address the choice between forward and backward
allow for demand uncertainty. They show that integration. Second, our paper differs in that the prod-
whether demand variability affects the equilibrium uct quality is endogenously determined. Finally, there
supply chain structure depends on the form of the are two periods which allow capturing the product
demand probability distribution function: when it perishability. These elements enable us to capture
takes a certain form, higher variability favors vertical quality and pricing benefits of vertical integration,
integration. and they are critical to our research questions and
All of these papers show that McGuire and Staelin’s their results; dropping any of them leads to trivial
(1983) disintegration result continues to hold in vari- outcomes.
ous scenarios; in contrast we show that the disintegra- Another relevant line of papers studies the channel
tion result does not hold in our model. The key conflict that arises when a manufacturer competes
difference that leads to this contrast is that these with its retailer by directly selling to consumers,
papers, including McGuire and Staelin (1983), con- which is a form of forward integration. These papers
sider two-tier supply chains and they allow only for- explicitly model the consumer choice between chan-
ward integration, whereas our model considers a nels. They consider attributes like product availabil-
three-tier supply chain allowing both forward and ity, delivery lead time, and relative inconvenience of
backward integrations. each channel (Chen et al. 2008) and consumer cost for
Corbett and Karmarkar (2001) show that when two searching online or traveling (Cattani et al. 2006, Guo
competing supply chains both adopt vertical integra- and Liu 2008) in addition to prices. In these papers,
tion, they both suffer a drop in their profitability. the manufacturer decides whether to add a direct
However, Corbett and Karmarkar (2001) do not study channel to compete with its independent retailer; the
whether firms would choose vertical integration in structures of the channels, however, are fixed. In con-
equilibrium; in contrast, we study the vertical integra- trast, in our paper, there are already two competing
tion strategies manufacturers choose in equilibrium. channels, and each one determines its structure by
Cho (2011) extends Corbett and Karmarkar (2001) by deciding whether to integrate vertically. Furthermore,
studying horizontal merger among firms within the these papers study competition within the supply
same tier of a supply chain, whereas we focus on ver- chain of the same product produced by the same
tical integration. Cho (2011) finds that retail price is manufacturer, that is, competing products are
urk, and Swaminathan: Vertical Integration under Competition
Lin, Parlakt€
22 Production and Operations Management 23(1), pp. 19–35, © 2013 Production and Operations Management Society

identical. In contrast, competing supply chains inde- Table 1 Parameters and Decision Variables
pendently determine the quality of their products in Symbol Definition
our model.
t Time period
Our work also relates to papers that study joint k Size of consumer population in the second period
quality and pricing decisions in a vertically disinte- m Consumer reservation value
grated supply chain. Kaya and Ozer € (2009) find that a Consumer quality sensitivity
vertical disintegration by outsourcing production to a d Consumer disutility per unit deviation from the ideal product
contract manufacturer whereby the contract manufac- wi;t Distance between product i and a consumer’s ideal product
in period t
turer decides product quality results in a lower qual- hi Quality of product i
ity product similar to our results. However, they find ri Raw material price charged by supplier i
that vertical disintegration results in a lower price wi Wholesale price charged by manufacturer i
contrary to our findings. This contrast is due to a pi;t Retail price of product i in period t

difference in the sequence of events. In Kaya and Ozer Qi;t Sales quantity of product i in period t
c Cost coefficient for quality improvement
(2009), the downstream firm dictates the wholesale N,F,B No integration, forward integration, and backward integration
price by offering a two-part tariff contract before the respectively
upstream firm chooses the product quality, whereas Ii Manufacturer i’s vertical integration strategy
cd
in our paper the upstream firm dictates the wholesale c a2
price after choosing product quality, which leads to a
higher wholesale price. Thus, in Kaya and Ozer €
(2009), the downstream firm can affect the upstream
Following Salop’s (1979) spatial differentiation
firm’s quality choice through its contract terms, and
model, we assume consumers are utility maximizers
not knowing the upstream firm’s cost or inability to
and they are uniformly distributed along a circle at 12
contract on quality hurts the efficiency of its contract.
units of density in each period.1 Each consumer is
In contrast, in our model the downstream firm can
identified by a point on the circle which represents
affect the product quality only by vertically integrat-
her ideal product. The two competing products are
ing with the upstream firm. Furthermore, when con-
located at the two ends of the diameter.2 Each cus-
sidering vertical integration, firms need to take into
tomer stays in the market only for one period, and a
account the competitor’s reaction. Our focus is on
new batch of customers arrives in the next period. If
quantifying the impact of competition on vertical inte-
buying a product yields nonnegative utility, the cus-
gration, whereas their focus is on quantifying the
tomer purchases one unit of the product that gives
effect of quality risk due to asymmetric quality cost
her the highest utility. Here
information and non-contractable quality in vertical
disintegration. Similarly, Gilbert and Cvsa (2003) and Uðhi ; pi;t ; wi;t Þ ¼ m þ ahi  pi;t  dwi;t ð1Þ
Xu (2009) also consider joint quality and pricing deci-
sions in a disintegrated supply chain, but they too do shows the utility from purchasing product i (i.e., the
not consider competition and their focus is different. product of supply chain i) in period t, where m
In Heese (2010), a retailer sells its own store-brand shows consumer reservation value, hi represents the
product in addition to the competing product of a quality of product i, and pi;t is the retail price of
national manufacturer, where both the retailer and product i in period t. Here, a captures consumer
manufacturer choose the quality of their products. sensitivity to product quality. We fix the consumer
Finally, vertical integration can eliminate double price sensitivity, that is, the coefficient to pi;t in
marginalization and achieve coordination, which is a Equation (1), to 1. However, we relax this assump-
very important issue for supply chains. There is quite tion and present additional insights in section 5.1.
a rich literature on this subject, and Cachon (2003) Finally, wi;t is the shortest distance between product
and Kaya and Ozer € (2012) provide excellent reviews i and the consumer’s ideal product as Figure 1b
of this literature. illustrates, and a consumer incurs disutility d > 0
per unit of distance.
The product popularity decreases over time. Spe-
3. Model cifically, the mass of potential customers, that is,
We consider two competing supply chains (i = 1,2) market size, in period 1 is normalized to 1, but it
selling products to a consumer market over two peri- shrinks to k < 1 in period 2. Thus, in t = 2, there are
ods (t = 1,2). In the following, we introduce our con- fewer consumers and they are distributed on a
sumer choice model, firm decisions and cost smaller circle, as seen in Figure 1a. In other words,
structure, and vertical integration choices. Table 1 differentiation between the products gets smaller in
summarizes the parameters and decision variables of period 2. This approach assumes that customers
our model. who buy a product in period 2 do not have strong
urk, and Swaminathan: Vertical Integration under Competition
Lin, Parlakt€
Production and Operations Management 23(1), pp. 19–35, © 2013 Production and Operations Management Society 23

Figure 1 Consumer Demand Model

(a) (b)

preferences between the products (relative to period (Peleg-Gillai 2007). Similarly, advances in spinning
1 customers), and the price becomes a relatively and knitting technologies improve the production
more important factor. process, allowing yarns to produce fabrics with supe-
Here, k measures the demand perishability: a smal- rior quality (Bainbridge 2009). In addition, to keep
ler k indicates a faster decrease in the product popu- our focus on the impact of vertical integration, we
larity over time; thus the demand perishability is assume firms do not incur variable costs for produc-
proportional to 1  k. The demand perishability plays tion and retailing, and they have sufficient capacity to
a critical role in the manufacturers’ forward integra- fulfill any demand.
tion decisions. Specifically, a smaller k corresponding As will be evident, the fact that quality is endo-
to highly perishable demand makes directly control- genously determined plays a critical role in the manu-
ling the price through forward integration more valu- facturers’ backward integration decisions in our
able, as it allows responding to changes in demand model. Backward integration enables a manufacturer
better.3 to better coordinate quality choice in its supply chain
Each supply chain i consists of a supplier ðSi Þ, a by directly controlling quality decision, but the manu-
manufacturer ðMi Þ, and a retailer ðRi Þ, and all firms facturer needs to absorb the quality investment cost.
are risk neutral profit maximizers. A supplier pro- In fact, Appendix B shows that when the quality
vides raw materials to its downstream manufacturer investment cost disappears, backward integration is
at a unit material price ri , which is determined by the always preferred. Furthermore, vertical (both forward
supplier. Supplier i invests in material quality, which and backward) integrations create an additional
in turn determines the product quality hi . Manufac- dynamic due to endogenous quality: reduction in
turer i produces each product i with one unit of raw double marginalization incentivizes further invest-
material and sells it to retailer i at its chosen unit ment in quality, and this in turn can lead to an addi-
wholesale price wi . Finally, retailer i determines the tional benefit from vertical integration.
retail price pi;t for product i, in each period t, and sells While a number of studies including ours treat
it in the consumer market. quality improvement as a fixed cost investment (e.g.,
The material price ri and wholesale price wi do not Bhaskaran and Krishnan 2009, Bonanno 1986, Demir-
change across periods because firms often sign rela- €
han et al. 2007, Kaya and Ozer 2009), there are others
tively long-term contracts with their suppliers; long- assuming quality improvement accompanies an
term contracts are common in B2B settings in many increase in marginal production cost. Both examples
industries such as textile, computer hardware, tele- are prevalent in practice, and our model considers a
communication, mining, and energy (AT&T 2012, setting in which quality is improved by a one-time
Hachman 2012, Saigol 2012).4 In contrast, we allow investment characterized by a fixed cost.
the retail price pi to be adjusted from period to period, As Figure 2 indicates, we envision three integration
reflecting the fact that a retailer has more flexibility in strategies for each manufacturer: no integration (N),
pricing. forward integration (F), and backward integration (B).
Supplier i incurs a fixed cost ch2i for achieving qual- When a manufacturer does not integrate, its material
ity level hi , where c determines how expensive it is to supply and product retail are accomplished through
improve quality. This assumes quality improvement other independent firms. In that case, the manufac-
is achieved through process improvement. Indeed, it turer has control only over the wholesale price it
is not uncommon to see quality improvement exam- charges to the retailer. When a manufacturer forward
ples as fixed cost investments in practice. For exam- integrates, it sells the product through its own com-
ple, Esquel, a major Chinese apparel manufacturer, pany stores and controls the retail price pi . Finally,
provides its cotton suppliers training in process when a manufacturer backward integrates, it per-
improvement techniques, such as seed selection and forms supply operations in-house and controls the
impurities elimination, to improve cotton quality quality level hi .
urk, and Swaminathan: Vertical Integration under Competition
Lin, Parlakt€
24 Production and Operations Management 23(1), pp. 19–35, © 2013 Production and Operations Management Society

Figure 2 Vertical Integration Choices

When a manufacturer is indifferent between the quality differentiation relatively less important com-
integration options, we break the tie in favor of no pared to the spatial differentiation.
integration over integration and forward over back- Furthermore, we make the following two paramet-
ward integration. This refinement does not affect our ric assumptions to keep our focus on the interesting
insights. We follow this convention for ease of exposi- scenarios and avoid trivial cases. These assumptions
tion; otherwise multiple equilibria exist at the bound- are only for ease of exposition; relaxing them, while
ary points of equilibrium regions. We use Ii 2 adding additional equilibrium regions, does not
fN; F; Bg to denote manufacturer i’s integration strat- change our insights.
egy, and I1 I2 to denote different scenarios of supply
A1. m [ dð3ð5þ4kÞ2  1þk
6c Þ; otherwise the market is
chain structures in the industry.
not covered, and firms do not compete, forming
Let Qi;t be the sales quantity of product i in period t.
local monopolies.
Then the profit functions for the retailer pNRi , manufac- A2. 9c4 ð11  1kÞ [ 1; otherwise in an asymmetric
turer pNMi , and supplier pN
Si in a disintegrated supply
competition, a disintegrated supply chain com-
chain i are
peting against a vertically integrated supply
X
2 chain cannot sell any products in period 2.
Ri ¼
pN ðpi;t  wi ÞQi;t ; ð2Þ
Assumption A2 avoids this trivial case by ensuring
t¼1
that the market size in period 2 is sufficiently large (i.e.,
X
2 large k) and the relative return from quality investment
Mi ¼ ðwi  ri Þ
pN Qi;t ; ð3Þ is not too high (i.e., large c) so the advantaged vertically
t¼1 integrated supply chain cannot drive its disadvantaged
competitor out of market in period 2.
X
2
The sequence of decisions is as follows: first, each
Si ¼ r i
pN Qi;t  ch2i : ð4Þ
t¼1 manufacturer chooses its vertical integration strategy,
which determines the supply chain structure I1 I2 of the
When manufacturer i forward integrates, it sets the industry. Then, firms who control the material supply
retail price itself. In this case, the profit function for (a supplier or a backward-integrated manufacturer)
manufacturer i becomes competitively determine their quality levels. These
firms then set the unit price they charge to their down-
X
2
pFMi ¼ ðpi;t  ri ÞQi;t : ð5Þ stream customers. Thereafter, a manufacturer sets its
t¼1 wholesale price if it does not vertically integrate.
Finally, the selling season begins, and firms that sell
On the other hand, backward integration allows products to consumers (a retailer or a forward-inte-
manufacturer i to dictate its quality level. This yields grated manufacturer) set their retail prices for each
the following profit function for manufacturer i: period and demand is realized. We seek a SPNE of this
game. When there are multiple equilibria, we eliminate
X
2
pBMi ¼ wi Qi;t  ch2i : ð6Þ the ones that are Pareto dominated by another equilib-
t¼1 rium in the sense of resulting in lower payoffs for all
parties. Specifically, there are multiple equilibria in
To facilitate our discussion, we define xþ ¼ only one scenario and it is explicitly stated in our dis-
maxðx; 0Þ and cussion of equilibrium results. This approach is for
cd ease of exposition and it does not affect our key find-
c¼ : ð7Þ ings.
a2
Our sequence of events is consistent with the notion
Essentially, c is a measure of relative return from that quality decisions are made before pricing deci-
quality investment, and a high c due to either high sions as they need more advanced planning (Banker
cost of quality c or low consumer sensitivity to quality et al. 1998, Chambers et al. 2006, Desai 2001, Xu 2009).
a indicates low return from a quality investment. Furthermore, it is common to assume that upstream
Likewise, a high d, which yields a high c, makes firms move before downstream firms in studying
urk, and Swaminathan: Vertical Integration under Competition
Lin, Parlakt€
Production and Operations Management 23(1), pp. 19–35, © 2013 Production and Operations Management Society 25

vertical integration and the structure of supply chains main model allows us to extract the impact of compe-
(Corbett and Karmarkar 2001, Gupta and Loulou tition. When the monopolist supply chain serves the
1998, McGuire and Staelin 1983, Wu et al. 2007). We entire market, vertical integration cannot increase its
follow this convention so our results can be con- demand (it has no impact on the quality and retail
trasted with these studies. price as well). Thus, we confine our monopoly bench-
mark to regions in which the manufacturer is not
limited by the market size in both periods, which is
4. Equilibrium and Vertical Integration ensured by m \ dkc ð4c  1Þ.5 Together with assump-
First, we describe how we derive the equilibrium. We tion A1, this means that the market is sufficiently big
then demonstrate the monopoly benchmark. Subse- for a single firm so there is potential for increasing
quently, we present price–quality equilibrium for two sales, but sufficiently small for two firms so they
competing supply chains for all possible supply chain compete.
structures I1 I2 . By comparing our results across differ-
ent supply chain structures, we quantify the value of
PROPOSITION 1. Consider a monopolist supply chain.
forward and backward integration, which also allows
characterizing the vertical integration equilibrium. (i) There exists a unique SPNE, and the equilibrium
Proofs for all of our analytical results are provided in decisions are described in Appendix A.
the online Appendix. (ii) The manufacturer and the entire supply chain
always achieve higher profits when the manufac-
4.1. Characterization of Equilibrium turer moves from disintegration (N) to forward (F)
When none of the manufacturers vertically integrate or backward (B) integration.
(NN), a SPNE satisfies the following for i = 1, 2 and
t = 1, 2: Vertical integration eliminates double-marginaliza-
tion. It can improve sales only when the market is not
X
2
already covered. In this case, it always increases prof-
hi ¼ arg max ri Qi;t ðh; p ðr ; hÞÞ  ch2i ; ð8Þ
hi itability of the manufacturer and the entire supply
t¼1
chain.
X
2 Now we return our focus to duopolist supply
ri ¼ arg max ri Qi;t ðh; p ðr; hÞÞ  ch2i ; ð9Þ chains. In this case, firms need to take both its compet-
ri
t¼1 itor’s and downstream partner’s actions into account
when making decisions.
X
2
wi ¼ arg maxðwi  ri Þ Qi;t ðh; p ðwÞÞ; ð10Þ
wi LEMMA 1. Consider two competing supply chains. There
t¼1
is a unique SPNE of price-quality competition in all sup-
X
2
ply chain scenarios I1 I2 , Ii 2 fN; F; Bg. Equilibrium
pi ¼ arg max ðpi;t  wi ÞQi;t ðh; pÞ: ð11Þ product quality hi , retail price pi;t , and total sales quan-
pi;1 ;pi;2
t¼1
tity Qi for each scenario are as follows.
Problems (8)–(11) formulate the optimization prob- (i) When none of the manufacturers vertically inte-
lems for the suppliers, manufacturers, and retailers. grates, NN,
Essentially, problems (8) and (9) state that each
supplier chooses the quality and material price to ð1 þ kÞa
h1 ¼ h2 ¼ ;
maximize its profit. Problem (10) indicates that each 6c
manufacturer sets the wholesale price to maximize its p1;1 ¼ p2;1 ¼ dð7 þ 6kÞ;
profit. Finally, Problem (11) states that each retailer
p1;2 ¼ p2;2 ¼ dð6 þ 7kÞ;
maximizes its profit by setting the retail price.
When manufacturer i vertically integrates, it no 1þk
Q1 ¼ Q2 ¼ :
longer solves problem (10), and a new problem arises: 2
when manufacturer i forward integrates, it sets retail
prices and solves problem (11) with wi replaced by ri . (ii) When only manufacturer 1 forward or backward
Alternatively, when manufacturer i backward inte- integrates, FN or BN,
grates, it determines its quality hi , solving problems
(8) and (9) with ri replaced by wi . We derive the equi- ð1 þ kÞð63c  2Þa
librium by applying backward induction, essentially h1 ¼ ;
12cð27c  1Þ
solving problems (8)–(11) in reverse order.
dð9cð55 þ 43kÞ  4ð4 þ 3kÞÞ
Let us first consider a monopolist supply chain as a p1;1 ¼ ;
benchmark; contrasting this benchmark with our 4ð27c  1Þ
urk, and Swaminathan: Vertical Integration under Competition
Lin, Parlakt€
26 Production and Operations Management 23(1), pp. 19–35, © 2013 Production and Operations Management Society

dð9cð43 þ 55kÞ  4ð3 þ 4kÞÞ Recall that vertical integration always benefits a
p1;2 ¼ ;
4ð27c  1Þ monopolist manufacturer (Proposition 1). In contrast,
ð1 þ kÞð63c  2Þ the next proposition shows that vertical integration
Q1 ¼ ; can actually harm profitability in a competitive
4ð27c  1Þ
setting.
ð1 þ kÞð45c  2Þa
h2 ¼ ;
12cð27c  1Þ
LEMMA 2.
dð18cð14 þ 11kÞ  ð11 þ 9kÞÞ
p2;1 ¼ ; (i.a) PFN
M1  PM1 if and only if k  d1 .
NN
2ð27c  1Þ
dð18cð11 þ 14kÞ  ð9 þ 11kÞÞ (i.b) PFI NI2
M1  PM1 for I2 2 fF; Bg if and only if
2

p2;2 ¼ ;
2ð27c  1Þ k  d2 .
ð1 þ kÞð45c  2Þ (ii) PBI NI2
M1 [ PM1 for I2 2 fF; N; Bg.
2

Q2 ¼ : pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
4ð27c  1Þ
2ð8396c þ 4779c2 Þþ 4ð27c  1Þ ð8396c þ 4779c2 Þþ
Here, d1 ¼ 1  4180c þ 1863c2
pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
(iii) When both manufacturers forward or backward 2ð8324c þ 3159c Þ 4ð27c1Þ ð8324c þ 3159c2 Þþ
2 þ
and d2 ¼ 1  4108c þ 243c2
.
integrate, FF, BF, FB, or BB:
In addition to enabling direct control on quality
ð1 þ kÞa and price, vertical integration reduces double margin-
h1 ¼ h2 ¼ ; alization in a supply chain. Therefore, one may expect
6c
dð5 þ 3kÞ it to improve profitability. However, in a competitive
p1;1 ¼ p2;1 ¼ ; market, vertical integration intensifies the price com-
2
dð3 þ 5kÞ petition, which could negate its benefits. The manu-
p1;2 ¼ p2;2 ¼ ; facturer feels the competitive effect more strongly
2
1þk when it forward integrates, as it moves closer to price
Q1 ¼ Q2 ¼ : competition. Therefore, while backward integration
2
always benefits a manufacturer, as part (ii) illustrates,
forward integration can be detrimental as shown in
When only manufacturer 1 is vertically integrated, parts (i.a) and (i.b). The benefit of forward integration
Lemma 1(ii) states that FN and BN scenarios share the depends on the level of demand perishability mea-
same equilibrium quality, price, and sales quantity sured by k. Specifically, a small k indicates a bigger
outcomes. This is because the sequence of events and drop in the market size (i.e., the mass of potential cus-
decisions are identical in these scenarios. Manufac- tomers) in period 2, which makes the ability to
turer 1, however, achieves different profits. In the BN directly control pricing by forward integration more
scenario, it collects the profit of a supplier in a two- valuable. Thus, when k is sufficiently small, the bene-
tier supply chain, whereas it collects the profit of a fit of forward integration dominates.
retailer in the FN scenario. Likewise, when both man- The previous lemma discusses the value of vertical
ufacturers are vertically integrated as in Lemma 1(iii), integration when the manufacturer moves from disin-
FF, BF, FB, and BB scenarios have the same equilib- tegration to vertical integration. The next proposition
rium quality, price, and sales quantity outcomes. examines the choice between forward and backward
Consistent with the sequence of events, it is straight- integration.
forward to show that the supplier’s margin is higher
than the manufacturer’s, which is in turn higher than LEMMA 3.
the retailer’s in a disintegrated supply chain (this is
also true in monopoly benchmark). (i) PBN
M1 [ PM1 .
FN

(ii) PFI 2 BI2


M1  PM1 [ PM1  PM1 for I2 2 fF; Bg.
FN BN

4.2. Vertical Integration Equilibrium (iii) PFI BI2


M1  PM1 for I2 2 fF; Bg if and only if k  d3 .
2

Having characterized price–quality equilibrium, we pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi


now turn our focus to the choice of vertical integra- 2ð18c1Þþ 6 cð18c1Þþ
Here d3 ¼ 1  9c1 .
tion strategies and their impact on profitability. Spe-
cifically, in the following, Lemmas 2 and 3 show the Because forward integration intensifies the impact
value of forward and backward integration in a com- of competition more than backward integration for
petitive market, and then Proposition 2 describes the the manufacturer, backward integration always domi-
chosen vertical integration strategies in equilibrium. nates forward integration against a disintegrated
Let PIM1 I12 be the equilibrium profit of manufacturer 1 competitor as in part (i). However, when the compet-
when manufacturer i, i = 1,2, chooses strategy Ii . ing supply chain is vertically integrated, its price
urk, and Swaminathan: Vertical Integration under Competition
Lin, Parlakt€
Production and Operations Management 23(1), pp. 19–35, © 2013 Production and Operations Management Society 27

reaction is weaker due to fewer firms adjusting their The proposition shows that symmetric manufactur-
margins. Thus, a vertically integrated competitor ers make symmetric choices. However, section 5.4
improves the relative attractiveness of forward inte- shows that the cost asymmetry can lead to asymmet-
gration as shown in part (ii). Indeed, when the com- ric equilibrium outcomes. Parts (i) and (ii) provide
petitor is vertically integrated, forward integration benchmarks in which only one of the integration
can dominate backward integration as part (iii) dem- options is available. Their results immediately follow
onstrates. from Lemmas 2 and 3. Specifically, backward integra-
The result in part (iii) depends on how benefits of tion is always desirable, whereas a smaller k indicat-
controlling price and quality compare to each other. ing higher degree of demand perishability makes
Recall that a high c, which is defined in Equation (7), forward integration desirable.8
indicates a lower return on quality investment. Part (iii) states the equilibrium for our main
Moreover d3 is decreasing in c, thus a lower d3 model. It shows that staying disintegrated cannot be
means a lower return from quality investment. an equilibrium outcome when the manufacturers
Therefore, when d3 is low, an independent supplier consider both forward and backward integration
would underinvest in quality too much. Doing so options. This is in sharp contrast to the celebrated
increases the attractiveness of backward integration result that disintegration can be an equilibrium out-
for the manufacturer, as it allows directly controlling come (e.g., Gupta and Loulou 1998, McGuire and
quality. Staelin 1983, Trivedi 1998). The key difference is that
In contrast, when d3 is high, quality investment in those studies the manufacturers can choose
becomes attractive. The suppliers overinvest in qual- among no integration and forward integration (the
ity due to competition; thus the manufacturers do not backward integration option is not available) as in
need to control quality. Furthermore, overinvestment part (ii). Not surprisingly, their findings are consis-
in quality hurts the suppliers’ profitability, which tent with our part (ii) benchmark.
gives the manufacturers another reason to stay away Part (iii) demonstrates that both manufacturers
from backward integration.6 On the other hand, a low choose to vertically integrate in the same direction in
k indicates a bigger intertemporal drop in market size, equilibrium. Consistent with Lemma 3, the chosen
and this in turn makes controlling price through for- direction depends on how benefits of more closely
ward integration desirable. The overall effect depends controlling demand and supply side compare to each
on how k compares to d3 as shown in part (iii).7 To other. When k is small, indicating higher degree of
sum up, Lemma 3 shows that the choice between for- demand perishability, there is bigger need for control-
ward and backward integration critically depends on ling price, whereas when d3 is small, indicating low
the structure of the competing supply chain, return return from quality investment, the need for control-
on quality investment, and the degree of demand per- ling quality prevails.
ishability. Note that when k = 1, demand is no longer perish-
Having characterized each manufacturer’s best able, and both periods become identical; thus the
response integration strategy in Lemmas 2 and 3, now products are sold at the same price in each period. In
we are ready to state integration strategies I1 I2 the this case, the model becomes similar to a single-period
manufacturers choose in equilibrium. model, yielding the same equilibrium structure as in
Proposition 2, but quality investment becomes the
only dynamic determining the equilibrium outcomes.9
PROPOSITION 2. The next proposition reveals that the equilibrium in
(i) When manufacturers can choose among no integra- part (iii) of Proposition 2 results in a prisoner’s
tion (N) and backward integration (B), I1 I2 ¼ BB. dilemma.
(ii) When manufacturers can choose among no integra-
tion (N) and forward integration (F), then PROPOSITION 3. PNN
M1 [ PM1 and PM1 [ PM1 .
FF NN BB


I1 I2 ¼ FF for k\d1 ; In equilibrium, both manufacturers vertically inte-
NN otherwise : grate, and they both suffer due to competing with a
stronger competitor. Observe that when the backward
(iii) When manufacturers can choose among no integra- integration option is not available (i.e., in the setting
tion (N) and both forward (F) and backward (B) of McGuire and Staelin 1983), the equilibrium does
integration, then not necessarily lead to a prisoner’s dilemma, as no
 integration can be an equilibrium outcome.
FF for k  d3 ;
I1 I2 ¼ Proposition 2 characterizes the equilibrium under
BB otherwise;
competition. It is worthwhile to contrast its results
where d1 , d2 , and d3 are given in Lemmas 2 and 3. with the monopoly benchmark (Proposition 1) to see
urk, and Swaminathan: Vertical Integration under Competition
Lin, Parlakt€
28 Production and Operations Management 23(1), pp. 19–35, © 2013 Production and Operations Management Society

how competition affects the chosen vertical integra- (ii) QI21 I2 \ QNI 2 I1 I2 NI2 I1 I2 NI2
2 , h2 \ h2 , and p2;t \ p2;t , for
tion strategy. I1 2 fF; Bg and any I2 2 fF; N; Bg.
(iii) QIi 1 I2 ¼ QNN I 1 I2
1 , hi ¼ hNN I1 I 2
1 , and pi;t \ pi;t , for
NN
COROLLARY 1. The manufacturers are more likely to Ii 2 fF; Bg and i = 1,2.
choose backward integration under duopoly competition
compared with the monopoly benchmark.
Interestingly, Proposition 5(i) shows that manufac-
turer 1’s vertical integration (both forward and back-
Forward integration increases the intensity of price
ward) results in a better quality product 1 sold at a
competition more than backward integration. A
lower retail price in both periods. Because vertical
monopolist does not need to worry about the price
integration alleviates double marginalization, it
reaction of the competitor and more freely integrates
encourages more quality investment for product 1,
forward whereas the competitor’s response is an issue
which can potentially increase the retail price. On the
for a duopolist. Therefore, a manufacturer is more
other hand, vertical integration removes intermediaries
likely to choose backward integration in duopoly than
who add their margins to the retail price, and this leads
in monopoly.
to an opposite force that can lower the retail price.
So far we have showed that vertical integration can
Similarly, vertical integration forces the competitor to
hurt a manufacturer. An immediate question becomes
drop its prices. This reaction intensifies the price com-
how it affects the entire supply chain. The next propo-
petition, which can also lead to a lower retail price. As
sition addresses this question. Let PIC11I2 be the total
a result, the latter forces dominate, and the quality of
equilibrium profit achieved by supply chain 1 when
product 1 improves while its retail price drops. Part (ii)
manufacturer i, i = 1,2, chooses strategy Ii .
shows that the competitor decreases its quality invest-
ment because it now faces a stronger opponent (one
PROPOSITION 4.
with less double marginalization inefficiency).
(i) PFI 2 NI2 BI2 NI2
C1 \ PC1 and PC1 \ PC1 for any I2 . Finally, part (iii) compares what happens when
I I both of the manufacturers vertically integrate to
(ii) PC11 2  PNN
C1 . when none of them do so. The retail prices are lower
when they vertically integrate due to more intense
Part (i) shows that both forward and backward inte-
competition. Furthermore, because no supply chain
grations decrease profitability of the supply chain.
has the advantage, they equally split the market and
Thus, even when the manufacturer benefits from
choose the same product quality in both scenarios.
vertical integration (as shown in Lemmas 2 and 3),
this happens at the expense of its supply chain part-
ners. Note that the adverse effect of vertical integra- 5. Extensions
tion is due to the competitor’s reaction because in
monopoly benchmark vertical integration always In this section, we consider various extensions of our
improves a supply chain’s total profit. model. Section 5.1 allows forward integration to alter
Proposition 3 indicates that the equilibrium results consumer price sensitivity; section 5.2 allows manu-
in a prisoner’s dilemma for manufacturers. Part (ii) of facturers to modify the wholesale price in period 2;
Proposition 4 shows that both supply chains suffer in section 5.3 studies retailers’ quality contribution;
equilibrium as well. The equality in this case occurs finally, section 5.4 allows suppliers to differ in their
when none of the manufacturers vertically integrate quality improvement costs.
(i.e., I1 I2 ¼ NN); otherwise supply chain profits
decrease strictly when equilibrium involves vertical 5.1. Forward Integration and Price Sensitivity
integration. So far we have assumed vertical integration does not
alter the consumer price sensitivity. In this section, we
relax this assumption and consider what happens
4.3. Impact on Product Quality, Sales Quantity, when forward integration reduces the consumer price
and Retail Price sensitivity. Intuitively, direct contact with consumers
The previous section has focused on the impact of through company stores can generate better brand
vertical integation on profitability. Here, we discuss perception, which can increase consumers’ willing-
the impact on sales quantity, product quality, and ness to pay. Indeed, it is common to see higher retail
retail price. prices in company stores than in general retailers, and
some examples are provided in Table 2.10
PROPOSITION 5. For t = 1,2,
(i) QI11 I2
[ QNI
1 ,
2
hI11 I2 [ hNI I1 I2 NI2
1 , and p1;t \ p1;t , for
2
5.1.1. Symmetric Price Sensitivity. Suppose man-
I1 2 fF; Bg and any I2 2 fF; N; Bg. ufacturers enjoy equal reduction in the consumer price
urk, and Swaminathan: Vertical Integration under Competition
Lin, Parlakt€
Production and Operations Management 23(1), pp. 19–35, © 2013 Production and Operations Management Society 29

Table 2 Difference in Retail Prices First, we present new findings regarding the value
Company
of vertical integration to a manufacturer.
store Private Retailer
Product price retailer price
PROPOSITION 6.
Columbia Steep Slop $181.90 REI $139.93 (i) PFI
M1 [ PM1
2 NI2
if and only if bF \ sI12 for
Parka Men’s Ski Jacket I2 2 fF; N; Bg.
North Face Denali $199 Dick’s Sporting $178.99 (ii) PFI BI2
if and only if bF \ sI22 for
M1 [ PM1
2
Thermal Women’s Goods
Jacket
I2 2 fF; N; Bg.
F BI2 NI2
Nike Dri-Fit UV Men’s $70 Dick’s Sporting $65 (iii) PBF
M1 \ PM1 if and only if b \ s3 ; PM1 [ PM1
NF

Stripe Golf Polo Goods for I2 2 fN; Bg.


Apple iPod Nano 5th Gen $149 Walmart $133.99
8GB The thresholds sI12 , sI22 , and s3 are characterized in the
Sony DSC-T90 Digital $279 Walmart $248 proof in online Appendix E.
Camera
When forward integration improves a manufac-
turer’s pricing advantage, manufacturers are more
sensitivity when they forward integrate. Specifically, likely to adopt this strategy. Consequently, forward
let bIi be the consumer price sensitivity to product i integration can be beneficial, and it can be favored
when manufacturer i chooses strategy I, I ∈ {F,N,B}. over backward integration when the pricing advan-
Then the base model described in section 3 entails tage is significant, as in Proposition 6(i) and Proposi-
tion 6(ii).
bIi ¼ 1, I ∈ {F,N,B}, i = 1,2, as Equation (1) shows. In
Proposition 6(iii) demonstrates an additional
this section, we relax that assumption, allowing
insight: the potential benefit of backward integration
bFi ¼ bF \ 1 while keeping bIi ¼ 1, I ∈ {N,B}, i = 1,2. can be nullified by the competitor’s pricing advan-
Furthermore, to account for bF \ 1, we generalize tage. This is in direct contrast to our base model
9cbF bF 1
assumption A2 as 3þbF
ð11  1kÞ [ 1  kð3þbF Þ
, which where backward integration is always beneficial.
F When manufacturer 2’s pricing advantage from for-
reduces to the original A2 when b ¼ 1. We assume
ward integration is significant, it relies on this advan-
that the price sensitivity advantage of forward integra-
tage and reacts to manufacturer 1’s backward
tion is not extreme, specifically bF [ 1 1þ3k
kþ54ck, to avoid integration by increasing the quality of its product.
the trivial case in which a backward-integrated supply This in turn decreases manufacturer 1’s return from
chain competing against a forward-integrated supply quality investment when it backward integrates.
chain cannot sell any products in a period. We present Next, we formally state that staying disintegrated
the resulting equilibrium quality, price, and sales cannot be an equilibrium outcome when manufactur-
quantity for all possible supply chain configurations ers competitively determine their vertical integration
in Appendix C. strategies.
While our discussion in the following will focus on
new findings due to relaxing bF ¼ 1, we want to PROPOSITION 7. When bF \ 1 and manufacturers choose
point out that most of the key results of the base among no integration (N), forward (F), and backward (B)
model continue to hold. Specifically, Proposition 6 integration, then NN cannot be an equilibrium.
shows vertical integration can be detrimental to a
manufacturer, which is consistent with Lemma 2. This occurs because backward integration does not
Proposition 6 also characterizes the conditions that affect the consumer price sensitivity. Thus, when a
make forward integration more attractive than back- manufacturer chooses to stay disintegrated (N), its
ward integration similar to Lemma 3. Proposition 8 competitor can always improve its profitability by
shows vertical integration can improve product qual- backward integration, as Lemma 2 shows. Finally, we
ity while reducing the retail price as in Proposition 5. examine the effect of vertical integration on product
However, allowing bF \ 1 complicates the analysis; quality and sales quantity.
characterizing equilibrium vertical integration strate-
PROPOSITION 8. Let I1 ; I2 2 fF; N; Bg:
gies as in Proposition 2 becomes intractable. This diffi-
culty arises because the profit expressions involve (i.a) For ðI1 ; I2 Þ ¼ ðB; FÞ: hI11 I2 \ hNI I1 I2
1 , Q1 \ Q1 ,
2 NI2
I1 I2 NI2 I1 I2 NI2
high order polynomials, and characterizing equilib- h2 [ h2 , and Q2 [ Q2 if and only if
rium regions requires comparing multiple high order bF \ 2þ27c
4
.
polynomials. Even though we cannot fully character-
(i.b) For ðI1 ; I2 Þ 6¼ ðB; FÞ: hI11 I2  hNI I1 I2
1 , Q1
2
 QNI
1 ,
2
ize equilibrium integration strategies, Proposition 7 I1 I2 NI2 I1 I2 NI2
confirms that no integration still cannot be an equilib- h2  h2 , and Q2  Q2 .
rium integration strategy when bF \ 1. (ii.a) pFI NI2
1 [ p1
2
if and only if bF \ rI2 .
urk, and Swaminathan: Vertical Integration under Competition
Lin, Parlakt€
30 Production and Operations Management 23(1), pp. 19–35, © 2013 Production and Operations Management Society

(ii.b) pBI 2 NI2 I1 I2


1 \ p1 ; p2  pNI
2
2
for I1 6¼ B. When forward integration gives manufacturer 1 the
The threshold rI2 is stated in the proof in online Appen- pricing advantage (bF1 \ bF2 ), its product quality and
dix E and the inequalities in (i.b) and (ii.b) hold strictly sales quantity always increase while those of the com-
when I1 6¼ N. petitor decrease as shown in part (i). What happens
when the competitor forward integrates is more sub-
When facing a competing supply chain that is tle. When manufacturer 2 forward integrates, the
already forward integrated, Proposition 8(i.a) shows competing supply chain 1 relying on its pricing
that the quality of product 1 gets lower when manufac- advantage can respond aggressively by increasing its
turer 1 backward integrates, whereas in the base model quality and force supply chain 2 to lower its quality.
we find that vertical integration always increases prod- Part (ii) shows that when quality cost c is sufficiently
uct quality. This is because the competing supply chain low, supply chain 1 indeed follows this hostile strat-
relies on its pricing advantage, reacting to manufac- egy. However, when quality cost c is sufficiently high,
turer 1’s backward integration by increasing quality of it cannot afford overinvesting in quality. In this case,
its product. Consequently, manufacturer 1’s return supply chain 1 accommodates manufacturer 2’s for-
from quality improvement gets lower, forcing it to ward integration by reducing its quality and quantity,
lower its product quality. Additionally, contrary to our allowing manufacturer 2 to take advantage of forward
earlier result where vertical integration always lowers integration to have higher quality and sales quantity.
retail price, case (ii.a) shows that forward integration Finally, part (iii) demonstrates that the competitor is
can increase the retail price when the pricing advan- more likely to respond aggressively to manufacturer
tage is significant, because consumers become very 2’s forward integration when the competitor has a
price insensitive. Thus, Proposition 8(i.b) and (ii.a) bigger pricing advantage.
suggests that forward integration can increase both
product quality and retail price when it has a signifi- 5.2. Dynamic Wholesale Pricing
cant pricing advantage, that is, bF \ rI2 . In the base model, manufacturers set the same whole-
sale price for both periods. In this section, we examine
5.1.2. Asymmetric Price Sensitivity. In the previ- what happens if manufacturers can choose their
ous section, the manufacturers have identical price wholesale prices dynamically in each period.
sensitivity when they forward integrate, that is, Assumptions A1 and A2 described in section 3 are
bF1 ¼ bF2 . Now, we relax this assumption, allowing for replaced by m [ dð9ð2þkÞ  1þk 5c
6c Þ and 9 ð45  k Þ þ
9
2
bF1 6¼ bF2 . Suppose bF1 \ bF2  1 without loss of 1
[ 1 respectively in this extension.
9k
generality.
The next proposition shows that our key results
Similar to section 5.1.1, we assume the price sen-
continue to hold. Recall that I1 I2 denotes manufactur-
sitivity advantage is not extreme, specifically
ers’ equilibrium strategy.
ð1þ3kÞbF2  ð1  kÞbF1
bF1 bF2
\ 54ck, to avoid the trivial cases.
Note that when bF2 ¼ 1, this assumption becomes PROPOSITION 10. Suppose manufacturers set wholesale
identical to that of section 5.1.1. The resulting equi- prices dynamically for each period and manufacturers choose
librium quality, price, and sales quantity for each among no (N), forward (F), and backward (B) integration.
scenario are summarized in Appendix C. Here, we (i) The equilibrium integration strategy is
focus on results concerning competition between ( pffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi
two forward integrated manufacturers with asym- 8ð18c1Þþ 12 cð18c1Þþ
 
I1 I2 ¼ FF for k  1  63c4 ;
metric price sensitivities, which is the most interest-
BB otherwise:
ing scenario.

PROPOSITION 9. (ii) Manufacturers encounter a prisoner’s dilemma, that


I I
is, pi 1 2 \ pNN
i .
(i) 1 \ Q1 ,
QNF FF
hNF
1 \ hFF
1 , QNF
2 [ QFF
2 , and
hNF FF
2 [ h2 . Proposition 10 shows that the key results of the
(ii) There exists nhi and nQ
i , i = 1,2, such that base model continue to hold. That is, staying disinte-
ðaÞ QFN
1 \ Q1
FF
if and only if c \ nQ1 , and
grated is never an equilibrium outcome when manu-
FN FF
h1 \ h1 if and only if c \ n1 .
h facturers consider both forward and backward
ðbÞ QFN if and only if c \ nQ integrations. Manufacturers prefer forward integra-
2 [ Q2
FF
2 , and
FN FF tion when the product is highly perishable and back-
h2 [ h2 if and only if c \ nh2 .
ward integration when the return from quality
(iii) nhi and nQi are stated explicitly in the proof of the
investment is low (the threshold in part (i) decreases
proposition and they increase in bF2  bF1 . in c). Furthermore, the equilibrium results in a
urk, and Swaminathan: Vertical Integration under Competition
Lin, Parlakt€
Production and Operations Management 23(1), pp. 19–35, © 2013 Production and Operations Management Society 31

prisoner’s dilemma. In the next corollary, we examine with g ¼ 4ðb=aÞ6 þ 324ðb=aÞ4 c  45927ðb=aÞ2 c2 þ
how manufacturers’ dynamic pricing ability affects 59049c ð18c  1Þ.
2

their integration choices. (ii) Manufacturers encounter a prisoner’s dilemma, that


I  I2
is, pi 1  pNN
i .
COROLLARY 2. Manufacturers are more likely to back-
ward integrate when they gain dynamic pricing ability. No integration still cannot be an equilibrium out-
come when manufacturers consider both forward and
When manufacturers cannot set their wholesale backward integrations. Furthermore, the equilibrium
prices dynamically, forward integration has the results in a prisoner’s dilemma. Moreover, the same as
added benefit of enabling pricing flexibility. But when in our base model (see Proposition 2), the threshold in
they already have the dynamic pricing ability, this part (i) increases in a and decreases in c and d. There-
benefit is not as valuable, making forward integration fore our corresponding insights continue to hold.
less attractive. Finally, the threshold in part (i) increases in the con-
sumer sensitivity to retailer quality b, indicating that
5.3. Retailers’ Quality Contribution the manufacturers prefer forward integration when
In the base model, product quality is determined the retail quality has a significant impact on the over-
solely by the supplier. In some settings, retailers can all perceived product quality. Intuitively, when b is
also affect the perceived product quality significantly, high, the retailer chooses a high level of quality
for example, by their store design and employee train- investment. Because of the resulting high quality
ing. We now consider what happens if retailers can product, the retailer tends to sell to a smaller segment,
also contribute to the product quality. Thus, the con- which in turn forces the manufacturers to drop their
sumer utility in Equation (1) is appended as follows price to maintain its sales quantity. Forward integra-
with an additional term bhir , which is controlled by tion eliminates this problem for the manufacturer.
the retailer.
5.4. Asymmetric Quality Cost
Ui;t ¼ m þ ahi þ bhir  pi;t  dwi : ð12Þ Here we consider what happens when the two supply
chains differ in their efficiency of quality improve-
Here, hir is the quality level chosen by the retailer in ment. Specifically, ci shows the quality improvement
supply chain i, and b  0 shows the consumer sensi- cost coefficient of supply chain i. Suppose c1 [ c2
tivity to retailer quality. To avoid introducing any without loss of generality. Let c1 ¼ c and c2 ¼ vc1 ,
bias, we assume the supplier and the retailer have where v ∈ (0,1). Assumptions A1 and A2 are
equal quality cost coefficients. Specifically, the retailer 2
ð5þ4kÞv9cð19þ17kÞð1þvÞþ4ð1þkÞ
incurs quality cost ch2ir . Similar to our base model, replaced with m [ dð1458c 12cð81cvð1þvÞÞ Þ
9vc
quality decisions are made before pricing decisions, and 3þv ð11  1kÞ [ 1 þ kð3þvÞ
1v
, respectively, which
and suppliers precede manufacturers and retailers. reduce back to A1 and A2 when v = 1. Furthermore,
Specifically, a supplier’s quality decision is followed we assume that the cost advantage is not extremely
by that of the retailer, which is followed by the pricing high, that is, v [ 1 1þ3k
kþ54ck, so that the high cost supply
decisions.
chain can also sell its product in both periods.
Assumptions A1 and A2 of the base model are
2
ð2ðb=aÞ2 ð1 þ kÞ  81cð19 þ 17kÞÞ
replaced with m [ dððb=aÞ 54cð729c2ðb=aÞ2 Þ
þ PROPOSITION 12. Suppose suppliers have asymmetric
243ð9cð5þ4kÞð1þkÞÞ
Þ and 9c b 2 1 1 quality costs such that c2 ¼ vc1 , v ∈ (0,1) and manu-
4 ð11  k Þ [ 1  ðaÞ ð72 ðk  23Þ þ
1
2ð729c2ðb=aÞ2 Þ facturers choose among no (N), forward (F), and back-
2
972c ðaÞ Þ, respectively. Note
1 b
these assumptions and ward (B) integration.
our results in this section reduce to those of the base
(i) NN cannot be an equilibrium.
model when b = 0. The following proposition shows
(ii) I1 I2 ¼ NB for v  d4 and k  minðd6 ; d7 Þ.
that our key results continue to hold when retailers
(iii) I1 I2 ¼ FB for d5 \ k \ minðd6 ; d7 Þ, d4 to d7 are
contribute to quality.
stated in the addendum in Appendix D.
PROPOSITION 11. Suppose both supplier and retailer con- Proposition 12 shows even with asymmetric costs,
trol quality as in Equation (12) and manufacturers choose both firms staying disintegrated cannot be an equilib-
among no (N), forward (F), and backward (B) integration. rium. While Proposition 12 does not state all possible
(i) equilibrium outcomes (which are stated in Appendix
( pffiffiffiffiffiffi D), it demonstrates the asymmetry in the quality costs
2gþ þ 18ð81c2ðb=aÞ2 Þ cgþ
I1 I2 ¼ FF if k  1  4ðb=aÞ6 19683ðb=aÞ2 c2 þ 59049c2 ð9c1Þ ; can lead to asymmetry in equilibrium outcomes. Part
BB otherwise ; (ii) illustrates that manufacturer 1 can stay disintegrated
urk, and Swaminathan: Vertical Integration under Competition
Lin, Parlakt€
32 Production and Operations Management 23(1), pp. 19–35, © 2013 Production and Operations Management Society

while manufacturer 2 integrates backward when Basically, with pricing advantage a forward-inte-
manufacturer 2 has a sufficiently strong cost advan- grated manufacturer undermines the return from
tage. In this case, manufacturer 1 does not want to quality investment for its competitor, disallowing the
increase the intensity of competition due to the com- competitor to take advantage of backward integra-
petitor’s cost advantage. Finally, part (iii) shows that tion. While we provide several examples that show
with the cost asymmetry, manufacturers can choose that forward integration may enable manufacturers to
to integrate in the opposite directions in contrast to set higher prices in their company stores, there could
our symmetric base model. be opposite examples whereby forward integration
may increase the consumer price sensitivity. In those
examples, we expect forward integration to be less
6. Concluding Remarks attractive for manufacturers and it would be less
In this study we examine equilibrium vertical integra- likely to be an equilibrium outcome.
tion strategies under supply chain competition. To While manufacturers with symmetric costs never
this end, we analyze two competing three-tier supply stay disintegrated in equilibrium, the manufacturer
chains, each with a supplier, a manufacturer, and a with the cost disadvantage can stay disintegrated
retailer. Each manufacturer considers three vertical when there is cost asymmetry in our model. Further-
integration strategies: forward, backward, and no more, organizational, cultural, and geographic barri-
integration. Forward integration enables a manufac- ers, which are omitted in our model, can also stop
turer to better manage the demand side by directly manufacturers from pursuing vertical integration.
controlling the retail price, whereas backward inte- These factors are also omitted in McGuire and Staelin
gration allows it to better manage the supply side by (1983), Gupta and Loulou (1998), and Trivedi (1998),
directly controlling the quality investment. and they argue that firms choose to stay disintegrated
When competing manufacturers consider solely mov- to avoid intensifying competition. Our results show
ing from disintegration to forward integration, a cele- that competition alone cannot explain why firms may
brated result in prior studies is that manufacturers may choose to stay disintegrated when backward integra-
strategically choose to stay disintegrated (e.g., Gupta tion is an option in addition to forward integration.
and Loulou 1998, McGuire and Staelin 1983). Interest- Our model has limitations. We assume that each
ingly, we demonstrate this result does not continue to retailer sells a single product variant. However, in
hold when backward integration is also an option for practice most retailers will be selling a product line;
manufacturers. When they have both forward and back- thus we expect product proliferation to increase the
ward integration options, both manufacturers choose to intensity of price competition. Because forward inte-
vertically integrate (either forward or backward) even gration intensifies retail price competition more than
though this results in a prisoner’s dilemma situation. backward integration, we expect forward integration
We explain how the direction of vertical integration to be less valuable than our model predicts. Further-
manufacturers choose in equilibrium depends on more, while each manufacturer has a single distinct
supply and demand elements. Specifically, when the supplier in our model, they may have multiple sup-
dynamics of demand perishability dominate, forward pliers and share some of these suppliers with their
integration becomes more attractive. In contrast when competitors. In that case, there will be an additional
the dynamics of product quality dominate, backward incentive for backward integration due to the added
integration is preferred. Our equilibrium results char- benefit of controlling the competitor’s supply. This
acterize this trade-off explicitly. can be a fruitful direction for future research. More
We also quantify the value of unilaterally imple- broadly, it would be worthwhile to study how the
menting vertical integration and how this relates to value of vertical integration depends on various sup-
the structure of the competing supply chain. A verti- ply chain configurations.
cally integrated competitor compared with a disinte- Forward and backward integration may have addi-
grated competitor improves attractiveness of forward tional benefits beyond what is captured in our model.
integration relative to backward integration. In addi- For example, forward integration may enable a manu-
tion, backward integration always increases profit- facturer to collect more information about customer
ability regardless of the structure of the competing demand. Moreover, in our model, upstream firms
supply chain. In contrast, forward integration can be move before downstream firms and make a take-it-or-
detrimental both when the competitor is vertically leave-it offer. This is a common assumption in papers
integrated and when it is disintegrated. studying vertical integration decisions (Gray et al.
Examples from practice suggest that forward inte- 2009, Liu and Tyagi 2011, McGuire and Staelin 1983,
gration can reduce the consumer price sensitivity. Pun and Heese 2010). However, it would be worth-
In this case, forward integration can make back- while for future research to study how vertical inte-
ward integration unattractive for the competitor. gration choices depend on the relative bargaining
urk, and Swaminathan: Vertical Integration under Competition
Lin, Parlakt€
Production and Operations Management 23(1), pp. 19–35, © 2013 Production and Operations Management Society 33

power of the retailer and supplier within the supply ð1 þ kÞa


chain using a bargaining framework. Finally, our h1 ¼ h2 ¼ ; p1;1 ¼ p2;1 ¼ dð7 þ 6kÞ;
6c
analysis is restricted to competition between two sup- 1þk
ply chains, and an obvious extension would examine p1;2 ¼ p2;2 ¼ dð6 þ 7kÞ; Q1 ¼ Q2 ¼ :
2
the competition between many supply chains.
(ii) When only manufacturer 1 forward integrates, FN:
Because retail competition would be fiercer due to
more competitors, we expect increasing the number dð1kÞ
h1 ¼ ð63c  2ÞA; p1;1 ¼ B1 ; p1;2 ¼ B1  b1 ;
of competitors to deteriorate attractiveness of forward
Q1 ¼ ð63c  2ÞC;
integration relative to backward integration.
h2 ¼ ð45c  2ÞA; p2;1 ¼ B2 ; p2;2 ¼ B2  dð1  kÞ;
Acknowledgments Q2 ¼ ð45c  2ÞC:
The authors thank the senior editor and the referees for
(iii) When only manufacturer 1 backward integrates, BN:
many helpful comments and suggestions.

h1 ¼ ð63c  2ÞD; p1;1 ¼ E1 ; p1;2 ¼ E1  dð1  kÞ;


Appendix A: Monopoly Benchmark Q1 ¼ ð63c  2ÞF;
The unique SPNE product quality h, retail price pt ,
t = 1,2, and sales quantity Q for a monopolist supply h2 ¼ ð45c  2ÞD; p2;1 ¼ E1 þ E2 ;
chain are as follows assuming it does not serve the p2;2 ¼ E1 þ E2  dð1  kÞ; Q2 ¼ ð45c  2ÞF:
entire market in both periods.
(iv) When both manufacturers vertically integrate, FF,
(i) When the manufacturer does not vertically BF, FB or BB:
integrate: h1 ¼ ð27cb2  2ÞG; p1;1 ¼ H1 ; p1;2 ¼ H1  dð1kÞ
b1 ;
h ¼ ma
8cda2
; p1 ¼ p2 ¼ 7cdm
8cda2
;Q ¼ 2cm
8cda2
. Q1 ¼ b1 ð27cb2  2ÞJ

(ii) When the manufacturer forward or backward h2 ¼ ð27cb1  2ÞG; p2;1 ¼ H2 ; p2;2 ¼ H2  dð1kÞ
b2 ;
integrates: Q2 ¼ b2 ð27cb1  2ÞJ

h ¼ ma
; p1 ¼ p2 ¼ 4cda
3cdm
2 ; Q ¼ 4cda2 .
2cm where
4cda2
cd
In equilibrium, the monopolist manufacturer c¼ ;
a2
chooses to forward integrate when c \ 12 and it ð1 þ kÞa
chooses to backward integrate otherwise. A¼ ;
6cðð54c  1Þb1  1Þ
Appendix B: Exogenous Quality dðk  1  15b1  13kb1 þ cb1 ð495 þ 387kÞÞ
B1 ¼ ;
Benchmark 2b1 ðð54c  1Þb1  1Þ
Let h be the quality level for both products, which is dðð504c  1Þb1  21 þ kð396cb1 þ b1  19Þ  21Þ
B2 ¼ ;
exogenously determined. When the quality is deter- 2ðð54c  1Þb1  1Þ
mined exogenously, assumption A1 is replaced by ð1 þ kÞ
C ¼ ;
m [ 3dð5þ4kÞ
2  ah, which helps avoid the trivial case 2ð54c  1Þb1  2
where firms form local monopolies in the NN scenario. ð1 þ kÞa
D ¼ ;
12cð27c  1Þ
PROPOSITION 13. When quality is exogenously deter-
dð495c þ 3kð129c  4Þ  16Þ
mined, manufacturers always backward integrate when E1 ¼ ;
4ð27c  1Þ
they choose among no (N), forward (F), and backward
(B) integration. 3dð1 þ kÞð3c  2Þ
E2 ¼ ;
4ð27c  1Þ
ð1 þ kÞ
Appendix C: Forward Integration F ¼ ;
4ð27c  1Þ
Decreasing Price Sensitivity að1 þ kÞ
G ¼ ;
6cð27cb1 b2  b1  b2 Þ
LEMMA 4. Suppose bFi
\ 1, i = 1,2; the unique SPNE
product quality hi , retail price pi;t , and sales quantity Qi dðb1 b2 cð135 þ 81kÞ  ð9 þ 7kÞbi þ ðk  1Þb3i Þ
Hi ¼ ;
for each scenario I1 I2 , Ii 2 fN; F; Bg, are as follows. 2bi ð27cb1 b2  b1  b2 Þ
ð1 þ kÞ
(i) When none of the manufacturers vertically inte- J ¼
2ð27cb1 b2  b1  b2 Þ
grates, NN:
urk, and Swaminathan: Vertical Integration under Competition
Lin, Parlakt€
34 Production and Operations Management 23(1), pp. 19–35, © 2013 Production and Operations Management Society

5
and Recall that assumption A1 in our duopoly model assumes
 that two firms cover the market so they compete with
1 if Ii ¼ B each other rather than forming local monopolies. How-
bi ¼ ;
bFi \1 if Ii ¼ F ever, vertical integration can help a manufacturer increase
its demand in both periods, as one firm does not cover
the entire market by itself since assumption A2 ensures
that the other firm has a positive market share.
Appendix D. Addendum to 6
In line with this finding, when quality investment cost
Proposition 12 disappears, that is, quality is exogenously fixed, backward
(iv) I1 I2 ¼ FF for k  d5 . integration is always preferred, as seen in Appendix B.
(v) I1 I2 ¼ BB for v [ d4 and k  minðd6 ; d7 Þ. 7
As a robustness check, we have verified that this finding
continues to hold when total market size is independent
d4 is the largest root of v such that of k, specifically when period 1 and 2 market sizes are
1  k and k, respectively, with k < 1/2.
ð27c  1Þð1 þ v  54cvÞ2 ð27cv  2Þ2 8
Note that both FF and NN can be equilibria for
þ 27cð45cv  2Þ2 ð1 þ v  27cvÞ2 ¼ 0 d1  k \ d2 but only NN survives because it is Pareto
dominant in the sense that both manufacturers achieve a
d5 is the smaller root of k such that higher payoff with NN.
9
To make the model exactly identical to a single-period
 model, quality cost needs to be scaled to ^c ¼ 2c and prof-
6561ð1 þ 6k þ k2 Þc3 v2  243c2 vð1 þ 6v þ 10kð1 þ 2vÞ
its need to be divided by 2 to account for the fact that
þ k2 ð1 þ 6vÞÞ þ 9cð10v  1 þ 7v2 þ k2 ð10v  1 þ 7v2 Þ quality investment is recovered over two periods instead
 of one.
þ 2kð1 þ 14v þ 9v2 ÞÞ  4ð1 þ kÞ2 v ¼ 0 10
The prices were collected on February 11, 2010, from
both physical and online stores.
d6 is the smaller root of k such that

4ð1 þ kÞ2  6561ð1 þ 6k þ k2 Þc3 v2 þ 243c2 vð1 þ 6v References
þ 10kð1 þ 2vÞ þ k2 ð1 þ 6vÞÞ þ 9cðv2  k2 ð7 þ 10v  v2 Þ AT&T. 2012. TNCI Signs Long-Term Wholesale Contract With
 AT&T for Voice, Data and IP Networking Solutions. Available at
 2kð9 þ 14v þ v2 Þ  7  10vÞ ¼ 0 http://www.att.com/gen/press-room?pid=4800&cdvn=news&
newsarticleid=26956 (accessed date February 5, 2013).
Bainbridge, J. 2009. Market Survey: Clothing—Capsule Collection.
d7 is the smaller root of k such that Available at http://www.brandrepublic.com/features/
 870762/(accessed date February 5, 2013).
ð1 þ vÞ2 ð7 þ 2v þ v2  k2 ð7  2v  v2 Þ  2kð9 þ 2v Banker, R. D., I. Khosla, K. K. Sinha. 1998. Quality and competi-
þ v2 ÞÞ  177147c4 v4 ð1 þ 50k þ k2 Þ þ 13122c3 v3 ð7 tion. Manage. Sci. 44(9): 1179–1192.
Bhaskaran, S. R., V. Krishnan. 2009. Effort, revenue and cost shar-
þ v þ k2 ð7 þ vÞ þ kð86 þ 74vÞÞ  243c2 v2 ð43 þ 38v ing in collaborative new product development. Manage. Sci.
55(7): 1152–1169.
 17v2 þ k2 ð43 þ 38v  17v2 Þ þ 2kð121 þ 194v þ 61v2 ÞÞ
Bonanno, G. 1986. Vertical differentiation with Cournot competi-
 54cvð1 þ vÞð9  2v þ 3v2  k2 ð9 þ 2v  3v2 Þ tion. Economic Notes 15(2): 68–91.
 Boyaci, T., G. Gallego. 2004. Supply chain coordination in a market
 2kð15 þ 14v þ 3v2 ÞÞ ¼ 0 with customer service competition. Prod. Oper. Manage. 13(1): 3–22.
Cachon, G. P. 2003. Supply chain coordination with contracts. S.
C. Graves, T. de Kok, eds. Handbooks in OR & MS. Volume II,
Supply Chain Management: Design, Coordination and Operation.
Notes North Holland, Amsterdam, 227–339.
1
Density serves as a scaling factor; changing it does not Cachon, G. P., P. T. Harker. 2002. Competition and outsourcing
alter our insights. with scale economies. Manage. Sci. 48(10): 1314–1333.
2
It is well known in equilibrium, symmetric duopoly firms Cattani, K., W. Gilland, H. S. Heese, J. Swaminathan. 2006. Boiling
choose locations at each end of the diameter of a circular frogs: Pricing strategies for a manufacturer adding a direct
market (cf. Salop 1979). Thus, our circular market is iden- channel that competes with the traditional channel. Prod.
Oper. Manage. 15(1): 40–56.
tical to using Hotelling’s (1929) model with duopolists
located on each end of the Hotelling line. Chambers, C., P. Kouvelis, J. Semple. 2006. Quality-based compe-
3 tition, profitability, and variable costs. Manage. Sci. 52(12):
Alternatively, the market sizes in periods 1 and 2 can be 1884–1895.
1  k and k, respectively, with k < 1/2, so the total market € Ozer.

Chen, K. Y., M. Kaya, O. 2008. Dual sales channel manage-
size over two periods is independent of k. All of our key ment with service competition. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manage.
insights continue to hold in this alternative model. 10(4): 654.
4
We also examine the situation where manufacturers can Cho, S. H. 2011. Horizontal mergers in multi-tier decentralized
set a different wholesale price for each period in section supply chains. Working paper, Carnegie Mellon University,
5.2. Pittsburgh, PA.
urk, and Swaminathan: Vertical Integration under Competition
Lin, Parlakt€
Production and Operations Management 23(1), pp. 19–35, © 2013 Production and Operations Management Society 35

Collier, J. 2009. Will Coke follow suit? Pepsi Co wants to buy its two € Ozer.
Kaya, M., O. € 2012. Pricing in business-to-business contracts:
largest bottlers. The Atlanta Journal Constitution April 21, p. 5A. € Ozer,
Sharing risk, profit, and information. R. Phillips, O. € eds.
Corbett, C. J, U. S. Karmarkar. 2001. Competition and structure in The Oxford Handbook of Pricing Management, Oxford University
serial supply chains with deterministic demand. Manage. Sci. Press, New York, 738–783.
47(7): 966–978. Kostamis, D., I. Duenyas. 2009. Quantity commitment, production
Coughlan, A. 1985. Competition and cooperation in marketing and subcontracting with bargaining. IIE Trans. 41(8): 677–686.
channel choice: Theory and application. Market. Sci. 4(2): 110–129. Liu, Y., R. Tyagi. 2011. The benefits of competitive upward chan-
Demirhan, D., V. S. Jacob, S. Raghunathan. 2007. Strategic IT nel decentralization. Manag. Sci. 57(4): 741–751.
investments: The impact of switching cost and declining IT McGuire, T. W., R. Staelin. 1983. An industry equilibrium analysis
cost. Manage. Sci. 53(2): 208–226. of downstream vertical integration. Market. Sci. 2(2): 161–191.
Desai, P. S. 2001. Quality segmentation in spatial markets: When Moorthy, K. S. 1988. Strategic decentralization in channels. Market.
does cannibalization affect product line design? Market. Sci. Sci. 7 (4): 335–355.
20(3): 265–283. Peleg-Gillai, B. 2007. Esquel group transforming into a vertically
Gilbert, S. M., V. Cvsa. 2003. Strategic commitment to price to integrated, service-oriented, leading manufacturer of quality
stimulate downstream innovation in a supply chain. Eur. J. cotton. Harvard Business School Case GS-48.
Oper. Res. 150(3): 617–639. Pun, H., H. S. Heese. 2010. The value of losing control:
Gilbert, S. M., Y. Xia, G. Yu. 2006. Strategic outsourcing for com- Competition in markets for complements. Naval Res. Logist.
peting OEMs that face cost reduction opportunities. IIE Trans. 57(2): 188–210.
38(11): 903–915. Saigol, K. 2012. Spinners need short-term contracts to manage vol-
Gray, J. V., B. Tomlin, A. V. Roth. 2009. Outsourcing to a power- atility. Available at http://www.cotton247.com/article/
ful contract manufacturer: The effect of learning-by-doing. 27076/spinners-need-short-term-contracts-to-manage-volatility
Prod. Oper. Manag. 18(5): 487–505. (accessed date February 5, 2013).
Guo, L., Y. Liu. 2008. To restrain or to expand: Optimal retail Salop, S. C. 1979. Monopolistic competition with outside goods.
store opening strategies in coping with manufacturer direct Bell J. Econ. 10(1): 141–156.
entry. Working paper, University of Illinois at Urbana–Cham- Trivedi, M. 1998. Distribution channels: An extension of exclusive
paign, Champaign, IL. retailership. Manag. Sci. 44(7): 896–909.
Gupta, S. 2008. Channel structure with knowledge spillovers. Van Mieghem, J. A. 1999. Coordinating investment, production,
Market. Sci. 27(2): 247–261. and subcontracting. Manage. Sci. 45(7): 954–971.
Gupta, S., R. Loulou. 1998. Process innovation, product differenti- Worthen, B., C. Tuna, J. Scheck. 2009. Companies more prone to
ation, and channel structure: Strategic incentives in a duop- go vertical? Available at http://online.wsj.com/article/SB125
oly. Market. Sci. 17(4): 301–316. 954262100968855.html (accessed date February 5, 2013)
Hachman, M. 2012. Want a Seagate drive? Then pay up. Available Wu, C., N. C. Petruzzi, D. Chhajed. 2007. Vertical integration with
at http://www.pcmag.com/article2/0,2817,2399769,00.asp price-setting competitive newsvendors. Decis. Sci. 38(4): 581–610.
(accessed date February 5, 2013)
Xu, X. 2009. Optimal price and product quality decisions in a dis-
Heese, H. S. 2010. Competing with channel partners: Supply chain tribution channel. Manage. Sci. 55(8): 1347–1352.
conflict when retailers introduce store brands. Naval Res.
Logist. 57(5): 441–459.
Ho, L. 2002. Taiwan clothing brands explore global market. Supporting Information
China Post, October 28 Available at http://www.chinapost. Additional Supporting Information may be found in the
com.tw/business/asia/2002/10/28/31764/Taiwan-clothing.htm
(accessed date February 5, 2013).
online version of this article:
Hotelling, H. 1929. Stability in competition. Econ. J. 39(153): 41–
57. Appendix S1: Proofs.
€ Ozer.
Kaya, M., O. € 2009. Quality risk in outsourcing: Noncontract-
ible product quality and private quality cost information.
Naval Res. Logist. 56(7): 669–685.

You might also like