You are on page 1of 83

Is Free Trade Good for the Environment?

By WERNER ANTWEILER, BRIAN R. COPELAND, AND M. SCOTT TAYLOR*

This paper investigates how openness to international goods markets affects pol-
lution concentrations. We develop a theoretical model to divide trade’s impact on
pollution into scale, technique, and composition effects and then examine this theory
using data on sulfur dioxide concentrations. We find international trade creates
relatively small changes in pollution concentrations when it alters the composition
of national output. Estimates of the trade-induced technique and scale effects imply
a net reduction in pollution from these sources. Combining our estimates of all three
effects yields a somewhat surprising conclusion: freer trade appears to be good for
the environment. (JEL F11, Q25)

The debate over the role international trade veloped countries with trade. Empirical work by
plays in determining environmental outcomes James A. Tobey (1990), Gene M. Grossman and
has at times generated more heat than light. Alan B. Krueger (1993), and Adam B. Jaffe et
Theoretical work has been successful in identi- al. (1995) cast serious doubt on the strength of
fying a series of hypotheses linking openness to the simple pollution haven hypothesis because
trade and environmental quality, but the empir- they find that trade flows are primarily deter-
ical verification of these hypotheses has seri- mined by factor endowment considerations and
ously lagged. Foremost among these is the apparently not by differences in pollution abate-
pollution haven hypothesis that suggests rela- ment costs. Does this mean that trade has no
tively low-income developing countries will be effect on the environment?
made dirtier with trade. Its natural alternative, This paper investigates how “openness” to
the simple factor endowment hypothesis, sug- international markets affects pollution levels to
gests that dirty capital-intensive processes will assess the environmental consequences of inter-
relocate to the relatively capital-abundant de- national trade. We develop a theoretical model
to divide trade’s impact on pollution into scale,
technique, and composition effects and then ex-
* Antweiler: Faculty of Commerce, University of British
Columbia, 2053 Main Mall, Vancouver, BC, V6T 1Z2
amine this theory using data on sulfur dioxide
Canada. (e-mail: werner@economics.ca); Copeland: De- concentrations from the Global Environment
partment of Economics, University of British Columbia, Monitoring Project. The decomposition of
997-1873 East Mall, Vancouver, BC, V6T 1Z1 Canada trade’s effect into scale, technique, and compo-
(e-mail: copeland@econ.ubc.ca); Taylor: Department of
Economics, Social Science Building 6448, University of
sition effects has proven useful in other contexts
Wisconsin, 1180 Observatory Drive, Madison, WI 53706 [see Grossman and Krueger (1993); Copeland
(e-mail: staylor@ssc.wisc.edu). An earlier version of this and Taylor (1994, 1995)] and here we move one
paper was circulated under the title, “Trade and the Envi- step forward to provide estimates of their
ronment: Theory and Empirical Results” (August 1997). magnitude.
We express our thanks to, without implicating, P. Beaudry,
D. Green, H. Emery, G. Heal, K. Head, K. Scholz, J. We find that international trade creates rela-
McGregor, two anonymous referees, seminar participants at tively small changes in sulfur dioxide concen-
numerous universities, the NBER Summer Institute Work- trations when it alters the composition, and
shop on Public Policy and the Environment, the NBER hence the pollution intensity, of national output.
Trade, Resources, and the Environment conference, and the
Research Institute for Economics and Business in Kobe,
Combining this result with our estimates of
Japan. Financial support was provided by the SSRHC, the scale and technique effects yields a somewhat
Hampton Fund, and the NSF. surprising conclusion: if trade liberalization
877
878 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2001

raises GDP per person by 1 percent, then pol- For example, under the pollution haven hy-
lution concentrations fall by about 1 percent. pothesis, poor countries get dirtier with trade,
Free trade is good for the environment.1 whereas rich countries get cleaner.3 As a result,
We obtain this conclusion by estimating a very simply adding openness to trade as an additional
simple model highlighting the interaction of factor explanatory variable for pollution (across a
endowments and income differences in determin- panel of both rich and poor countries) is un-
ing the pattern of trade. Our approach, although likely to be fruitful. Instead we look for trade’s
relatively straightforward, is novel in four re- effect by conditioning on country characteris-
spects. First, by exploiting the panel structure of tics. We find that openness conditioned on
our data set, we are able to distinguish empirically country characteristics has a highly significant,
between the negative environmental conse- but relatively small, impact on pollution.
quences of scalar increases in economic activity— Third, we show how to combine economic
the scale effect—and the positive environmental theory with our estimates of scale, composition,
consequences of increases in income that call for and technique effects to arrive at an assessment
cleaner production methods—the technique ef- of the environmental impact of freer trade.
fect. This distinction is important for many rea- Grossman and Krueger’s influential study of
sons.2 Grossman and Krueger (1993) interpret NAFTA presented an argument based on the
their hump-shaped “Kuznets curve” as reflecting relative strength of these same three effects, but
the relative strength of scale versus technique ef- their estimate of the composition effect of trade
fects, but they do not provide separate estimates of was obtained from methods and data unrelated
their magnitude. Our estimates indicate that a 1- to their complementary work estimating the rel-
percent increase in the scale of economic activity ative strength of scale and technique effects.
raises pollution concentrations by 0.25 to 0.5 per- Moreover, their evidence on composition ef-
cent for an average country in our sample, but the fects was specific to the situation of Mexico.
accompanying increase in income drives concen- Here we estimate all three effects jointly on a
trations down by 1.25–1.5 percent via a technique data set that includes over 40 developed and
effect. developing countries.
Second, we devise a method for determining Finally, our approach forces us to distinguish
how trade-induced changes in the composition between the pollution consequences of income
of output affect pollution concentrations. Many growth brought about by increased openness
empirical studies include some measure of from those created by capital accumulation or
openness to capture the impact trade has in technological progress. We find that income
altering the composition (and hence the clean- gains brought about by further trade or neutral
liness) of national output, but there is very little technological progress tend to lower pollution,
reason to believe that openness affects the com- whereas income gains brought about by capital
position of output in all countries similarly. accumulation raise pollution. The key differ-
Both the pollution haven hypothesis and the ence is that capital accumulation necessarily
factor endowment hypothesis predict that open- favors the production of pollution-intensive
ness to trade will alter the composition of na- goods, whereas neutral technological progress
tional output in a manner that depends on a and further trade do not. One immediate impli-
nation’s comparative advantage. cation of this finding is that the pollution con-
sequences of economic growth are dependent
on the underlying source of growth.4
1
Free trade appears to lower sulfur dioxide concentra-
tions for an average country in our sample, but may of
course worsen the environment through other channels. Our
3
evidence is specific to sulfur dioxide; however, sulfur diox- That is, the composition effect of trade for poor coun-
ide emissions are highly correlated with other airborne tries makes them dirtier, whereas the composition effect for
emissions. rich countries makes them cleaner. The full effect of trade
2
For example, income transfers across countries raise may be positive even for poor countries, depending on the
national income but not output, whereas foreign direct in- strength of the technique and scale effects. See, for example,
vestment raises output more than national income. To eval- Proposition 2.
4
uate the environmental consequences of either we need Another more speculative implication of our results is
separate estimates of technique and scale effects. that pollution concentrations should at first rise and then fall
VOL. 91 NO. 4 ANTWEILER ET AL.: IS FREE TRADE GOOD FOR THE ENVIRONMENT? 879

The theoretical literature on trade and the was initiated by early work by Grossman and
environment contains many papers in which Krueger (1993, 1995) and has since produced a
pollution policy differences across countries sizable and fast growing empirical literature
drive pollution-intensive industries to countries examining what has come to be known as the
with lax regulations.5 One criticism of these “Environmental Kuznets curve.”7 Many of
papers is that, although they are successful in these studies also investigate the role of trade by
predicting trade patterns in a world where pol- adding a measure of openness as an additional
icy is fixed and unresponsive, their results may regressor. The defining feature of this literature
be a highly misleading guide to policy in a is its lack of explicit theory. Although the re-
world where environmental protection responds sults from these studies are often interpreted
endogenously to changing conditions. within the context of scale, composition, and
Empirical work by Grossman and Krueger technique effects, they do not provide separate
(1993) suggests that it is important to allow estimates of their magnitudes.
policy to change endogenously with income Our work is most closely related to this
levels, and in our earlier work (Copeland and branch of the literature, but differs in that we
Taylor, 1994, 1995) we investigated how income- employ an explicit theoretical model to guide
induced differences in pollution policy deter- our estimation; we present separate estimates of
mine trade patterns. Although this earlier work scale, composition, and technique elasticities;
produced several insights, it ignored the role and we provide a methodology for adding up
factor abundance could play in determining these effects to assess the environmental impli-
trade patterns. cations of freer trade. Despite the fact that this
In contrast, the model we develop here allows earlier work lacks a formal theory, some of their
income differences and factor abundance differ- conclusions receive support in our work. Most
ences to jointly determine trade patterns. The notably, Grossman and Krueger’s (1993) study
model contains as one limiting case the canon- of NAFTA had at its core the argument that
ical Heckscher–Ohlin–Samuelson (HOS) model technique effects offset scale effects—at least
of international trade and as another limiting for Mexico—and that the composition effect
case a simple pollution haven model. Consider- created by further United States–Mexico trade
ing these two motivations for trade is especially was likely to be driven more by factor endow-
important in an empirical investigation because ment considerations than by differences in en-
many of the most polluting industries are also vironmental regulation. Our work supports
highly capital intensive.6 Moreover, it allows us these conclusions: income effects appear to be
to examine whether changes in dirty goods pro- economically and statistically significant, and
duction brought about by trade is better ex- the trade-induced composition effects are not
plained by factor abundance motives or by driven by differences in pollution regulations.
pollution haven motives arising from an un- There is a second group of studies examining
equal distribution of world income. the link between the costs of pollution abate-
The empirical literature in this area has pro- ment cost and trade flows. This approach was
gressed in three distinct ways. One influential pioneered by Tobey (1990) and was employed
group of studies asks: “How does economic in the context of the NAFTA agreement by
growth affect the environment?”. This literature Grossman and Krueger (1993).8 This branch of
the literature asks a slightly different question:
“How do environmental regulations affect trade
flows?”. Nevertheless some of their results are
with increases in income per capita, if capital accumulation also relevant to our work. For example, a com-
becomes a less important source of growth as development
proceeds. mon result from these studies is that measures
5
For example, Rüdiger Pethig (1976), Horst Siebert et
al. (1980), and Martin C. McGuire (1982) all present models
7
where the costs of pollution-intensive goods are lower in the Some authors refer to it as the Grossman–Krueger
region with no environmental policy. Kuznets Curve. Other early contributions to this literature
6
See Muthukumara Mani and David Wheeler (1997) are Thomas M. Selden and Daqing Song (1994) and Nemat
and Werner Antweiler et al. (1998), Appendix Section B.1, Shafik (1994).
8
for evidence linking capital intensity and pollution intensity. Arik Levinson (1996) reviews this work.
880 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2001

of environmental stringency have little effect on difficult. Additional difficulties arise because
trade flows. This result immediately casts doubt good data on pollution levels are scarce, and
on the pollution haven hypothesis, which holds even the best data reflect not only anthropogenic
that trade in dirty goods primarily responds to influences but also the little-understood natural
cross-country differences in regulations. Al- processes of dispersion and absorption. As a
though our work is quite different in approach consequence, our simple first-generation pollu-
and method, we too find little support for the tion and trade model carries a heavy burden in
pollution haven hypothesis. We do not infer providing us with the structure needed to isolate
from this, however, that the cost of regulations and identify the implications of international
does not matter to trade flows; instead, we sug- trade. Although this is a concern, we suggest
gest it is because other offsetting factors more that earlier empirical investigations failed to
than compensate for the costs of tight regulation find a strong and convincing link between en-
in developed economies. vironmental outcomes and freer trade precisely
Finally, there are those studies that employ because they lacked a strong theoretical under-
either the U.S. Toxic Release Inventory, U.S. pinning. With a more complete theoretical
emission intensity data, or simple rules to cate- framework to guide us, we are able to look in
gorize goods industries as dirty or clean, to the “right directions” for trade’s effect. More-
construct measures of the toxic (or pollution) over, our simple pollution demand-and-supply
intensity of production and trade flows. Work model may play a useful role in focusing future
along these lines includes Patrick Low and Al- efforts in this area.
exander Yeats (1992), Robert E. B. Lucas et al. The rest of the paper is organized as follows.
(1992), and Mani and Wheeler (1997). The In Section I we develop a relatively simple
strength of this branch of the literature is its general equilibrium model of trade to determine
broad cross-country coverage; its weakness is how a fall in trade barriers affects pollution
that this coverage arises from the construction levels. In Section II we then describe our strat-
of data under various assumptions regarding the egy for dealing with econometric difficulties
similarity of emission intensities across coun- and present our estimating equation. In Section
tries. This literature typically asks: “How has III we present our empirical results. Section IV
the pollution intensity of exports or production concludes. Appendices A and B contain proofs
changed over time?” By comparing the answer of propositions and a description of our data. An
to this question across countries differing in additional Technical Appendix, available on re-
development level, income, or trade stance, the quest from the authors, contains further support-
authors hope to identify links between various ing materials.
policy options, country characteristics, and en-
vironmental outcomes. Although this work is I. Theory
useful in documenting trends in the pollution
intensity of output and trade, it cannot answer A. The Model
why these trends exist. Our work differs from
this method by using theory to identify those A population of N agents lives in a small
factors we believe to be crucial to environmen- open economy that produces two final goods, X
tal outcomes, and by using regression analysis and Y, with two primary factors, labor L and
to hold all else equal when evaluating the links capital K. Industry Y is labor intensive and does
between country characteristics and environ- not pollute. Industry X is capital intensive and
mental outcomes. generates pollution as a by-product. We assume
The overall impression one gets from this constant returns to scale, and hence the produc-
literature is that, even though there are many tion technology for X and Y can be described by
interesting findings, a consensus view does not unit cost functions c X (w, r) and c Y (w, r). Let Y
exist—and the path to building such a consen- be the numeraire, and denote the relative price
sus view is unclear. The unsettled nature of the of X by p. Because countries differ in their
literature arises, at least in part, because existing location, proximity to suppliers, and existing
studies are hamstrung by the lack of a well- trade barriers, domestic prices will not be iden-
defined theory. This naturally makes inference tical to world prices. Accordingly we write
VOL. 91 NO. 4 ANTWEILER ET AL.: IS FREE TRADE GOOD FOR THE ENVIRONMENT? 881

(1) p ⫽ ␤ p w, where p N ⫽ p(1 ⫺ ␪ ) ⫺ ␶ e( ␪ ) is the net


producer price for gross output. Because of
where ␤ measures the importance of trade fric- constant returns, the output of an individual
tions and p w is the common world relative price firm is indeterminate, but for any level of
of X. Note ␤ ⬎ 1 if a country imports X and output, the first-order condition for the choice
␤ ⬍ 1 if a country exports X.9 of ␪ implies

Pollution Abatement.—We denote pollution


emissions by Z. Pollution is generated by X (4) p ⫽ ⫺␶ e⬘共 ␪ 兲.
production, but firms have access to an abate-
ment technology. Abatement is costly but uses Hence, we have ␪ ⫽ ␪ ( ␶ /p) with ␪⬘ ⬎ 0 and
the same factor intensities as all other activities we can write emissions per unit output as
in the X industry; hence, we simply treat units
of X as inputs into abatement. If a firm has a
gross output of x units, and allocates x a units to (5) e ⫽ e共 ␶ /p兲,
abatement, then its net output is x n ⫽ x(1 ⫺
␪ ), where ␪ ⫽ x a /x is a measure of the intensity where e⬘ ⬍ 0. The production side equilibrium
of abatement. If pollution is proportional to conditions are simply (2), (4), and the standard
output and abatement is a constant returns ac- zero profit and full employment conditions:
tivity, then we can write pollution emissions as
(6) p N ⫽ c X 共w, r兲 1 ⫽ c Y 共w, r兲
(2) z ⫽ e共 ␪ 兲x,
K ⫽ c rX x ⫹ c rY y L ⫽ cw
X
x ⫹ cw
Y
y.

where e( ␪ ) is emissions per unit of X produced Consumers.—For most of our analysis, con-
and is decreasing in ␪.10 We assume abatement sumers differ only in their preferences over
is worthwhile [e⬘(0) ⫽ ⫺⬁], but with physical pollution. There are two groups in society: N g
limits [e(1) ⬎ 0]. Green consumers who care greatly about the
The government uses pollution emission environment (Greens), and N b ⫽ N ⫺ N g
taxes to reduce pollution. Given the pollution Brown consumers (Browns) who care less about
tax ␶, the profits ␲ x for a firm producing X are the environment. Each consumer maximizes
given by revenue less factor payments, pollu- utility, treating pollution as given. For simplic-
tion taxes, and abatement costs. Using (1) and ity, we write the indirect utility function of a
our definition of ␪, we may write profits suc- consumer in the ith group as
cinctly as

(3) ␲ x ⫽ p N x ⫺ wL x ⫺ rK x ,
(7) V i 共 p, G/N, z兲 ⫽ u 冉 冊
G/N
␳ 共 p兲
⫺ ␦ iz

for i ⫽ { g, b} and where ␦ g ⬎ ␦ b ⱖ 0, G is


9
For example, let ␷ be the level of iceberg transport costs
(that is, ␷ ⬍ 1 is the fraction of the good that arrives at the national income (so G/N is per capita income),
destination when a unit is exported). Then if the good is ␳ ( p) is a price index, and u is increasing and
exported from home, we have p d ⫽ ␷ p w , and if the good is concave. Implicit in (7) is the assumption of
imported, we have p d ⫽ p w / ␷ . Freer trade (an increase in ␷) homothetic preferences over consumption
raises p d if X is exported and lowers p d if X is imported.
10 goods. Pollution is a pure public bad, but
When x units of gross output are produced, and x a
units are devoted to abatement, emissions are given by Greens suffer a greater disutility than Browns. It
E( x a , x). Given our assumptions, E is decreasing in x a , is now convenient to define real per capita in-
increasing in x, strictly convex in x a , and linearly homoge- come as I ⫽ [G/N]/ ␳ ( p) and rewrite indirect
neous in x and x a together. Convexity in abatement inputs utility as simply u(I) ⫺ ␦ i z.
follows from diminishing returns to the variable factor and
implies increasing marginal abatement costs. Linear homo-
geneity follows from constant returns. Using the linear Government.—We model the policy pro-
homogeneity of E, we then write E( x a , x) ⫽ e( ␪ ) x. cess very simply. We assume the government
882 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2001

chooses a pollution tax to maximize a weighted damage per person, and MD iI ⬎ 0 given the
sum of each group’s preferences. It solves concavity of the utility function. Simplifying
allows us to rewrite (9) slightly as:

(8) max N关 ␭ V g ⫹ 共1 ⫺ ␭ 兲V b 兴, (10) ␶ ⫽ T ␾ 共 p, I兲.


We refer to T ⫽ ␭ N ␦ g ⫹ (1 ⫺ ␭ ) N ␦ b as
where ␭ is the weight put on Greens. ␭ may “country type” and T ␾ ( p, I) as effective mar-
vary across governments.11 We introduce this ginal damage (MD). Pollution policy therefore
formulation to allow for the realistic possibility varies with economic conditions and govern-
that government behavior varies across coun- ment type.
tries (perhaps across Communist and non-
Communist countries), while allowing for an B. Pollution Demand and Supply
endogenous link between pollution policy and
economic conditions. Our model yields a relatively simple reduced
The optimal pollution tax maximizes the form linking pollution emissions to a short list
weighted sum of utilities in (8) subject to pri- of (predetermined) economic factors. To isolate
vate sector behavior, production possibilities, the role of trade, it is important to understand
fixed world prices, and fixed trade frictions (see, how these different economic factors affect the
however, Section III, subsection E, for a con- demand for, and supply of, pollution. To do so,
sideration of optimal tariffs). Private sector be- we use the terminology of scale, composition,
havior can be represented by a standard GNP and technique effects. We start by noting the
function giving maximized private sector (net private sector’s demand for pollution is implic-
of tax) revenue as R( p N , K, L). 12 Overall in- itly defined by (2). To rewrite this demand in a
come is private sector revenue plus rebated more convenient form for empirical work, we
taxes G ⫽ R( p N , K, L) ⫹ ␶ z. The first-order define an economy’s scale as the value of na-
condition yields tional output at base-year world prices. In ob-
vious notation, our measure of scale S is
dI dz
u⬘共I兲 ⫺ 关 ␭␦ g ⫹ 共1 ⫺ ␭ 兲 ␦ b 兴 ⫽ 0. (11) S ⫽ p x0 x ⫹ p y0 y.
d␶ d␶

With world prices fixed we have Choosing units so that base-year prices are
unity, we now write pollution emissions as
dI

1
d ␶ N ␳ 共 p兲 冋 R pN
dp N
d␶
⫹z⫹␶
dz
d␶ 册 (12) z ⫽ ex ⫽ e ␸ S,

␶ dz where ␸ is the share of X in total output. Equa-


⫽ .
N ␳ 共p兲 d ␶ tion (12) provides a simple decomposition: pol-
lution depends on the pollution intensity of the
Rearranging our first-order condition now dirty industry e( ␪ ), the relative importance of
yields an amended Samuelson rule: the dirty industry in the economy ␸, and the
overall scale of the economy S. In differential
(9) ␶ ⫽ N关␭MDg共p, I兲 ⫹ 共1 ⫺ ␭ 兲MD b 共 p, I兲兴, form,

where MD i ( p, I) ⫽ ␦ i ␳ ( p)/u⬘ is marginal (13) ẑ ⫽ Ŝ ⫹ ␸ˆ ⫹ ê,

where hats denote percent change. The first


11
For example, if the government is utilitarian, then ␭ ⫽ term is the scale effect. It measures the increase
N g /N; if the government is controlled by the Greens, ␭ ⫽ 1,
and if controlled by Browns, ␭ ⫽ 0. in pollution generated if the economy were sim-
12
See Avinash K. Dixit and Victor Norman (1980) and ply scaled up, holding constant the mix of goods
Alan D. Woodland (1982). produced ␸ and production techniques e( ␪ ).
VOL. 91 NO. 4 ANTWEILER ET AL.: IS FREE TRADE GOOD FOR THE ENVIRONMENT? 883

For example, if all endowments of the economy All elasticities are positive. If we draw this
grew by 10 percent, and if there was no change in derived demand in { z, ␶ }-space, then (17)
the composition of output or emission intensities, shows that an increase in scale, capital abun-
then we should expect to see a 10-percent increase dance, or the world price of dirty goods shifts
in pollution. The second term in (13) is the com- the pollution demand curve to the right. A
position effect. If we hold the scale of the econ- movement of ␤ toward 1 captures a reduction in
omy and emissions intensities constant, then an trade frictions. However, because ␤ is greater
economy that devotes more of its resources to than 1 for a dirty good importer this implies ␤ˆ ⬍
producing the polluting good will pollute more. 0; and because ␤ is less than 1 for a dirty good
Finally, we have the technique effect, captured by exporter, a reduction in trade frictions implies
the last term. All else constant, an increase in the ␤ˆ ⬎ 0. Therefore, a reduction in trade frictions
emission intensity will increase pollution. shifts the pollution demand curve to the right for
We will use a quantity index of output to a dirty good exporter, but to the left for a dirty
measure the scale effect. Because a change in good importer.
prices creates opposing composition and tech- Increases in the pollution tax reduce the
nique effects, however, it is necessary to divide quantity demanded of pollution through two
each into its more primitive determinants. Using channels. First they lower the demand for pol-
(6) we can solve for the share of X in total lution by raising abatement and lowering the
output ␸ as a function of the capital/labor ratio emissions per unit of X produced. This is cap-
␬ ⫽ K/L, the net producer price p N and base- tured by the elasticity ␧ e,p/ ␶ ⬎ 0. Second,
year world prices (suppressed here). That is, the higher pollution taxes lower the producer price
composition of output is ␸ ⫽ ␸ ( ␬ , p N ), and we of X and induce a shift in the composition of
have the composition effect given by output that lowers X output for any given emis-
sions intensity. The strength of this effect de-
(14) ␸ˆ ⫽ ␧ ␸␬ ␬ˆ ⫹ ␧ ␸ p p̂ N , pends on the importance of pollution taxes in
the net producer price (a) and the elasticity of ␸
where the elasticity of ␸ with respect to ␬ and with respect to a change in producer prices,
p N are both positive. Next differentiate p N and ␧ ␸ ,p .
employ (1) and (4) to find Pollution supply is in effect given by govern-
ment policy that sets the price for polluting.
(15) p̂ N ⫽ 共 ␤ˆ ⫹ p̂ w 兲共1 ⫹ a兲 ⫺ a ␶ˆ , From (1) and (10) we obtain a decomposition of
pollution supply:
where a ⫽ e( ␪ ) ␶ /p N . Similarly, using (1) and
(5) we find
(18) ␶ˆ ⫽ T̂ ⫹ ␧ MD,p ␤ˆ ⫹ ␧ MD,p p̂ w ⫹ ␧ MD,I Î,
(16) ê ⫽ ␧ e,p/ ␶ 共 ␤ˆ ⫹ p̂ w ⫺ ␶ˆ 兲,
where ␧ MD,p ⬎ 0 and ␧ MD,I ⬎ 0. If we draw
where the elasticity of emission intensity with (18) in { z, ␶ }-space, then increases in real
respect to p/ ␶ is positive.13 Combining (13)– income, relative prices, or country type shift
(16) we obtain a decomposition of the private the pollution supply curve upward. For exam-
sector’s demand for pollution: ple, if Greens are given a greater weight in
social welfare, or become a larger fraction of
(17) ẑ ⫽ Ŝ ⫹ ␧ ␸ , ␬ ␬ˆ ⫹ 关共1 ⫹ a兲␧ ␸ ,p ⫹ ␧ e,p/ ␶ 兴 ␤ˆ the population over time, then policy becomes
more stringent and pollution supply shifts up-
⫹ 关共1 ⫹ a兲␧ ␸ ,p ⫹ ␧ e,p/ ␶ 兴p̂ w ward. Similarly, an increase in real income
will increase the demand for environmental
⫺ 关a␧ ␸ ,p ⫹ ␧ e,p/ ␶ 兴 ␶ˆ . quality and shift up the pollution supply
curve. An increase in the world relative price
of X makes consumption of market goods
13
It is convenient to define elasticities so that they are
more expensive relative to environmental
positive. Note that e is decreasing in ␶ /p, and therefore protection. This creates a pure substitution
increasing in p/ ␶ . effect toward more environmental protection,
884 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2001

reflected in (18) by ␧ MD,p ⬎ 0. As a result The Trade-Induced Composition Effect.


pollution supply shifts up. An identical sub-
stitution effect is at work when trade frictions PROPOSITION 1: Consider two economies
fall. that differ only in their trade frictions: (i) if
both countries export the polluting good, then
A Reduced Form.—Combining supply in pollution is higher in the country with lower
(17) and demand in (18) yields a simple reduced trade frictions; (ii) if both import the polluting
form linking pollution emissions to a small set good, then pollution is lower in the country with
of economic factors: lower trade frictions.

PROOF:
(19) ẑ ⫽ ␲ 1 Ŝ ⫹ ␲ 2 ␬ˆ ⫺ ␲ 3 Î See Appendix A.
⫹ ␲ 4 ␤ˆ ⫹ ␲ 5 p̂ w ⫺ ␲ 6 T̂, Proposition 1 isolates the trade-induced com-
position effect. The sign of this composition
where all ␲ i are positive, and none of the right- effect differs across countries. For an exporter
hand-side variables are determined simulta- of the polluting good, ␤ rises with freer trade
neously with emissions. Two features of (19) and this raises the relative price of the dirty
warrant further comment. First, because a good X. This shifts a dirty good exporter’s
change in domestic prices shifts pollution sup- pollution demand curve to the right and shifts its
ply and demand in opposing directions, it is not pollution supply curve up. Pollution demand
obvious that ␲4 and ␲5 are positive. We evalu- shifts out for two reasons: the composition of
ate this claim more formally in Proposition 1 national output shifts toward X; and emission
below. Second, we claim “a reduced form” links intensities rise because abatement inputs are
emissions to our economic factors, despite the now more costly. The shift in the pollution
fact that emissions and these same factors are supply curve dampens this increase in pollution
clearly endogenous variables. In our frame- as the pure substitution effect of the goods price
work, emissions are determined endogenously, increase leads the government to raise the pol-
but recursively. As a result, the factors on the lution tax. However, the direct demand-side ef-
right-hand side of (19) are not simultaneously fects swamp the substitution effect in supply,
determined with or by the level of emissions.14 and pollution rises.15 Consequently, holding all
This feature of our simple general equilibrium other determinants of pollution supply and de-
model has the benefit of providing us a simple, mand constant, emissions must rise. This in-
straightforward, and parsimonious reduced crease in emissions represents the trade-induced
form linking pollution emissions to economic composition effect for a dirty good exporter.
determinants. We evaluate our first claim In contrast, ␤ falls with freer trade for an
below. importer of the polluting good. This raises the
relative price of the clean good Y, and again shifts
both pollution demand and supply. Demand-
14
To see this, note that R( p N , K, L) ⫹ ␶ z ⫽ p(1 ⫺ side determinants dominate and emissions fall.
␪ ) x ⫹ y, which is independent of z. Next, note that (4), (6),
and (10) solve for I, ␶ , and ␪, given world prices. With ␶, ␪, This reduction in emissions represents the trade-
and p determined, p N is given. Outputs are determined by induced composition effect for a clean good
p N , and z follows from z ⫽ e( ␪ ) x. This result follows for exporter.
two reasons. First, a society may decide to spend some of its
potential income on improving environmental quality and
the remainder on consumption goods— but higher pollution
does not cause higher real income. Second, because mar-
ginal damage is independent of z, the equilibrium level of 15
To see this, note that the increase in ␶ is less than
emissions does not affect the pollution tax. As a result, a proportional to the increase in ␤, because the increase in ␶
change in emissions does not cause second-order changes in induced by ␤ is a pure substitution effect, which is propor-
the composition of output or our measures of scale and tional to the share of X in consumption (which is less than
income. As a result of these two features, real income, scale, one). This ensures both that emission intensity e rises, and
and the pollution tax are set simultaneously, whereas emis- that the share of X in production rises. Details are in the
sions are set recursively. Appendices.
VOL. 91 NO. 4 ANTWEILER ET AL.: IS FREE TRADE GOOD FOR THE ENVIRONMENT? 885

Proposition 1 therefore implies that, if we


look across all countries and hold other deter-
minants of emissions constant, we should not
expect to find openness per se related in any
systematic way to emissions. Although Propo-
sition 1 is useful, it is limited in two respects.
First, although it isolates the trade-induced
composition effect, any fall in trade frictions
will alter the scale of output and income per
capita of the liberalizing country as well. There-
fore, to account for the full environmental im-
pact of a fall in trade frictions we must also
account for the accompanying scale and tech-
nique effects. Proposition 1 captures the partial
effect of trade liberalization; an overall assess-
ment needs the full effect. Second, the results
from the proposition are conditional on trade
patterns, but the proposition itself is silent on
the determinants of trade patterns. We treat each
of these issues in turn below.

The Full Impact of Openness.—To find the


full impact of a change in trade frictions we
must account for the change created in real
incomes, the scale of output, and its composi-
tion. Differentiate (12) with respect to ␤, hold-
ing world prices, country type, and factor
endowments constant, to find
FIGURE 1. A DIRTY GOOD EXPORTER
dz ␤ dS ␤ dI ␤
(20) ⫽ ␲1 ⫺ ␲3 ⫹ ␲4 .
d␤ z d␤ S d␤ I depict the equilibrium pollution level both be-
fore and after the fall in trade frictions. Recall
A fall in trade frictions produces a scale effect, that z ⫽ e( ␪ ) x. Hence when production is at A,
a technique effect, and the trade-induced com- and emissions intensity is e( ␪ A ), pollution is
position effect, discussed previously. To under- given by z A .
stand how these three effects interact to When trade frictions fall the domestic price
determine the environmental consequences of approaches the world price and production
trade, we employ Figure 1. moves to point C at the new producer price of
In the top panel of Figure 1 we depict the p N⬘ . At C, real income is higher and there is a
production response of a dirty good exporter to change in the techniques of production. The
a fall in trade frictions. In the bottom panel we emissions intensity falls to e( ␪ C ) and overall
depict the pollution consequences of these pollution falls to z C . Our methodology divides
changes. Before the reduction in trade frictions, the movement from z A to z C into three compo-
production is at point A, the world price is p w , nent parts. First, holding both the scale of the
and the net price is p N . We have assumed this economy and the techniques of production
country is an exporter of the dirty good and fixed, trade creates a change in the composition
therefore has consumption at a point to the of output given by the movement from A to B.
northwest of A along the economy’s budget Corresponding to this movement is the increase
constraint (not drawn). Note that the value (in in pollution from z A to z B in the bottom panel.
world prices) of domestic output at A measures This is the trade-induced composition effect
this economy’s scale. In the bottom panel we isolated in Proposition 1.
886 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2001

The movement in the top panel from point B effect and the scale effect are positive. Pollution
to point C is the scale effect. The increase in demand shifts right from these two forces, and
pollution from z B to z S in the bottom panel Proposition 2 indicates that if the policy re-
gives the pollution consequences of this scale sponse is sufficiently weak (an elasticity of mar-
effect. Finally, note that the value of output ginal damage with respect to income less than
measured at world prices rises because of trade one) emissions will rise. That is, the upward
and this real income gain (indirectly) creates the shift in pollution supply is overwhelmed by the
technique effect shown in the bottom panel. The demand shifts. Alternatively, if the elasticity of
technique effect is the fall in pollution from z S marginal damage is sufficiently strong, then
to z C as producers switch to cleaner techniques emissions will fall as the technique effect dom-
with lower emissions intensity. inates. The full effect of a trade liberalization
In total the diagram shows that trade liberal- differs from the partial effect because of two
ization for a dirty good exporter leads to less additional effects, and because these new ef-
pollution if the composition and scale effects fects can be strong enough to overwhelm the
are overwhelmed by the technique effect. Be- composition effect.
cause this is only a possibility, and not a neces-
sity within our model, we formalize our results C. Adding Up Scale, Composition, and
in Proposition 2. Technique Effects

PROPOSITION 2: Consider a small reduction The amount of information required to im-


in trade frictions for our small open economy, plement an adding-up exercise akin to (20) is
then: great. In our empirical work we develop esti-
(i) if the small open economy exports the mates for ␲1 , ␲3 , and ␲4. But even with these
clean good, the full effect of this trade liberal- estimates in hand we are faced with disentan-
ization is to lower pollution emissions; gling the effects of trade liberalization on in-
(ii) if the small open economy exports the come growth from all other potential sources.
dirty good and the elasticity of marginal dam- Because attempts to link trade to growth and
age with respect to income is below one, then income levels are the subject of an already large
the full effect of this trade liberalization is to and somewhat controversial literature, we do
raise its pollution emissions; not attempt to measure trade’s effect on GDP
(iii) if the small open economy exports the (dS/d ␤ ) or GNP per person (dI/d ␤ ). Instead
dirty good and the elasticity of marginal dam- we employ economic theory to add up our es-
age with respect to income is sufficiently above timated scale, composition, and technique ef-
one, then the full effect of this trade liberaliza- fects. Taking factor endowments as fixed, a
tion is to lower its pollution emissions. lowering of transport costs or trade barriers raises
the value of domestic output and real income in a
PROOF: small open economy. The value of output and
See Appendix A. income rise by the same percentage and this cre-
ates both scale and technique effects.17 Therefore,
The first part of the proposition concerns we can simplify (20) slightly and write
dirty good importers. For dirty good importers
the trade-induced composition effect is negative dz ␤ dI ␤
and because X production falls, the sum of (21) ⫽ 关␲1 ⫺ ␲3 兴 ⫹ ␲4 .
composition and scale effects must also be neg- d␤ z d␤ I
ative.16 Consequently, pollution emissions will
fall for a dirty good importer. For a dirty good In some circumstances we can add up these
exporter, both the trade-induced composition three effects to come to an overall assessment of

16
This is a product of our two-good model. With many
17
polluting goods the scale effect may dominate the compo- If GNP differs from GDP because of receipts or pay-
sition effect, leading to a rise in pollution from these two ments from abroad, then we would need to correct for the
sources. (generally small) share of these payments in GNP.
VOL. 91 NO. 4 ANTWEILER ET AL.: IS FREE TRADE GOOD FOR THE ENVIRONMENT? 887

trade without knowledge of trade’s effect on abundance matters to comparative advantage.


income or scale. For example, consider a dirty Similarly, if the environment is a normal
good exporter. Note that dI/d ␤ is positive be- good, then ␧ MD,I is nonzero and real income
cause an increase in ␤ represents lower trade matters as well.
frictions. If we find ␲1 ⬎ ␲3 and ␲4 ⬎ 0, then we
conclude that trade liberalization raises pollution The Role of Factor Endowments.—Standard
for a dirty good exporter: scale effects dominate factor endowment theories predict capital abun-
technique and the trade-induced composition ef- dant countries export capital-intensive goods. In
fect is positive. Under these same circumstances, our model this need not be true because pollu-
trade liberalization would have an ambiguous ef- tion policy can reverse this pattern of trade.
fect on emissions for a clean good exporter. Con- Nevertheless, capital abundance is still a key
sequently, even to implement our more limited determinant of comparative advantage in our
adding-up exercise, it is necessary to ask: who model. Because X is relatively capital intensive,
exports dirty goods and why? an increase in ␬, holding all else constant, in-
creases Home’s relative supply of X, and lowers
Pollution Haven versus Factor Abundance Home’s autarky relative price of X. Using (23)
Motives.—In our model comparative advantage we obtain p̂ ⬍ 0 because ␧␹,␬ ⬎ 0. All else
is primarily a function of relative factor abun- equal, an increase in the abundance of the factor
dance and relative incomes. Although limiting used intensively in the pollution-intensive sec-
cases of our model reflect only pollution haven tor increases the likelihood that a country will
motives or pure factor endowment motives, in be an exporter of pollution-intensive goods. We
general we expect both determinants of com- can show that if the country is sufficiently cap-
parative advantage to matter. To investigate fur- ital abundant, it must export the capital inten-
ther, we solve for autarky prices. Let RD( p) sive (polluting) good:
denote the demand for good X relative to good
Y. Then the relative price of good X is deter- PROPOSITION 3: Suppose the world price p w
mined by the intersection of the (net) relative is fixed. Then, for a given level of real income I,
supply and demand curves there exists a ␬គ such that if ␬ ⬎ ␬គ , then Home
exports X. Moreover, for such a country, the
trade-induced composition effect will be positive.
(22) RD共p兲 ⫽ 共1 ⫺ ␪ 兲 ␹ 共 ␬ , p N 兲,
PROOF:
where ␹ ⫽ x/y is determined from (6), and net See Appendix A.
relative supply is (1 ⫺ ␪)␹. Totally differenti-
ating, using (15), (16), and (18), and rearranging The Role of Income Differences.—An alter-
gives an expression linking autarky prices to native theory of trade patterns is the pollution
real income and endowments: haven hypothesis. According to this view, poor
countries have a comparative advantage in dirty
(23) goods because they have lax pollution policy,
and rich countries have a comparative advan-

p̂ ⫽

␧ MD,I a␧ ␹ ,p N ⫹


1 ⫺ ␪ ␪ , ␶ /p 册
Î ⫺ ␧ ␹ , ␬ ␬ˆ
,
tage in clean goods because of their stringent
pollution policy.18 This result can be obtained
as a special case of our model: if all countries
⌬ have the same relative factor endowments, but
differ in per capita incomes, then richer coun-
where all elasticities and ⌬ are positive. tries will have stricter pollution policy and this
Equation (23) shows that in general, the pat- will lead to a comparative advantage in clean
tern of trade is determined by both factor goods. Using (23) we obtain p̂ ⬎ 0 whenever
abundance and income-driven differences in
pollution policy. For example, unless both the
dirty and clean sectors use identical factor 18
See Copeland and Taylor (1994) for a model that
proportions then ␧␹,␬ is not zero and capital explores this issue.
888 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2001

Î ⬎ 0. When countries differ in factor endow- PROOF:


ments and income levels, we can show that if See Appendix A.
the country is sufficiently rich, it must export the
labor-intensive (clean) good. Proposition 5 links unobservable trade fric-
tions with observable trade intensity. Lower
PROPOSITION 4: Suppose the world price p w trade frictions means greater trade intensity, re-
is fixed and there exists an ␧ such that ␧ MD,I ⬎ gardless of a country’s comparative advantage.
␧ ⬎ 0. Then, for a given level of the capital/ Therefore, in our empirical application we re-
labor ratio ␬, there exists an គI , such that if I ⬎ place unobservable trade frictions with observ-
Iគ , then Home exports Y. Moreover, for such a able trade intensity.20
country, the trade-induced composition effect To address our second question, interpret
will be negative. the hat notation in equation (23) as describing
small differences across countries. With this
PROOF: interpretation, (23) links differences in au-
See Appendix A. tarky relative prices across countries to dif-
ferences in their relative factor abundance and
From Theory to Estimation.—Proposition 1 real income levels. If we take the rest of the
contains a very simple message: comparative world as our small country’s partner in this
advantage matters. If we compare countries exercise, then the strength and direction of
with similar incomes and scale, openness country i’s comparative advantage will de-
should be associated with higher pollution in pend on its capital abundance relative to a
dirty good exporters and lower pollution in dirty world average (denoted by ␬ i ), and its real
good importers. Therefore to isolate the trade- income relative to a world average (denoted
induced composition effect, we must condition by ␫ i ). Although other factors play a role in
on country characteristics. This observation determining comparative advantage, capital
begs three questions: how are we to measure abundance and real income are the key coun-
openness, what country characteristics should try characteristics within our model.
we use, and how should we condition on these Finally, to condition on these characteris-
characteristics? tics we let ⌿ be a function measuring the
Various measures of “openness” exist. We partial effect of an increase in trade intensity
need a measure with both time-series variation on pollution. Our theory tells us that we can
and a wide cross-country coverage. In our the- write ⌿ ⫽ ⌿( ␬ i , ␫ i ), but does not give us
ory a lowering of trade frictions brings domestic much more guidance in this regard. The in-
prices closer to world prices and it does not teraction between factor abundance and pol-
matter whether this occurs because of a fall in lution haven motives depends quite delicately
transport and communication costs or (apart on elasticities of substitution, factor shares,
from revenue effects) because of a GATT- and (unknown) third derivative properties of
inspired reduction in trade restrictions.19 How- our more basic functions. This is apparent
ever, because we do not observe movements in from (23) because the elasticities in this ex-
␤ directly we must make use of an observable pression are functions of prices, incomes, and
consequence of heightened integration: increases trade frictions. Consequently, we adopt a
in a country’s trade intensity ratio (defined as the flexible approach to capturing these influ-
ratio of exports plus imports to GDP valued at ences by adopting a second-order Taylor se-
world prices). We formalize this link below. ries approximation to ⌿ in our empirical
work. That is, we employ
PROPOSITION 5: If preferences over con-
sumption goods are homothetic, trade intensity
rises as ␤ approaches 1. 20
If trade frictions are not exogenous, but are endog-
enously determined along with pollution policy, then our
proxy (trade intensity) may be correlated with unmeasured
determinants of pollution policy. In Section III, subsection
19
See, however, Section III, subsection E, on the tariff- E, we discuss the likely implications of such a link between
substitution effect in a large open economy. trade and pollution policy.
VOL. 91 NO. 4 ANTWEILER ET AL.: IS FREE TRADE GOOD FOR THE ENVIRONMENT? 889

(24) ⌿ i ⬵ ␺ 0 ⫹ ␺ 1 ␬ i ⫹ ␺ 2 ␬ 2i matter, and sea spray. Anthropogenic sources


are thought to be responsible for somewhere
⫹ ␺ 3 ␫ i ⫹ ␺ 4 ␫ 2i ⫹ ␺ 5 ␬ i ␫ i , between one-third to one-half of all emissions
(United Nations Environment Programme,
1991; Jack J. Kraushaar and Robert A. Ristinen,
and then interact this measure with trade intensity 1998). SO2 is primarily emitted as either a di-
to capture the trade-induced composition effect. rect or indirect product of goods production and
This method has several advantages. It allows is not strongly linked to automobile use. Be-
the impact of further openness on pollution to cause energy-intensive industries are also typi-
depend on country characteristics. It does not cally capital intensive, a reasonable proxy for
dictate whether one or both motives are present dirty SO2-creating activities may be physical
in the data or how they interact. And we can capital-intensive production processes. Readily
evaluate ⌿ using our estimates to provide some available, although costly, methods for the con-
simple reality checks. For example, does the trol of emissions exist and their efficacy is well
pollution demand curve shift right for some established. In addition, in many countries SO2
countries and not for others (i.e., does ⌿ i vary emissions have been actively regulated for some
in sign depending on country characteristics)? time.
For which countries does it shift right? Are The Global Environment Monitoring System
these countries poor countries as predicted by (GEMS) has been recording SO2 concentrations
the pollution haven hypothesis, or are they in major urban areas in developed and develop-
capital abundant countries as predicted by the ing countries since the early 1970’s. Our data
factor abundance hypothesis? Finally, the for- set consists of 2,555 observations from 290
mulation is a relatively parsimonious and rea- observation sites located in 108 cities represent-
sonably flexible method for estimating an ing 43 countries spanning the years 1971–1996.
unknown nonlinear function. The GEMS network was set up to monitor the
concentrations of several pollutants in a cross
II. Empirical Strategy section of countries using comparable measur-
ing devices.21 The panel of countries includes
This section describes how we move from primarily developed countries in the early years,
our theory to an estimating equation. To do so but from 1976 to the early 1990’s the United
we need to discuss our data, its sources and Nations Environment Programme provided
limitations (subsection A), and address the links funds to expand and maintain the network. The
between theory and our estimating equation coverage of developing economies grew over
(subsection B). time until the late 1980’s. In the 1990’s cover-
age fell with data from the United States only
A. Data Sources and Measurement Issues for 1996. The World Health Organization
(1984) reports that until the late 1970’s data
A real-world pollutant useful for our purposes comparability may be limited as monitoring ca-
would: (1) be a by-product of goods production; pabilities were being assessed, many new coun-
(2) be emitted in greater quantities per unit of tries were added, and procedures were being
output in some industries than others; (3) have developed to ensure validated samples. Accord-
strong local effects; (4) be subject to regulations ingly, we investigate the sensitivity of our find-
because of its noxious effect on the population; (5) ings to the time period.
have well known abatement technologies avail- The GEMS data are comprised of summary
able for implementation; and (6), for econometric statistics for the yearly distribution of concen-
purposes, have data available from a mix of de- trations at each site. In this study we use the log
veloped and developing as well as “open” and
“closed” economies. An almost perfect choice for 21
this study is sulfur dioxide. The range of sophistication of monitoring techniques
used in the network varies quite widely, but the various
Sulfur dioxide (SO2) is a noxious gas pro- techniques have been subject to comparability tests over the
duced by the burning of fossil fuels. Natural years. Some stations offer continuous monitoring, whereas
sources include volcanoes, decaying organic others measure only at discrete intervals.
890 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2001

of median SO2 concentrations at a given site, or real GDP per person) will be highly or per-
for each year, as our dependent variable. We use fectly correlated with real income per capita that
a log transform because the distribution of shifts pollution supply.
yearly summary statistics for SO2 appears to be We address this problem by exploiting three
lognormal (WHO, 1984). Previous work in this different sources of variation in our data. First, we
area by the WHO and others has argued that a note that changes in the scale of output must have
lognormal distribution is appropriate because contemporaneous effects on pollution concentra-
temperature inversions or other special pollu- tions, whereas pollution policy is likely to respond
tion episodes often lead to large values for some slowly, if at all, to changes in income levels.
observations. In contrast, even weather very Consequently, we use as our proxy for income a
helpful to dissipation cannot drive the level of one-period lagged, three-year moving average of
the pollutant below zero. income per capita, but link pollution concentra-
In addition to the data on concentrations, the tions to a contemporaneous measure of economic
GEMS network also classifies each site within a activity. To the extent that there is significant
city as either city center, suburban, or rural in variation over time in activity measures, this source
land type, and we employ these land-type cate- of variation will help in our identification.22
gories in our analysis. A list of the cities Second, the scale of economic activity should
involved, the years of operation of GEMS sta- be measured by economic activity within a
tions, and the number of observations from each country’s borders (i.e., GDP), whereas the in-
city along with a frequency distribution of SO2 come relevant to the technique effect should
emissions is given in our Technical Appendix reflect the income of residents wherever it is
(available upon request). earned (i.e., GNP). Therefore, we can exploit
In moving from our theoretical model to its the difference between GDP and GNP measures
empirical counterpart we need to include vari- to separate technique from scale effects. Even
ables to reflect scale, technique, and composi- though the gap between these two figures is not
tion effects. As well, we have to include site- large for most economies, it is significant for
specific variables to account for meteorological some. This cross-country variation will be use-
conditions. Our estimations will require the use ful in separating scale from technique.
of data on real GDP per capita, capital-to-labor Finally, we measure the scale of economic
ratios, population densities, and various mea- activity S at any site by an intensive measure of
sures of “openness.” The majority of the eco- economic activity per unit area. This intensive
nomic data were obtained from the Penn World measure is GDP per square kilometer. Lacking
Tables 5.6. The remainder was obtained from detailed data on “Gross City Product,” we con-
several sources. A description of data sources struct GDP per square kilometer for each city
and our methods for collection are provided in and each year by multiplying city population
Appendix B together with a table of means, density with country GDP per person. As a
standard deviations, and units of measurement result, scale is now measured in intensive form,
for the data. as is our dependent variable.23 To explain concen-
trations of pollution we need a measure of scale
B. The Estimating Equation

In moving from our theoretical model to es- 22


For example, we expect that a significant recession
timation we face several issues. Here we discuss would drive down concentrations (a scale effect) but not
three: identification, excluded variables, and lead to a rewriting of pollution control laws (i.e., a technique
effect). This source of variation in pollution data has been
functional form. exploited before. See Kenneth Y. Chay and Michael B.
Greenstone (1999).
Identification.—The private sector’s demand 23
This is admittedly a rough measure of economic activity,
for pollution, written in differential form, is and the quality of this proxy may vary systematically with a
given by (17). The pollution supply curve is country’s development level. To investigate this concern we
have allowed the scale effect to vary across countries divided
given by (18). A problem arises because most by income category, by allowing for nonlinearities in the
measures of the scale of economic activity that response to scale, and by excluding the perhaps most troubling
shifts pollution demand (for example real GDP rural observations. Our results are similar to those reported for
VOL. 91 NO. 4 ANTWEILER ET AL.: IS FREE TRADE GOOD FOR THE ENVIRONMENT? 891

reflecting the concentration of economic activity in the overall population. Because the panel is
within the same geographical area. Other possible relatively short for almost all countries, we take
measures of scale fail this test. Moreover, since we these country-type and distribution parameters
assume pollution policy is determined by national as fixed over time. As well, there are unmea-
averages for income per capita and the number of sured topographical and meteorological features
exposed individuals, we are in effect fixing the that undoubtedly affect the dissipation of pollu-
pollution supply curve for all cities within a given tion at each site. Finally, we allow for an idiosyn-
country. This “allows” us to employ the within- cratic measurement error ␯ijkt. Two sources of this
country variation in scale across cities to separate error would be machine error in reading concentra-
the influence of scale from that of technique. tions and human error in calculation or tabulation.
Throughout we present both fixed- and
Unobservable Variables: Fixed or Random random-effects estimates for every model.
Effects?—Several variables relevant to our the- Whereas random-effects estimation is in theory
ory are unobservable. To account for these ex- more efficient, it is unclear whether excluded
clusions we estimate an individual effects country-specific effects subsumed in our error
model for ␧ ijkt given by term are uncorrelated with our regressors. Al-
though fixed-effects estimation is preferable in
just these cases, fixed effects limits the cross-
(25) ␧ ijkt ⫽ ␰ t ⫹ ␪ ijk ⫹ ␯ ijkt , sectional variation we can exploit for separating
scale from technique effects.
where ␰ t is a time-specific effect, ␪ ijk is a site-
specific effect, and ␯ ijkt is an idiosyncratic mea- Functional Form.—Our model predicts emis-
surement error for observation station i in city j sion levels but our data are on concentrations.
in country k in year t. Meteorological models mapping emissions from a
Our common-to-world but time-specific ef- (single) stack into measured concentrations at a
fect is included to capture changes in knowl- receptor are functions of emission rates, stack
edge concerning pollution, changes in the world height, the distance to the receptor, wind speed,
relative price of dirty goods, and improvements temperature gradients, and turbulence. Much of
in abatement technologies. Although proxies for this information is not presently available. In view
some of these variables could be constructed, of these limitations we adopt a linear approxima-
choosing proxies will of course introduce new tion to measured concentrations by writing con-
issues of data quality, coverage, and so forth. centrations at site ijk, at time t as
Instead we note that, because each of these
variables affects all countries in a similar way, a
preferred method may be to treat them as un- (26) Z Cijkt ⫽ X⬘j kt ␣ ⫹ Y⬘i jkt ␥ ⫹ ␧ ijkt
observable. For example, a rise in the world X⬘jkt ␣ ⫽ ␣ 0 ⫹ ␣ 1 SCALEjkt ⫹ ␣ 2 KLkt
price of dirty goods affects all countries in a
similar way. Accordingly, we capture these ⫹ ␣ 3 INCkt ⫹ ␣ 4 ⌿ kt TIkt
common-to-world excluded variables with a set
of unrestricted time dummies. ⌿ kt ⫽ ␺ 0 ⫹ ␺ 1 REL.KLkt
␪ ijk is a site-specific effect representing ex-
cluded site (or country-specific) variables such ⫹ ␺ 2 REL.KL2kt
as excluded economic determinants or excluded
meteorological variables. For example, country
⫹ ␺ 3 REL.INCkt
type T appears in (19) but is virtually unobserv-
able in that it relies on both knowledge of the
⫹ ␺ 4 REL.INC2kt
weight governments apply to Greens and
Browns in their economy and the share of each
⫹ ␺ 5 REL.KLkt REL.INCkt ,

our simpler specification. For one such sensitivity test see where SCALE is city-specific GDP/km2, KL is
Table 2. the national capital-to-labor ratio, INC is a
892 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2001

one-period-lagged three-year moving average as regressors, leaving out a role for factor en-
of GNP/N, TI is the trade intensity (X⫹M)/ dowments or scale to play independent effects.
GDP, REL.KL is country k’s capital-to-labor Grossman and Krueger (1993, 1995) are the
ratio measured relative to the world average, most prominent examples of this approach, but
and REL.INC is country k’s real income mea- there are many others. Lewis Gale and Jose A.
sured relative to the world average (see Appen- Mendez (1998) add measures of factor endow-
dix B for further details). Note that world price ments to a Kuznet’s curve regression, but their
and country-type variables are captured in (25), (one-year) cross-sectional analysis cannot dis-
and trade intensity has replaced trade frictions tinguish between constant-over-time site at-
in (19), as discussed previously. Y contains tributes and scale effects. Empirical work using
site-specific weather variables and site-specific (constructed) cross-country emission data or
physical characteristics (discussed below), and emission intensity data has tried to link country
␧ ijkt is a site-specific error reflecting unmea- characteristics (factor endowments, growth in
sured economic and physical variables. We re- income, fuel use, etc.) to environmental out-
fer to equation (26) as Model A in our comes, but these studies always fail to condi-
estimations. tion the impact of openness on country
Model A follows from our reduced form if characteristics. For example, see Low and
we assume linearity in the response to scale, Yeats (1992) and Lucas et al. (1992). As a
technique, and composition variables. This lin- result, we are not aware of even one study
earity assumption is, however, somewhat at where the impact of trade is conditioned on
odds with our theory. In theory, the impact of those country characteristics determining
capital accumulation on pollution depends on comparative advantage, despite the fact that
the techniques of production in place. But when the trade-induced composition effect should
countries differ in income per capita, they will vary across countries according to compara-
also differ in producer prices and hence their tive advantage.
techniques of production. Consequently, the
Rybczyinski derivatives embedded in (26) will III. Empirical Results
differ across countries. As well, the impact of
capital accumulation on the composition of out- A. Main Results
put is not a linear function of KL. Similarly, the
impact of income gains on pollution depends on Table 1 presents the main results from our
the existing composition of output and hence estimations. We present estimates from Models
the existing capital-to-labor ratio and income A, B, and C in Table 1 using both random and
per capita. To account for these possibilities we fixed effects.
amend Model A by adding the squares of in-
come per capita (INC2kt ) and the capital-to-labor Scale, Composition, and Technique Effects.—
ratio (KL2kt ) as well as their cross-product Consider our core variables representing scale,
(INCkt KLkt ). We refer to this amended form of composition, and technique effects. In all col-
(26) as Model B. As a consequence, the impact umns of Table 1 we find a positive and signif-
of factor accumulation can now differ across icant relationship between the scale of
countries and over time in closer accord with economic activity as measured by GDP/km2
our theory. Finally, we consider a further non- and concentrations. From the bottom of Table
linearity by adding SCALE2kt to Model B. A 1 we see that the coefficient estimates imply a
nonlinearity in the impact of scale could arise sample-mean elasticity of concentrations to an
from nonhomotheticities in production or con- increase in scale somewhere between 0.1 and
sumption. We refer to this slightly amended 0.4. The scale elasticity estimates increases in
model as Model C. magnitude as we move from Model A through
Models A, B, and C differ from those previ- to Model C, although the estimates differ only
ously estimated in several regards. For example, slightly across random and fixed effects. Be-
empirical work within the Environmental cause the models are nested, we can test the
Kuznets curve tradition employ measures only restrictions imposed in Models A and B via a
of site-specific attributes and income per capita likelihood ratio (LR) test. It appears there is
VOL. 91 NO. 4 ANTWEILER ET AL.: IS FREE TRADE GOOD FOR THE ENVIRONMENT? 893

TABLE 1—ALTERNATIVE HYPOTHESES TESTS

Estimation method: Random effects Fixed effects


Model specification: A B C A B C
Variable/column: (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Intercept ⫺2.865*** ⫺3.279*** ⫺3.311*** ⫺2.506*** ⫺4.324*** ⫺4.299***
City economic intensity GDP/km2 0.042*** 0.058*** 0.070*** 0.024* 0.058*** 0.089*
(City economic intensity)2/1,000 ⫺0.244 ⫺0.340
Capital abundance (K/L) 0.102** 0.293** 0.286* 0.165** 0.461** 0.437*
(K/L)2 0.014 0.013 0.006 0.008
Lagged per capita income ⫺0.982*** ⫺1.248*** ⫺1.312*** ⫺1.326*** ⫺0.096 ⫺0.228
(Income)2 0.708*** 0.669*** 0.559*** 0.578***
(K/L) ⫻ (I) ⫺0.309*** ⫺0.285*** ⫺0.381*** ⫺0.386***
Trade intensity TI ⫽ (X⫹M)/GDP ⫺0.915 ⫺0.488 ⫺0.510 ⫺3.677*** ⫺3.142** ⫺3.216**
TI ⫻ REL.K/L ⫺0.462 ⫺1.952* ⫺1.828* 0.159 ⫺2.252* ⫺2.121
TI ⫻ (REL.K/L)2 0.018 ⫺0.230 ⫺0.248 ⫺0.168 ⫺0.123 ⫺0.176
TI ⫻ REL.INC 0.470 1.056* 1.011* 2.128** 2.687*** 2.614***
TI ⫻ (REL.INC)2 0.118 ⫺0.308* ⫺0.285* ⫺0.108 ⫺0.595** ⫺0.584**
TI ⫻ (REL.K/L) ⫻ (REL.INC) ⫺0.165 0.870*** 0.822*** ⫺0.280 0.900** 0.924**
Suburban dummy ⫺0.299 ⫺0.435* ⫺0.422*
Rural dummy ⫺0.623 ⫺0.674 ⫺0.631
Communist country (C.C.) dummy 0.312 ⫺0.252 ⫺0.257
C.C. dummy ⫻ income ⫺0.283 4.569* 4.641* 1.170 9.621** 9.639**
C.C. dummy ⫻ (income)2 ⫺5.755** ⫺5.788** ⫺8.931*** ⫺8.806**
Average temperature ⫺0.055*** ⫺0.052*** ⫺0.052*** ⫺0.060* ⫺0.057* ⫺0.056*
Precipitation variation: 3.446 5.860 6.158 8.599 10.810* 10.716*
Helsinki Protocol: ⫺0.232* ⫺0.092 ⫺0.114 ⫺0.179 0.016 0.016

Observations 2,555 2,555 2,555 2,555 2,555 2,555


Groups 290 290 290 290 290 290
R2 0.3395 0.3737 0.374 0.2483 0.131 0.1499
Log-likelihood ⫺2550 ⫺2523 ⫺2522 ⫺3964 ⫺3906 ⫺3905
LR test/␹2 (df) 55.596*** 1.604 118.42*** 2.035
Hausman test/Wald ␹2 (df) 65.761** 15.158 53.789

Scale elasticity 0.192*** 0.265*** 0.315*** 0.112* 0.266*** 0.398**


Composition elasticity 0.583** 0.948*** 0.993*** 0.945** 1.006** 0.975*
Technique elasticity ⫺0.905*** ⫺1.577*** ⫺1.577*** ⫺1.222*** ⫺1.153** ⫺1.266**
Trade intensity elasticity ⫺0.436*** ⫺0.388*** ⫺0.394*** ⫺0.641*** ⫺0.864*** ⫺0.882***

Notes: To conserve space, no standard errors or t-statistics are shown. The dependent variable is the log of the median of SO2
concentrations at each observation site. Model A follows directly from our empirical implementation, whereas model B allows
for additional interaction between capital abundance and income. In addition to model B, model C allows for nonlinearity in
our scale variable. All model specifications use time-fixed effects. Elasticities are evaluated at sample means using the Delta
method.
* Significance at the 95-percent confidence level.
** Significance at the 99-percent confidence level.
*** Significance at the 99.9-percent confidence level.

little gained in moving to the slightly more Next consider the impact of a nation’s capital-
general Model C from Model B; conversely, the to-labor ratio. In all columns of Table 1, we find
restrictions imposed by Model A are rejected by a positive composition effect arising from an
the data as shown by the significant LR test increase in capital-to-labor ratios. The esti-
statistics in columns (1) and (4). These empiri- mated effect is typically quite large. With the
cal results together with our knowledge of the- exception of column (1), we find a 1-percent
ory suggest that less emphasis be placed on the increase in a nation’s capital-to-labor ratio—
estimates from Model A. holding scale, income, and other determinants
894 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2001

constant—leads to perhaps a 1-percent-point in- haven and factor abundance motives. We


crease in pollution. Our success in finding a link present several methods of evaluation below.
between factor endowments and pollution may
appear surprising given the universal difficulties Site-Specific and Country-Type Consider-
researchers have had in finding a strong link ations.—Because income gains may not equally
between factor endowments and trade flows. translate into policy responses we note it is
We would note, however, that the production important to distinguish between Communist
side of the HOS model has received some sup- and non-Communist countries. The Communist
port (see especially James Harrigan 1995, country interactions with income and income
1997), and our model focuses on a highly ag- squared in Models B and C suggest that the
gregate relationship between overall pollution technique effect is very small or nonexistent in
intensive output and factor endowments. Communist countries. For example, using the
The estimates in Table 1 also predict a strong fixed-effects results from column (6), we cannot
and significantly negative relationship between reject the hypothesis of a zero technique effect
per capita income levels and concentrations. in Communist countries! In the random-effects
The elasticity of concentrations to an increase in case in column (3), the technique elasticity is
income is typically quite large and is always fully one-third of that for our average, non-
significant. Using the estimates from Table Communist country.25 We investigated other
1, the technique elasticity varies between ⫺0.9 country-type effects by including a dummy
and ⫺1.5. This technique effect seems surpris- variable for those years a country was bound by
ingly strong, but the result appears to be robust. the Helsinki protocol on acid rain. Our results
Alternative specifications (discussed below) indicate this variable has little explanatory
lead to somewhat different conclusions, al- power. The results, however, do indicate that
though the elasticity is almost universally esti- site-specific land use and weather variables
mated to be greater than ⫺1 in magnitude, have a bearing on concentrations as expected.
suggesting a strong policy response to income Higher temperatures both dissipate pollution
gains. faster and reduce the need for home heating;
precipitation highly concentrated in one season
The Trade-Induced Composition Effect.— reduces the ability of rain to wash out
Next consider the estimates for the trade- concentrations.
induced composition effect. In all columns we
reject the hypothesis that the terms reflecting the B. Discussion and Evaluation
trade-induced composition effect are jointly
zero.24 Although the sign and significance of Although the results in Table 1 appear to be
some individual coefficients vary across speci- supportive of our theory, it is important to go
fications, the results from Model B and Model C beyond sign and significance tests to investigate
in both random and fixed effects are very sim- whether the magnitude of these estimates are in
ilar. At the sample mean, the overall elasticity some sense plausible. We pursue several of
of concentrations to an increase in trade inten- these reality checks below.
sity is relatively constant, ranging from approx- To start note that the implied scale, compo-
imately ⫺0.4 to ⫺0.9. Therefore, for an average sition, and technique elasticities are not implau-
country in our sample the trade-induced com- sibly high, and all are significantly different
position effect is negative. Considering the in- from zero. Together these elasticities provide
dividual coefficients, it is clear that country some simple reality checks. For example, sup-
characteristics describing both relative income pose our average economy experienced neutral
and abundance are important, but it is difficult technological progress of 1 percent, raising
to evaluate the relative strength of pollution both GDP and GNP per person by 1 percent.

24 25
This is in contrast to the case where trade intensity The technique elasticity in the random-effects case is
appears alone or is replaced by other measures of “open- much smaller ⫺0.50 but is significantly different from zero;
ness.” We investigated this issue more fully in Antweiler et the technique elasticity in the fixed-effects case is ⫺0.062
al. (1998 Table 2 p. 29). with a 95-percent confidence interval of [⫺0.90, 0.78].
VOL. 91 NO. 4 ANTWEILER ET AL.: IS FREE TRADE GOOD FOR THE ENVIRONMENT? 895

According to our estimates from Table 1, the elasticities against relative income using esti-
positive scale effect from this growth will al- mates from Model B in columns (2) and (5) of
ways be dominated by the negative technique Table 1. Although there are more positive elas-
effect.26 Although the estimates differ across ticities in Figure 2 than 3, in both there is a
columns, in all cases our results indicate neutral distribution of elasticities around zero. Our in-
technological progress lowers pollution concen- ference is simply that some countries’ pollution
trations. Alternatively, when an increase in in- demand shifts right with a fall in trade frictions
come and production is fueled entirely by and some shift left because countries differ in
capital accumulation, the picture is far less fa- their comparative advantage.28 For example,
vorable to the environment. If we assume a from either Figure 2 or Figure 3 we would
share of capital in output of 1⁄3 , then the full conclude a small trade liberalization in Canada,
impact of capital accumulation working through all else equal, shifts its pollution demand curve
scale, composition, and technique effects is to to the right. The inference is that, despite Can-
raise pollution concentrations.27 Even though ada’s relatively high income, its comparative
these two exercises are not tests of our theory, advantage lies in capital-intensive dirty prod-
the results are reassuringly close to what we ucts. Alternatively, we would conclude a small
may have expected ex ante. trade liberalization in India shifts its pollution
To assess the plausibility of our trade inten- demand curve to the left, the inference being
sity elasticity, we calculated the trade intensity that, despite its relatively low income, its com-
elasticity for all countries in our sample. From parative advantage lies in labor-intensive and
Proposition 1 we note that the sign of the trade- relatively clean goods production. Although
induced composition effect should reflect a these two countries estimates may accord well
country’s comparative advantage in clean ver- with our intuition, other country-specific elas-
sus dirty goods. Therefore it is not plausible that ticities are harder to explain [e.g., why is Ma-
all countries in the world have negative trade laysia’s elasticity (MYS) so negative and
intensity elasticities. Although we have only a Switzerland’s (CHE) so positive?]. Because our
sample of countries it seems reasonable to ex- country-specific estimates do vary across spec-
pect both positive and negative elasticities. ifications, we caution the reader from drawing
As a check on our theory we present in Fig- too strong an inference from any one of them.
ures 2 and 3 below a plot of country-specific
Pollution Haven and Factor Abundance
Motives.—The second feature of note in Figures
26
Holding input use constant (capital, labor, and pollu- 2 and 3 is that the elasticity estimates increase
tion), neutral technological progress raises output in our with relative income. Note that if the simple
model. Each unit of pollution is more productive than be- pollution haven hypothesis were literally true
fore, and this via a scale effect argues for more pollution.
Because real incomes are now higher, however, pollution
and the sole determinant of trade in dirty prod-
may in fact fall from a technique effect. Whether we have ucts, we would expect just the opposite—a
more or less pollution in equilibrium after the shock there- strong negative correlation between relative in-
fore depends on the relative strength of these two effects.
27
come and the magnitude of our country-specific
Take, for example, the estimates from column (6). elasticities. This is because, under the pollution
Then our estimates indicate that a 1-percent increase in the
capital-to-labor ratio raises concentrations by perhaps 1 haven hypothesis, poor countries specialize in
percent, all else equal. However, an increase in the capital- dirty goods and rich countries specialize in
to-labor ratio will have accompanying impacts on the scale clean goods. A small movement toward free
of economic activity and on real incomes. If we make a trade would shift the pollution demand curve
back-of-the-envelope calculation by taking capital’s share
in the value of domestic output at 1/3, then capital accumu-
inward for a rich country and outward for a poor
lation leading to a 1-percent increase in the capital-to-labor country. In fact, as shown in the figures, the
ratio creates a 1/3-percentage-point increase in GDP per relationship is definitely nonnegative and, in
capita and GDP/km2. Therefore, capital accumulation also
creates an induced technique effect of approximately ⫺1.2/
3 ⫽ ⫺0.4 and an induced scale effect of perhaps 0.13 ⫽ 28
The random-effects implementation in Figure 2 has
0.39/3. Adding the direct composition effect to these esti- more positive point elasticities than the fixed effects in
mates suggests that economic growth fueled entirely by Figure 3, but relatively minor changes in specifications
capital accumulation raises pollution concentrations. moves the entire set of fixed-effects estimates upward.
896 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2001

FIGURE 2. COUNTRY-SPECIFIC TRADE ELASTICITIES [MODEL B, RANDOM EFFECTS, CORRESPONDING TO TABLE 1 COLUMN (2)]

fact, slightly positive.29 It appears that if any- gues in favor of trade lowering the pollution
thing, high-income countries have a comparative intensity of output, whereas the latter argues in
advantage in dirty capital-intensive products. favor of trade raising it.
In total, although changes in trade intensity Judging from Figure 2 and 3 it appears that, if
seem to matter, the magnitude of the induced anything, factor endowment motives are offset-
change in pollution concentrations appears rel- ting tighter pollution policy in relatively rich
atively small. In Figure 2 the vast majority of countries. This may explain why other investi-
countries have trade intensity elasticities less gations have failed to find a significant rela-
than 1 in absolute value; in Figure 3 the major- tionship between the strictness of pollution
ity of countries also satisfy this requirement. regulations and decreased trade in capital-
One explanation for these findings is simple: intensive dirty goods. It may also explain why
low-income countries typically have both low previous researchers have found it quite difficult
incomes per capita and low capital-to-labor ra- to find pollution haven effects in the data. It is
tios. The pollution haven hypothesis suggests not that the (ceterus paribus) pollution haven
that a low-income economy should be made hypothesis is wrong, or that the (ceterus pari-
dirtier by trade, but if pollution-intensive indus- bus) factor endowment driven basis for trade is
tries are also capital-intensive then, whatever absent. But rather, because these two partial
benefits accrue from lax pollution regulation theories work against each other, the net result
could be largely undone by the relatively higher of the potentially very large composition effects
price of capital in this capital-scarce country. As predicted by either theory turn out to be rather
a result, further openness to trade will have a small in practice.
very small effect on the pollution intensity of
output for low-income countries. Similarly, C. An Environmental Assessment
high-income countries have both high income of Freer Trade
and high capital-to-labor ratios. The former ar-
Taking factor endowments as fixed, a lower-
ing of transport costs or trade barriers raises the
29
Even excluding the strongly negative elasticities of
value of domestic output and real income in a
Malaysia (MYS) and Iraq (IRQ), the relationship is signif- small open economy. The value of output and
icantly positive in both Figures 2 and 3. the value of income rise by (approximately) the
VOL. 91 NO. 4 ANTWEILER ET AL.: IS FREE TRADE GOOD FOR THE ENVIRONMENT? 897

FIGURE 3. COUNTRY-SPECIFIC TRADE ELASTICITIES [MODEL B, FIXED EFFECTS, CORRESPONDING TO TABLE 1 COLUMN (5)]

same percentage, and this creates both scale and elsewhere in the world. Given that countries
technique effects. Using the estimates from ei- will differ somewhat in their particular elastic-
ther Model B or Model C in Table 1, the net ities, some may indeed be made dirtier from a
effect of a 1-percent change in income created reduction in trade frictions, but we expect that
by trade is a 0.8 – 0.9-percent fall in emissions: trade’s effect—whether positive or negative—
that is, using (21) we have ␲1 ⫺ ␲3 ⬍ 0. The will be small.31 After all, the estimated impact
composition effect of trade for our average of even a large trade liberalization on GDP is
country is also negative; that is, from (21) we small, and when this small increase in GDP is
have ␲4 ⬍ 0. Therefore, for an average country filtered through our estimated scale and tech-
in our sample, the full impact of further open- nique elasticities, the net effect is likely to be
ness to international trade—through scale, tech- smaller still. Although, in theory, trade’s impact
nique, and composition effects—will be a on the pollution intensity of output can be large,
reduction in SO2 concentrations! in practice our estimates suggest a much more
Similar results follow from all of our speci- muted response.
fications: the scale elasticity is dominated by the These conclusions, however, rely on our
technique elasticity, whereas the trade-induced assumption that factor endowments and tech-
composition effect of trade is typically small in nology remain fixed when trade frictions fall.
magnitude.30 How large a reduction any one
country reaps from a fall in trade frictions will, 31
of course, depend on country characteristics, the Averaging across countries and years, the average
trade intensity is 41 percent with a standard deviation of 32
impact further trade has on domestic income percentage points. A one-standard-deviation change in trade
and output, and how the ongoing process of intensity is then equal to a 79 percent change in trade
globalization is affecting country characteristics intensity from its average value, whereas a one-standard-
deviation change in pollution concentrations is equivalent to
a 203-percent change from its average value. Using our
fixed-effects estimate of the trade intensity elasticity from
30
In the Technical Appendix we investigate a two- Table 1, column (6), a 79-percent increase in trade intensity
equation two-stage least-squares (2SLS) fixed-effects model amounts to a 69-percent reduction in pollution concentra-
where our city scale measure and pollution are determined tions, or about one-third of a standard deviation of pollution
simultaneously. We find a scale elasticity in excess of 1, but concentration. Using the random-effects estimate from col-
also a much larger technique elasticity (approaching ⫺2). umn (3) in Table 1, the same one-standard-deviation change
As a result, our conclusion on their relative magnitude in trade intensity amounts to a change of less than one-sixth
remains unchanged. of the standard deviation in pollution concentration.
898 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2001

If further trade spurs capital accumulation or tio. Other potential factor endowments were
brings knowledge spillovers and hastens tech- excluded because, even though they are un-
nological progress, then other calculations doubtedly relevant to income levels, there is
must come into play. Whether these trade- little reason to believe that they have an inde-
induced changes bring about a net improve- pendent effect on either the demand for a clean
ment in the environment will depend on their environment or the derived demand for pollu-
estimated size because they have opposing tion emissions; however, local abundance either
effects on pollution concentrations. There is a in clean or dirty fuels may affect emissions. We
burgeoning empirical literature linking open- investigate this possibility by adding in columns
ness to growth and technology adoption and we (2) and (6) country-specific measures of hard
have nothing new to add here. But clearly our and soft coal deposits per worker. Overall the
estimates, together with input from these other results support our earlier conclusions.
sources, might provide another method for assess- Although a greater endowment of high sulfur
ing trade’s full impact. soft coal leads to more concentrations, at least in
the random-effects implementation in column (2),
D. Alternative Specifications this effect disappears in the fixed-effects estima-
tion in column (6). These results are not surpris-
The results from Table 1 and Figures 2 and 3 ing: an abundance of soft coal means that
suggest that our approach of dividing the deter- countries like China will have higher concentra-
minants of pollution into scale, technique, and tions, all else equal, but because mineral endow-
composition effects is fruitful. It is, however, ments have very little time series variation they
important to investigate whether our results are will be well captured by country fixed effects.
robust to reasonable changes in specification, Consequently, although abundance of high sulfur
time period, and so forth. We have conducted coal surely adds to emissions, its explicit inclusion
numerous sensitivity tests of our specification has very little effect on our results.
and report four alternatives in Table 2. Addi- In columns (3) and (6) we investigate the
tional results are available in our Technical Ap- impact foreign direct investment may have on
pendix, available upon request from the authors. our results. If multinational corporations have
In all columns we amend our full Model C from common production methods in both developed
Table 1 to include other determinants, investi- and developing countries for engineering, qual-
gate other time periods, or adopt more flexible ity control, or other reasons, then the pollution
specifications. intensity of their production will be determined
In columns (1) and (5) we have restricted by the income per capita of the source country.
the time period of our analysis to the years As a result, a larger multinational presence in a
1976 –1991. Before 1976 only a few countries poor country may mean it is cleaner, all else
participated and after funding ceased in 1991 equal; however, there is an alternative hypoth-
country coverage is reduced. To allow for esis working in the other direction. If multina-
possible data quality and sample selection tionals locate in poor countries because of their
problems we consider this shorter time pe- lax environmental protection, then we may in-
riod. This shortened period has 489 fewer stead find a positive relationship between for-
observations, although as shown in columns eign direct investment (FDI) and pollution. To
(1) and (5) the results are similar both in investigate this issue we have calculated for
terms of elasticity estimates and significance each year and country in our sample the ratio of
levels. Our overall conclusions regarding the its inward stock of FDI to its overall capital
relative strength of scale versus technique stock.32 We refer to this as FDI intensity: it
effects remains, as does the muted response to measures the share of the domestic capital stock
changes in trade intensity.
In columns (2) and (6) we investigate the 32
importance of other factor endowments. In our In theory we may want to distinguish between acqui-
sitions of brownfields, capacity expansions, and greenfield
parsimonious model of pollution demand and investments because greenfield investors are perhaps more
supply “factor endowments” enter directly only likely to bring their own plant-specific technology to the
through the inclusion of the capital-to-labor ra- foreign country.
VOL. 91 NO. 4 ANTWEILER ET AL.: IS FREE TRADE GOOD FOR THE ENVIRONMENT? 899

TABLE 2—SENSITIVITY TESTS

Estimation method: Random effects Fixed effects

Model specification: Time Factors FDI Scale Time Factors FDI Scale
Variable/column: (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Intercept ⫺2.545*** ⫺3.141*** ⫺3.650*** ⫺3.635*** ⫺1.697 ⫺4.679*** ⫺4.679*** ⫺4.345***


City economic intensity GDP/km2 0.068*** 0.075*** 0.070*** 0.154*** 0.091* 0.087* 0.092* 0.029
(City economic intensity)2/1,000 ⫺0.054 ⫺0.275 ⫺0.231 ⫺0.254 ⫺0.329 ⫺0.373
Capital abundance (K/L) ⫺0.115 0.289* 0.439*** 0.279* ⫺0.077 0.426* 0.754*** 0.489**
(K/L)2 0.036** 0.012 ⫺0.002 0.010 0.032 0.008 ⫺0.024 0.006
Lagged per capita income ⫺1.771*** ⫺1.629*** ⫺1.451*** ⫺0.852* ⫺3.109** ⫺0.428 ⫺0.981 ⫺0.052
(Income)2 0.585*** 0.717*** 0.660*** 0.611*** 0.512* 0.757*** 0.563*** 0.564***
(K/L) ⫻ (I) ⫺0.147* ⫺0.276*** ⫺0.255*** ⫺0.278*** ⫺0.041 ⫺0.401*** ⫺0.297*** ⫺0.400***
Trade intensity TI ⫽ (X⫹M)/GDP ⫺2.466*** ⫺0.671 ⫺0.198 ⫺0.501 ⫺7.161*** ⫺3.333** ⫺3.747*** ⫺2.964**
TI ⫻ REL.K/L 0.934 ⫺1.758* ⫺2.879** ⫺1.890* 1.699 ⫺2.281* ⫺2.737* ⫺2.541*
TI ⫻ (REL.K/L)2 ⫺0.876** ⫺0.252 0.304 ⫺0.142 ⫺1.043** ⫺0.131 0.811 ⫺0.112
TI ⫻ REL.INC. 1.344** 1.167* 1.518** 1.212* 4.495*** 3.097*** 2.720** 2.677***
TI ⫻ (REL.INC.)2 ⫺0.228 ⫺0.309* ⫺0.308* ⫺0.354** ⫺0.742** ⫺0.723*** ⫺0.360 ⫺0.617**
TI ⫻ (REL.K/L) ⫻ (REL.INC.) 0.333 0.803*** 0.519 0.784** 0.164 0.922** 0.092 0.993**
Suburban dummy ⫺0.284 ⫺0.424* ⫺0.445* ⫺0.490**
Rural dummy ⫺0.519 ⫺0.620 ⫺0.655 ⫺0.730*
Inward FDI stock/capital stock 0.039 1.234*
FDI/K ⫻ poor countries 4.736 6.314
FDI/K ⫻ rich countries ⫺0.362 ⫺0.828
Communist country (C.C.) dummy ⫺0.971* ⫺0.326 ⫺0.110 ⫺0.475
C.C. dummy ⫻ income 7.785*** 4.602* 4.201 5.668** 16.809*** 11.751*** 10.271** 9.819**
C.C. dummy ⫻ (income)2 ⫺8.683*** ⫺5.683* ⫺5.677* ⫺7.127** ⫺14.13*** ⫺10.84*** ⫺8.840** ⫺9.039***
Average temperature ⫺0.061*** ⫺0.056*** ⫺0.051*** ⫺0.052*** ⫺0.072* ⫺0.055* ⫺0.049 ⫺0.062*
Precipitation variation 8.867* 5.859 7.633 5.882 14.298** 10.893* 13.972** 11.471*
Hard coal (per worker) ⫺0.690 4.217
Soft coal (per worker) 2.998* 4.120
Helsinki Protocol ⫺0.242* ⫺0.157 ⫺0.092 ⫺0.094 ⫺0.173 ⫺0.054 0.036 0.035

Observations 2066 2555 2525 2555 2066 2555 2525 2555


Groups 274 290 284 290 274 290 284 290
R2 0.3243 0.3779 0.3684 0.389 0.1677 0.0605 0.1577 0.1337
Log-likelihood ⫺2030 ⫺2519 ⫺2496 ⫺2512 ⫺2982 ⫺3900 ⫺3858 ⫺3899
Hausman test/Wald ␹2 (df) 94.211*** 55.536 84.269*** 59.331*

Scale elasticity (all/middle) 0.314*** 0.333*** 0.318*** 0.499*** 0.414* 0.388* 0.412** 0.094
Scale elasticity (poor countries) 0.643*** 0.355*
Scale elasticity (rich countries) 0.537*** 0.598***
Composition elasticity 0.985*** 1.008*** 1.026*** 0.803*** 1.442** 0.864* 1.150** 1.056**
Technique elasticity ⫺1.425*** ⫺1.740*** ⫺1.551*** ⫺1.218*** ⫺2.220*** ⫺1.230** ⫺1.505*** ⫺1.204**
Trade intensity elasticity ⫺0.266** ⫺0.351*** ⫺0.364** ⫺0.292** ⫺0.543** ⫺0.791*** ⫺1.189*** ⫺0.899***
FDI elasticity (poor countries) 0.091 0.143
FDI elasticity (middle) 0.004 0.121*
FDI elasticity (rich countries) ⫺0.039 0.049

Notes: No standard errors or t-statistics are shown. The dependent variable is the log of the median of SO2 concentrations
at each observation site. All model specifications use time fixed effects. Elasticities are evaluated at sample means using the
Delta method. Model “Time” includes only the years 1976 –1991 of the primary GEMS phase; model “Factors” introduces
factor endowment-related variables; and model “FDI” allows for an an inward foreign direct investment stock relative to the
overall capital stock, interacted with income. The terms rich countries and poor countries refer to the top and bottom 30
percent of countries in the Penn World Tables with respect to per capita GDP.
* Significance at the 95-percent confidence level.
** Significance at the 99-percent confidence level.
*** Significance at the 99.9-percent confidence level.

that may have cleaner than expected techniques countries. The results from this exercise are
of production. We then interact this measure mixed. In the fixed-effects estimation, there is a
with a categorical variable representing a coun- slight positive relationship between FDI and
try’s income per capita to allow the multina- concentrations for poor, middle-income, and rich
tional effect to differ across rich and poor countries. Only the middle-income relationship
900 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2001

is statistically significant. Moreover, the coeffi- or to redistribute income. As a result, the pol-
cient estimates imply that a 10 percentage point lution tax is always equal to effective marginal
increase in the ratio of the FDI stock to K stock damage, and changes in openness affect our
would raise concentrations by about 1 percent. pollution supply curve only through its impact
This is a small effect on pollution concentra- on real income and relative prices. More gener-
tions arising from a very large change in FDI. In ally, pollution policy and openness may be
the random-effects estimation, none of the co- linked through other channels if governments
efficients is significantly different from zero. use pollution policy for other purposes. To ex-
Overall, we find little relationship between the amine this possibility further we need to specify
extent of FDI in an economy (even a poor one) the potential theoretical links involved and then
and its pollution level. Again our elasticity es- ask what variation in the data such a link would
timates are changed only slightly from our ear- create. There are (at least) two reasons why
lier specification. trade and environmental policies may be linked.
Finally, in columns (4) and (8) we investigate Each of these links is probably deserving of a
whether our scale effect differs significantly paper-length treatment of both theory and fur-
across countries categorized by income per cap- ther empirical work, but here our goal is merely
ita levels. If there were important nonhomothe- to sketch two possibilities and identify their
ticities in production or consumption, or if our probable impact on our empirical results.
method of constructing scale was more appro-
priate for some income categories than others, Tariff Substitution.—The first link arises
this may show up when we allow for disaggre- from market power. If countries were large and
gation. The results in column (4) indicate that, had complete discretion in setting both trade
whereas separate estimation of scale across in- and pollution policy, then both instruments
come categories tends to raise the overall elas- would be targeted: the tariff would be set at its
ticity estimates to approximately 0.5 or 0.6, the optimal level according to the inverse elasticity
results are very similar to those presented ear- rule, and the pollution tax would equal effective
lier. In column (8) we find similar results for the marginal damage as in our small open economy
poor and rich categories, but the middle-income case. But if tariff choices are constrained by
group has a much lower elasticity and it is not international agreements, then governments
precisely estimated. The middle-income group may find it useful to substitute environmental
results may be a consequence of the exclusive policy for trade policy. We will refer to this as
reliance of fixed effects on the (now smaller) the tariff substitution motive. To proceed further
within-group variation for estimation. Despite consider the optimal pollution tax for a large
these caveats, the elasticity estimates, although open economy:
different across classes, are not significantly
different from each other.33

E. Alternative Theories: Tariff Substitution


(27) 冉
␶ ⫽ T ␾ 共 p, I兲 ⫹ pE *p t ⫺
1
␧* 冊冏 冏
dp/d ␶
dz/d ␶
,

and Distributional Motives


where ␧* is the elasticity of foreign export sup-
In our framework, governments use pollution ply, E *p is the price derivative of foreign export
policy only to target pollution, and not for other supply, and t is the ad valorem tariff. To high-
purposes, such as to influence the terms of trade light the tariff substitution motive, rewrite (27)
to obtain the gap between the pollution tax and
effective marginal damage:
33
In our random-effects implementation we can go fur-
ther and divide the components of our scale measure into
population density and contemporaneous GDP/N. Doing so
yields an elasticity of concentrations to population density
(28) 冉
␶ ⫺ T ␾ 共 p, I兲 ⫽ pE *p t ⫺
1
␧* 冊冏 冏
dp/d ␶
dz/d ␶
.
of 0.57; an elasticity with respect to contemporaneous
GDP/N of 0.25; and an overall scale elasticity of 0.65. We
cannot reject our restriction that both population density and This gap reflects the tariff substitution motive.
contemporaneous GDP/N share the same elasticity. Consider first a dirty good importer. When the
VOL. 91 NO. 4 ANTWEILER ET AL.: IS FREE TRADE GOOD FOR THE ENVIRONMENT? 901

tariff is set at its optimal level, the right-hand damage. This is because higher pollution taxes
side of (28) is zero: each instrument is targeted lower the producer price of X and raise the real
and there is no tariff substitution motive. If the return to labor. Alternatively, if the weight
tariff is constrained to be below its optimal given to Browns is greater than their current
level, then the right-hand side of (28) is nega- income share, the right-hand side of (29) is
tive and a dirty good importer sets the pollution negative: the pollution tax is set below marginal
tax below marginal damage to substitute for the damage to raise the real return to capital.
tariff. Increased openness therefore induces a Consider the effects of increased openness,
loosening of pollution policy that was not ac- starting from the position where ␭ ⫽ s. In this
counted for in our empirical work.34 For a dirty case, the pollution tax in a dirty good exporting
good exporter, a similar argument works in re- country rises above marginal damage to com-
verse: as trade restrictions are reduced below pensate for the Greens’ loss in income.35 In-
their optimal level, there is an incentive to creased openness hurts workers in this case, and
tighten pollution policy because pollution taxes the government cushions the blow by tightening
can be used as a substitute for an export tax. the pollution tax to raise wages. For a dirty good
Increased openness in this case leads to a tight- importer, the result is reversed: increased open-
ening of pollution policy not accounted for in ness leads to a loosening of pollution policy to
the empirical work. compensate for Browns’ loss in income.

The Redistribution Motive.—Even if coun- Implications of the Theories.—Each theory


tries are small in world markets, governments adds a country-specific unmeasured factor to
may adjust pollution taxes to try to undo the our simpler determinants of pollution. The fac-
redistribution of income caused by increased tor is a country-type effect, and it is relevant to
openness. We refer to this as the redistribu- both a country’s degree of openness and its
tive motive. To illustrate this motive, retain pollution supply curve. In the large-country
our small open economy framework, but now case, the unmeasured country type is described
assume Greens and Browns differ in factor by its trade pattern and market power; and in the
ownership, with Browns having greater capi- redistributive theory, by its preferred and actual
tal per person than Greens; for simplicity, let income distribution.
u(I) ⫽ ln(I). Then given the government’s The impact these country-type effects have
weight ␭ on Greens, the pollution tax will be on our empirical results depends on whether
used both to target pollution and also to in- they are time varying. If the country differences
fluence the income distribution. This again are simple level effects and do not vary over
yields a gap between the pollution tax and time, then our fixed-effects implementation is
effective marginal damage: appropriate, even if country type is correlated
with other right-hand-side regressors. If country
(29) ␶ ⫺ T ␾ 共 p, I兲 ⫽
␭⫺s
s共1 ⫺ s兲
G 冏
ds/d ␶
dz/d ␶
, 冏 type is uncorrelated with the right-hand-side
variables, then our random-effects estimation is
more efficient and still unbiased. On average,
countries of different types would have different
where s is the share of Greens in national in- pollution levels, but they would respond simi-
come. Note that if the weight given to Greens larly to changes in openness, scale, and so forth.
exceeds their current share of national income, Given that the panel is quite short for many
then the pollution tax is higher than marginal countries, this constant-over-time country-type
assumption may be appropriate.
If these country-type effects are time varying,
34
We know that the gap is zero when tariffs are optimal then they will be correlated with our measure of
and is negative when tariffs are zero, so “on average” we
expect an increase in openness to widen the gap. However,
it should be noted that because the right-hand side of (28) 35
Let ⌫ ⫽ ␶ ⫺ T ␾ ( p, I). Then, evaluating at ␭ ⫽ s, we
includes the elasticity of foreign export supply, world have d⌫/d ␤ ⫽ ⫺s ␤ G兩s ␶ 兩/[兩z ␶ 兩s(1 ⫺ s)] ⬎ 0, because
prices, and so forth, the gap between ␶ and marginal damage s ␤ ⬍ 0 (an increase in openness reduces workers’ share of
may not increase monotonically as tariffs fall. income).
902 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2001

openness. Consequently, our results concerning country and time-series data on pollution regu-
the effects of further openness and income lations and trade protection are unavailable, and
on pollution may be undermined. To assess the preferred income distribution is unobserv-
whether these motives could be responsible for able. These two alternative theories are perhaps
our results, consider what is left out by our best examined within a single country context
simpler specification. Start with tariff substitu- where data on regulations, tariffs, and income
tion. When tariffs are reduced and openness distribution are available.36
rises, tariff substitution creates an unaccounted-
for upward shift in pollution supply for a dirty IV. Conclusions
good exporter. This leads to less pollution than
our model would predict. Alternatively, tariff This paper investigates how openness to trad-
substitution produces an unaccounted-for down- ing opportunities affects pollution concentra-
ward shift in pollution supply for a dirty good tions. We started with a theoretical specification
importer. In this case, tariff substitution leads to highlighting scale, technique, and composition
more pollution than our model would predict. In effects and then showed how this theoretical
both cases, unaccounted-for shifts in supply decomposition is useful in thinking about the
work against the shift in pollution demand cre- relationship between openness to international
ated by further openness. Similarly, the redis- markets and the environment. In our empirical
tributive motive shifts the pollution supply section we adopted a specification directly
curve up for a dirty good exporter and down for linked to our earlier theory. We then estimated
a dirty good importer in response to increased this specification, paying special attention to the
openness. Again, we find that this additional potentially confounding influences introduced
potential determinant of pollution tends to by the panel structure of our data set. Our re-
dampen the composition effect created by fur- sults consistently indicate that scale, technique,
ther openness. and composition effects are not just theoretical
Could tariff substitution or redistribution mo- constructs with no empirical counterparts;
tives be responsible for the large technique ef- rather, these theoretical constructs can be iden-
fects we find? Both of these alternative theories tified and their magnitude measured. Moreover,
lead to an unmeasured positive relationship be- once measured they can play a useful role in
tween pollution and openness for some coun- determining the likely environmental conse-
tries. Therefore, it is difficult to see how the quences of technological progress, capital accu-
omission of either of these two additional de- mulation, or increased trade. These estimates
terminants would manifest itself in a stronger may also be useful in aggregate CGE modeling
measured negative relationship between income of the effects of various free trade agreements
and pollution. and other trade reforms [see, e.g., Michael J.
These two alternative theories, however, do Ferrantino and Linda A. Linkins (1996)].
suggest a smaller (than we would otherwise Our work is distinguished by the endogeneity
predict) change in the composition of output of pollution policy and the close connection we
created by a fall in trade frictions. As such, have tried to draw between theory and empirical
another interpretation of our findings of a small estimation. Although it represents a useful first
trade-induced composition effect is that govern- step toward answering our title’s question, it is
ments may be simultaneously dampening the clearly not the last. The benefits of our approach
impact of increased openness on pollution with are transparency, simplicity, and explicitness.
compensating changes in pollution taxes. To
disentangle the additional shifts in pollution
supply suggested by either theory from the other 36
We discuss here the extreme case where pollution
effects in our data would require us to obtain policy is the only available instrument. There are many
information on changes in both tariff levels and other instruments (such as production subsidies), which are
pollution regulations over time for many coun- a better substitute for a tariff; and similarly there are many
other instruments (such as income transfers), which can
tries in our sample; or employ knowledge about redistribute income. To the extent that these other instru-
the preferred and actual income distribution in ments are available, then the dampening shift in pollution
many countries over time. But good cross- supply that we find above will be less relevant.
VOL. 91 NO. 4 ANTWEILER ET AL.: IS FREE TRADE GOOD FOR THE ENVIRONMENT? 903

We have presented an explicit model of trade come by 1 percent, pollution concentrations fall
and pollution and we have moved from theory by approximately 1 percent. Putting this calcula-
to empirical estimation in a transparent manner. tion together with our earlier evidence on compo-
Transparency immediately leads to suggestions sition effects yields a somewhat surprising
for extension along both theoretical and empir- conclusion with regard to sulfur dioxide: freer
ical lines. Simplicity means additional questions trade is good for the environment.
can be addressed within our framework. And
the benefit of presenting an explicit pollution APPENDIX: A: PROOF OF PROPOSITIONS
demand-and-supply model is that researchers
should now be drawn to deeper questions con- PROOF OF PROPOSITION 1:
cerning endogeneity, omitted variables, and sam- Use (17) and (18), and hold T, S, I, K/L, and
ple selection. We view this paper’s attempt at p w constant:
integrating theory with empirical work as its ma-
jor contribution to ongoing research in this area. ẑ ⫽ 关共1 ⫹ a兲␧ ␸ ,p ⫹ ␧ e,p/ ␶ 兴 ␤ˆ
Several extensions seem natural. One cost of
reduced-form estimation is that structural pa- ⫺ 关a␧ ␸ ,p ⫹ ␧ e,p/ ␶ 兴 ␶ˆ
rameters remain hidden. Reduced-form estima-
tion was essentially forced on us by the lack of ⫽ 关␧ ␸ ,p ⫹ 共a␧ ␸ ,p ⫹ ␧ e,p/ ␶ 兲共1 ⫺ ␧ MD,p 兲兴 ␤ˆ .
data on regulations in many developing coun-
tries. If we adopt similar methods but restrict Using Roy’s identity, we can show that ␧MD,p is
the sample to industrialized countries, we could equal to the share of x in consumption (note that
then employ measures of pollution stringency when calculating this elasticity, real income I is
as proxies for pollution regulations. With data held constant, and so we obtain a pure substitution
on both the quantity and “price” of pollution, effect). Hence, ␧MD,p ⬍ 1, and z rises as ␤ rises.
the identification of structural parameters seems For a dirty good exporter, increased openness cor-
possible. A shift to a narrower set of countries responds to an increase in ␤, and hence all else
with more detailed data may also allow us to equal, a reduction in trade frictions raises pollu-
examine the tariff substitution and redistributive tion. For a dirty good importer, a reduction in
motives we discussed, but did not estimate, trade frictions lowers ␤, and pollution falls.
here. Finally, our method for adding up scale,
composition, and technique effects could be en- PROOF OF PROPOSITION 2:
hanced by direct estimates of the income gains Note z ⫽ ⫺R ␶ (where R ␶ ⫽ ⫺eR p N and
brought about by trade liberalization, and im- R ␶␶ ⬎ 0). Then
proved by explicit consideration of foreign di-
rect investment and technology transfer. dz ⫽ ⫺ 关R ␶␶ d ␶ ⫹ p w 共1 ⫺ ␪ 兲R ␶ p N d ␤ 兴
As with any empirical exercise some questions

冋 冏 册
remain unanswered, but overall our estimates in- d␶
dicate that increases in a country’s exposure to ⫽ R ␶␶ p w d␤ ⫺ d␶ ,
international markets create small but measurable dp z
changes in pollution concentrations by altering the
pollution intensity of national output. Although where the last step follows from differentiating
our estimates indicate that greater trade intensity z ⫽ ⫺R␶, holding z constant. Next eliminate d␶ by
creates only relatively small changes in pollution differentiating (10), noting that I ⫽ G/(N␳) and
via a composition effect, economic theory and that dG ⫽ pw(1 ⫺ ␪ ) RpN d␤ ⫹ ␶ dz. Rearranging
numerous empirical studies demonstrate that trade and converting to elasticity form yields
also raises the value of national output and in-
come. These associated increases in output and
incomes will then exert an impact on pollution
concentrations via our estimated scale and tech-
dz
d␤
⫽ 冋 冏
p d␶
␶ dp z
⫺ ␧ MD,p ⫹ ␧ MD,I
pM
G 册冒 H,

nique effects. Our estimates of the scale and tech-


nique elasticities indicate that, if openness to where M is imports of X and H is a positive
international markets raises both output and in- expression. From the proof of Proposition 1,
904 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2001

␧ MD,p ⬍ 1. But ( p/ ␶ )(d ␶ /dp)兩 z ⬎ 1 because 兩M x 兩


z ⫽ ex and e is decreasing in ␶ /p. (An increase TI ⫽ 2p w ,
p 共1 ⫺ ␪ 兲x ⫹ y
w
in p raises x, and so to keep z constant, we need
␶ /p to rise.) Hence, if M ⬎ 0, then dz/d ␤ ⬎ 0
and so increased openness reduces pollution for where M x is imports of X. Consider first an
a dirty good importer (␤ falls). For a dirty good importer of X (M x ⬎ 0). Let G w ⫽ p w (1 ⫺
exporter, M ⬍ 0 and ␤ rises when openness ␪ ) x ⫹ y, and G ⫽ ␤ p w (1 ⫺ ␪ ) x ⫹ y. By
rises. From the proof of Proposition 1, ␧ MD,p is homotheticity, we can write the demand for X
the share of X in consumption, and so with as D x ⫽ h( p)G. Letting ␦ x ⫽ p w D x /G w , and
␧ MD,I ⱕ 1, we have ␸ ⫽ pw(1 ⫺ ␪ )x/Gw, we have TI ⫽ 2(␦x ⫺ ␸).
With some rearranging, we can write
dz
d␤
⬎ 冋 冏 册冒
p d␶
␶ dp z

px
G
H ⬎ 0, ␦ x ⫽ p w h关1 ⫹ 共 ␤ ⫺ 1兲 ␸ 兴.

where px/G ⬍ 1 is the share of X in output at Then


domestic prices. So pollution rises for a dirty
good exporter if ␧ MD,I ⱕ 1. Finally, if ␧ MD,I is 1 ⭸TI ⭸ ␦ x ⭸ ␸
sufficiently large, the sign of dz/d ␤ is reversed ⫽ ⫺
2 ⭸␤ ⭸␤ ⭸␤
for a dirty good exporter and pollution falls as
openness rises.

PROOF OF PROPOSITION 3:
⫽ 冋 冏
共p w 兲 2 ⭸D x
G w ⭸p u

⭸D x
⭸G x
M 册
For a given p and I, Home’s relative de-
mand RD( p) is fixed. For given p and I, the ⫹ 关p w h共 ␤ ⫺ 1兲 ⫺ 1兴 ␸ ␤ ⬍ 0,
unit input coefficients given in (6) are fixed,
and hence ␹ approaches infinity as ␬ rises. where we have used the Slutsky decomposition.
Consequently, there exists a ␬គ such that for Note that the substitution effect in demand is
␬ ⬎ ␬គ , ␹ exceeds relative demand, and Home negative (⭸D x /⭸p兩 u ⬍ 0) and the income effect
exports X. The increase in pollution via the (⭸D x /⭸G) is positive, so the bracketed term
trade-induced composition effect follows involving demand changes is negative. As well,
from Proposition 1. p w ␤ h ⬍ 1 from the consumer’s budget con-
straint, and ␸␤ ⬎ 0 (an increase in ␤ shifts
PROOF OF PROPOSITION 4: production toward X) and so the last term is
The relative producer price of X is p N ⬍ negative as well. Thus ⭸TI/⭸␤ ⬍ 0 for an im-
p(1 ⫺ ␪ ) ⫺ ␶ e(1), where e(1) ⬎ 0. Because porter of X. Hence a fall in ␤ (a movement
␧ MD,I ⬎ ␧ ⬎ 0, ␶ increases without bound as toward 1) increases trade intensity. For an ex-
income rises given (18). Moreover, ␪ rises porter of X, one can proceed most simply by
from (4), and hence there exists some I for replacing 兩p w M x 兩 with imports of Y, M y in the
which p N falls to 0, in which case X output definition of trade intensity and following a
is 0. The relative demand for X is, how- similar analysis as earlier to conclude that an
ever, independent of income. Hence for suf- increase in ␤ (a movement toward 1) raises
ficiently large I, Home must import X and trade intensity.
export Y. The fall in pollution from the trade-
induced composition effect follows from APPENDIX B: DATA SET DESCRIPTION
Proposition 1.
The dependent variable in our study is the
PROOF OF PROPOSITION 5: concentration of sulfur dioxide at observation
Define trade intensity as the value of exports sites in major cities around the world as ob-
plus imports at world prices (excluding trans- tained through the GEMS/AIR data set supplied
portation services). Using the trade balance con- by the World Health Organization. Measure-
straint, ments are carried out using comparable meth-
VOL. 91 NO. 4 ANTWEILER ET AL.: IS FREE TRADE GOOD FOR THE ENVIRONMENT? 905

ods. Each observation station reports annual nomic data, the World Investment Report39 for
summary statistics of SO2 concentrations such inward FDI stock data, the CIESIN Global Pop-
as the median, the arithmetic and geometric ulation Distribution Database40 for population
mean, as well as 90th and 95th percentiles. density data, the World Resources Institute
We have chosen to use a logarithmic trans- World Resources Database41 for natural re-
formation of the median SO2 concentration as sources and physical endowments, and data
our dependent variable. The distribution of con- from the Global Historical Climatology Net-
centrations is highly skewed toward zero when work42 (GHCN) for weather conditions at the
viewed on a linear scale. As was pointed out in observation stations. Yet more time series were
the WHO (1984) report about the GEMS/AIR obtained for tariff and nontariff trade barriers43
project, concentrations are more suitably de- and educational attainment.44
scribed by a lognormal distribution with a num- Summary statistics for the major variables
ber of observations concentrated at the appear in Table B1. Some of the variables war-
measurement threshold of the measurement de- rant further explanation. First, our scale mea-
vices. There is also an ambient level of SO2 in sure of economic activity GDP per square
the air that has natural causes. kilometer is calculated by multiplying a
A large share of observations were from the country’s real per capita GDP ($/person) with
United States because of this country’s exten- each city’s population density (people/km2).
sive network of air quality measurement sta- Extrapolations for per capita GDP were carried
tions. Other large contributor countries were out for the years past 1993 based on real growth
China, Canada, and Japan. Many of the other rates obtained from the IMF/IFS statistics. Pop-
observation stations provided short or discon- ulation densities were available only for 1990.
tinuous streams of data while participating in The capital abundance (K/L) of countries was
the GEMS/AIR project. All in all, our analysis obtained from the physical capital stock per
is based on over 2,600 observations from 293 worker variable in the Penn World Tables. We
observation stations in 109 cities around the have adjusted this series for human capital by
world; these cities are located in 44 countries. applying a 0 –1 average education index (in
The primary source for our data is the AIRS
Executive International Database that contains
information about ambient air pollution in na-
tions that voluntarily provide data to the GEMS/ isons, 1950 –1988.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, May
1991, 106(2), pp. 327– 68. Available in revision 5.6 from
AIR program sponsored by the United Nations the Center for International Comparisons at the University
World Health Organization.37 We had problems of Pennsylvania at http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu/.
with the identification of several observation 39
United Nations Centre on Transnational Corporations,
stations. The longitude and latitude information 1992 and 1999 volumes.
40
provided in one of the ancillary files was in This data set from the Consortium for International
Earth Science Information Network (CIESIN) is available
some cases incorrect and was corrected case by only for 1990. It can be obtained freely from the United
case based on the description of the location. Nations Environmental Programme server maintained by
Additional data sources for our regressors the U.S. Geological Survey at http://grid2.cr.usgs.gov/
include the Penn World Tables38 for macroeco- globalpop/1-degree/description.html.
41
World resources 1998 –1999: A guide to the global
environment, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1998.
42
Information is available on monthly average temper-
37
This package is available from the United States atures, monthly precipitation, and atmospheric pressure.
Environmental Protection Agency (US-EPA) at http:// The raw data and description file are available from the
www.epa.gov/airs/aexec.html. The US-EPA kindly pro- National Climatic Data Center of the U.S. National Oceanic
vided a much more complete version of this data set that and Atmospheric Administration at ftp://ftp.ncdc.noaa.gov/
included not only averages but also median and other per- pub/data/ghcn/.
43
centiles of SO2 concentrations. We would like to express See Jeffrey D. Sachs and Andrew M. Warner: “Eco-
our gratitude to Jonathan Miller of the US-EPA for provid- nomic Convergence and Economic Policies.” National Bu-
ing additional GEMS/air data not contained in the public reau of Economic Research (Cambridge, MA) Working
release of the data base, and for patiently answering our Paper No. 5039, February 1995.
44
numerous technical questions. These figures were obtained from Robert J. Barro and
38
Robert Summers and Alan Heston, “The Penn World Jong-Wha Lee’s (1994) study, available from the NBER
Table (Mark 5): An Expanded Set of International Compar- website at http://www.nber.org/pub/barro.lee/ZIP/.
906 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2001

TABLE B1—SUMMARY STATISTICS

Number of
Variable Dimension observations Mean SD Min Max
Log of SO2 log10 (ppm) 2,555 ⫺2.112 0.481 ⫺3.000 ⫺0.939
City economic intensity $m per km2 2,555 0.790 0.878 0.010 5.934
GDP per capita (current) $10k 2,555 1.478 0.862 0.109 2.718
Population density 1,000 people/km2 2,555 0.063 0.055 0.001 0.276
Capital abundance (adjusted) $10k/worker 2,555 5.612 2.497 0.829 17.189
Capital abundance
(unadjusted) $10k/worker 2,555 3.207 1.763 0.130 7.750
Education attainment 0–1 range 2,555 0.540 0.226 0.088 0.799
GNP per capita, 3-yr average $10k 2,555 1.396 0.815 0.111 2.635
Communist country (C.C.) [—] 2,555 0.125 0.331 0.000 1.000
C.C. ⫻ income $10k 319 0.302 0.208 0.127 0.716
Trade intensity (X⫹M)/GDP [—] 2,555 0.409 0.322 0.088 2.617
Relative (K/L) (adjusted) World ⫽ 1.00 2,555 1.357 0.605 0.203 4.174
Relative income World ⫽ 1.00 2,555 2.500 1.392 0.221 4.138
Inward FDI stock/capital stock [—] 2,525 0.106 0.250 0.001 2.193
Average temperature °C 2,555 14.689 5.600 2.617 28.967
Precipitation coefficient of
variation [—] 2,555 0.011 0.006 0.001 0.054
Hard coal reserves GJoule/worker 2,555 0.040 0.043 0.000 0.146
Soft coal reserves GJoule/worker 2,555 0.038 0.052 0.000 0.348

Notes: All monetary figures are in 1995 U.S. dollars. The interaction term for income with the Communist countries dummy
shows the case only where the dummy is equal to 1; thus the mean for this line is the mean for the Communist countries only.

which 1 represents 16 years of schooling) ob- unavailable for the former Czechoslovakia, Egypt,
tained from the Barro/Lee data set. Relative Hong Kong, Iraq, Peru, Poland, and the former
capital abundance is obtained by dividing each Yugoslavia. Unadjusted GDP figures were used in
country’s capital abundance by the correspond- these cases.
ing world average for the given year, where The data on foreign direct investment (FDI)
“world average” is defined by all the countries were obtained as percentages of the stock of
in the Penn World Tables. inward FDI relative to GDP, and interpolated
Our income (I) variable is the three-year where necessary. These figures were then di-
average of lagged GNP per capita. This ad- vided by GDP to capital stock ratios obtained
dresses two problems. First, contemporaneous from the Penn World Tables to obtain the per-
income and the level of pollution may be deter- centage of inward FDI stock relative to a coun-
mined simultaneously. Lagged income, how- try’s entire capital stock.
ever, is exogenous. Second, it is reasonable to The suburban and rural location type dummy
assume that income changes translate only variables are from the original GEMS/AIR data
slowly into policy changes. We therefore set. The third (default) location type is central
smooth out some of the variation introduced city. Our trade intensity measure is calculated as
through business cycles and include three years the sum of exports and imports expressed as a
of data. (We also experimented with longer percentage of gross domestic product. The
lags, without much effect on our results.) More Communist country dummy used in our study
concretely, for a given year t we compute I t ⫽ identifies the following countries: China,
( y t ⫺ 1 ⫹ y t ⫺ 2 ⫹ y t ⫺ 3 )/3. Relative income is Czechoslovakia, Poland, and Yugoslavia. The
constructed in the same fashion as our relative country dummy for the Helsinki Protocol iden-
capital-abundance measure. GNP figures were tifies Austria, Belgium, Bulgaria, Canada,
obtained by adjusting GDP figures with a GNP/ Czechoslovakia, Denmark, Finland, France,
GDP correction factor obtained from the Inter- Germany, Hungary, Italy, Luxembourg, The
national Monetary Fund’s International Financial Netherlands, Norway, and Switzerland, in the
Statistics. However, such correction factors were years after 1985.
VOL. 91 NO. 4 ANTWEILER ET AL.: IS FREE TRADE GOOD FOR THE ENVIRONMENT? 907

For the purpose of calculating sample-mean metric Evidence for the OECD, 1970 –1985.”
elasticities we used averages of the relevant Journal of International Economics, August
variables calculated as follows. An average 1995, 39(1–2), pp. 123– 41.
country value for variable X is calculated by . “Technology, Factor Supplies, and In-
first averaging X’s values over time for each ternational Specialization: Estimating the
country, and then averaging across countries. Neoclassical Model.” American Economic
This procedure gives equal weight to all Review, September 1997, 87(4), pp. 475–94.
countries. Jaffe, Adam B.; Peterson, Steven R.; Portney,
Paul R. and Stavins, Robert N. “Environmen-
REFERENCES tal Regulation and the Competitiveness of
U.S. Manufacturing: What Does the Evi-
Antweiler, Werner; Copeland, Brian R. and Tay- dence Tell Us?” Journal of Economic Liter-
lor, M. Scott. “Is Free Trade Good for the ature, March 1995, 33(1), pp. 132– 63.
Environment?” National Bureau of Eco- Kraushaar, Jack J. and Ristinen, Robert A. En-
nomic Research (Cambridge, MA) Working ergy and problems of a technical society.
Paper 6707, August 1998. New York: Wiley, 1998.
Chay, Kenneth Y. and Greenstone, Michael B. Levinson, Arik. “Environmental Regulations and
“The Impact of Air Pollution on Infant Mor- Industry Location: International and Domes-
tality: Evidence from Geographic Variation tic Evidence,” in J. N. Bhagwati and R. E.
in Pollution Shocks Induced by a Recession.” Hudec, eds., Fair trade and harmonization:
National Bureau of Economic Research Prerequisites for free trade? Cambridge,
(Cambridge, MA) Working Paper No. 7442, MA: MIT Press, 1996, pp. 429 –57.
December 1999. Low, Patrick and Yeats, Alexander. “Do ‘Dirty’
Copeland, Brian R. and Taylor, M. Scott. “North- Industries Migrate,” in Patrick Low, ed., In-
South Trade and the Environment.” Quar- ternational trade and the environment. World
terly Journal of Economics, August 1994, Bank Discussion Paper No. 159. Washington,
109(3), pp. 755– 87. DC: World Bank, 1992, pp. 89 –104.
. “Trade and Transboundary Pollution.” Lucas, Robert E. B.; Wheeler, David and Hettige,
American Economic Review, September Hemamala. “Economic Development, Envi-
1995, 85(4), pp. 716 –37. ronmental regulation and the International
Dixit, Avinash K. and Norman, Victor. Theory of Migration of Toxic Industrial Pollution:
international trade. Cambridge: Cambridge 1960 –1988,” in Patrick Low, ed., Interna-
University Press, 1980. tional trade and the environment. World
Ferrantino, Michael J. and Linkins, Linda A. Bank Discussion Paper No. 159. Washington,
“Global Trade Liberalization and Toxic Re- DC: World Bank, 1992, pp. 67– 86.
leases.” U.S. International Trade Commis- Mani, Muthukumara and Wheeler, David. “In
sion discussion paper, 1996. Search of Pollution Havens?: Dirty Indus-
Gale, Lewis and Mendez, Jose A. “The Empirical try Migration in the World Economy.”
Relationship between Trade, Growth and the World Bank Working Paper No. 16, April
Environment.” International Review of Eco- 1997.
nomics and Finance, 1998, 7(1), pp. 53– 61. McGuire, Martin C. “Regulation, Factor Rewards,
Grossman, Gene M. and Krueger, Alan B. “En- and International Trade.” Journal of Public
vironmental Impacts of a North American Economics, April 1982, 17(3), pp. 335–54.
Free Trade Agreement,” in Peter M. Garber, Pethig, Rüdiger. “Pollution, Welfare, and Environ-
ed., The U.S.–Mexico free trade agreement. mental Policy in the Theory of Comparative
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1993, pp. 13– Advantage.” Journal of Environmental Eco-
56. nomics and Management, February 1976, 2(3),
. “Economic Growth and the Environ- pp. 160 – 69.
ment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, May Selden, Thomas M. and Song, Daqing. “Environ-
1995, 110(2), pp. 353–77. mental Quality and Development: Is There a
Harrigan, James. “Factor Endowments and the Kuznets Curve for Air Pollution Emissions?”
International Location of Production: Econo- Journal of Environmental Economics and
908 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW SEPTEMBER 2001

Management, September 1994, 27(2), pp. Trade: An Empirical Test.” Kyklos, 1990,
147– 62. 43(2), pp. 191–209.
Shafik, Nemat. “Economic Development and United Nations Environment Programme. Urban
Environmental Quality: An Econometric air pollution. Nairobi: UNEP, 1991.
Analysis.” Oxford Economic Papers, Octo- Woodland, Alan D. International trade and re-
ber 1994, Supp. 46, pp. 757–73. source allocation. Amsterdam: North-Holland,
Siebert, Horst; Eichberger, Jürgen.; Gronych, R. 1982.
and Pethig, Rüdiger. Trade and the environ- World Health Organization. Urban air pollution:
ment: A theoretical enquiry. Amsterdam: 1973–1980. Geneva: Published under the
Elsevier/North-Holland, 1980. joint sponsorship of United Nations Environ-
Tobey, James A. “The Effects of Domestic En- ment Programme and the World Health Or-
vironmental Policies on Patterns of World ganization, 1984.
This article has been cited by:

1. Jiandong Chen, Qin Xian, Jixian Zhou, Ding Li. 2020. Impact of income inequality on CO2 emissions
in G20 countries. Journal of Environmental Management 271, 110987. [Crossref]
2. Muhammad Umar, Xiangfeng Ji, Dervis Kirikkaleli, Qinghui Xu. 2020. COP21 Roadmap: Do
innovation, financial development, and transportation infrastructure matter for environmental
sustainability in China?. Journal of Environmental Management 271, 111026. [Crossref]
3. Haichao Fan, Faqin Lin, Shu Lin. 2020. The hidden cost of trade liberalization: Input tariff shocks
and worker health in China. Journal of International Economics 126, 103349. [Crossref]
4. Andreas Kammerlander, Günther G. Schulze. 2020. Are Democracies Cleaner?. European Journal of
Political Economy 64, 101920. [Crossref]
5. Mohammad Mafizur Rahman, Xuan-Binh Vu. 2020. The nexus between renewable energy, economic
growth, trade, urbanisation and environmental quality: A comparative study for Australia and Canada.
Renewable Energy 155, 617-627. [Crossref]
6. Mohd Arshad Ansari, Salman Haider, N.A. Khan. 2020. Environmental Kuznets curve revisited: An
analysis using ecological and material footprint. Ecological Indicators 115, 106416. [Crossref]
7. Muhammad Zubair Chishti, Sana Ullah, Ilhan Ozturk, Ahmed Usman. 2020. Examining the
asymmetric effects of globalization and tourism on pollution emissions in South Asia. Environmental
Science and Pollution Research 27:22, 27721-27737. [Crossref]
8. Madanmohan Ghosh, Deming Luo, Muhammad Shahid Siddiqui, Thomas Rutherford, Yunfa Zhu.
2020. The Drivers of Greenhouse Gas Emissions Intensity Improvements in Major Economies:
Analysis of Trends 1995–2009. Foreign Trade Review 55:3, 277-297. [Crossref]
9. Muhammad Usman, Rakhshanda Kousar, Muhammad Rizwan Yaseen, Muhammad Sohail Amjad
Makhdum. 2020. An empirical nexus between economic growth, energy utilization, trade policy, and
ecological footprint: a continent-wise comparison in upper-middle-income countries. Environmental
Science and Pollution Research 35. . [Crossref]
10. Helmi Hamdi, Abdelaziz Hakimi. 2020. Corruption, FDI, and Growth: An Empirical Investigation
into the Tunisian Context. The International Trade Journal 34:4, 415-440. [Crossref]
11. Pasquale Pazienza, Caterina De Lucia. 2020. How does FDI in the “agricultural and fishing” sector
affect methane emission? Evidence from the OECD countries. Economia Politica 37:2, 441-462.
[Crossref]
12. Muhammad Yousaf Malik, Kashmala Latif, Zeeshan Khan, Hassan Daud Butt, Mudassar Hussain,
Muhammad Athar Nadeem. 2020. Symmetric and asymmetric impact of oil price, FDI and economic
growth on carbon emission in Pakistan: Evidence from ARDL and non-linear ARDL approach.
Science of The Total Environment 726, 138421. [Crossref]
13. Chuanwang Sun, Lanyun Chen, Fan Zhang. 2020. Exploring the trading embodied CO2 effect and
low-carbon globalization from the international division perspective. Environmental Impact Assessment
Review 83, 106414. [Crossref]
14. Matilde Bombardini, Bingjing Li. 2020. Trade, pollution and mortality in China. Journal of
International Economics 125, 103321. [Crossref]
15. Shukria Hotak, Moinul Islam, Makoto Kakinaka, Koji Kotani. 2020. Carbon emissions and carbon
trade balances: International evidence from panel ARDL analysis. Environmental Science and Pollution
Research 27:19, 24115-24128. [Crossref]
16. Aqib Mujtaba, Pabitra Kumar Jena, D. Mukhopadhyay. 2020. Determinants of CO2 emissions in
upper middle-income group countries: an empirical investigation. Environmental Science and Pollution
Research 96. . [Crossref]
17. Mfonobong Udom Etokakpan, Festus Fatai Adedoyin, Yorucu Vedat, Festus Victor Bekun. 2020.
Does globalization in Turkey induce increased energy consumption: insights into its environmental
pros and cons. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 27:21, 26125-26140. [Crossref]
18. Mounir Belloumi, Atef Alshehry. 2020. The Impact of International Trade on Sustainable
Development in Saudi Arabia. Sustainability 12:13, 5421. [Crossref]
19. Sam Asher, Teevrat Garg, Paul Novosad. 2020. The Ecological Impact of Transportation
Infrastructure. The Economic Journal 130:629, 1173-1199. [Crossref]
20. Thi Cam Van NGUYEN, Quoc Hoi LE. 2020. Impact of Globalization on Coal Consumption in
Vietnam: An Empirical Analysis. The Journal of Asian Finance, Economics and Business 7:6, 185-195.
[Crossref]
21. Xin Peng, Yue Pu. 2020. Trade openness and pollutant emissions in China: the role of capital
abundance and income. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 3. . [Crossref]
22. Azka Amin, Babar Aziz, Xi-Hua Liu. 2020. The relationship between urbanization, technology
innovation, trade openness, and CO2 emissions: evidence from a panel of Asian countries.
Environmental Science and Pollution Research 90. . [Crossref]
23. Usman Mehmood, Salman Tariq. 2020. Globalization and CO2 emissions nexus: evidence from
the EKC hypothesis in South Asian countries. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 91. .
[Crossref]
24. Onur A. Koska, Frank Stähler, Onur Yeni. 2020. Trade and commodity taxes as environmental
instruments in an open economy. Journal of Economic Studies ahead-of-print:ahead-of-print. .
[Crossref]
25. Farzana Naheed Khan, Aiman Sana, Umaima Arif. 2020. Information and communication technology
(ICT) and environmental sustainability: a panel data analysis. Environmental Science and Pollution
Research 21. . [Crossref]
26. Gökçe MANAVGAT. 2020. Ticarete Açıklığı Sağlık Düzeyinin Yükseltilmesinde Etkili midir? Üst-
Orta Gelirli Ülkeler için Panel Veri Analizi. Uluslararası İktisadi ve İdari Bilimler Dergisi 23-33.
[Crossref]
27. Ling-Yun He, Xi Lin, Qiren Liu. 2020. How Did Free Trade Reshape the Transitional China?
Evidence from Heterogeneous Exporters and Firm-Level Pollution Emissions. Emerging Markets
Finance and Trade 56:8, 1651-1676. [Crossref]
28. Muhammed Ashiq Villanthenkodath, Muhamed Faizudheen Arakkal. 2020. Exploring the existence
of environmental Kuznets curve in the midst of financial development, openness, and foreign direct
investment in New Zealand: insights from ARDL bound test. Environmental Science and Pollution
Research 51. . [Crossref]
29. Wen Jun, Hamid Mahmood, Muhammad Zakaria. 2020. IMPACT OF TRADE OPENNESS ON
ENVIRONMENT IN CHINA. Journal of Business Economics and Management 21:4, 1185-1202.
[Crossref]
30. Ling-Yun He, Liang Wang. 2020. Distinct exporters and the environment: Empirical evidence from
China manufacturing. Journal of Cleaner Production 258, 120614. [Crossref]
31. Xiuting Wang, Yan Luo. 2020. Has technological innovation capability addressed environmental
pollution from the dual perspective of FDI quantity and quality? Evidence from China. Journal of
Cleaner Production 258, 120941. [Crossref]
32. Nguyen Van Tran. 2020. The environmental effects of trade openness in developing countries: conflict
or cooperation?. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 27:16, 19783-19797. [Crossref]
33. Mumin Atalay Cetin, Ibrahim Bakirtas. 2020. The long-run environmental impacts of economic
growth, financial development, and energy consumption: Evidence from emerging markets. Energy &
Environment 31:4, 634-655. [Crossref]
34. Yan Zhang, Jingbo Cui, Chenghao Lu. 2020. Does environmental regulation affect firm exports?
Evidence from wastewater discharge standard in China. China Economic Review 61, 101451. [Crossref]
35. Wei Hu, Di Wang. 2020. How does environmental regulation influence China’s carbon productivity?
An empirical analysis based on the spatial spillover effect. Journal of Cleaner Production 257, 120484.
[Crossref]
36. Hoang Phong Le, Ilhan Ozturk. 2020. The impacts of globalization, financial development,
government expenditures, and institutional quality on CO2 emissions in the presence of environmental
Kuznets curve. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 27:18, 22680-22697. [Crossref]
37. Alexandre Repkine, Dongki Min. 2020. Foreign-Funded Enterprises and Pollution Halo Hypothesis:
A Spatial Econometric Analysis of Thirty Chinese Regions. Sustainability 12:12, 5048. [Crossref]
38. Mihai Mutascu, Alexandre Sokic. 2020. Trade Openness - CO2 Emissions Nexus: a Wavelet Evidence
from EU. Environmental Modeling & Assessment 25:3, 411-428. [Crossref]
39. Steve Yaw Sarpong, Murad A. Bein. 2020. The relationship between good governance and CO2
emissions in oil- and non-oil-producing countries: a dynamic panel study of sub-Saharan Africa.
Environmental Science and Pollution Research 27:17, 21986-22003. [Crossref]
40. YASIR KHAN, QIU BIN. 2020. THE ENVIRONMENTAL KUZNETS CURVE FOR CARBON
DIOXIDE EMISSIONS AND TRADE ON BELT AND ROAD INITIATIVE COUNTRIES:
A SPATIAL PANEL DATA APPROACH. The Singapore Economic Review 65:04, 1099-1126.
[Crossref]
41. Hashim Zameer, Humaira Yasmeen, Muhammad Wasif Zafar, Abdul Waheed, Avik Sinha. 2020.
Analyzing the association between innovation, economic growth, and environment: divulging the
importance of FDI and trade openness in India. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 37. .
[Crossref]
42. Suleyman Koc, Gokay Canberk Bulus. 2020. Testing validity of the EKC hypothesis in South Korea:
role of renewable energy and trade openness. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 35. .
[Crossref]
43. Jan Dithmer, Awudu Abdulai. 2020. Trade openness and child health: a heterogeneous panel
cointegration analysis. Applied Economics 52:23, 2508-2525. [Crossref]
44. Shuai Chen, Faqin Lin, Xi Yao, Peng Zhang. 2020. WTO accession, trade expansion, and air pollution:
Evidence from China’s county‐level panel data. Review of International Economics 13. . [Crossref]
45. Jaana Korhonen, Prakash Nepal, Jeffrey P. Prestemon, Frederick W. Cubbage. 2020. Projecting global
and regional outlooks for planted forests under the shared socio-economic pathways. New Forests 91. .
[Crossref]
46. Sayed Saghaian, Hanane Aghasafari, Milad Aminizadeh, Andisheh Riahi. 2020. Factors Influencing
Climate-Smart Goods Trade in Some Developing Countries in the Middle East and North Africa
Region: An Application of the Spatial Panel Model. The International Trade Journal 34:3, 281-296.
[Crossref]
47. Yu Pei, Yingming Zhu, Suxia Liu, Menglu Xie. 2020. Industrial agglomeration and environmental
pollution: based on the specialized and diversified agglomeration in the Yangtze River Delta.
Environment, Development and Sustainability 80. . [Crossref]
48. Jingjing Zhang. 2020. International production fragmentation, trade in intermediate goods and
environment. Economic Modelling 87, 1-7. [Crossref]
49. Nicholas Apergis, James E. Payne. 2020. NAFTA and the convergence of CO2 emissions intensity
and its determinants. International Economics 161, 1-9. [Crossref]
50. Lihua WU, Tianshu MA, Yuanchao BIAN, Sijia LI, Zhaoqiang YI. 2020. Improvement of regional
environmental quality: Government environmental governance and public participation. Science of The
Total Environment 717, 137265. [Crossref]
51. Xinxian Qi, Xiyan Mao, Xianjin Huang, Danyang Wang, Hongyan Zhao, Hong Yang. 2020. Tracing
the sources of air pollutant emissions embodied in exports in the Yangtze River Delta, China: A four-
level perspective. Journal of Cleaner Production 254, 120155. [Crossref]
52. Shaowei Chen, Qiang (Patrick) Qiang. 2020. The Trade Network Structure of the “One Belt and One
Road” and Its Environmental Effects. Sustainability 12:9, 3519. [Crossref]
53. Erik Hille, Bernhard Lambernd. 2020. The role of innovation in reducing South Korea's energy
intensity: Regional-data evidence on various energy carriers. Journal of Environmental Management
262, 110293. [Crossref]
54. Hafezali Iqbal Hussain, Muhammad Haseeb, Manuela Tvaronavičienė, Leonardus W. W. Mihardjo,
Kittisak Jermsittiparsert. 2020. The Causal Connection of Natural Resources and Globalization with
Energy Consumption in Top Asian Countries: Evidence from a Nonparametric Causality-in-Quantile
Approach. Energies 13:9, 2273. [Crossref]
55. Xiaoyuan Qi, Ying Han, Po Kou. 2020. Population urbanization, trade openness and carbon emissions:
an empirical analysis based on China. Air Quality, Atmosphere & Health 13:5, 519-528. [Crossref]
56. Chien-Hui Lee, Po-Sheng Ko, Yu-Lin Wang, Jen-Yao Lee, Jiong-Hung Kwo. 2020. Centralized and
Decentralized Recycle Policy with Transboundary Pollution. Environments 7:5, 40. [Crossref]
57. Yan Dong, Jinhuan Tian, Jingjing Ye. 2020. Environmental regulation and foreign direct investment:
Evidence from China's outward FDI. Finance Research Letters 101611. [Crossref]
58. Ming Zhang, Xinran Sun, Wenwen Wang. 2020. Study on the effect of environmental regulations
and industrial structure on haze pollution in China from the dual perspective of independence and
linkage. Journal of Cleaner Production 256, 120748. [Crossref]
59. Pradeepta Sethi, Debkumar Chakrabarti, Sankalpa Bhattacharjee. 2020. Globalization, financial
development and economic growth: Perils on the environmental sustainability of an emerging
economy. Journal of Policy Modeling 42:3, 520-535. [Crossref]
60. Xiaofei Qi, Bingxin Zhao, Jiang-Hua Zhang. 2020. What does the product space mean for firms in
the development of marine-related products?. Marine Policy 115, 103822. [Crossref]
61. Johan Graafland. 2020. When Does Economic Freedom Promote Well Being? On the Moderating
Role of Long-Term Orientation. Social Indicators Research 149:1, 127-153. [Crossref]
62. Xin Jiang, Wei Fu, Guanglong Li. 2020. Can the improvement of living environment stimulate urban
Innovation?——Analysis of high-quality innovative talents and foreign direct investment spillover
effect mechanism. Journal of Cleaner Production 255, 120212. [Crossref]
63. Dilvin Taşkın, Gülin Vardar, Berna Okan. 2020. Does renewable energy promote green economic
growth in OECD countries?. Sustainability Accounting, Management and Policy Journal 11:4, 771-798.
[Crossref]
64. Zhen Huangfu, Hui Hu, Nan Xie, Yu-Qi Zhu, Hao Chen, Yang Wang. 2020. The heterogeneous
influence of economic growth on environmental pollution: evidence from municipal data of China.
Petroleum Science 91. . [Crossref]
65. Lafang Wang, Youfu Yue, Rui Xie, Shaojian Wang. 2020. How global value chain participation affects
China's energy intensity. Journal of Environmental Management 260, 110041. [Crossref]
66. Sulaman Muhammad, Xingle Long, Muhammad Salman, Lamini Dauda. 2020. Effect of urbanization
and international trade on CO2 emissions across 65 belt and road initiative countries. Energy 196,
117102. [Crossref]
67. Sajid Ali, Zulkornain Yusop, Shivee Ranjanee Kaliappan, Lee Chin. 2020. Dynamic common
correlated effects of trade openness, FDI, and institutional performance on environmental quality:
evidence from OIC countries. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 27:11, 11671-11682.
[Crossref]
68. Jing Li, Xing Shi, Huaqing Wu, Liwen Liu. 2020. Trade-off between economic development and
environmental governance in China: An analysis based on the effect of river chief system. China
Economic Review 60, 101403. [Crossref]
69. Obed Kwame Essandoh, Moinul Islam, Makoto Kakinaka. 2020. Linking international trade and
foreign direct investment to CO2 emissions: Any differences between developed and developing
countries?. Science of The Total Environment 712, 136437. [Crossref]
70. George N. Ike, Ojonugwa Usman, Samuel Asumadu Sarkodie. 2020. Testing the role of oil production
in the environmental Kuznets curve of oil producing countries: New insights from Method of
Moments Quantile Regression. Science of The Total Environment 711, 135208. [Crossref]
71. Şükrü APAYDIN. 2020. Küreselleşmenin Ekolojik Ayakizi Üzerindeki Etkileri: Türkiye Örneği.
Ekonomi, Politika & Finans Araştırmaları Dergisi 23-42. [Crossref]
72. Emma Aisbett, Magdalene Silberberger. 2020. Tariff liberalization and product standards: Regulatory
chill and race to the bottom?. Regulation & Governance 91. . [Crossref]
73. Yu Hao, Yerui Wu, Haitao Wu, Siyu Ren. 2020. How do FDI and technical innovation affect
environmental quality? Evidence from China. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 27:8,
7835-7850. [Crossref]
74. Ojonugwa Usman, Ifedolapo O. Olanipekun, Paul Terhemba Iorember, Maryam Abu-Goodman.
2020. Modelling environmental degradation in South Africa: the effects of energy consumption,
democracy, and globalization using innovation accounting tests. Environmental Science and Pollution
Research 27:8, 8334-8349. [Crossref]
75. Elodie Mania. 2020. Export Diversification and CO 2 Emissions: An Augmented Environmental
Kuznets Curve. Journal of International Development 32:2, 168-185. [Crossref]
76. Hong Chen, Wenzhe Hu. 2020. Determining Whether Trade Can Affect Regional Environmental
Sustainability from the Perspective of Environmental Pollution. Sustainability 12:5, 1746. [Crossref]
77. Ling-Yun He, Geng Huang. 2020. Tariff Reduction and Environment: Evidence from CAFTA and
Chinese Manufacturing Firms. Sustainability 12:5, 2017. [Crossref]
78. Yu Hao, Yunxia Guo, Yitong Guo, Haitao Wu, Siyu Ren. 2020. Does outward foreign direct
investment (OFDI) affect the home country’s environmental quality? The case of China. Structural
Change and Economic Dynamics 52, 109-119. [Crossref]
79. María A. González-Álvarez, Antonio Montañés, Lorena Olmos. 2020. Towards a sustainable energy
scenario? A worldwide analysis. Energy Economics 87, 104738. [Crossref]
80. Abdul M. Nadeem, Tariq Ali, Muhammad T. I. Khan, Zhengquan Guo. 2020. Relationship between
inward FDI and environmental degradation for Pakistan: an exploration of pollution haven hypothesis
through ARDL approach. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 60. . [Crossref]
81. Yingzhi Xu, Xiaomin Fan, Zhiqian Zhang, Ruijie Zhang. 2020. Trade liberalization and haze pollution:
Evidence from China. Ecological Indicators 109, 105825. [Crossref]
82. Xiaofei Qi, Bingxin Zhao, Jianghua Zhang, Wenwen Xiao. 2020. The drawing of a national blue
product space and its evolution. Marine Policy 112, 103773. [Crossref]
83. Dengli Tang, Shijie Li, Yuanhua Yang, Lianglie Gu. 2020. Regional Difference in Spatial Effects:
A Theoretical and Empirical Study on the Environmental Effects of FDI and Corruption in China.
Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society 2020, 1-12. [Crossref]
84. Ya Chen, Xiaoli Fan, Qian Zhou. 2020. An Inverted-U Impact of Environmental Regulations on
Carbon Emissions in China’s Iron and Steel Industry: Mechanisms of Synergy and Innovation Effects.
Sustainability 12:3, 1038. [Crossref]
85. Fumei He, Ke-Chiun Chang, Min Li, Xueping Li, Fangjhy Li. 2020. Bootstrap ARDL Test on the
Relationship among Trade, FDI, and CO2 Emissions: Based on the Experience of BRICS Countries.
Sustainability 12:3, 1060. [Crossref]
86. Hummera Saleem, Muhammad Bilal Khan, Malik Shahzad Shabbir. 2020. The role of financial
development, energy demand, and technological change in environmental sustainability agenda:
evidence from selected Asian countries. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 27:5, 5266-5280.
[Crossref]
87. Li-Jing Liu, Felix Creutzig, Yun-Fei Yao, Yi-Ming Wei, Qiao-Mei Liang. 2020. Environmental and
economic impacts of trade barriers: The example of China–US trade friction. Resource and Energy
Economics 59, 101144. [Crossref]
88. Pengyan Zhang, Yu Zhang, Jay Lee, Yanyan Li, Jiaxin Yang, Wenliang Geng, Ying Liu, Tianqi Rong,
Jingwen Shao, Bin Li. 2020. Characteristics of the Spatio-Temporal Trends and Driving Factors
of Industrial Development and Industrial SO2 Emissions Based on Niche Theory: Taking Henan
Province as an Example. Sustainability 12:4, 1389. [Crossref]
89. Xiaomeng Zhao, Chuanjiang Liu, Chuanwang Sun, Mian Yang. 2020. Does stringent environmental
regulation lead to a carbon haven effect? Evidence from carbon-intensive industries in China. Energy
Economics 86, 104631. [Crossref]
90. Dengli Tang, Yinan Lu, Wenyi Cai, Xinwei Zhu. 2020. Temporal and Spatial Distribution
Characteristics of Air Pollution and the influence of Energy Structure in Guangdong-Hong Kong-
Macao Greater Bay Area. IOP Conference Series: Earth and Environmental Science 446, 032029.
[Crossref]
91. Shu-Chen Chang, Hsiao-Fen Chang. 2020. Same Trade Openness Yet Different Environmental
Quality — But Why?. Journal of International Commerce, Economics and Policy 11:01, 2050002.
[Crossref]
92. Huiying Ye, Qi Zhang, Xunzhang Pan, Arash Farnoosh. 2020. Market-induced carbon leakage in
China’s certified emission reduction projects. Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for Global Change
163. . [Crossref]
93. Hang Jiang, Peiyi Kong, Yi-Chung Hu, Peng Jiang. 2020. Forecasting China’s CO2 emissions
by considering interaction of bilateral FDI using the improved grey multivariable Verhulst model.
Environment, Development and Sustainability 91. . [Crossref]
94. Haimanti Bhattacharya. 2020. Environmental and socio-economic sustainability in India: evidence
from CO 2 emission and economic inequality relationship. Journal of Environmental Economics and
Policy 9:1, 57-76. [Crossref]
95. Abdelaziz Hakimi, Helmi Hamdi. 2020. Environmental effects of trade openness: what role do
institutions have?. Journal of Environmental Economics and Policy 9:1, 36-56. [Crossref]
96. Julia Swart, Lisa Brinkmann. Economic Complexity and the Environment: Evidence from Brazil 3-45.
[Crossref]
97. Anna Rita Germani, Alan P. Ker, Angelo Castaldo. 2020. On the existence and shape of an
environmental crime Kuznets Curve: A case study of Italian provinces. Ecological Indicators 108,
105685. [Crossref]
98. Qichang Xie, Qiankun Sun. 2020. Assessing the impact of FDI on PM2.5 concentrations: A nonlinear
panel data analysis for emerging economies. Environmental Impact Assessment Review 80, 106314.
[Crossref]
99. Ryan Abman, Clark Lundberg. 2020. Does Free Trade Increase Deforestation? The Effects of
Regional Trade Agreements. Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists 7:1,
35-72. [Crossref]
100. Iftikhar Yasin, Nawaz Ahmad, M. Aslam Chaudhary. 2020. Catechizing the Environmental-
Impression of Urbanization, Financial Development, and Political Institutions: A Circumstance of
Ecological Footprints in 110 Developed and Less-Developed Countries. Social Indicators Research
147:2, 621-649. [Crossref]
101. 文文 文. 2020. Research on Carbon Emission Reduction Effect of Heterogeneous Low-Carbon
Technology Innovation under Space Effect. Sustainable Development 10:01, 74-84. [Crossref]
102. Faik Bilgili, Recep Ulucak, Emrah Koçak, Salih Çağrı İlkay. 2020. Does globalization matter for
environmental sustainability? Empirical investigation for Turkey by Markov regime switching models.
Environmental Science and Pollution Research 27:1, 1087-1100. [Crossref]
103. Kamalova Mariyakhan, Elyas Abdulahi Mohamued, Muhammad Asif Khan, József Popp, Judit Oláh.
2020. Does the Level of Absorptive Capacity Matter for Carbon Intensity? Evidence from the USA
and China. Energies 13:2, 407. [Crossref]
104. Satoshi Honma, Yushi Yoshida. 2020. An empirical investigation of the balance of embodied emission
in trade: Industry structure and emission abatement. Economic Modelling . [Crossref]
105. Daniel Balsalobre-Lorente, Muhammad Shahbaz, Aviral K. Tiwari, Jose C. Jabbour. The
Applicability of the Inflection Point in the Environmental Correction Process 771-779. [Crossref]
106. Alex O. Acheampong, Janet Dzator. Managing Environmental Quality in Sub-Saharan Africa: Does
Institutional Quality Matter? 1-29. [Crossref]
107. Surender Kumar, Prerna Prabhakar. 2020. Industrial energy prices and export competitiveness:
evidence from India. Environmental Economics and Policy Studies 22:1, 1-20. [Crossref]
108. 文文 文. 2020. How Can Technological Innovation Restrain Carbon Intensity?—Research on the
Intermediary Effect Based on Energy Consumption Structure. Advances in Environmental Protection
10:02, 159-165. [Crossref]
109. Tehmina Zahid, Noman Arshed, Mubbasher Munir, Kamran Hameed. 2020. Role of energy
consumption preferences on human development: a study of SAARC region. Economic Change and
Restructuring . [Crossref]
110. Zia Ur RAHMAN. 2019. Does CO2 and Its Possible Determinants are Playing Their Role in the
Environmental Degradation in Turkey. Environment Kuznets Curve Does Exist in Turkey. Journal
of Wellbeing Management and Applied Psychology 2:2, 19-37. [Crossref]
111. Hao Wang, Changgui Dong, Yi Liu. 2019. Beijing direct investment to its neighbors: A pollution
haven or pollution halo effect?. Journal of Cleaner Production 239, 118062. [Crossref]
112. Weiming Lin, Jianling Chen, Yi Zheng, Yongwu Dai. 2019. Effects of the EU Emission Trading
Scheme on the international competitiveness of pulp-and-paper industry. Forest Policy and Economics
109, 102021. [Crossref]
113. Shu-Hong Wang, Ma-Lin Song, Tao Yu. 2019. Hidden Carbon Emissions, Industrial Clusters, and
Structure Optimization in China. Computational Economics 54:4, 1319-1342. [Crossref]
114. Zhaohua Wang, Yasir Rasool, Muhammad Mansoor Asghar, Bo Wang. 2019. Dynamic linkages
among CO2 emissions, human development, financial development, and globalization: empirical
evidence based on PMG long-run panel estimation. Environmental Science and Pollution Research
26:36, 36248-36263. [Crossref]
115. Yu Tu, Benhong Peng, Guo Wei, Ehsan Elahi, Tongrui Yu. 2019. Regional environmental regulation
efficiency: spatiotemporal characteristics and influencing factors. Environmental Science and Pollution
Research 26:36, 37152-37161. [Crossref]
116. Yicheng Fu, Xiaoyu Cui, Laisheng Liu, Jinyong Zhao, Jiwei Leng, Shouping Zhang. 2019.
Equilibrium cost of water environmental protection based on watershed sustainability. Journal of
Hydrology 579, 124216. [Crossref]
117. Yan Xia, Yishu Kong, Qiang Ji, Dayong Zhang. 2019. Impacts of China-US trade conflicts on the
energy sector. China Economic Review 58, 101360. [Crossref]
118. Wenxin Mao, Wenping Wang, Huifang Sun. 2019. Driving patterns of industrial green
transformation: A multiple regions case learning from China. Science of The Total Environment 697,
134134. [Crossref]
119. Yayun Ren, Xiang Ren, Jianbo Hu. 2019. Driving factors of China’s city-level carbon emissions from
the perspective of spatial spillover effect. Carbon Management 10:6, 551-566. [Crossref]
120. Natalia Zugravu-Soilita. 2019. Trade in Environmental Goods and Air Pollution: A Mediation
Analysis to Estimate Total, Direct and Indirect Effects. Environmental and Resource Economics 74:3,
1125-1162. [Crossref]
121. Irfan Ullah, Sher Ali, Muhammad Haroon Shah, Farrah Yasim, Alam Rehman, Basheer M. Al-
Ghazali. 2019. Linkages between Trade, CO2 Emissions and Healthcare Spending in China.
International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health 16:21, 4298. [Crossref]
122. Suvajit Banerjee. 2019. Addressing the Drivers of Carbon Emissions Embodied in Indian Exports:
An Index Decomposition Analysis. Foreign Trade Review 54:4, 300-333. [Crossref]
123. Priyanka Menon. 2019. An Indian story on carbon emission, energy consumption, trade openness,
and financial development. Journal of Public Affairs 19:4. . [Crossref]
124. Liang Chen, B. Cecilia Garcia‐Medina, Rui Wan. 2019. Trade liberalization, consumption shifting
and pollution: Evidence from Mexico's used vehicle imports. Review of International Economics 27:5,
1591-1608. [Crossref]
125. Xin Zhao, Yuping Shang, Malin Song. 2019. Industrial structure distortion and urban ecological
efficiency from the perspective of green entrepreneurial ecosystems. Socio-Economic Planning Sciences
100757. [Crossref]
126. Daniel Kwabena Twerefou, Wisdom Akpalu, Angela Cindy Emefa Mensah. 2019. Trade-induced
environmental quality: the role of factor endowment and environmental regulation in Africa. Climate
and Development 11:9, 786-798. [Crossref]
127. Maxwell Chukwudi Udeagha, Nicholas Ngepah. 2019. Revisiting trade and environment nexus in
South Africa: fresh evidence from new measure. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 26:28,
29283-29306. [Crossref]
128. Muhammad Asim Afridi, Sampath Kehelwalatenna, Imran Naseem, Muhammad Tahir. 2019. Per
capita income, trade openness, urbanization, energy consumption, and CO2 emissions: an empirical
study on the SAARC Region. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 26:29, 29978-29990.
[Crossref]
129. Danling Chen, Xinhai Lu, Xu Liu, Xue Wang. 2019. Measurement of the eco-environmental effects
of urban sprawl: Theoretical mechanism and spatiotemporal differentiation. Ecological Indicators 105,
6-15. [Crossref]
130. Maia King, Bassel Tarbush, Alexander Teytelboym. 2019. Targeted carbon tax reforms. European
Economic Review 119, 526-547. [Crossref]
131. Muhammad Kamran Khan, Jian-Zhou Teng, Muhammad Imran Khan, Muhammad Owais Khan.
2019. Impact of globalization, economic factors and energy consumption on CO2 emissions in
Pakistan. Science of The Total Environment 688, 424-436. [Crossref]
132. Thomas Jobert, Fatih Karanfil, Anna Tykhonenko. 2019. DEGREE OF STRINGENCY
MATTERS: REVISITING THE POLLUTION HAVEN HYPOTHESIS BASED ON
HETEROGENEOUS PANELS AND AGGREGATE DATA. Macroeconomic Dynamics 23:07,
2675-2697. [Crossref]
133. Yongyi Cheng, Tianyuan Shao, Huilin Lai, Manhong Shen, Yi Li. 2019. Total-Factor Eco-Efficiency
and Its Influencing Factors in the Yangtze River Delta Urban Agglomeration, China. International
Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health 16:20, 3814. [Crossref]
134. Rihab Bellakhal, Sonia Ben Kheder, Houda Haffoudhi. 2019. Governance and renewable energy
investment in MENA countries:How does trade matter?. Energy Economics 84, 104541. [Crossref]
135. Jing Wang, Guanghua Wan, Chen Wang. 2019. Participation in GVCs and CO2 emissions. Energy
Economics 84, 104561. [Crossref]
136. Shuai Shao, Yang Chen, Ke Li, Lili Yang. 2019. Market segmentation and urban CO2 emissions in
China: Evidence from the Yangtze River Delta region. Journal of Environmental Management 248,
109324. [Crossref]
137. Edward B. Barbier. Natural Resources and Economic Development 9, . [Crossref]
138. João Paulo Cerdeira Bento, António Moreira. 2019. Environmental impact of FDI – the case of US
subsidiaries. Multinational Business Review 27:3, 226-246. [Crossref]
139. Xiaobing Huang, Xiaolian Liu. 2019. The Impact of Environmental Regulation on Productivity and
Exports: A Firm-Level Evidence from China. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 55:11, 2589-2608.
[Crossref]
140. Umut Uzar, Kemal Eyuboglu. 2019. Is foreign direct investment an engine for energy consumption?
An empirical investigation for Turkey. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 26:27,
28092-28105. [Crossref]
141. Abdelhafidh Dhrifi. 2019. Does Environmental Degradation, Institutional Quality, and Economic
Development Matter for Health? Evidence from African Countries. Journal of the Knowledge Economy
10:3, 1098-1113. [Crossref]
142. Dennis Kolcava, Quynh Nguyen, Thomas Bernauer. 2019. Does trade liberalization lead to
environmental burden shifting in the global economy?. Ecological Economics 163, 98-112. [Crossref]
143. Li Li, Xuemin Liu, Jiaoju Ge, Xianghua Chu, Jun Wang. 2019. Regional differences in spatial spillover
and hysteresis effects: A theoretical and empirical study of environmental regulations on haze pollution
in China. Journal of Cleaner Production 230, 1096-1110. [Crossref]
144. Martin Köppel, Detlef F. Sprinz. 2019. Do Binding Beat Nonbinding Agreements? Regulating
International Water Quality. Journal of Conflict Resolution 63:8, 1860-1888. [Crossref]
145. Jingling Chen, Tao Eric Hu, Rob van Tulder. 2019. Is the Environmental Kuznets Curve Still Valid:
A Perspective of Wicked Problems. Sustainability 11:17, 4747. [Crossref]
146. Alex O. Acheampong. 2019. Modelling for insight: Does financial development improve
environmental quality?. Energy Economics 83, 156-179. [Crossref]
147. Yuwan Duan, Bingqian Yan. 2019. Economic gains and environmental losses from international trade:
A decomposition of pollution intensity in China's value-added trade. Energy Economics 83, 540-554.
[Crossref]
148. Xin Zhao, Gregmar I. Galinato, Tim A. Graciano. 2019. The Welfare Effects of Opening to
Foreign Direct Investment in Polluting Sectors. Environmental and Resource Economics 74:1, 243-269.
[Crossref]
149. Li. 2019. Spatiotemporal Dynamics of Ecological Total-Factor Energy Efficiency and Their Drivers
in China at the Prefecture Level. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health
16:18, 3480. [Crossref]
150. Muhammad Shahbaz, Mantu Kumar Mahalik, Syed Jawad Hussain Shahzad, Shawkat Hammoudeh.
2019. Testing the globalization-driven carbon emissions hypothesis: International evidence.
International Economics 158, 25-38. [Crossref]
151. Alex O. Acheampong, Samuel Adams, Elliot Boateng. 2019. Do globalization and renewable energy
contribute to carbon emissions mitigation in Sub-Saharan Africa?. Science of The Total Environment
677, 436-446. [Crossref]
152. Lingyun Zhu, Yu Hao, Zhi-Nan Lu, Haitao Wu, Qiying Ran. 2019. Do economic activities cause air
pollution? Evidence from China’s major cities. Sustainable Cities and Society 49, 101593. [Crossref]
153. Dongxia Wei, Yuan Liu, N. Zhang. 2019. Does industry upgrade transfer pollution: Evidence from
a natural experiment of Guangdong province in China. Journal of Cleaner Production 229, 902-910.
[Crossref]
154. Abdulkadir Abdulrashid Rafindadi, Ojonugwa Usman. 2019. Globalization, energy use, and
environmental degradation in South Africa: Startling empirical evidence from the Maki-cointegration
test. Journal of Environmental Management 244, 265-275. [Crossref]
155. Hua-ping Sun, Gulzara Tariq, Muhammad Haris, Muhammad Mohsin. 2019. Evaluating the
environmental effects of economic openness: evidence from SAARC countries. Environmental Science
and Pollution Research 26:24, 24542-24551. [Crossref]
156. Muhammad Shahbaz. 2019. Globalization–Emissions Nexus: Testing the EKC Hypothesis in
Next-11 Countries. Global Business Review 134, 097215091985849. [Crossref]
157. Satoshi Honma, Yushi Yoshida. 2019. Convergence in pollution terms of trade. The Journal of
International Trade & Economic Development 28:5, 603-627. [Crossref]
158. Pasquale Pazienza. 2019. The impact of FDI in the OECD manufacturing sector on CO2 emission:
Evidence and policy issues. Environmental Impact Assessment Review 77, 60-68. [Crossref]
159. Alex O. Acheampong, Emmanuel B. Boateng. 2019. Modelling carbon emission intensity: Application
of artificial neural network. Journal of Cleaner Production 225, 833-856. [Crossref]
160. Yantuan Yu, Chong Peng, Yushuang Li. 2019. Do neighboring prefectures matter in promoting eco-
efficiency? Empirical evidence from China. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 144, 456-465.
[Crossref]
161. Shu-Hong Wang, Zheng-Zheng Li, Malin Song. 2019. How embodied carbon in trade affects labor
income in developing countries. Science of The Total Environment 672, 71-80. [Crossref]
162. Yankun Zhou, Xiaoqiang Zhi, Huiying Wu, Yongqing Li. 2019. The role of Chinese people’s
political consultative conference in environmental governance. Sustainability Accounting, Management
and Policy Journal ahead-of-print:ahead-of-print. . [Crossref]
163. Ling-Yun He, Xi Lin. 2019. Trade Imbalance, Heterogeneous Firms and Pollution Emissions:
Evidence from China’s Manufacturing Sector. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 84, 1-26.
[Crossref]
164. Erik Hille, Muhammad Shahbaz, Imad Moosa. 2019. The impact of FDI on regional air pollution
in the Republic of Korea: A way ahead to achieve the green growth strategy?. Energy Economics 81,
308-326. [Crossref]
165. Nicolas Koch, Houdou Basse Mama. 2019. Does the EU Emissions Trading System induce investment
leakage? Evidence from German multinational firms. Energy Economics 81, 479-492. [Crossref]
166. Stuart J. Barnes. 2019. Understanding plastics pollution: The role of economic development and
technological research. Environmental Pollution 249, 812-821. [Crossref]
167. NGUYEN VAN BON. 2019. THE ROLE OF INSTITUTIONAL QUALITY IN THE
RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN FDI AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN VIETNAM: EMPIRICAL
EVIDENCE FROM PROVINCIAL DATA. The Singapore Economic Review 64:03, 601-623.
[Crossref]
168. Saša Obradović, Nemanja Lojanica. 2019. Does environmental quality reflect on national
competitiveness? The evidence from EU-15. Energy & Environment 30:4, 559-585. [Crossref]
169. Megha Jain, Aishwarya Nagpal. 2019. Relationship Between Environmental Sustainability and
Human Development Index: A Case of Selected South Asian Nations. Vision: The Journal of Business
Perspective 23:2, 125-133. [Crossref]
170. Hoong Chen Teo, Alex Mark Lechner, Grant W. Walton, Faith Ka Shun Chan, Ali Cheshmehzangi,
May Tan-Mullins, Hing Kai Chan, Troy Sternberg, Ahimsa Campos-Arceiz. 2019. Environmental
Impacts of Infrastructure Development under the Belt and Road Initiative. Environments 6:6, 72.
[Crossref]
171. Mohammad Salahuddin, Jeff Gow, Md. Idris Ali, Md. Rahat Hossain, Khaleda Shaheen Al-Azami,
Delwar Akbar, Ayfer Gedikli. 2019. Urbanization-globalization-CO2 emissions nexus revisited:
empirical evidence from South Africa. Heliyon 5:6, e01974. [Crossref]
172. Xueping Wu, Ming Gao, Shihong Guo, Wei Li. 2019. Effects of environmental regulation on air
pollution control in China: a spatial Durbin econometric analysis. Journal of Regulatory Economics
55:3, 307-333. [Crossref]
173. Sin-Yu Ho, Bernard Njindan Iyke. 2019. Trade Openness and Carbon Emissions: Evidence from
Central and Eastern European Countries. Review of Economics 70:1, 41-67. [Crossref]
174. Cheon Yu, Danilova Nataliia, Seung-Jick Yoo, Yun-Seop Hwang. 2019. Does trade openness convey
a positive impact for the environmental quality? Evidence from a panel of CIS countries. Eurasian
Geography and Economics 60:3, 333-356. [Crossref]
175. Maria Savona, Tommaso Ciarli. 2019. Structural Changes and Sustainability. A Selected Review of
the Empirical Evidence. Ecological Economics 159, 244-260. [Crossref]
176. Johan Graafland. 2019. Economic freedom and corporate environmental responsibility: The role
of small government and freedom from government regulation. Journal of Cleaner Production 218,
250-258. [Crossref]
177. Nepal, Korhonen, Prestemon, Cubbage. 2019. Projecting Global and Regional Forest Area under
the Shared Socioeconomic Pathways Using an Updated Environmental Kuznets Curve Model. Forests
10:5, 387. [Crossref]
178. Ling-Yun He, Liang Wang. 2019. Import Liberalization of Intermediates and Environment: Empirical
Evidence from Chinese Manufacturing. Sustainability 11:9, 2579. [Crossref]
179. Huaping Sun, Samuel Attuquaye Clottey, Yong Geng, Kai Fang, Joshua Clifford Kofi Amissah. 2019.
Trade Openness and Carbon Emissions: Evidence from Belt and Road Countries. Sustainability 11:9,
2682. [Crossref]
180. X.F. Wu, G.Q. Chen. 2019. Global overview of crude oil use: From source to sink through inter-
regional trade. Energy Policy 128, 476-486. [Crossref]
181. Ojonugwa Usman, Paul Terhemba Iorember, Ifedolapo O. Olanipekun. 2019. Revisiting the
environmental Kuznets curve (EKC) hypothesis in India: the effects of energy consumption and
democracy. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 26:13, 13390-13400. [Crossref]
182. Lamini Dauda, Xingle Long, Claudia Nyarko Mensah, Muhammad Salman. 2019. The effects of
economic growth and innovation on CO2 emissions in different regions. Environmental Science and
Pollution Research 26:15, 15028-15038. [Crossref]
183. Dilawar Khan, Arif Ullah. 2019. Testing the relationship between globalization and carbon dioxide
emissions in Pakistan: does environmental Kuznets curve exist?. Environmental Science and Pollution
Research 26:15, 15194-15208. [Crossref]
184. Zhike Lv, Ting Xu. 2019. Trade openness, urbanization and CO 2 emissions: Dynamic panel data
analysis of middle-income countries. The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development
28:3, 317-330. [Crossref]
185. Dhimitri Qirjo, Razvan Pascalau. 2019. The Role of TTIP on the Environment. Southern Economic
Journal 85:4, 1262-1285. [Crossref]
186. Muhammad Shahbaz, Daniel Balsalobre, Syed Jawad Hussain Shahzad. 2019. The Influencing Factors
of CO2 Emissions and the Role of Biomass Energy Consumption: Statistical Experience from G-7
Countries. Environmental Modeling & Assessment 24:2, 143-161. [Crossref]
187. Christina W.Y. Wong, Kee-hung Lai, Yu Pang, Hazel Sung Yan Lee, T.C.E. Cheng. 2019. Sourcing
green makes green: Evidence from the BRICs. Industrial Marketing Management . [Crossref]
188. Muhammad Shahbaz, Daniel Balsalobre-Lorente, Avik Sinha. 2019. Foreign direct Investment–
CO2 emissions nexus in Middle East and North African countries: Importance of biomass energy
consumption. Journal of Cleaner Production 217, 603-614. [Crossref]
189. Chris Jeffords, Alexi Thompson. 2019. The human rights foundations of an EKC with a minimum
consumption requirement: theory, implications, and quantitative findings. Letters in Spatial and
Resource Sciences 12:1, 41-49. [Crossref]
190. Arshian Sharif, Sahar Afshan, Muhammad Asif Qureshi. 2019. Idolization and ramification between
globalization and ecological footprints: evidence from quantile-on-quantile approach. Environmental
Science and Pollution Research 26:11, 11191-11211. [Crossref]
191. Ian Coxhead. 2019. Environmentalism with Chinese Characteristics—A Review of Matthew E. Kahn
and Siqi Zheng’s Blue Skies over Beijing: Economic Growth and the Environment in China. Journal
of Economic Literature 57:1, 161-179. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
192. Mayula Chaikumbung, Hristos Doucouliagos, Helen Scarborough. 2019. Institutions, Culture, and
Wetland Values. Ecological Economics 157, 195-204. [Crossref]
193. Lin-Sea Lau, Chee-Keong Choong, Cheong-Fatt Ng, Feng-Mei Liew, Suet-Ling Ching. 2019.
Is nuclear energy clean? Revisit of Environmental Kuznets Curve hypothesis in OECD countries.
Economic Modelling 77, 12-20. [Crossref]
194. Xudong Chen, Bihong Huang, Chin-Te Lin. 2019. Environmental awareness and environmental
Kuznets curve. Economic Modelling 77, 2-11. [Crossref]
195. Muhammad Shahbaz, Ilham Haouas, Thi Hong Van Hoang. 2019. Economic growth and
environmental degradation in Vietnam: Is the environmental Kuznets curve a complete picture?.
Emerging Markets Review 38, 197-218. [Crossref]
196. P. Montalbano, S. Nenci. 2019. Energy efficiency, productivity and exporting: Firm-level evidence in
Latin America. Energy Economics 79, 97-110. [Crossref]
197. Lawrence D. LaPlue. 2019. The environmental effects of trade within and across sectors. Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management 94, 118-139. [Crossref]
198. Yu-Bong Lai. 2019. Environmental policy competition and heterogeneous capital endowments.
Regional Science and Urban Economics 75, 107-119. [Crossref]
199. Anis Omri, Jalel Euchi, Abdel Hafiez Hasaballah, Ahmad Al-Tit. 2019. Determinants of
environmental sustainability: Evidence from Saudi Arabia. Science of The Total Environment 657,
1592-1601. [Crossref]
200. Bin Fan, Yun Zhang, Xiuzhen Li, Xiao Miao. 2019. Trade Openness and Carbon Leakage: Empirical
Evidence from China’s Industrial Sector. Energies 12:6, 1101. [Crossref]
201. Muhammad Zakaria, Samina Bibi. 2019. Financial development and environment in South Asia: the
role of institutional quality. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 26:8, 7926-7937. [Crossref]
202. Neha Saini, Monica Sighania. 2019. Environmental impact of economic growth, emission and FDI:
systematic review of reviews. Qualitative Research in Financial Markets 11:1, 81-134. [Crossref]
203. Dong-Hyeon Kim, Yu-Bo Suen, Shu-Chin Lin. 2019. Carbon dioxide emissions and trade: Evidence
from disaggregate trade data. Energy Economics 78, 13-28. [Crossref]
204. Erik Hille, Muhammad Shahbaz. 2019. Sources of emission reductions: Market and policy-stringency
effects. Energy Economics 78, 29-43. [Crossref]
205. Paolo Agnolucci, Theodoros Arvanitopoulos. 2019. Industrial characteristics and air emissions: Long-
term determinants in the UK manufacturing sector. Energy Economics 78, 546-566. [Crossref]
206. Mehdi Nemati, Wuyang Hu, Michael Reed. 2019. Are free trade agreements good for the
environment? A panel data analysis. Review of Development Economics 23:1, 435-453. [Crossref]
207. Luciana Echazu, Martin Heintzelman. 2019. Environmental regulation and love for variety. Review
of International Economics 27:1, 413-430. [Crossref]
208. Xing Yao, Rizwana Yasmeen, Yunong Li, Muhammad Hafeez, Ihtsham Padda. 2019. Free Trade
Agreements and Environment for Sustainable Development: A Gravity Model Analysis. Sustainability
11:3, 597. [Crossref]
209. Rizwana Yasmeen, Yunong Li, Muhammad Hafeez. 2019. Tracing the trade–pollution nexus in global
value chains: evidence from air pollution indicators. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 26:5,
5221-5233. [Crossref]
210. Hui Wang, Huifang Liu. 2019. Foreign direct investment, environmental regulation, and
environmental pollution: an empirical study based on threshold effects for different Chinese regions.
Environmental Science and Pollution Research 26:6, 5394-5409. [Crossref]
211. Boopendra Seetanah, Raja Vinesh Sannassee, Sheereen Fauzel, Y. Soobaruth, Giancarlo Giudici,
Anh Pham Huy Nguyen. 2019. Impact of Economic and Financial Development on Environmental
Degradation: Evidence from Small Island Developing States (SIDS). Emerging Markets Finance and
Trade 55:2, 308-322. [Crossref]
212. Michael Hübler. 2019. How trade in ecotourism services can save nature: a policy scenario analysis.
Development Southern Africa 36:1, 127-143. [Crossref]
213. Michael L. Polemis, Thanasis Stengos. 2019. Does competition prevent industrial pollution? Evidence
from a panel threshold model. Business Strategy and the Environment 28:1, 98-110. [Crossref]
214. Muhammad Shahbaz, Mantu Kumar Mahalik, Syed Jawad Hussain Shahzad, Shawkat Hammoudeh.
2019. Does the environmental Kuznets curve exist between globalization and energy consumption?
Global evidence from the cross-correlation method. International Journal of Finance & Economics 24:1,
540-557. [Crossref]
215. Soumyananda Dinda. Literature Review 9-14. [Crossref]
216. Soumyananda Dinda. Emerging Climate Business in South Asia 77-88. [Crossref]
217. Pham Ngoc Thanh, Nguyen Duy Phuong, Bui Hoang Ngoc. Economic Integration and
Environmental Pollution Nexus in Asean: A PMG Approach 427-439. [Crossref]
218. Claude Njomgang. Some Theoretical and Policy Issues in Green Economy 7-26. [Crossref]
219. Aïcha EL Alaoui, Hassane Nekrache. Economic Growth and Environment: An Empirical Analysis
Applied to Morocco, Algeria, Tunisia, and Egypt 357-376. [Crossref]
220. Raymond J. MacDermott, A. Basuchoudhary, J. Bang. Trade, Trade Agreements, and the
Environment 107-112. [Crossref]
221. Luís Miguel Marques, José Alberto Fuinhas, António Cardoso Marques. The impacts of China’s
effect and globalization on the augmented energy–nexus: evidence in four aggregated regions 97-139.
[Crossref]
222. Zhao Xin-gang, Zhang Yuan-feng, Li Yan-bin. 2019. The spillovers of foreign direct investment and
the convergence of energy intensity. Journal of Cleaner Production 206, 611-621. [Crossref]
223. Helene Naegele, Aleksandar Zaklan. 2019. Does the EU ETS cause carbon leakage in European
manufacturing?. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 93, 125-147. [Crossref]
224. Maria Savona, Tommaso Ciarli. 2019. Structural Changes and Sustainability. A Selected Review of
the Empirical Evidence. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
225. Jiansuo Pei, Bodo Sturm, Anqi Yu. 2019. Are Exporters More Environmentally Friendly? A Re-
Appraisal that Uses China’s Micro-Data. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
226. Mohammad Salahuddin, Md. Idris Ali, Nick Vink, Jeff Gow. 2019. The effects of urbanization
and globalization on CO2 emissions: evidence from the Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) countries.
Environmental Science and Pollution Research 26:3, 2699-2709. [Crossref]
227. Shuquan He. 2019. The Impact of Trade on Environmental Quality: A Business Ethics Perspective
and Evidence from China. Business Ethics and Leadership 3:4, 43-48. [Crossref]
228. Victor Troster, Muhammad Shahbaz. Globalization and CO2 Emissions: Addressing an Old Question
with New Techniques 251-270. [Crossref]
229. Deniz Güvercin. The Benefits and Costs of Foreign Direct Investment for Sustainability in Emerging
Market Economies 39-59. [Crossref]
230. Tonmoy Chatterjee. Environmental Regulation, International Trade, and Informal Sector 80-106.
[Crossref]
231. João Bento, Miguel Torres, Paolo Maranzano. Outward US Foreign Direct Investment and
Environmental Degradation 252-268. [Crossref]
232. Muhammad Imran Nazir, Muhammad Rizwan Nazir, Shujahat Haider Hashmi, Zahid Ali. 2018.
Environmental Kuznets Curve hypothesis for Pakistan: Empirical evidence form ARDL bound testing
and causality approach. International Journal of Green Energy 15:14-15, 947-957. [Crossref]
233. Joseph S. Shapiro, Reed Walker. 2018. Why Is Pollution from US Manufacturing Declining? The
Roles of Environmental Regulation, Productivity, and Trade. American Economic Review 108:12,
3814-3854. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
234. Mansor H. Ibrahim. 2018. Trade–finance complementarity and carbon emission intensity: panel
evidence from middle-income countries. Environment Systems and Decisions 38:4, 489-500. [Crossref]
235. Inmaculada Martínez-Zarzoso, Walid Oueslati. 2018. Do deep and comprehensive regional trade
agreements help in reducing air pollution?. International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and
Economics 18:6, 743-777. [Crossref]
236. Rizwana Yasmeen, Yunong Li, Muhammad Hafeez, Haseeb Ahmad. 2018. The trade-environment
nexus in light of governance: a global potential. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 25:34,
34360-34379. [Crossref]
237. Murat Cetin, Eyyup Ecevit, Ali Gokhan Yucel. 2018. The impact of economic growth, energy
consumption, trade openness, and financial development on carbon emissions: empirical evidence from
Turkey. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 25:36, 36589-36603. [Crossref]
238. Sabrina Auci, Giovanni Trovato. 2018. The environmental Kuznets curve within European countries
and sectors: greenhouse emission, production function and technology. Economia Politica 35:3,
895-915. [Crossref]
239. Lulu Zhang, Lichun Xiong, Baodong Cheng, Chang Yu. 2018. How does foreign trade influence
China’s carbon productivity? Based on panel spatial lag model analysis. Structural Change and
Economic Dynamics 47, 171-179. [Crossref]
240. Qian Dang, Megan Konar, Peter Debaere. 2018. Trade openness and the nutrient use of nations.
Environmental Research Letters 13:12, 124016. [Crossref]
241. Muhammad Shahbaz, Syed Jawad Hussain Shahzad, Shaista Alam, Nicholas Apergis. 2018.
Globalisation, economic growth and energy consumption in the BRICS region: The importance of
asymmetries. The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 27:8, 985-1009. [Crossref]
242. Muhammad Shahbaz, Amatul Razzaq Chaudhary, Syed Jawad Hussain Shahzad. 2018. Is energy
consumption sensitive to foreign capital inflows and currency devaluation in Pakistan?. Applied
Economics 50:52, 5641-5658. [Crossref]
243. Shyam Ranganathan, Ranjula Bali Swain. 2018. Sustainable development and global emission targets:
A dynamical systems approach to aid evidence-based policy making. Sustainable Development 26:6,
812-821. [Crossref]
244. Mouyad Alsamara, Zouhair Mrabet, Ali Salman Saleh, Sajid Anwar. 2018. The environmental Kuznets
curve relationship: a case study of the Gulf Cooperation Council region. Environmental Science and
Pollution Research 25:33, 33183-33195. [Crossref]
245. Nita Rudra, Meir Alkon, Siddharth Joshi. 2018. FDI, Poverty, and the Politics of Potable Water
Access. Economics & Politics 30:3, 366-393. [Crossref]
246. Songping Zhu, Azhong Ye. 2018. Does the Impact of China’s Outward Foreign Direct Investment on
Reverse Green Technology Process Differ across Countries?. Sustainability 10:11, 3841. [Crossref]
247. Wen Jun, Muhammad Zakaria, Syed Shahzad, Hamid Mahmood. 2018. Effect of FDI on Pollution
in China: New Insights Based on Wavelet Approach. Sustainability 10:11, 3859. [Crossref]
248. Karim Mimouni, Akram Temimi. 2018. What drives energy efficiency? New evidence from financial
crises. Energy Policy 122, 332-348. [Crossref]
249. Michele Imbruno, Tobias D. Ketterer. 2018. Energy efficiency gains from importing intermediate
inputs: Firm-level evidence from Indonesia. Journal of Development Economics 135, 117-141. [Crossref]
250. Natalia Zugravu-Soilita. 2018. The impact of trade in environmental goods on pollution: what are
we learning from the transition economies’ experience?. Environmental Economics and Policy Studies
20:4, 785-827. [Crossref]
251. Pradyot Ranjan Jena. 2018. Does trade liberalization create more pollution? Evidence from a panel
regression analysis across the states of India. Environmental Economics and Policy Studies 20:4, 861-877.
[Crossref]
252. Muhammad Shahbaz, Syed Jawad Hussain Shahzad, Mantu Kumar Mahalik. 2018. Is Globalization
Detrimental to CO2 Emissions in Japan? New Threshold Analysis. Environmental Modeling &
Assessment 23:5, 557-568. [Crossref]
253. Tobias Erhardt. 2018. Does International Trade Cause Overfishing?. Journal of the Association of
Environmental and Resource Economists 5:4, 695-711. [Crossref]
254. Sudeshna Ghosh. 2018. Globalization and Environment: An Asian Experience. Journal of International
Commerce, Economics and Policy 09:03, 1850010. [Crossref]
255. Hongxun Liu, Jianglong Li, Houyin Long, Zhi Li, Canyu Le. 2018. Promoting energy and
environmental efficiency within a positive feedback loop: Insights from global value chain. Energy
Policy 121, 175-184. [Crossref]
256. Robi Kurniawan, Shunsuke Managi. 2018. Coal consumption, urbanization, and trade openness
linkage in Indonesia. Energy Policy 121, 576-583. [Crossref]
257. Zheng Fang, Bihong Huang, Zhuoxiang Yang. 2018. Trade openness and the environmental Kuznets
curve: Evidence from Chinese cities. The World Economy 91. . [Crossref]
258. Kunofiwa Tsaurai. 2018. FDI Inspired Energy Consumption in Selected Emerging Markets: Does
Financial Development Matter?. Comparative Economic Research. Central and Eastern Europe 21:3,
5-23. [Crossref]
259. Kashif Munir, Ayesha Ameer. 2018. Effect of economic growth, trade openness, urbanization, and
technology on environment of Asian emerging economies. Management of Environmental Quality: An
International Journal 29:6, 1123-1134. [Crossref]
260. Lin-Sea Lau, Chee-Keong Choong, Cheong-Fatt Ng. Role of Institutional Quality on Environmental
Kuznets Curve: A Comparative Study in Developed and Developing Countries 223-247. [Crossref]
261. Malin Song, Shuhong Wang, Kaiya Wu. 2018. Environment-biased technological progress and
industrial land-use efficiency in China’s new normal. Annals of Operations Research 268:1-2, 425-440.
[Crossref]
262. Yulin Liu, Zhihui Li, Xingmin Yin. 2018. The effects of three types of environmental regulation
on energy consumption—evidence from China. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 25:27,
27334-27351. [Crossref]
263. Vicente Rios, Lisa Gianmoena. 2018. Convergence in CO2 emissions: A spatial economic analysis
with cross-country interactions. Energy Economics 75, 222-238. [Crossref]
264. Rikard Forslid, Toshihiro Okubo, Karen Helene Ulltveit-Moe. 2018. Why are firms that export
cleaner? International trade, abatement and environmental emissions. Journal of Environmental
Economics and Management 91, 166-183. [Crossref]
265. Tonmoy Chowdhury, A K M Nazrul Islam. 2018. China’s trade in climate smart goods: an analysis
of trends and trading patterns. Environmental Economics 9:3, 12-22. [Crossref]
266. Amanda M. Countryman, Travis Warziniack, Erin Grey. 2018. Implications for U.S. Trade and
Nonindigenous Species Risk Resulting from Increased Economic Integration of the Asia-Pacific
Region. Society & Natural Resources 31:8, 942-959. [Crossref]
267. Xianchun Liao, Xunpeng (Roc) Shi. 2018. Public appeal, environmental regulation and green
investment: Evidence from China. Energy Policy 119, 554-562. [Crossref]
268. Frank Pothen, Michael Hübler. 2018. The interaction of climate and trade policy. European Economic
Review 107, 1-26. [Crossref]
269. Alex O. Acheampong. 2018. Economic growth, CO2 emissions and energy consumption: What causes
what and where?. Energy Economics 74, 677-692. [Crossref]
270. Akihiro Otsuka, Mika Goto. 2018. Regional determinants of energy intensity in Japan: the impact of
population density. Asia-Pacific Journal of Regional Science 2:2, 257-278. [Crossref]
271. Giulia Ceccantoni, Ornella Tarola, Skerdilajda Zanaj. 2018. Green Consumption and Relative
Preferences in a Vertically Differentiated International Oligopoly. Ecological Economics 149, 129-139.
[Crossref]
272. Boqiang Lin, Junpeng Zhu. 2018. Changes in urban air quality during urbanization in China. Journal
of Cleaner Production 188, 312-321. [Crossref]
273. Emilio Gutiérrez, Kensuke Teshima. 2018. Abatement expenditures, technology choice, and
environmental performance: Evidence from firm responses to import competition in Mexico. Journal
of Development Economics 133, 264-274. [Crossref]
274. Shulin Wan, Weixin Luan. 2018. Export trade and Environmental Pollution: An Analysis from a
Spatial Perspective. IOP Conference Series: Materials Science and Engineering 394, 052025. [Crossref]
275. Feng Liu, Kangning Xu, Meina Zheng. 2018. The Effect of Environmental Regulation on
Employment in China: Empirical Research Based on Individual-Level Data. Sustainability 10:7, 2373.
[Crossref]
276. Bo Li, Fei Xing, Mark Yu. 2018. Upstream Pricing Schemes, Trade Liberalization, Trade and
Environmental Policies of Downstream Countries. Sustainability 10:7, 2428. [Crossref]
277. Zheming Yan, Rui Shi, Zhiming Yang. 2018. ICT Development and Sustainable Energy
Consumption: A Perspective of Energy Productivity. Sustainability 10:7, 2568. [Crossref]
278. Eirik B. Abrahamsen, Frank Asche, Roy E. Dahl. Safety and economic activity 434-440. [Crossref]
279. Wanhai You, Zhike Lv. 2018. Spillover effects of economic globalization on CO2 emissions: A spatial
panel approach. Energy Economics 73, 248-257. [Crossref]
280. Prathibha Joshi, Kris Beck. 2018. Democracy and carbon dioxide emissions: Assessing the interactions
of political and economic freedom and the environmental Kuznets curve. Energy Research & Social
Science 39, 46-54. [Crossref]
281. Xinzheng Shi, Zhufeng Xu. 2018. Environmental regulation and firm exports: Evidence from the
eleventh Five-Year Plan in China. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 89, 187-200.
[Crossref]
282. Ibrahim A. Tajudeen, Ada Wossink, Prasenjit Banerjee. 2018. How significant is energy efficiency to
mitigate CO2 emissions? Evidence from OECD countries. Energy Economics 72, 200-221. [Crossref]
283. Meeta Keswani Mehra, Deepti Kohli. 2018. Environmental regulation and intra-industry trade.
International Economic Journal 32:2, 133-160. [Crossref]
284. Muhammad Shahbaz, Syed Jawad Hussain Shahzad, Mantu Kumar Mahalik, Shawkat Hammoudeh.
2018. Does Globalisation Worsen Environmental Quality in Developed Economies?. Environmental
Modeling & Assessment 23:2, 141-156. [Crossref]
285. Fredj Jawadi, Sami El Gouddi, Zied Ftiti, Abdeljaoued Kacem. 2018. Assessing the Effect of Trade
Openness on Health in the MENA Region: a Panel Data Analysis. Open Economies Review 29:2,
469-479. [Crossref]
286. Mihai Mutascu. 2018. A time-frequency analysis of trade openness and CO2 emissions in France.
Energy Policy 115, 443-455. [Crossref]
287. Lixia Yang, Hao Xia, Xiaoling Zhang, Shaofeng Yuan. 2018. What matters for carbon emissions in
regional sectors? A China study of extended STIRPAT model. Journal of Cleaner Production 180,
595-602. [Crossref]
288. Muhammad Shahbaz, Syed Jawad Hussain Shahzad, Mantu Kumar Mahalik, Perry Sadorsky. 2018.
How strong is the causal relationship between globalization and energy consumption in developed
economies? A country-specific time-series and panel analysis. Applied Economics 50:13, 1479-1494.
[Crossref]
289. Muhammad Shahbaz, Amine Lahiani, Salah Abosedra, Shawkat Hammoudeh. 2018. The role of
globalization in energy consumption: A quantile cointegrating regression approach. Energy Economics
71, 161-170. [Crossref]
290. J. Scott Holladay, Mohammed Mohsin, Shreekar Pradhan. 2018. Emissions leakage, environmental
policy and trade frictions. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 88, 95-113. [Crossref]
291. Jacint Balaguer, Manuel Cantavella. 2018. The role of education in the Environmental Kuznets Curve.
Evidence from Australian data. Energy Economics 70, 289-296. [Crossref]
292. Daniel Balsalobre-Lorente, Muhammad Shahbaz, David Roubaud, Sahbi Farhani. 2018. How
economic growth, renewable electricity and natural resources contribute to CO2 emissions?. Energy
Policy 113, 356-367. [Crossref]
293. Hongxiao Liu, Baolong Han, Lan Wang. 2018. Modeling the spatial relationship between urban
ecological resources and the economy. Journal of Cleaner Production 173, 207-216. [Crossref]
294. Luis Antonio López, Guadalupe Arce, Tobias Kronenberg, João F.D. Rodrigues. 2018. Trade from
resource-rich countries avoids the existence of a global pollution haven hypothesis. Journal of Cleaner
Production 175, 599-611. [Crossref]
295. Abdulkadir Abdulrashid Rafindadi, Ibrahim Muhammad Muye, Rayyanu Abdulkarim Kaita. 2018.
The effects of FDI and energy consumption on environmental pollution in predominantly resource-
based economies of the GCC. Sustainable Energy Technologies and Assessments 25, 126-137. [Crossref]
296. Elsayed Mettwally Abd-Elkader. 2018. Trade Liberalization and Carbon Dioxide Emissions: A Pooled
Mean Group Analysis. International Journal of Trade, Economics and Finance 9:1, 1-7. [Crossref]
297. , , , . 2018. Environmental Regulation, Foreign Direct Investment and Green Technological Progress
—Evidence from Chinese Manufacturing Industries. International Journal of Environmental Research
and Public Health 15:2, 221. [Crossref]
298. Deshan Li, Rongwei Wu. 2018. A Dynamic Analysis of Green Productivity Growth for Cities in
Xinjiang. Sustainability 10:2, 515. [Crossref]
299. Mian Yang, Tiemeng Ma, Chuanwang Sun. 2018. Evaluating the impact of urban traffic investment
on SO2 emissions in China cities. Energy Policy 113, 20-27. [Crossref]
300. Vinicius A. Vale, Fernando S. Perobelli, Ariaster B. Chimeli. 2018. International trade, pollution,
and economic structure: evidence on CO 2 emissions for the North and the South. Economic Systems
Research 30:1, 1-17. [Crossref]
301. Rossarin Osathanunkul, Natthaphat Kingnetr, Songsak Sriboonchitta. Emissions, Trade Openness,
Urbanisation, and Income in Thailand: An Empirical Analysis 517-535. [Crossref]
302. Unmesh Patnaik, Santosh K. Sahu. Foreign Direct Investment and Business Cycle Co-movement:
Evidence from Asian Countries 63-88. [Crossref]
303. Paramita Dasgupta, Kakali Mukhopadhyay. India’s Intra-industry Trade: Implication on Vertical
Specialization, Environment and Employment 315-344. [Crossref]
304. Cristian Barra, Roberto Zotti. 2018. Investigating the non-linearity between national income and
environmental pollution: international evidence of Kuznets curve. Environmental Economics and Policy
Studies 20:1, 179-210. [Crossref]
305. David I. Stern. The Environmental Kuznets Curve 文 . [Crossref]
306. Philip Kofi Adom, Samuel Adams. 2018. Energy savings in Nigeria. Is there a way of escape from
energy inefficiency?. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 81, 2421-2430. [Crossref]
307. Yong Tu. 2018. Urban debates for climate change after the Kyoto Protocol. Urban Studies 55:1, 3-18.
[Crossref]
308. Maia King, Bassel Tarbush, Alexander Teytelboym. 2018. Targeted Carbon Tax Reforms. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
309. Teresa Cyrus. 2018. Pathways from trade to health. Revista Panamericana de Salud Pública 42. .
[Crossref]
310. Hatice Özkoç, Aynur Yıldırım, Emir Kudubeş. 2017. ÇEVRESEL KUZNETS EĞRİSİNİN
GEÇERLİLİĞİNİN DÜŞÜK VE ÜST ORTA GELİRLİ ÜLKELER İÇİN SINANMASI:
1964-2009 DÖNEMİ - TESTING ENVIRONMENTAL KUZNETS CURVE VALIDITY FOR
THE LOWER AND UPPER MIDDLE INCOME COUNTRIES: 1964-2009 PERIOD. Mehmet
Akif Ersoy Üniversitesi Sosyal Bilimler Enstitüsü Dergisi 327-340. [Crossref]
311. Peng Tian, Boqiang Lin. 2017. Promoting green productivity growth for China's industrial exports:
Evidence from a hybrid input-output model. Energy Policy 111, 394-402. [Crossref]
312. Mingquan Li, Qi Wang. 2017. Will technology advances alleviate climate change? Dual effects of
technology change on aggregate carbon dioxide emissions. Energy for Sustainable Development 41,
61-68. [Crossref]
313. Daniel Kwabena Twerefou, Kwadwo Danso-Mensah, Godfred A. Bokpin. 2017. The environmental
effects of economic growth and globalization in Sub-Saharan Africa: A panel general method of
moments approach. Research in International Business and Finance 42, 939-949. [Crossref]
314. Brian R. Copeland, M. Scott Taylor. 2017. Environmental and resource economics: A Canadian
retrospective. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 50:5, 1381-1413.
[Crossref]
315. Roberto Ezcurra, Beatriz Manotas. 2017. Is there a link between globalisation and civil conflict?. The
World Economy 40:12, 2592-2610. [Crossref]
316. Wenbin Cao, Hui Wang, Huihui Ying. 2017. The Effect of Environmental Regulation on
Employment in Resource-Based Areas of China—An Empirical Research Based on the Mediating
Effect Model. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health 14:12, 1598.
[Crossref]
317. Linda Fernandez, Monica Das. 2017. Effective Policies for Transportation and Pollution Reduction
on North America’s International Borders. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy 17:4. .
[Crossref]
318. Jingbo Cui. 2017. Induced clean technology adoption and international trade with heterogeneous
firms. The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 26:8, 924-954. [Crossref]
319. Dina Frutos-Bencze, Kanix Bukkavesa, Nat Kulvanich. 2017. Impact of FDI and trade on
environmental quality in the CAFTA-DR region. Applied Economics Letters 24:19, 1393-1398.
[Crossref]
320. Yanqing Jiang, Jinghai Zheng. 2017. Economic Growth or Environmental Sustainability? Drivers of
Pollution in the Yangtze River Delta Urban Agglomeration in China. Emerging Markets Finance and
Trade 53:11, 2625-2643. [Crossref]
321. Xiaoyang Li, Yue M. Zhou. 2017. Offshoring Pollution while Offshoring Production?. Strategic
Management Journal 38:11, 2310-2329. [Crossref]
322. Keita Abe, Gakushi Ishimura, Tetsuya Tsurumi, Shunsuke Managi, Ussif Rashid Sumaila. 2017. Does
trade openness reduce a domestic fisheries catch?. Fisheries Science 83:6, 897-906. [Crossref]
323. Xiyan Mao, Canfei He. 2017. Export upgrading and environmental performance: Evidence from
China. Geoforum 86, 150-159. [Crossref]
324. Jing Lan, Alistair Munro, Zhen Liu. 2017. Environmental regulatory stringency and the market for
abatement goods and services in China. Resource and Energy Economics 50, 105-123. [Crossref]
325. Zekai He, Xiuzhen Shi, Xinhao Wang, Yuwei Xu. 2017. Urbanisation and the geographic
concentration of industrial SO 2 emissions in China. Urban Studies 54:15, 3579-3596. [Crossref]
326. Ann Harrison, Leslie A. Martin, Shanthi Nataraj. 2017. Green Industrial Policy in Emerging Markets.
Annual Review of Resource Economics 9:1, 253-274. [Crossref]
327. Jingbo Cui, Hang Qian. 2017. The effects of exports on facility environmental performance: Evidence
from a matching approach. The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 26:7, 759-776.
[Crossref]
328. Hongjun Tao, Jeff Luckstead, Liang Zhao, Christopher G Davis. 2017. Is pork trade good for China’s
greenhouse gas emissions?. Chinese Journal of Population Resources and Environment 15:4, 301-311.
[Crossref]
329. Alexandra Rudolph, Lukas Figge. 2017. Determinants of Ecological Footprints: What is the role of
globalization?. Ecological Indicators 81, 348-361. [Crossref]
330. Luís Miguel Marques, José Alberto Fuinhas, António Cardoso Marques. 2017. Augmented energy-
growth nexus: economic, political and social globalization impacts. Energy Procedia 136, 97-101.
[Crossref]
331. Junbing Huang, Dan Du, Qizhi Tao. 2017. An analysis of technological factors and energy intensity
in China. Energy Policy 109, 1-9. [Crossref]
332. Corrado Di Maria, Sjak Smulders. 2017. A paler shade of green: Environmental policy under induced
technical change. European Economic Review 99, 151-169. [Crossref]
333. Wisdom Akpalu, Babatunde Abidoye, Edwin Muchapondwa, Witness Simbanegavi. 2017. Public
disclosure for carbon abatement: African decision-makers in a PROPER public good experiment.
Climate and Development 9:6, 548-558. [Crossref]
334. Feng Tao, Huiqin Zhang, Yi Hu, Andrew A. Duncan. 2017. Growth of Green Total Factor
Productivity and Its Determinants of Cities in China: A Spatial Econometric Approach. Emerging
Markets Finance and Trade 53:9, 2123-2140. [Crossref]
335. Sheng Liu, Feng Tao, Huiqin Zhang. 2017. Term Limits of Public Officials, Environmental
Regulations, and Sustainable Development: An Analysis Based on Empirical Spatial Econometrics.
Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 53:9, 2141-2155. [Crossref]
336. Jianhuan Huang, Xudong Chen, Bihong Huang, Xiaoguang Yang. 2017. Economic and environmental
impacts of foreign direct investment in China: A spatial spillover analysis. China Economic Review
45, 289-309. [Crossref]
337. Faqin Lin. 2017. Trade openness and air pollution: City-level empirical evidence from China. China
Economic Review 45, 78-88. [Crossref]
338. Philipp M. Richter, Alexander Schiersch. 2017. CO 2 emission intensity and exporting: Evidence from
firm-level data. European Economic Review 98, 373-391. [Crossref]
339. Wajahat Ali, Azrai Abdullah, Muhammad Azam. 2017. Re-visiting the environmental Kuznets
curve hypothesis for Malaysia: Fresh evidence from ARDL bounds testing approach. Renewable and
Sustainable Energy Reviews 77, 990-1000. [Crossref]
340. James R. Markusen. 2017. An Alternative Base Case for Modeling Trade and the Global Environment.
Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists 4:3, 895-925. [Crossref]
341. Rikard Forslid, Toshihiro Okubo, Mark Sanctuary. 2017. Trade Liberalization, Transboundary
Pollution, and Market Size. Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists 4:3,
927-957. [Crossref]
342. MUHAMMAD SHAHBAZ, SALEHEEN KHAN, AMJAD ALI, MITA BHATTACHARYA.
2017. THE IMPACT OF GLOBALIZATION ON CO 2 EMISSIONS IN CHINA. The Singapore
Economic Review 62:04, 929-957. [Crossref]
343. Abdul Ridzuan, Nor Ismail, Abdul Che Hamat. 2017. Does Foreign Direct Investment Successfully
Lead to Sustainable Development in Singapore?. Economies 5:3, 29. [Crossref]
344. Talat S. Genc, Abdurrahman Aydemir. 2017. Power trade, welfare, and air quality. Energy Economics
67, 423-438. [Crossref]
345. Stefano Cucurachi, Sangwon Suh. 2017. Cause-effect analysis for sustainable development policy.
Environmental Reviews 25:3, 358-379. [Crossref]
346. Jevan Cherniwchan, Brian R. Copeland, M. Scott Taylor. 2017. Trade and the Environment: New
Methods, Measurements, and Results. Annual Review of Economics 9:1, 59-85. [Crossref]
347. Raymond G. Batina, Gregmar I. Galinato. 2017. The Spillover Effects of Good Governance in a
Tax Competition Framework with a Negative Environmental Externality. Environmental and Resource
Economics 67:4, 701-724. [Crossref]
348. Ning Zhang, Keren Yu, Zhongfei Chen. 2017. How does urbanization affect carbon dioxide emissions?
A cross-country panel data analysis. Energy Policy 107, 678-687. [Crossref]
349. Ruhul Salim, Yao Yao, George Chen, Lin Zhang. 2017. Can foreign direct investment harness energy
consumption in China? A time series investigation. Energy Economics 66, 43-53. [Crossref]
350. Jung‐Ah Hwang, Yeonbae Kim. 2017. Effects of Environmental Regulations on Trade Flow in
Manufacturing Sectors: Comparison of Static and Dynamic Effects of Environmental Regulations.
Business Strategy and the Environment 26:5, 688-706. [Crossref]
351. Antoine Dechezleprêtre, Misato Sato. 2017. The Impacts of Environmental Regulations on
Competitiveness. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 11:2, 183-206. [Crossref]
352. , , . 2017. The UK’s Emissions and Employment Footprints: Exploring the Trade-Offs. Sustainability
9:7, 1242. [Crossref]
353. Jonathan M. Harris, Brian Roach. World Trade and the Environment 566-590. [Crossref]
354. Li Zhou, Xi Tian, Zhengyi Zhou. 2017. The effects of environmental provisions in RTAs on PM2.5
air pollution. Applied Economics 49:27, 2630-2641. [Crossref]
355. Feng Tao, Huiqin Zhang, Jun Hu, X.H. Xia. 2017. Dynamics of green productivity growth for major
Chinese urban agglomerations. Applied Energy 196, 170-179. [Crossref]
356. Solomon Aboagye. 2017. Economic Expansion and Environmental Sustainability Nexus in Ghana.
African Development Review 29:2, 155-168. [Crossref]
357. Lanouar Charfeddine. 2017. The impact of energy consumption and economic development on
Ecological Footprint and CO2 emissions: Evidence from a Markov Switching Equilibrium Correction
Model. Energy Economics 65, 355-374. [Crossref]
358. Catia Cialani. 2017. CO 2 emissions, GDP and trade: a panel cointegration approach. International
Journal of Sustainable Development & World Ecology 24:3, 193-204. [Crossref]
359. Wajahat Ali, Azrai Abdullah, Muhammad Azam. 2017. The dynamic relationship between structural
change and CO2 emissions in Malaysia: a cointegrating approach. Environmental Science and Pollution
Research 24:14, 12723-12739. [Crossref]
360. Octavio Fernández-Amador, Joseph F. Francois, Doris A. Oberdabernig, Patrick Tomberger. 2017.
Carbon Dioxide Emissions and Economic Growth: An Assessment Based on Production and
Consumption Emission Inventories. Ecological Economics 135, 269-279. [Crossref]
361. Jayjit Roy. 2017. On the environmental consequences of intra-industry trade. Journal of Environmental
Economics and Management 83, 50-67. [Crossref]
362. Hirokazu Akahori, Daisuke Sawauchi, Yasutaka Yamamoto. 2017. Measuring the Changes of
Greenhouse Gas Emissions Caused by the Trans-Pacific Partnership. Sustainability 9:5, 715. [Crossref]
363. Gizem Kaya, M. Özgür Kayalica, Merve Kumaş, Burc Ulengin. 2017. The role of foreign direct
investment and trade on carbon emissions in Turkey. Environmental Economics 8:1, 8-17. [Crossref]
364. Weixian Wei, Peng Li, Siyu Wang, Jiaqi Gao. 2017. CO 2 emission driving forces and corresponding
mitigation strategies under low-carbon economy mode: evidence from China’s Beijing–Tianjin–Hebei
region. Chinese Journal of Population Resources and Environment 15:2, 109-119. [Crossref]
365. Chia-Hui Lu, Yu Pang. 2017. An anatomy of China’s eco-efficiency gains: the role of FDI. Asia-
Pacific Journal of Accounting & Economics 24:1-2, 106-126. [Crossref]
366. David I. Stern. 2017. The environmental Kuznets curve after 25 years. Journal of Bioeconomics 19:1,
7-28. [Crossref]
367. Rebecca Ray. 2017. The Panda's Pawprint: The Environmental Impact of the China-led Re-
primarization in Latin America and the Caribbean. Ecological Economics 134, 150-159. [Crossref]
368. Sakiru Adebola Solarin, Usama Al-Mulali, Ibrahim Musah, Ilhan Ozturk. 2017. Investigating the
pollution haven hypothesis in Ghana: An empirical investigation. Energy 124, 706-719. [Crossref]
369. Syed Jawad Hussain Shahzad, Ronald Ravinesh Kumar, Muhammad Zakaria, Maryam Hurr. 2017.
Carbon emission, energy consumption, trade openness and financial development in Pakistan: A
revisit. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 70, 185-192. [Crossref]
370. HARVEY E. LAPAN, SHIVA SIKDAR. 2017. Can Trade Be Good for the Environment?. Journal
of Public Economic Theory 19:2, 267-288. [Crossref]
371. Zheming Yan, Lan Yi, Kerui Du, Zhiming Yang. 2017. Impacts of Low-Carbon Innovation and Its
Heterogeneous Components on CO2 Emissions. Sustainability 9:4, 548. [Crossref]
372. Giuseppe DI VITA. 2017. THE INTERNATIONAL STRENGTHENING OF IPR AND AIR
POLLUTION ABATEMENT: THE ROLE OF THE TRIPS AGREEMENT. Technological and
Economic Development of Economy 23:2, 316-338. [Crossref]
373. Maximilian Auffhammer, Weizeng Sun, Jianfeng Wu, Siqi Zheng. The Decomposition and Dynamics
of Industrial Carbon Dioxide Emissions for 287 Chinese Cities in 1998-2009 71-94. [Crossref]
374. Zouhair Mrabet, Mouyad AlSamara, Shaif Hezam Jarallah. 2017. The impact of economic
development on environmental degradation in Qatar. Environmental and Ecological Statistics 24:1,
7-38. [Crossref]
375. Jevan Cherniwchan. 2017. Trade liberalization and the environment: Evidence from NAFTA and
U.S. manufacturing. Journal of International Economics 105, 130-149. [Crossref]
376. Ross McKitrick, Joel Wood. 2017. An Examination of the Relationship between Air Quality and
Income in Canada. Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics/Revue canadienne d'agroeconomie 65:1,
69-92. [Crossref]
377. Rajneesh. 2017. Do Trade Openness, Structure of the Economy and FDI Affect Energy Intensity
in India? A Case for Including Energy Intensity as a Policy Parameter. The Indian Economic Journal
65:1-4, 172-192. [Crossref]
378. Inmaculada Martínez-Zarzoso, Martina Vidovic, Anca M. Voicu. 2017. Are the Central East European
Countries Pollution Havens?. The Journal of Environment & Development 26:1, 25-50. [Crossref]
379. Jiajia Zheng, Pengfei Sheng. 2017. The Impact of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) on the
Environment: Market Perspectives and Evidence from China. Economies 5:1, 8. [Crossref]
380. Natalia Zugravu-Soilita. 2017. How does Foreign Direct Investment Affect Pollution? Toward a Better
Understanding of the Direct and Conditional Effects. Environmental and Resource Economics 66:2,
293-338. [Crossref]
381. Alexi Thompson, Christopher Jeffords. 2017. Virtual Water and an EKC for Water Pollution. Water
Resources Management 31:3, 1061-1066. [Crossref]
382. Yuwan Duan, Xuemei Jiang. 2017. Temporal Change of China's Pollution Terms of Trade and its
Determinants. Ecological Economics 132, 31-44. [Crossref]
383. Dierk Herzer. 2017. The Long-run Relationship Between Trade and Population Health: Evidence
from Five Decades. The World Economy 40:2, 462-487. [Crossref]
384. Aïcha El Alaoui. 2017. What is the relationship between environmental quality, economic growth
and free trade?. International Journal of Social Sciences and Education Research 3:1, 124-124. [Crossref]
385. Akihiro Otsuka. Energy Efficiency and Productivity 41-63. [Crossref]
386. Touitou Mohammed. A CGE Analysis of the Macroeconomic Effects of Carbon Dioxide Emission
Reduction on the Algerian Economy 1-20. [Crossref]
387. Ronald W. Jones, Rolf Weder. Current Challenges of Globalization in the Light of the Ricardian
Trade Theory 221-231. [Crossref]
388. Rolf Weder. The Ricardian Trade Model: Implications and Applications 73-97. [Crossref]
389. Hansa Jain. Review of the Existing Literature 17-43. [Crossref]
390. Hansa Jain. Methodology 45-59. [Crossref]
391. Hansa Jain. Trade Liberalization, Manufacturing Growth and Environmental Externalities 111-124.
[Crossref]
392. Thiago Alexandre das Neves Almeida, Isabel-María García-Sánchez. 2017. Sociopolitical and
economic elements to explain the environmental performance of countries. Environmental Science and
Pollution Research 24:3, 3006-3026. [Crossref]
393. Tomoyuki Sakamoto, Shunsuke Managi. 2017. New evidence of environmental efficiency on the
export performance. Applied Energy 185, 615-626. [Crossref]
394. Binru Cao, Shuhong Wang. 2017. Opening up, international trade, and green technology progress.
Journal of Cleaner Production 142, 1002-1012. [Crossref]
395. Qiaoling Liu, Qi Wang. 2017. How China achieved its 11th Five-Year Plan emissions reduction target:
A structural decomposition analysis of industrial SO2 and chemical oxygen demand. Science of The
Total Environment 574, 1104-1116. [Crossref]
396. Xiaofeng Zhao, Chunlei Deng, Xianjin Huang, Mei-Po Kwan. 2017. Driving forces and the spatial
patterns of industrial sulfur dioxide discharge in China. Science of The Total Environment 577,
279-288. [Crossref]
397. Bidisha Lahiri. 2017. Dissimilar Relations Between Income and Environmental Quality for Open
Economies in a Growth Model. Eastern Economic Journal 43:1, 104-127. [Crossref]
398. Kenichi Shimamoto. 2017. Decomposition analysis of the pollution intensities in the case of the United
Kingdom. Cogent Economics & Finance 5:1. . [Crossref]
399. Hui Zuo, Danxiang Ai, Yuling Lin. 2017. Foreign trade and pollution: the case of South China water
quality. IOP Conference Series: Earth and Environmental Science 52, 012074. [Crossref]
400. Xiaoyang Li, Yue Maggie Zhou. 2017. Offshoring Pollution While Offshoring Production. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
401. Sylvain Weber, Reyer Gerlagh, Nicole A. Mathys, Daniel D. Moran. 2017. CO2 Embedded in Trade:
Trends and Fossil Fuel Drivers. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
402. Joseph S. Shapiro, Reed Walker. 2017. Why is Pollution from U.S. Manufacturing Declining? The
Roles of Environmental Regulation, Productivity, and Trade. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
403. Helene Naegele, Aleksandar Zaklan. 2017. Does the EU ETS Cause Carbon Leakage in European
Manufacturing?. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
404. Clinton Levitt, Morten Saaby Pedersen, Anders Sorensen. 2017. The Impact of China's Trade
Liberalisation on the Greenhouse Gas Emissions of WTO Countries. SSRN Electronic Journal .
[Crossref]
405. Xu Wang, Liyan Han, Libo Yin. 2017. Environmental Efficiency and Its Determinants for
Manufacturing in China. Sustainability 9:1, 47. [Crossref]
406. Christopher A. Hartwell. 2016. The institutional basis of efficiency in resource-rich countries.
Economic Systems 40:4, 519-538. [Crossref]
407. Feng Tao, Huiqin Zhang, Xiaohua Xia. 2016. Decomposed Sources of Green Productivity Growth
for Three Major Urban Agglomerations in China. Energy Procedia 104, 481-486. [Crossref]
408. Lisa Anouliès. 2016. Are trade integration and the environment in conflict? The decisive role of
countries’ strategic interactions. International Economics 148, 1-15. [Crossref]
409. Joseph S. Shapiro. 2016. Trade Costs, CO2, and the Environment. American Economic Journal:
Economic Policy 8:4, 220-254. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
410. Adeolu O. Adewuyi. 2016. Effects of public and private expenditures on environmental pollution: A
dynamic heterogeneous panel data analysis. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 65, 489-506.
[Crossref]
411. Bouwe R. Dijkstra, Anuj J. Mathew. 2016. Liberalizing trade in environmental goods and services.
Environmental Economics and Policy Studies 18:4, 499-526. [Crossref]
412. Hélène Ollivier. 2016. North–South Trade and Heterogeneous Damages from Local and Global
Pollution. Environmental and Resource Economics 65:2, 337-355. [Crossref]
413. Boqiang Lin, Oluwasola E. Omoju, Ngozi M. Nwakeze, Jennifer U. Okonkwo, Ebenezer T.
Megbowon. 2016. Is the environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis a sound basis for environmental
policy in Africa?. Journal of Cleaner Production 133, 712-724. [Crossref]
414. Ömer Tarık GENÇOSMANOĞLU, Ahmet ŞAHİNÖZ. 2016. Doha Ticaret ve Çevre Müzakereleri:
Gelişmekte Olan Ülkeler için Pazara Giriş. Hacettepe Üniversitesi İktisadi ve İdari Bilimler Fakültesi
Dergisi 34:3, 51-71. [Crossref]
415. Alejandro E. Dellachiesa, Aung P. Myint. 2016. Trade openness and the changing water polluting
intensity patterns of ‘dirty’ and ‘clean’ industrial sectors. Ecological Economics 129, 143-151. [Crossref]
416. Daniel H. Simon, Jeffrey T. Prince. 2016. The effect of competition on toxic pollution releases.
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 79, 40-54. [Crossref]
417. Mustafa Disli, Adam Ng, Hossein Askari. 2016. Culture, income, and CO2 emission. Renewable and
Sustainable Energy Reviews 62, 418-428. [Crossref]
418. Behnaz Saboori, Jamalludin Sulaiman, Saidatulakmal Mohd. 2016. Environmental Kuznets curve
and energy consumption in Malaysia: A cointegration approach. Energy Sources, Part B: Economics,
Planning, and Policy 11:9, 861-867. [Crossref]
419. Shuijun Peng, Wencheng Zhang, Chuanwang Sun. 2016. ‘Environmental load displacement’ from the
North to the South: A consumption-based perspective with a focus on China. Ecological Economics
128, 147-158. [Crossref]
420. Ihtisham ul Haq, Shujin Zhu, Muhammad Shafiq. 2016. Empirical investigation of environmental
Kuznets curve for carbon emission in Morocco. Ecological Indicators 67, 491-496. [Crossref]
421. Hasan Murat Ertugrul, Murat Cetin, Fahri Seker, Eyup Dogan. 2016. The impact of trade openness
on global carbon dioxide emissions: Evidence from the top ten emitters among developing countries.
Ecological Indicators 67, 543-555. [Crossref]
422. Junbing Huang, Shiwei Yu. 2016. Effects of investment on energy intensity: evidence from China.
Chinese Journal of Population Resources and Environment 14:3, 197-207. [Crossref]
423. Malin Song, Yuanxiang Zhou. 2016. Quantitative Analysis of Foreign Trade and Environmental
Efficiency in China. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 52:7, 1647-1660. [Crossref]
424. Shuddhasattwa Rafiq, Ruhul Salim, Nicholas Apergis. 2016. Agriculture, trade openness and
emissions: an empirical analysis and policy options. Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource
Economics 60:3, 348-365. [Crossref]
425. Maximilian Auffhammer, Weizeng Sun, Jianfeng Wu, Siqi Zheng. 2016. THE DECOMPOSITION
AND DYNAMICS OF INDUSTRIAL CARBON DIOXIDE EMISSIONS FOR 287 CHINESE
CITIES IN 1998-2009. Journal of Economic Surveys 30:3, 460-481. [Crossref]
426. Kai Li, Shaozhou Qi. 2016. Does FDI Increase Industrial Energy Consumption of China? Based on
the Empirical Analysis of Chinese Provinces Industrial Panel Data. Emerging Markets Finance and
Trade 52:6, 1305-1314. [Crossref]
427. Bin Hu, Ross McKitrick. 2016. Decomposing the Environmental Effects of Trade Liberalization: The
Case of Consumption-Generated Pollution. Environmental and Resource Economics 64:2, 205-223.
[Crossref]
428. Sandeep Mohapatra, Wiktor Adamowicz, Peter Boxall. 2016. Dynamic technique and scale effects of
economic growth on the environment. Energy Economics 57, 256-264. [Crossref]
429. Saidi Kais, Hammami Sami. 2016. An econometric study of the impact of economic growth and energy
use on carbon emissions: Panel data evidence from fifty eight countries. Renewable and Sustainable
Energy Reviews 59, 1101-1110. [Crossref]
430. Dana C. Andersen. 2016. Credit Constraints, Technology Upgrading, and the Environment. Journal
of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists 3:2, 283-319. [Crossref]
431. Mansor H. Ibrahim, Siong Hook Law. 2016. Institutional Quality and CO 2 Emission-Trade
Relations: Evidence from Sub-Saharan Africa. South African Journal of Economics 84:2, 323-340.
[Crossref]
432. Octavio Fernández-Amador, Joseph F. Francois, Patrick Tomberger. 2016. Carbon dioxide emissions
and international trade at the turn of the millennium. Ecological Economics 125, 14-26. [Crossref]
433. Shuddhasattwa Rafiq, Ruhul Salim, Ingrid Nielsen. 2016. Urbanization, openness, emissions, and
energy intensity: A study of increasingly urbanized emerging economies. Energy Economics 56, 20-28.
[Crossref]
434. Thai-Ha Le, Youngho Chang, Donghyun Park. 2016. Trade openness and environmental quality:
International evidence. Energy Policy 92, 45-55. [Crossref]
435. Kankesu Jayanthakumaran, Ying Liu. 2016. Bi-lateral CO 2 emissions embodied in Australia–China
trade. Energy Policy 92, 205-213. [Crossref]
436. Khalid Ahmed, Mita Bhattacharya, Ahmer Qasim Qazi, Wei Long. 2016. Energy consumption in
China and underlying factors in a changing landscape: Empirical evidence since the reform period.
Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 58, 224-234. [Crossref]
437. Abdelaziz Hakimi, Helmi Hamdi. 2016. Trade liberalization, FDI inflows, environmental quality and
economic growth: A comparative analysis between Tunisia and Morocco. Renewable and Sustainable
Energy Reviews 58, 1445-1456. [Crossref]
438. Horatiu A. Rus. 2016. Renewable Resources, Pollution and Trade. Review of International Economics
24:2, 364-391. [Crossref]
439. Khalid Ahmed, Muhammad Shahbaz, Phouphet Kyophilavong. 2016. Revisiting the emissions-
energy-trade nexus: evidence from the newly industrializing countries. Environmental Science and
Pollution Research 23:8, 7676-7691. [Crossref]
440. Muhammad Shahbaz, Hrushikesh Mallick, Mantu Kumar Mahalik, Perry Sadorsky. 2016. The role
of globalization on the recent evolution of energy demand in India: Implications for sustainable
development. Energy Economics 55, 52-68. [Crossref]
441. Jingbo Cui, Harvey Lapan, GianCarlo Moschini. 2016. Productivity, Export, and Environmental
Performance: Air Pollutants in the United States. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 98:2,
447-467. [Crossref]
442. Lanouar Charfeddine, Karim Ben Khediri. 2016. Financial development and environmental quality in
UAE: Cointegration with structural breaks. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 55, 1322-1335.
[Crossref]
443. Thai-Ha Le. 2016. Dynamics between energy, output, openness and financial development in sub-
Saharan African countries. Applied Economics 48:10, 914-933. [Crossref]
444. Caspar Sauter, Jean-Marie Grether, Nicole A. Mathys. 2016. Geographical spread of global emissions:
Within-country inequalities are large and increasing. Energy Policy 89, 138-149. [Crossref]
445. Johan Graafland, Paul Hudson, Jonas Werner. 2016. Does corporate social performance reduce
greenhouse gas emissions at the macro level?. Journal of Environmental Planning and Management
59:2, 203-221. [Crossref]
446. J. Scott Holladay. 2016. Exporters and the environment. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue
canadienne d'économique 49:1, 147-172. [Crossref]
447. Paul J. J. Welfens, Jens K. Perret, Tony Irawan, Evgeniya Yushkova. Green Innovation Dynamics
39-46. [Crossref]
448. Trupti Mishra. Linkages Between Environment and Globalization: A Case Study of Developing
Countries 267-272. [Crossref]
449. Federico Demaria. Can the Poor Resist Capital? Conflicts over ‘Accumulation by Contamination’ at
the Ship Breaking Yard of Alang (India) 273-304. [Crossref]
450. Yanqing Jiang. Development and the Environmental Kuznets Curve in China 21-30. [Crossref]
451. Yanqing Jiang. Economic Growth and Environmental Input 31-41. [Crossref]
452. Yanqing Jiang. Foreign Trade and Sustainable Development 43-50. [Crossref]
453. Rosa Duarte, Vicente Pinilla, Ana Serrano. 2016. Globalization and natural resources: the expansion of
the Spanish agrifood trade and its impact on water consumption, 1965–2010. Regional Environmental
Change 16:1, 259-272. [Crossref]
454. Raja Vinesh Sannassee, Boopen Seetanah. Trade Openness and CO2 Emission 165-177. [Crossref]
455. Dhimitri Qirjo, Robert Christopherson. Will TAFTA Be Good or Bad for the Environment? 179-206.
[Crossref]
456. Musiliu O. Oseni, Michael G. Pollitt. 2016. The promotion of regional integration of electricity
markets: Lessons for developing countries. Energy Policy 88, 628-638. [Crossref]
457. Jianhua Yin, Mingzheng Zheng, Xin Li. 2016. Interregional transfer of polluting industries: a
consumption responsibility perspective. Journal of Cleaner Production 112, 4318-4328. [Crossref]
458. Per G. Fredriksson, Xenia Matschke. 2016. Trade Liberalization and Environmental Taxation in
Federal Systems. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 118:1, 150-167. [Crossref]
459. Toshihiro Okubo, Yuta Watabe, Kaori Furuyama. 2016. Export of Recyclable Materials: Evidence
from Japan. Asian Economic Papers 15:1, 134-148. [Crossref]
460. Joseph E. Aldy. 2016. Frameworks for Evaluating Policy Approaches to Address the Competitiveness
Concerns of Mitigating Greenhouse Gas Emissions. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
461. Aries Prasetyo, Wei Lo, Ariana Chang. 2016. Corporate Environmentalism; Dealing with Myopic
and Future Agenda. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
462. Inmaculada Martinez-Zarzoso, Walid Oueslati. 2016. Are Deep and Comprehensive Regional Trade
Agreements Helping to Reduce Air Pollution?. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
463. Akira Miyaoka. 2016. The Signaling Effect of Emission Taxes Under International Duopoly. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
464. Nicolas Koch. 2016. European Climate Policy and Industrial Relocation: Evidence from German
Multinational Firms. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
465. Ha Thai Le, Youngho Chang. 2016. Governance, Vulnerability to Climate Change, and Green
Growth: International Evidence. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
466. Mehdi Nemati, Wuyang Hu, Michael R. Reed. 2016. Are Free Trade Agreements Good for the
Environment? A Panel Data Analysis. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
467. Tonmoy Chatterjee, Soumyananda Dinda. Climate Change, Human Health and Some Economic
Issues 26-41. [Crossref]
468. Tonmoy Chatterjee, Soumyananda Dinda. Climate Change, Human Health and Some Economic
Issues 1971-1986. [Crossref]
469. Chong Hui Ling, Khalid Ahmed, Rusnah Binti Muhamad, Muhammad Shahbaz. 2015. Decomposing
the trade-environment nexus for Malaysia: what do the technique, scale, composition, and comparative
advantage effect indicate?. Environmental Science and Pollution Research 22:24, 20131-20142.
[Crossref]
470. Sanghoon Lee, Dae-Won Oh. 2015. Economic growth and the environment in China: Empirical
evidence using prefecture level data. China Economic Review 36, 73-85. [Crossref]
471. Tomoyuki Sakamoto, Shunsuke Managi. 2015. Energy pricing impact on domestic economy under
recent climate action. Economic Analysis and Policy 48, 150-162. [Crossref]
472. Andreas Löschel, Frank Pothen, Michael Schymura. 2015. Peeling the onion: Analyzing aggregate,
national and sectoral energy intensity in the European Union. Energy Economics 52, S63-S75.
[Crossref]
473. Carlos Aller, Lorenzo Ductor, M.J. Herrerias. 2015. The world trade network and the environment.
Energy Economics 52, 55-68. [Crossref]
474. Jayjit Roy, Mahmut Yasar. 2015. Energy efficiency and exporting: Evidence from firm-level data.
Energy Economics 52, 127-135. [Crossref]
475. Joseph E. Aldy, William A. Pizer. 2015. The Competitiveness Impacts of Climate Change Mitigation
Policies. Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists 2:4, 565-595. [Crossref]
476. Satoshi Honma. 2015. Does international trade improve environmental efficiency? An application of
a super slacks-based measure of efficiency. Journal of Economic Structures 4:1. . [Crossref]
477. Mansor H. Ibrahim, Syed Aun R. Rizvi. 2015. Emissions and trade in Southeast and East Asian
countries: a panel co-integration analysis. International Journal of Climate Change Strategies and
Management 7:4, 460-475. [Crossref]
478. Christoph Böhringer, Thomas F. Rutherford, David G. Tarr, Natalia Turdyeva. 2015. Market
Structure and the Environmental Implications of Trade Liberalization: Russia's Accession to the
World Trade Organization. Review of International Economics 23:5, 897-923. [Crossref]
479. Sahbi Farhani, Ilhan Ozturk. 2015. Causal relationship between CO2 emissions, real GDP, energy
consumption, financial development, trade openness, and urbanization in Tunisia. Environmental
Science and Pollution Research 22:20, 15663-15676. [Crossref]
480. Puyang Sun, Yan Yuan. 2015. Industrial Agglomeration and Environmental Degradation: Empirical
Evidence in Chinese Cities. Pacific Economic Review 20:4, 544-568. [Crossref]
481. Derek Kellenberg. 2015. The Economics of the International Trade of Waste. Annual Review of
Resource Economics 7:1, 109-125. [Crossref]
482. Ashleigh Keene, Steven C. Deller. 2015. Evidence of the Environmental Kuznets’ Curve among US
Counties and the Impact of Social Capital. International Regional Science Review 38:4, 358-387.
[Crossref]
483. Yihua Yu, Yonghui Zhang, Feng Song. 2015. World energy intensity revisited: a cluster analysis.
Applied Economics Letters 22:14, 1158-1169. [Crossref]
484. Muhammad Shahbaz, Samia Nasreen, Faisal Abbas, Omri Anis. 2015. Does foreign direct investment
impede environmental quality in high-, middle-, and low-income countries?. Energy Economics 51,
275-287. [Crossref]
485. Xiaobing Zhao, Ding Du. 2015. Forecasting carbon dioxide emissions. Journal of Environmental
Management 160, 39-44. [Crossref]
486. Xuemei Jiang, Yifang Liu, Jin Zhang, Lei Zu, Shouyang Wang, Christopher Green. 2015. Evaluating
the role of international trade in the growth of china’s CO2 emissions. Journal of Systems Science and
Complexity 28:4, 907-924. [Crossref]
487. Wajahat Ali, Azrai Abdullah. The long-run relationship between economic growth, financial
development, trade openness and CO<inf>2</inf> emissions in Malaysia 309-313. [Crossref]
488. Kathryn Harrison. 2015. International Carbon Trade and Domestic Climate Politics. Global
Environmental Politics 15:3, 27-48. [Crossref]
489. P. Srinivasan, Inder Siddanth Ravindra. 2015. Causality among Energy Consumption, CO 2 Emission,
Economic Growth and Trade. Foreign Trade Review 50:3, 168-189. [Crossref]
490. Kazuki Kagohashi, Tetsuya Tsurumi, Shunsuke Managi. 2015. The Effects of International Trade on
Water Use. PLOS ONE 10:7, e0132133. [Crossref]
491. Stefano Carattini, Andrea Baranzini, Jordi Roca. 2015. Unconventional Determinants of Greenhouse
Gas Emissions: The role of trust. Environmental Policy and Governance 25:4, 243-257. [Crossref]
492. Wei Jin. 2015. Can China harness globalization to reap domestic carbon savings? Modeling
international technology diffusion in a multi-region framework. China Economic Review 34, 64-82.
[Crossref]
493. Mehdi Ben Jebli, Slim Ben Youssef. 2015. The environmental Kuznets curve, economic growth,
renewable and non-renewable energy, and trade in Tunisia. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews
47, 173-185. [Crossref]
494. Sourafel Girma, Aoife Hanley. 2015. How Green are Exporters?. Scottish Journal of Political Economy
62:3, 291-309. [Crossref]
495. Lin Xuemei, Ki-Soo Kim. 2015. A Study on the Effect of Chinese Marine Pollution on Chinese
Fisheries Export. The Journal of Fisheries Business Administration 46:1, 75-91. [Crossref]
496. Sijeong Lim, Victor Menaldo, Aseem Prakash. 2015. Foreign aid, economic globalization, and
pollution. Policy Sciences 48:2, 181-205. [Crossref]
497. Zhongyi Xiao. 2015. An empirical test of the pollution haven hypothesis for China: intra-host country
analysis. Nankai Business Review International 6:2, 177-198. [Crossref]
498. Yanqing Jiang. 2015. Foreign Direct Investment, Pollution, and the Environmental Quality: A Model
with Empirical Evidence From the Chinese Regions. The International Trade Journal 29:3, 212-227.
[Crossref]
499. Laura Márquez-Ramos. 2015. The relationship between trade and sustainable transport: A
quantitative assessment with indicators of the importance of environmental performance and
agglomeration externalities. Ecological Indicators 52, 170-183. [Crossref]
500. Muhammad Shahbaz, Hrushikesh Mallick, Mantu Kumar Mahalik, Nanthakumar Loganathan.
2015. Does globalization impede environmental quality in India?. Ecological Indicators 52, 379-393.
[Crossref]
501. Philip Kofi Adom. 2015. Asymmetric impacts of the determinants of energy intensity in Nigeria.
Energy Economics 49, 570-580. [Crossref]
502. Xiuping Hua, Agyenim Boateng. Trade Openness, Financial Liberalization, Economic Growth, and
Environment Effects in the North-South: New Static and Dynamic Panel Data Evidence 253-289.
[Crossref]
503. Michael Hübler. 2015. A theory-based discussion of international technology funding. Environmental
Economics and Policy Studies 17:2, 313-327. [Crossref]
504. John P. Tang. 2015. Pollution havens and the trade in toxic chemicals: Evidence from U.S. trade flows.
Ecological Economics 112, 150-160. [Crossref]
505. Pasquale Pazienza. 2015. The relationship between CO2 and Foreign Direct Investment in the
agriculture and fishing sector of OECD countries: Evidence and policy considerations. Intellectual
Economics 9:1, 55-66. [Crossref]
506. Alief A. Rezza. 2015. A meta-analysis of FDI and environmental regulations. Environment and
Development Economics 20:2, 185-208. [Crossref]
507. Yuping Deng, Helian Xu. 2015. International Direct Investment and Transboundary Pollution: An
Empirical Analysis of Complex Networks. Sustainability 7:4, 3933-3957. [Crossref]
508. Pasquale Pazienza. 2015. The Environmental Impact of the FDI Inflow in the Transport Sector of
OECD Countries and Policy Implications. International Advances in Economic Research 21:1, 105-116.
[Crossref]
509. Emil Georgiev, Emil Mihaylov. 2015. Economic growth and the environment: reassessing the
environmental Kuznets Curve for air pollution emissions in OECD countries. Letters in Spatial and
Resource Sciences 8:1, 29-47. [Crossref]
510. Muhammad Shahid Siddiqui. 2015. Environmental taxes and international spillovers: The case of a
small open economy. Energy Economics 48, 70-80. [Crossref]
511. Marina Povitkina, Sverker C. Jagers, Martin Sjöstedt, Aksel Sundström. 2015. Democracy,
development and the marine environment – A global time-series investigation. Ocean & Coastal
Management 105, 25-34. [Crossref]
512. Rahel Aichele, Gabriel Felbermayr. 2015. Kyoto and Carbon Leakage: An Empirical Analysis of the
Carbon Content of Bilateral Trade. Review of Economics and Statistics 97:1, 104-115. [Crossref]
513. Jianhua Yin, Mingzheng Zheng, Jian Chen. 2015. The effects of environmental regulation and
technical progress on CO2 Kuznets curve: An evidence from China. Energy Policy 77, 97-108.
[Crossref]
514. Muhammad Azam, Abdul Qayyum Khan, Khalid Zaman, Mehboob Ahmad. 2015. Factors
determining energy consumption: Evidence from Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand. Renewable and
Sustainable Energy Reviews 42, 1123-1131. [Crossref]
515. Insa Flachsbarth, Bárbara Willaarts, Hua Xie, Gauthier Pitois, Nathaniel D. Mueller, Claudia
Ringler, Alberto Garrido. 2015. The Role of Latin America’s Land and Water Resources for Global
Food Security: Environmental Trade-Offs of Future Food Production Pathways. PLOS ONE 10:1,
e0116733. [Crossref]
516. Yan Luo, Xiaolin Qian, Jinjuan Ren. 2015. Initial public offerings and air pollution: evidence from
China. Journal of Asia Business Studies 9:1, 99-114. [Crossref]
517. Shu-Chen Chang. 2015. The effects of trade liberalization on environmental degradation. Quality &
Quantity 49:1, 235-253. [Crossref]
518. Adnan Kasman, Yavuz Selman Duman. 2015. CO2 emissions, economic growth, energy consumption,
trade and urbanization in new EU member and candidate countries: A panel data analysis. Economic
Modelling 44, 97-103. [Crossref]
519. Xianqiang Mao, Peng Song, Lone Kørnøv, Gabriel Corsetti. 2015. A review of EIAs on trade policy
in China: Exploring the way for economic policy EIAs. Environmental Impact Assessment Review 50,
53-65. [Crossref]
520. Joseph S. Shapiro, Reed Walker. 2015. Why is Pollution from U.S. Manufacturing Declining? The
Roles of Trade, Regulation, Productivity, and Preferences. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
521. Andreas LLschel, Frank Pothen, Michael Schymura. 2015. Peeling the Onion: Analyzing Aggregate,
National and Sectoral Energy Intensity in the European Union. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
522. Chia-Hui Lu, Yu Pang. 2015. Explaining the Post-2000 Brown Shift in US Manufacturing: The
Roles of China, Bush, and Induced Innovation. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
523. Jingbo Cui, Hang Qian. 2015. The Effects of Exports on Facility Environmental Performance:
Evidence from a Matching Approach. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
524. Haoyi Wu, Huanxiu Guo, Bing Zhang, Maoliang Bu. 2015. Westward Movement of Water Polluting
Firms in China: Pollution Reduction Mandates and Location Choice. SSRN Electronic Journal .
[Crossref]
525. Exbrayat Nelly, Stephane Riou, Skerdilajda Zanaj. 2015. Carbon Tax, Pollution and Spatial Location
of Heterogeneous Firms. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
526. David I. Stern. 2015. The Environmental Kuznets Curve after 25 Years. SSRN Electronic Journal .
[Crossref]
527. Mohamed El-Kamel Bakari. 2015. Sustainable Development in a Global Context: A Success or a
Nuisance?. New Global Studies 9:1. . [Crossref]
528. Murat Cetin, Fahri Seker, Hakan Cavlak. The Impact of Trade Openness on Environmental Pollution
221-232. [Crossref]
529. Lei Jiang, Henk Folmer, Minhe Ji. 2014. The drivers of energy intensity in China: A spatial panel
data approach. China Economic Review 31, 351-360. [Crossref]
530. Francis Tan, Hooi Hooi Lean, Habibullah Khan. 2014. Growth and environmental quality in
Singapore: Is there any trade-off?. Ecological Indicators 47, 149-155. [Crossref]
531. Ana Jesús López-Menéndez, Rigoberto Pérez, Blanca Moreno. 2014. Environmental costs and
renewable energy: Re-visiting the Environmental Kuznets Curve. Journal of Environmental
Management 145, 368-373. [Crossref]
532. Soumyananda Dinda. 2014. Climate Change: An Emerging Trade Opportunity in South Asia. South
Asian Journal of Macroeconomics and Public Finance 3:2, 221-239. [Crossref]
533. Xiao Xue, Wang, Hwang Yun Seop. 2014. The impact of Foreign direct investment on Energy
intensity: absorptive capacity as moderator. International Commerce and Information Review 16:5,
179-201. [Crossref]
534. Gang Yang, Xuan Chao Cai, Li Juan Chao, Shi Yu Lu. 2014. Study on the Investment and Financing
Issue of Environmental Protection Industry in Yangtze River Delta. Advanced Materials Research
1073-1076, 2714-2718. [Crossref]
535. Maoliang Bu, Shuwen Zhai, Jie Zhang, Wenping Zheng. Foreign Direct Investment and Pollution
Havens Hypothesis: Firm-Level Panel Data Evidence from China 73-96. [Crossref]
536. Michael Jakob, Jan Christoph Steckel, Ottmar Edenhofer. 2014. Consumption- Versus Production-
Based Emission Policies. Annual Review of Resource Economics 6:1, 297-318. [Crossref]
537. Matthew A. Cole, Robert J. R. Elliott, Toshihiro Okubo. 2014. International environmental
outsourcing. Review of World Economics 150:4, 639-664. [Crossref]
538. Akihiko Yanase. 2014. Indeterminacy and Pollution Haven Hypothesis in a Dynamic General
Equilibrium Model. Open Economies Review 25:5, 959-980. [Crossref]
539. Shu-Hong Wang, Ma-Lin Song. 2014. Review of hidden carbon emissions, trade, and labor income
share in China, 2001–2011. Energy Policy 74, 395-405. [Crossref]
540. Ayse M. Erdogan. 2014. Bilateral trade and the environment: A general equilibrium model based on
new trade theory. International Review of Economics & Finance 34, 52-71. [Crossref]
541. Michael Benarroch, James Gaisford. 2014. Intra-industry Trade Liberalization and the Environment.
Review of International Economics 22:5, 886-904. [Crossref]
542. E.D. Gemechu, I. Butnar, M. Llop, F. Castells, G. Sonnemann. 2014. CO 2 emissions flow due to
international trade: multi-regional input–output approach for Spain. Greenhouse Gas Measurement
and Management 4:2-4, 201-214. [Crossref]
543. Tetsuya Tsurumi, Shunsuke Managi. 2014. The effect of trade openness on deforestation: empirical
analysis for 142 countries. Environmental Economics and Policy Studies 16:4, 305-324. [Crossref]
544. Ronald B. Davies, Helen T. Naughton. 2014. Cooperation in environmental policy: a spatial approach.
International Tax and Public Finance 21:5, 923-954. [Crossref]
545. Azmat Gani, Frank Scrimgeour. 2014. Modeling governance and water pollution using the
institutional ecological economic framework. Economic Modelling 42, 363-372. [Crossref]
546. Yuheng Li, Cong Chen, Yanfei Wang, Yansui Liu. 2014. Urban-rural transformation and farmland
conversion in China: The application of the environmental Kuznets Curve. Journal of Rural Studies
36, 311-317. [Crossref]
547. Ceyhun Elgin, Oguz Oztunali. 2014. Pollution and informal economy. Economic Systems 38:3,
333-349. [Crossref]
548. Nikos Tsakiris, Michael S. Michael, Panos Hatzipanayotou. 2014. Asymmetric Tax Policy Responses
in Large Economies With Cross-Border Pollution. Environmental and Resource Economics 58:4,
563-578. [Crossref]
549. Sahbi Farhani, Sana Mrizak, Anissa Chaibi, Christophe Rault. 2014. The environmental Kuznets
curve and sustainability: A panel data analysis. Energy Policy 71, 189-198. [Crossref]
550. Ida Ferrara, Paul Missios, Halis Murat Yildiz. 2014. Inter-regional competition, comparative advantage
and environmental federalism. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 47:3,
905-952. [Crossref]
551. Olugbenga A. Onafowora, Oluwole Owoye. 2014. Bounds testing approach to analysis of the
environment Kuznets curve hypothesis. Energy Economics 44, 47-62. [Crossref]
552. Mireille Chiroleu-Assouline, Mouez Fodha. 2014. From regressive pollution taxes to progressive
environmental tax reforms. European Economic Review 69, 126-142. [Crossref]
553. Joel Rodrigue, Omolola Soumonni. 2014. Deforestation, foreign demand and export dynamics in
Indonesia. Journal of International Economics 93:2, 316-338. [Crossref]
554. Emmanuel Kumi, Albert A. Arhin, Thomas Yeboah. 2014. Can post-2015 sustainable development
goals survive neoliberalism? A critical examination of the sustainable development–neoliberalism
nexus in developing countries. Environment, Development and Sustainability 16:3, 539-554. [Crossref]
555. Shenggang Ren, Baolong Yuan, Xie Ma, Xiaohong Chen. 2014. The impact of international trade on
China文s industrial carbon emissions since its entry into WTO. Energy Policy 69, 624-634. [Crossref]
556. Muhammad Shahbaz, Naceur Khraief, Gazi Salah Uddin, Ilhan Ozturk. 2014. Environmental Kuznets
curve in an open economy: A bounds testing and causality analysis for Tunisia. Renewable and
Sustainable Energy Reviews 34, 325-336. [Crossref]
557. Akihiro Otsuka, Mika Goto, Toshiyuki Sueyoshi. 2014. Energy efficiency and agglomeration
economies: the case of Japanese manufacturing industries. Regional Science Policy & Practice 6:2,
195-212. [Crossref]
558. Li Ming Hong. 2014. Does Trade Liberalization Improve the Environment in China? Evidence Form
the Dynamic Panel Data of Chinese Prefecture City. Advanced Materials Research 950, 175-180.
[Crossref]
559. Soumyananda Dinda. 2014. Climate Change and Trade Opportunity in Climate Smart Goods in Asia:
Application of Gravity Model. The International Trade Journal 28:3, 264-280. [Crossref]
560. Michael Hübler, Alexander Glas. 2014. The Energy-Bias of North–South Technology Spillovers:
A Global, Bilateral, Bisectoral Trade Analysis. Environmental and Resource Economics 58:1, 59-89.
[Crossref]
561. Ramón López, Amparo Palacios. 2014. Why has Europe Become Environmentally Cleaner?
Decomposing the Roles of Fiscal, Trade and Environmental Policies. Environmental and Resource
Economics 58:1, 91-108. [Crossref]
562. Sunghoon Chung. 2014. Environmental regulation and foreign direct investment: Evidence from
South Korea. Journal of Development Economics 108, 222-236. [Crossref]
563. Udo Kreickemeier, Philipp M. Richter. 2014. Trade and the Environment: The Role of Firm
Heterogeneity. Review of International Economics 22:2, 209-225. [Crossref]
564. Yi Yu, Hui Zhang, Hao Hu. 2014. An empirical analysis on the impact of environmental regulations
on pork trade: evidence from China. Chinese Journal of Population Resources and Environment 12:2,
171-177. [Crossref]
565. Pei Li, Yong Tu. 2014. The impacts of openness on air quality in China. Environment and Development
Economics 19:2, 201-227. [Crossref]
566. Jie He, Jingyan Fu. 2014. Carbon leakage in China's manufacturing trade: An empirical analysis based
on the carbon embodied in trade. The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 23:3,
329-360. [Crossref]
567. STEVEN LUGAUER, RICHARD JENSEN, CLAYTON SADLER. 2014. AN ESTIMATE OF
THE AGE DISTRIBUTION'S EFFECT ON CARBON DIOXIDE EMISSIONS. Economic Inquiry
52:2, 914-929. [Crossref]
568. Shenggang Ren, Baolong Yuan, Xie Ma, Xiaohong Chen. 2014. International trade, FDI (foreign
direct investment) and embodied CO2 emissions: A case study of Chinas industrial sectors. China
Economic Review 28, 123-134. [Crossref]
569. Utpal Kumar De. 2014. Globalisation and cointegration among the states and convergence across the
continents: A panel data analysis. Economic Analysis and Policy 44:1, 107-121. [Crossref]
570. Danny T. Wang, Wendy Y. Chen. 2014. Foreign direct investment, institutional development, and
environmental externalities: Evidence from China. Journal of Environmental Management 135, 81-90.
[Crossref]
571. Timothy P. Hubbard. 2014. Trade and transboundary pollution: quantifying the effects of trade
liberalization on CO 2 emissions. Applied Economics 46:5, 483-502. [Crossref]
572. Felix Groba. 2014. Determinants of trade with solar energy technology components: evidence on the
porter hypothesis?. Applied Economics 46:5, 503-526. [Crossref]
573. Sahbi Farhani, Muhammad Shahbaz, Rashid Sbia, Anissa Chaibi. 2014. What does MENA region
initially need: Grow output or mitigate CO2 emissions?. Economic Modelling 38, 270-281. [Crossref]
574. Sahbi Farhani, Anissa Chaibi, Christophe Rault. 2014. CO2 emissions, output, energy consumption,
and trade in Tunisia. Economic Modelling 38, 426-434. [Crossref]
575. Liangliang Jiang, Chen Lin, Ping Lin. 2014. The determinants of pollution levels: Firm-level evidence
from Chinese manufacturing. Journal of Comparative Economics 42:1, 118-142. [Crossref]
576. Pasquale Pazienza. The Environmental Effects of FDI 15-26. [Crossref]
577. Pasquale Pazienza. Concluding Remarks 55-62. [Crossref]
578. Rashid Sbia, Muhammad Shahbaz, Helmi Hamdi. 2014. A contribution of foreign direct investment,
clean energy, trade openness, carbon emissions and economic growth to energy demand in UAE.
Economic Modelling 36, 191-197. [Crossref]
579. Ramiro Parrado, Enrica De Cian. 2014. Technology spillovers embodied in international trade:
Intertemporal, regional and sectoral effects in a global CGE framework. Energy Economics 41, 76-89.
[Crossref]
580. Mansor H. Ibrahim, Siong Hook Law. 2014. Social capital and CO2 emission—output relations: A
panel analysis. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 29, 528-534. [Crossref]
581. Yanqing Jiang. Environmental factors and sustainable development 187-203. [Crossref]
582. Giuseppe Francesco Gori, Luca Lambertini. 2014. Trade, Externalities, and the Impact of Asymmetric
Information on Trade Policy. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
583. Xiaoyang Li, Yue Maggie Zhou. 2014. Offshoring Production or Offshoring Pollution?. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
584. Jingbo Cui. 2014. Induced Clean Technology Adoption and International Trade with Heterogeneous
Firms. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
585. Dina Frutos-Bencze. Impact of CAFTA-DR's Environmental Provisions on Member Countries and
Firm-Level Environmental Voluntary Mechanisms 265-290. [Crossref]
586. Yoon Loong (Andrew) Wong, Lynne Lewis. 2013. The disappearing Environmental Kuznets Curve:
A study of water quality in the Lower Mekong Basin (LMB). Journal of Environmental Management
131, 415-425. [Crossref]
587. Roberto Ezcurra, Andrés Rodríguez-Pose. 2013. Does Economic Globalization affect Regional
Inequality? A Cross-country Analysis. World Development 52, 92-103. [Crossref]
588. Alakananda Ganguli. 2013. Green productivity and bilateral trade flows in an augmented gravity model
– A panel data analysis. The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 22:8, 1161-1182.
[Crossref]
589. Renato J. Orsato, Stewart R. Clegg, Horacio Falcão. 2013. The Political Ecology of Palm Oil
Production. Journal of Change Management 13:4, 444-459. [Crossref]
590. Debashis Chakraborty, Sacchidananda Mukherjee. 2013. Do Foreign Trade and Investment Lead
to Higher CO 2 Emissions? Evidence from Cross-Country Empirical Estimates. Review of Market
Integration 5:3, 329-361. [Crossref]
591. Lian Fen Wang, Ping Ping Sun, Jian Jun Zhu. 2013. Research on the Causes of China's Industrial
Environmental Efficiency. Advanced Materials Research 869-870, 698-701. [Crossref]
592. Marcel Kohler. 2013. CO2 emissions, energy consumption, income and foreign trade: A South African
perspective. Energy Policy 63, 1042-1050. [Crossref]
593. Bernhard Michel. 2013. Does offshoring contribute to reducing domestic air emissions? Evidence from
Belgian manufacturing. Ecological Economics 95, 73-82. [Crossref]
594. Yong Wang, Lingyan Kang, Xiaoqing Wu, Yang Xiao. 2013. Estimating the environmental Kuznets
curve for ecological footprint at the global level: A spatial econometric approach. Ecological Indicators
34, 15-21. [Crossref]
595. George E. Halkos, Nickolaos G. Tzeremes. 2013. Carbon dioxide emissions and governance: A
nonparametric analysis for the G-20. Energy Economics 40, 110-118. [Crossref]
596. Robert J.R. Elliott, Puyang Sun, Siyang Chen. 2013. Energy intensity and foreign direct investment:
A Chinese city-level study. Energy Economics 40, 484-494. [Crossref]
597. M. Kirchner, E. Schmid. 2013. Integrated regional impact assessment of agricultural trade and
domestic environmental policies. Land Use Policy 35, 359-378. [Crossref]
598. Julianne H. Mills Busa. 2013. Dynamite in the EKC tunnel? Inconsistencies in resource stock analysis
under the environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis. Ecological Economics 94, 116-126. [Crossref]
599. Hao Tan, Aijun Sun, Henry Lau. 2013. CO2 embodiment in China–Australia trade: The drivers and
implications. Energy Policy 61, 1212-1220. [Crossref]
600. Muhammad Shahbaz, Aviral Kumar Tiwari, Muhammad Nasir. 2013. The effects of financial
development, economic growth, coal consumption and trade openness on CO2 emissions in South
Africa. Energy Policy 61, 1452-1459. [Crossref]
601. Sam Fankhauser, Alex Bowen, Raphael Calel, Antoine Dechezleprêtre, David Grover, James Rydge,
Misato Sato. 2013. Who will win the green race? In search of environmental competitiveness and
innovation. Global Environmental Change 23:5, 902-913. [Crossref]
602. VALESKA GROENERT, BEN ZISSIMOS. 2013. Developing Country Second-Mover Advantage
in Competition Over Environmental Standards and Taxes. Journal of Public Economic Theory 15:5,
700-728. [Crossref]
603. 文文文. 2013. An Empirical Study of the Relationship between Trade Openness and CO2 Emissions in
Japan. Journal of Product Research 31:5, 1-12. [Crossref]
604. Thomas Bernauer, Vally Koubi. 2013. Are bigger governments better providers of public goods?
Evidence from air pollution. Public Choice 156:3-4, 593-609. [Crossref]
605. Ross McKitrick, Joel Wood. 2013. Co-fluctuation patterns of per capita carbon dioxide emissions:
The role of energy markets. Energy Economics 39, 1-12. [Crossref]
606. Luis Antonio López, Guadalupe Arce, Jorge Enrique Zafrilla. 2013. Parcelling virtual carbon in the
pollution haven hypothesis. Energy Economics 39, 177-186. [Crossref]
607. Muhammad Shahbaz, Ilhan Ozturk, Talat Afza, Amjad Ali. 2013. Revisiting the environmental
Kuznets curve in a global economy. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 25, 494-502. [Crossref]
608. Muthukumara Mani. 2013. Environmental Reviews and Case Studies: Trade and the Environment
Debate: Recent Developments and Implications for China. Environmental Practice 15:3, 313-322.
[Crossref]
609. David Riker. 2013. Environmental Performance and U.S. Exports. The International Trade Journal
27:4, 325-335. [Crossref]
610. P. Chintrakarn. 2013. Subnational trade flows and state-level energy intensity: an empirical analysis.
Applied Economics Letters 20:14, 1344-1351. [Crossref]
611. Li Ma. 2013. The Effect of Trade Liberalization on the Environment: An Empirical Analysis in
Zhongshan City. Advanced Materials Research 779-780, 1576-1579. [Crossref]
612. Travis Roach. 2013. A dynamic state-level analysis of carbon dioxide emissions in the United States.
Energy Policy 59, 931-937. [Crossref]
613. Yang Xu, Wen Bin Shang. 2013. Empirical Analysis of the Impact of FDI on China‘s Environment.
Advanced Materials Research 726-731, 1001-1005. [Crossref]
614. Leila Baghdadi, Inmaculada Martinez-Zarzoso, Habib Zitouna. 2013. Are RTA agreements with
environmental provisions reducing emissions?. Journal of International Economics 90:2, 378-390.
[Crossref]
615. Giuseppe Francesco Gori, Luca Lambertini. 2013. Trade liberalisation between asymmetric countries
with environmentally concerned consumers. Regional Science and Urban Economics 43:4, 549-560.
[Crossref]
616. Subhayu Bandyopadhyay, Sumon Bhaumik, Howard J. Wall. 2013. Biofuel Subsidies and International
Trade. Economics & Politics 25:2, 181-199. [Crossref]
617. Khalid Ahmed, Wei Long. 2013. An empirical analysis of CO 2 emission in Pakistan using EKC
hypothesis. Journal of International Trade Law and Policy 12:2, 188-200. [Crossref]
618. Xiao Chen, Alan Woodland. 2013. International trade and climate change. International Tax and
Public Finance 20:3, 381-413. [Crossref]
619. Ma-Lin Song, Wei Zhang, Shu-Hong Wang. 2013. Inflection point of environmental Kuznets curve
in Mainland China. Energy Policy 57, 14-20. [Crossref]
620. Carol McAusland, Daniel L. Millimet. 2013. Do national borders matter? Intranational trade,
international trade, and the environment. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 65:3,
411-437. [Crossref]
621. Valeria Costantini, Francesco Crespi. 2013. Public policies for a sustainable energy sector: regulation,
diversity and fostering of innovation. Journal of Evolutionary Economics 23:2, 401-429. [Crossref]
622. Nicholas Apergis, Sofia Eleftheriou, James E. Payne. 2013. The relationship between international
financial reporting standards, carbon emissions, and R&D expenditures: Evidence from European
manufacturing firms. Ecological Economics 88, 57-66. [Crossref]
623. Debashis Chakraborty, Sacchidananda Mukherjee. 2013. How do trade and investment flows
affect environmental sustainability? Evidence from panel data. Environmental Development 6, 34-47.
[Crossref]
624. Danny T. Wang, Flora F. Gu, David K. Tse, Chi Kin (Bennett) Yim. 2013. When does FDI matter?
The roles of local institutions and ethnic origins of FDI. International Business Review 22:2, 450-465.
[Crossref]
625. Don P. Clark, Alejandro E. Dellachiesa. 2013. Industrial and Agricultural Pollution Patterns. Global
Economy Journal 13:1, 1-24. [Crossref]
626. Linda Kleemann, Awudu Abdulai. 2013. THE IMPACT OF TRADE AND ECONOMIC
GROWTH ON THE ENVIRONMENT: REVISITING THE CROSS-COUNTRY EVIDENCE.
Journal of International Development 25:2, 180-205. [Crossref]
627. Malin Song, Linling Zhang, Qingxian An, Zeya Wang, Zhen Li. 2013. Statistical analysis and
combination forecasting of environmental efficiency and its influential factors since China entered the
WTO: 2002–2010–2012. Journal of Cleaner Production 42, 42-51. [Crossref]
628. Matthew A. Cole, Robert J.R. Elliott, Toshihiro Okubo, Ying Zhou. 2013. The carbon dioxide
emissions of firms: A spatial analysis. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 65:2,
290-309. [Crossref]
629. Andreas Löschel, Sascha Rexhäuser, Michael Schymura. 2013. Trade and the environment: An
application of the WIOD database. Chinese Journal of Population Resources and Environment 11:1,
51-61. [Crossref]
630. Luisa Blanco, Fidel Gonzalez, Isabel Ruiz. 2013. The Impact of FDI on CO 2 Emissions in Latin
America. Oxford Development Studies 41:1, 104-121. [Crossref]
631. Frank Vöhringer, Jean-Marie Grether, Nicole A. Mathys. 2013. Trade and Climate Policies: Do
Emissions from International Transport Matter?. The World Economy 36:3, 280-302. [Crossref]
632. M.J. Herrerias, A. Cuadros, V. Orts. 2013. Energy intensity and investment ownership across Chinese
provinces. Energy Economics 36, 286-298. [Crossref]
633. NANCY H. CHAU, ROLF FÄRE, SHAWNA GROSSKOPF. 2013. Trade Restrictiveness and
Pollution. Journal of Public Economic Theory 15:1, 25-52. [Crossref]
634. Kathryn Hochstetler. 2013. South-South Trade and the Environment: A Brazilian Case Study. Global
Environmental Politics 13:1, 30-48. [Crossref]
635. Sudeshna Chattopadhyay, Sarmila Banerjee. 2013. Shifting of Pollution Loads to Informal Units in
India: A Possible Escape Route for Compliance with WTO Standards. Foreign Trade Review 48:1,
23-44. [Crossref]
636. Bettina Kretschmer, Michael Hübler, Peter Nunnenkamp. 2013. DOES FOREIGN AID REDUCE
ENERGY AND CARBON INTENSITIES OF DEVELOPING ECONOMIES?. Journal of
International Development 25:1, 67-91. [Crossref]
637. Elke Moser, Alexia Prskawetz, Gernot Tragler. Environmental Regulations, Abatement and Economic
Growth 87-111. [Crossref]
638. Davide Dragone, Luca Lambertini, Arsen Palestini. The Incentive to Invest in Environmental-Friendly
Technologies: Dynamics Makes a Difference 165-188. [Crossref]
639. Jean-Marie Grether, Nicole A. Mathys. 2013. The pollution terms of trade and its five components.
Journal of Development Economics 100:1, 19-31. [Crossref]
640. Andreas Löschel, Sascha Rexhauser, Michael Schymura. 2013. Trade and the Environment: An
Application of the WIOD Database. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
641. Michael Hübler, Alexander Glas. 2013. The Energy-Bias of North-South Technology Spillovers – A
Global, Bilateral, Bisectoral Trade Analysis. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
642. Keisuke Kawata, Yasunori Ouchida. 2013. Offshoring, Trade and Environmental Policies: Effects of
Transboundary Pollution. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
643. Talat Genc, Abdurrahman Aydemir. 2013. Power Trade, Welfare, and Air Quality. SSRN Electronic
Journal . [Crossref]
644. Enrica De Cian, Michael Schymura, Elena Verdolini, Sebastian Voigt. 2013. Energy Intensity
Developments in 40 Major Economies: Structural Change or Technology Improvement?. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
645. Felix Groba, Barbara Breitschopf. 2013. Impact of Renewable Energy Policy and Use on Innovation:
A Literature Review. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
646. Richard A. Jensen, Steven Lugauer, Clayton Sadler. 2013. An Estimate of the Age Distribution's
Effect on Carbon Dioxide Emissions. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
647. Stefano Carattini, Andrea Baranzini, Jordi Roca. 2013. Unconventional Determinants of Greenhouse
Gas Emissions: The Role of Trust. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
648. Chia-Hui Lu, Yu Pang. 2013. An Anatomy of China's Eco-Efficiency Gains: The Role of FDI. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
649. Syed Uddin, Sunera Khan. 2013. Air Pollutions and Environmental Goods trade: Re-visiting the EKC
hypothesis. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
650. Wan-Ping Yang, Ban Lan, Kunshi Zheng. 2013. The Impact of Energy Consumption and Economic
Development on Changes in China’s Provincial-Level Environmental Quality. Modern Economy
04:04, 257-264. [Crossref]
651. Laixun Zhao. 2013. Some Alternative Catching Up Strategies for Developing Countries. The
International Economy 16:0, 5-13. [Crossref]
652. Marek Loužek. 2013. Global Problems as Seen by Environmental Economics. Politická ekonomie 61:3,
393-410. [Crossref]
653. Mehdi Abbas. 2013. Libre-échange et changements climatiques : “soutien mutuel” ou divergence ?.
Mondes en développement n° 162:2, 33. [Crossref]
654. Aseem Prakash, Matthew Potoski. 2012. Voluntary environmental programs: A comparative
perspective. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 31:1, 123-138. [Crossref]
655. Zhaoyang Liu, Xianqiang Mao, Wei Tang, Tao Hu, Peng Song. 2012. An assessment of China-
Japan-Korea Free Trade Agreement’s economic and environmental impacts on China. Frontiers of
Environmental Science & Engineering 6:6, 849-859. [Crossref]
656. Michael M. Bechtel, Thomas Bernauer, Reto Meyer. 2012. The green side of protectionism:
Environmental concerns and three facets of trade policy preferences. Review of International Political
Economy 19:5, 837-866. [Crossref]
657. Stratford Douglas, Shuichiro Nishioka. 2012. International differences in emissions intensity and
emissions content of global trade. Journal of Development Economics 99:2, 415-427. [Crossref]
658. Faiz Ur Rehman, Muhammad Nasir, Faiza Kanwal. 2012. Nexus between corruption and regional
Environmental Kuznets Curve: the case of South Asian countries. Environment, Development and
Sustainability 14:5, 827-841. [Crossref]
659. Xianfeng Jin, Suocheng Dong, Lingjun Luo, Yu Li, Chao Yuan, Kesheng Shu, Jiaquan Chen. 2012.
Environmental effects of foreign trade and its spatial variations in mid-eastern provinces and cities of
China. Chinese Geographical Science 22:5, 626-636. [Crossref]
660. Roberto Ezcurra. 2012. Is There a Link between Globalization and Governance?. Environment and
Planning C: Government and Policy 30:5, 848-870. [Crossref]
661. Maarten van Rossum, Kees Baas. 2012. The effect of globalization and technology change on water
emissions embodied in imports and exports. Sustainable Development 20:5, 309-319. [Crossref]
662. Svetlana Batrakova, Ronald B. Davies. 2012. Is there an environmental benefit to being an exporter?
Evidence from firm-level data. Review of World Economics 148:3, 449-474. [Crossref]
663. Mohamed El Hedi Arouri, Guglielmo Maria Caporale, Christophe Rault, Robert Sova, Anamaria
Sova. 2012. Environmental Regulation and Competitiveness: Evidence from Romania. Ecological
Economics 81, 130-139. [Crossref]
664. Claustre Bajona, David L. Kelly. 2012. Trade and the environment with pre-existing subsidies: A
dynamic general equilibrium analysis. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 64:2,
253-278. [Crossref]
665. Derek Kellenberg. 2012. Trading wastes. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 64:1,
68-87. [Crossref]
666. Ning Chang. 2012. The empirical relationship between openness and environmental pollution in
China. Journal of Environmental Planning and Management 55:6, 783-796. [Crossref]
667. Roberta De Santis. 2012. Impact of Environmental Regulations on Trade in the Main EU Countries:
Conflict or Synergy?. The World Economy 35:7, 799-815. [Crossref]
668. Deniz Erdem. 2012. Foreign direct investments, energy efficiency, and innovation dynamics. Mineral
Economics 24:2-3, 119-133. [Crossref]
669. Lammertjan Dam, Bert Scholtens. 2012. The curse of the haven: The impact of multinational
enterprise on environmental regulation. Ecological Economics 78, 148-156. [Crossref]
670. Canfei He, Fenghua Pan, Yan Yan. 2012. Is Economic Transition Harmful to China’s Urban
Environment? Evidence from Industrial Air Pollution in Chinese Cities. Urban Studies 49:8,
1767-1790. [Crossref]
671. Sonia Ben Kheder, Natalia Zugravu. 2012. Environmental regulation and French firms location abroad:
An economic geography model in an international comparative study. Ecological Economics 77, 48-61.
[Crossref]
672. Kankesu Jayanthakumaran, Ying Liu. 2012. Openness and the Environmental Kuznets Curve: Evidence
from China. Economic Modelling 29:3, 566-576. [Crossref]
673. Hui Huang Liu, Zi Hao Li. 2012. The Effects of FDI on Carbon Emission through Technical
Channels: Evidence from Chinese Industrial Sectors. Advanced Materials Research 524-527, 3491-3496.
[Crossref]
674. Jie He, Hua Wang. 2012. Economic structure, development policy and environmental quality: An
empirical analysis of environmental Kuznets curves with Chinese municipal data. Ecological Economics
76, 49-59. [Crossref]
675. Gairuzazmi M. Ghani. 2012. Does trade liberalization effect energy consumption?. Energy Policy 43,
285-290. [Crossref]
676. Gabriele Spilker. 2012. Helpful Organizations: Membership in Inter-Governmental Organizations and
Environmental Quality in Developing Countries. British Journal of Political Science 42:2, 345-370.
[Crossref]
677. Evangelina Dardati, Meryem Saygili. 2012. Multinationals and environmental regulation: are foreign
firms harmful?. Environment and Development Economics 17:2, 163-186. [Crossref]
678. Patrick Bernhagen. 2012. Air Pollution and Business Political Influence in Fifteen OECD Countries.
Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy 30:2, 362-380. [Crossref]
679. Edward Manderson, Richard Kneller. 2012. Environmental Regulations, Outward FDI and
Heterogeneous Firms: Are Countries Used as Pollution Havens?. Environmental and Resource
Economics 51:3, 317-352. [Crossref]
680. Kankesu Jayanthakumaran, Reetu Verma, Ying Liu. 2012. CO2 emissions, energy consumption, trade
and income: A comparative analysis of China and India. Energy Policy 42, 450-460. [Crossref]
681. Jing Lan, Makoto Kakinaka, Xianguo Huang. 2012. Foreign Direct Investment, Human Capital and
Environmental Pollution in China. Environmental and Resource Economics 51:2, 255-275. [Crossref]
682. Christoph Schmitz, Anne Biewald, Hermann Lotze-Campen, Alexander Popp, Jan Philipp Dietrich,
Benjamin Bodirsky, Michael Krause, Isabelle Weindl. 2012. Trading more food: Implications for land
use, greenhouse gas emissions, and the food system. Global Environmental Change 22:1, 189-209.
[Crossref]
683. Jean-Marie Grether, Nicole Andréa Mathys, Jaime de Melo. 2012. Unravelling the worldwide
pollution haven effect. The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 21:1, 131-162.
[Crossref]
684. Bidisha Lahiri. 2012. Input Intensity: A Missing Link between Production, Trade Patterns, and
Environmental Standards. Review of International Economics 20:1, 108-118. [Crossref]
685. Haixiao Huang. Linking Trade and the Environment in China 209-228. [Crossref]
686. Khalid Ahmed, Wei Long. 2012. Environmental Kuznets Curve and Pakistan: An Empirical Analysis.
Procedia Economics and Finance 1, 4-13. [Crossref]
687. Xun Cao, Aseem Prakash. 2012. Trade Competition and Environmental Regulations: Domestic
Political Constraints and Issue Visibility. The Journal of Politics 74:1, 66-82. [Crossref]
688. Monica Das, Sandwip K Das. 2012. Trade, Environment, and Welfare in a Model of Monopolistic
Competition. Eastern Economic Journal 38:1, 37-56. [Crossref]
689. Joseph E. Aldy, William A. Pizer. 2012. The Competitiveness Impacts of Climate Change Mitigation
Policies. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
690. Sijeong Lim, Victor A. Menaldo, Aseem Prakash. 2012. Economic Globalization, Foreign Aid, and
Pollution. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
691. Giuseppe Francesco Gori, Luca Lambertini. 2012. Trade Liberalisation between Asymmetric
Countries with Environmentally Concerned Consumers. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
692. Theo S. Eicher, Jeffrey Begun. 2012. In Search of a Sulphur Dioxide Environmental Kuznets Curve:
A Bayesian Model Averaging Approach. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
693. Enrica De Cian, Ramiro Parrado. 2012. Technology Spillovers Embodied in International Trade:
Intertemporal, Regional and Sectoral Effects in a Global CGE Framework. SSRN Electronic Journal
. [Crossref]
694. Gustavo Hernández. 2012. Incidencia de los Impuestos a las Emisiones en el Sector Industrial
(Incidence of the Pollution Tax on the Industrial Sector). SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
695. Travis Roach. 2012. A State-Level Analysis of Carbon Dioxide Emissions in the United States. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
696. Luciana Echazu, Martin D. Heintzelman. 2012. Strategic Environmental Taxation and International
Trade. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
697. Jaime de Melo. 2012. Trade in a 'Green Growth' Development Strategy Global Scale Issues and
Challenges. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
698. Sam Fankhauser, Alex Bowen, Raphael Calel, Antoine Dechezleprêtre, david grover, James Rydge,
Misato Sato. 2012. Who Will Win the Green Race? In Search of Environmental Competitiveness and
Innovation. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
699. David Hemous. 2012. Environmental Policy and Directed Technical Change in a Global Economy:
The Dynamic Impact of Unilateral Environmental Policies. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
700. Wei Jin. 2012. Can China Harness Globalization to Reap Carbon Savings? Modeling International
Technology Diffusion in a Multi-Region Framework. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
701. Wei Jin. 2012. International Knowledge Spillover and Technology Externality: Why Multilateral
R&D Coordination Matters for Global Climate Governance. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
702. Eric Olszak. 2012. Localisation des activités et développement durable des territoires : quelle
interactivité ?. Marché et organisations 16:2, 153. [Crossref]
703. Jun Jing Li, Meng Ling Li, Wei Cheng. 2012. Construction of Green City Development Strategies
in Shenyang City. Advanced Materials Research 433-440, 943-947. [Crossref]
704. Jaime de Melo, Nicole A. Mathys. 2012. Concilier les politiques commerciales et les politiques
climatiques. Revue d'économie du développement 20:2, 57. [Crossref]
705. Steven Yamarik, Sucharita Ghosh. 2011. Is natural openness or trade policy good for the environment?.
Environment and Development Economics 16:6, 657-684. [Crossref]
706. JENNY ZHANG, PARTHA GANGOPADHYAY. 2011. TRADE AND DYNAMICS OF
ENVIRONMENTAL DEGRADATION: THEORY AND EVIDENCE FROM YANGTZE
RIVER DELTA. International Journal of Development and Conflict 01:03, 435-455. [Crossref]
707. Antoni Riera Font, Javier Capó Parrilla, Teresa Palmer Tous. 2011. ¿Existe un conflicto entre la
globalización del turismo y los recursos naturales?. Economía Agraria y Recursos Naturales 6:12, 169.
[Crossref]
708. George E. Halkos, Nickolaos G. Tzeremes. 2011. Growth and environmental pollution: empirical
evidence from China. Journal of Chinese Economic and Foreign Trade Studies 4:3, 144-157. [Crossref]
709. Elitsa R. Banalieva, Ravi Sarathy. 2011. A Contingency Theory of Internationalization. Management
International Review 51:5, 593-634. [Crossref]
710. Tobias Menz, Jan Kühling. 2011. Population aging and environmental quality in OECD countries:
evidence from sulfur dioxide emissions data. Population and Environment 33:1, 55-79. [Crossref]
711. Ramón López, Gregmar I. Galinato, Asif Islam. 2011. Fiscal spending and the environment: Theory
and empirics. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 62:2, 180-198. [Crossref]
712. Junjie Zhang, Can Wang. 2011. Co-benefits and additionality of the clean development mechanism:
An empirical analysis. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 62:2, 140-154. [Crossref]
713. BAOZHI QU, YIFAN ZHANG. 2011. EFFECT OF INCOME DISTRIBUTION ON THE
ENVIRONMENTAL KUZNETS CURVE. Pacific Economic Review 16:3, 349-370. [Crossref]
714. Martin Gassebner, Michael J. Lamla, Jan-Egbert Sturm. 2011. Determinants of pollution: what do
we really know?. Oxford Economic Papers 63:3, 568-595. [Crossref]
715. Lucas Bretschger, Simone Valente. 2011. International economics and natural resources: from theory
to policy. International Economics and Economic Policy 8:2, 115-120. [Crossref]
716. Don P. Clark, Alejandro E. Dellachiesa. 2011. Cross-country pollution patterns. Applied Economics
Letters 18:9, 799-804. [Crossref]
717. Nita Rudra. 2011. Openness and the Politics of Potable Water. Comparative Political Studies 44:6,
771-803. [Crossref]
718. Muhan Li, Lianzhong Zhang. Notice of Retraction: Study on comparison the elasticity of CO 2
growth with GDP growth between China and America 806-807. [Crossref]
719. Yu Haishan, Liu Fang. Notice of Retraction: An analysis of export effect of environmental cost
internalization 1-3. [Crossref]
720. Shaun M. Tanger, Peng Zeng, Wayde Morse, David N. Laband. 2011. Macroeconomic conditions
in the U.S. and congressional voting on environmental policy: 1970–2008. Ecological Economics 70:6,
1109-1120. [Crossref]
721. Abdul Jalil, Mete Feridun. 2011. The impact of growth, energy and financial development on the
environment in China: A cointegration analysis. Energy Economics 33:2, 284-291. [Crossref]
722. Muhammad Nasir, Faiz Ur Rehman. 2011. Environmental Kuznets Curve for carbon emissions in
Pakistan: An empirical investigation. Energy Policy 39:3, 1857-1864. [Crossref]
723. Maoliang Bu, Zhibiao Liu, Yanyan Gao. 2011. Influence of International Openness on Corporate
Environmental Performance in China. China & World Economy 19:2, 77-92. [Crossref]
724. QUN BAO, YUANYUAN CHEN, LIGANG SONG. 2011. Foreign direct investment and
environmental pollution in China: a simultaneous equations estimation. Environment and Development
Economics 16:1, 71-92. [Crossref]
725. Matthew A. Cole, Robert J.R. Elliott, Jing Zhang. 2011. GROWTH, FOREIGN DIRECT
INVESTMENT, AND THE ENVIRONMENT: EVIDENCE FROM CHINESE CITIES. Journal
of Regional Science 51:1, 121-138. [Crossref]
726. R. MacDermott, A. Basuchoudhary, J. Bang. Trade, Trade Agreements and the Environment
394-399. [Crossref]
727. YUE Ting, LONG Ru Yin, ZHUANG Ying Ying. 2011. Analysis of the FDI Effect on Energy
Consumption Intensity in Jiangsu Province. Energy Procedia 5, 100-104. [Crossref]
728. Wang Xiaofang. 2011. Challenges and Strategies of Chinese Low-carbon Trade. Energy Procedia 5,
2178-2182. [Crossref]
729. Michael Hübler. 2011. Technology diffusion under contraction and convergence: A CGE analysis of
China. Energy Economics 33:1, 131-142. [Crossref]
730. Yinghua Meng, Xiaoyu Ni. 2011. Intra-Product Trade and Ordinary Trade on China'S Environmental
Pollution. Procedia Environmental Sciences 10, 790-795. [Crossref]
731. Reyer Gerlagh, Nicole A. Mathys. 2011. Energy Abundance, Trade and Industry Location. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
732. Mark Andrew Kelso. 2011. Green Democracy: Political Participation and Environmental Protection.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
733. Julia Swart, Charles van Marrewijk. 2011. The Pollution Effects of Mergers and Acquisitions:
Asymmetry, Disaggregation, and Multilateralism. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
734. Utpal Kumar De. 2011. Globalisation and Cointegration Among the States and Convergence Across
the Continents: A Panel Data Analysis. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
735. Felix Groba. 2011. Determinants of Trade with Solar Energy Technology Components: Evidence on
the Porter Hypothesis?. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
736. Jean-Marie Grether, Nicole A. Mathys, Jaime de Melo. 2011. Unravelling the Worldwide Pollution
Haven Effect. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
737. Alban Verchère. 2011. Le développement durable en question : analyses économiques autour d’un
improbable compromis entre acceptions optimiste et pessimiste du rapport de l’Homme à la Nature.
L'Actualité économique 87:3, 337-403. [Crossref]
738. Xiaodong Du, Fengxia Dong, Dermot J. Hayes, Tristan R. Brown. 2011. Assessment of
Environmental Impacts Embodied in U.S.‐China and U.S.‐India Trade and Related Climate Change
Policies. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 93:2, 537-544. [Crossref]
739. Fabrice Darrigues. 2011. Localisation géographique des firmes et environnement : entre contrainte
imposée et responsabilité incitée. Revue d'économie politique 121:5, 767. [Crossref]
740. Tai-Liang Chen, Leonard F. S. Wang. 2010. Trade liberalization and transboundary pollution in an
international mixed duopoly. Environmental Economics and Policy Studies 12:4, 187-200. [Crossref]
741. Nick Wills-Johnson. 2010. Lessons for sustainability from the world’s most sustainable culture.
Environment, Development and Sustainability 12:6, 909-925. [Crossref]
742. Gernot Wagner. 2010. Energy content of world trade. Energy Policy 38:12, 7710-7721. [Crossref]
743. J. Ederington. 2010. Should Trade Agreements Include Environmental Policy?. Review of
Environmental Economics and Policy 4:1, 84-102. [Crossref]
744. ChengWei, SuJian. Government green procurement implementation plan in Shenyang 2876-2879.
[Crossref]
745. Liliana B. Andonova, Ronald B. Mitchell. 2010. The Rescaling of Global Environmental Politics.
Annual Review of Environment and Resources 35:1, 255-282. [Crossref]
746. Lucas W. Davis,, Matthew E. Kahn. 2010. International Trade in Used Vehicles: The Environmental
Consequences of NAFTA. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 2:4, 58-82. [Abstract] [View
PDF article] [PDF with links]
747. Derek Kellenberg. 2010. Consumer Waste, Backhauling, and Pollution Havens. Journal of Applied
Economics 13:2, 283-304. [Crossref]
748. Munisamy Gopinath, He Min, Steven Buccola. 2010. Technical Barriers to Interstate Trade: Noxious
Weed Regulations. Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics 42:4, 617-630. [Crossref]
749. Ulla Lehmijoki, Tapio Palokangas. 2010. Trade, population growth, and the environment in
developing countries. Journal of Population Economics 23:4, 1351-1370. [Crossref]
750. Keisuke Hattori. 2010. Strategic Voting for Noncooperative Environmental Policies in Open
Economies. Environmental and Resource Economics 46:4, 459-474. [Crossref]
751. Matthew A. Cole, Robert J.R. Elliott, Toshihiro Okubo. 2010. Trade, environmental regulations
and industrial mobility: An industry-level study of Japan. Ecological Economics 69:10, 1995-2002.
[Crossref]
752. Xun Cao, Aseem Prakash. 2010. Trade Competition and Domestic Pollution: A Panel Study, 1980–
2003. International Organization 64:3, 481-503. [Crossref]
753. Yang Lu. 2010. Do environmental regulations influence the competitiveness of pollution-intensive
products?. Frontiers of Economics in China 5:2, 276-298. [Crossref]
754. Abay Mulatu, Reyer Gerlagh, Dan Rigby, Ada Wossink. 2010. Environmental Regulation and
Industry Location in Europe. Environmental and Resource Economics 45:4, 459-479. [Crossref]
755. Jie He, Patrick Richard. 2010. Environmental Kuznets curve for CO2 in Canada. Ecological Economics
69:5, 1083-1093. [Crossref]
756. Jie Guo, Le-Le Zou, Yi-Ming Wei. 2010. Impact of inter-sectoral trade on national and global CO2
emissions: An empirical analysis of China and US. Energy Policy 38:3, 1389-1397. [Crossref]
757. SLIM BEN YOUSSEF. 2010. R&D IN CLEANER TECHNOLOGY AND INTERNATIONAL
TRADE. International Game Theory Review 12:01, 61-73. [Crossref]
758. Thomas Bernauer, Patrick M. Kuhn. 2010. Is there an environmental version of the Kantian peace?
Insights from water pollution in Europe. European Journal of International Relations 16:1, 77-102.
[Crossref]
759. Tetsuya Tsurumi, Shunsuke Managi. 2010. Decomposition of the environmental Kuznets curve:
scale, technique, and composition effects. Environmental Economics and Policy Studies 11:1-4, 19-36.
[Crossref]
760. Jie He. 2010. What is the role of openness for China's aggregate industrial SO2 emission?: A structural
analysis based on the Divisia decomposition method. Ecological Economics 69:4, 868-886. [Crossref]
761. Aaron Kearsley, Mary Riddel. 2010. A further inquiry into the Pollution Haven Hypothesis and the
Environmental Kuznets Curve. Ecological Economics 69:4, 905-919. [Crossref]
762. MICHAEL HÜBLER, ANDREAS KELLER. 2010. Energy savings via FDI? Empirical evidence
from developing countries. Environment and Development Economics 15:1, 59-80. [Crossref]
763. Hilary Sigman, Howard F. Chang. Implications of Globalization and Trade for Water Quality in
Transboundary Rivers 97-111. [Crossref]
764. Jean-Marie Grether, Nicole A. Mathys, Jaime de Melo. 2010. Global manufacturing SO2 emissions:
does trade matter?. Review of World Economics 145:4, 713-729. [Crossref]
765. Yan Yunfeng, Yang Laike. 2010. China's foreign trade and climate change: A case study of CO2
emissions. Energy Policy 38:1, 350-356. [Crossref]
766. Jenny Minier. Trade and Environmental Regulations 1-3. [Crossref]
767. Brian R. Copeland. How Does Trade Affect the Environment? 206-247. [Crossref]
768. Emilio Galdeano-Gómez. 2010. Exporting and Environmental Performance: A Firm-level
Productivity Analysis. World Economy 33:1, 60-88. [Crossref]
769. Junjie Zhang, Can Wang. 2010. Co-Benefits and Additionality of the Clean Development Mechanism:
An Empirical Analysis. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
770. Bouwe Dijkstra, Anuj J. Mathew. 2010. Liberalizing Trade in Environmental Goods. SSRN Electronic
Journal . [Crossref]
771. John P. Tang. 2010. Pollution Havens and the Trade in Toxic Chemicals: Evidence from U.S. Trade
Flows. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
772. Valeria Costantini, Massimiliano Mazzanti. 2010. On the Green Side of Trade Competitiveness?
Environmental Policies and Innovation in the EU. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
773. Mehdi Fadaee. 2010. A Dynamic Approach to the Environmental Effects of Trade Liberalization.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
774. Tisorn Songsermsawas. 2010. Income, Trade and Pollution in Central Asia, Russia and China: An
Econometric Analysis. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
775. Yang Laike, Liao Chun. 2010. China-European Union Trade and Global Warming. International
Journal of Social Ecology and Sustainable Development 1:1, 30-40. [Crossref]
776. Abdul Jalil, Syed F. Mahmud. 2009. Environment Kuznets curve for CO2 emissions: A cointegration
analysis for China. Energy Policy 37:12, 5167-5172. [Crossref]
777. Arsène Rieber, Thi Anh-Dao Tran. 2009. The Effects of Unilateral Environmental Regulations in a
World with Capital Mobility and Trading Costs. Asia-Pacific Journal of Accounting & Economics 16:3,
317-338. [Crossref]
778. Michael M. Bechtel, Jale Tosun. 2009. Changing Economic Openness for Environmental Policy
Convergence: When Can Bilateral Trade Agreements Induce Convergence of Environmental
Regulation?. International Studies Quarterly 53:4, 931-953. [Crossref]
779. Michael J. Lamla. 2009. Long-run determinants of pollution: A robustness analysis. Ecological
Economics 69:1, 135-144. [Crossref]
780. Shunsuke Managi, Akira Hibiki, Tetsuya Tsurumi. 2009. Does trade openness improve environmental
quality?. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 58:3, 346-363. [Crossref]
781. René Verburg, Elke Stehfest, Geert Woltjer, Bas Eickhout. 2009. The effect of agricultural trade
liberalisation on land-use related greenhouse gas emissions. Global Environmental Change 19:4,
434-446. [Crossref]
782. RACHEL A. BOUVIER. 2009. Sulfur dioxide emissions and per capita income: a disaggregation of
the effects of long-run and short-run income growth. Environment and Development Economics 14:5,
601-619. [Crossref]
783. Robert Y. Shum. 2009. Can attitudes predict outcomes? Public opinion, democratic institutions and
environmental policy. Environmental Policy and Governance 19:5, 281-295. [Crossref]
784. Dao-Zhi Zeng, Laixun Zhao. 2009. Pollution havens and industrial agglomeration. Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management 58:2, 141-153. [Crossref]
785. Ida Ferrara, Paul Missios, Halis Murat Yildiz. 2009. Trading rules and the environment: Does
equal treatment lead to a cleaner world?. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 58:2,
206-225. [Crossref]
786. Giuseppe Di Vita. 2009. Legal families and environmental protection: Is there a causal relationship?.
Journal of Policy Modeling 31:5, 694-707. [Crossref]
787. Harry C. Wilting, Kees Vringer. 2009. CARBON AND LAND USE ACCOUNTING FROM A
PRODUCER'S AND A cONSUMER'S PERSPECTIVE – AN EMPIRICAL EXAMINATION
COVERING THE WORLD. Economic Systems Research 21:3, 291-310. [Crossref]
788. James B. Ang. 2009. CO2 emissions, research and technology transfer in China. Ecological Economics
68:10, 2658-2665. [Crossref]
789. Per G. Fredriksson, Herman R. J. Vollebergh. 2009. Corruption, federalism, and policy formation
in the OECD: the case of energy policy. Public Choice 140:1-2, 205-221. [Crossref]
790. Achim Kemmerling, Eric Seils. 2009. The Regulation of Redistribution: Managing Conflict in
Corporate Tax Competition. West European Politics 32:4, 756-773. [Crossref]
791. Daniel L. Millimet, Rusty Tchernis. 2009. On the Specification of Propensity Scores, With
Applications to the Analysis of Trade Policies. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 27:3, 397-415.
[Crossref]
792. Jean-Marie Grether, Nicole A. Mathys, Jaime de Melo. 2009. Scale, Technique and Composition
Effects in Manufacturing SO2 Emissions. Environmental and Resource Economics 43:2, 257-274.
[Crossref]
793. M. Auffhammer. 2009. The State of Environmental and Resource Economics: A Google Scholar
Perspective. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 3:2, 251-269. [Crossref]
794. Shunsuke Managi, Surender Kumar. 2009. Trade-induced technological change: Analyzing economic
and environmental outcomes. Economic Modelling 26:3, 721-732. [Crossref]
795. Taran Fæhn, Annegrete Bruvoll. 2009. Richer and cleaner—At others’ expense?. Resource and Energy
Economics 31:2, 103-122. [Crossref]
796. Michèle B. Bättig, Thomas Bernauer. 2009. National Institutions and Global Public Goods: Are
Democracies More Cooperative in Climate Change Policy?. International Organization 63:2, 281-308.
[Crossref]
797. JIE HE. 2009. China's industrial SO 2 emissions and its economic determinants: EKC's reduced vs.
structural model and the role of international trade. Environment and Development Economics 14:2,
227-262. [Crossref]
798. Valerica Vlad, Sajal Lahiri. 2009. Foreign Investment and Environment in a North-South Model with
Cross-border Pollution. Asia-Pacific Journal of Accounting & Economics 16:1, 1-17. [Crossref]
799. Thomas Bernauer, Vally Koubi. 2009. Effects of political institutions on air quality. Ecological
Economics 68:5, 1355-1365. [Crossref]
800. Anna Kukla-Gryz. 2009. Economic growth, international trade and air pollution: A decomposition
analysis. Ecological Economics 68:5, 1329-1339. [Crossref]
801. Christopher L. Weber, Glen P. Peters. 2009. Climate change policy and international trade: Policy
considerations in the US. Energy Policy 37:2, 432-440. [Crossref]
802. Jen Baggs. 2009. International Trade in Hazardous Waste. Review of International Economics 17:1,
1-16. [Crossref]
803. Akihiko Yanase. 2009. Indeterminacy and Pollution Haven Hypothesis in a Dynamic General
Equilibrium Model. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
804. Sean D. Ehrlich. 2009. Which Countries Go Green? An Access Point Theory of Democratic
Institutions and Environmental Regulations. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
805. Randy A. Becker, John P. Tang. 2009. U.S. Trade in Toxics: The Case of Chlorodifluoromethane
(HCFC-22). SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
806. Subhayu Bandyopadhyay, Sumon K. Bhaumik, Howard J. Wall. 2009. Biofuel Subsidies: An Open-
Economy Analysis. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
807. Richard Kneller, Edward Manderson. 2009. Environmental Regulations, Outward FDI and
Heterogeneous Firms: Are Countries Used as Pollution Havens?. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
808. Natalia Zugravu, Katrin Millock, Gérard Duchene. 2009. Les facteurs de la dépollution dans les pays
en transition. Recherches économiques de Louvain 75:4, 461. [Crossref]
809. John P. Hoehn, Kwami Adanu. 2008. Do growth, investment, and trade encourage water use or water
conservation?. Letters in Spatial and Resource Sciences 1:2-3, 127-146. [Crossref]
810. Derek K. Kellenberg. 2008. A reexamination of the role of income for the trade and environment
debate. Ecological Economics 68:1-2, 106-115. [Crossref]
811. JEFFREY BEGUN, THEO S. EICHER. 2008. In search of an environmental Kuznets curve in
sulphur dioxide concentrations: a Bayesian model averaging approach. Environment and Development
Economics 13:06, 795. [Crossref]
812. Andreas Waldkirch, Munisamy Gopinath. 2008. Pollution Control and Foreign Direct Investment in
Mexico: An Industry-Level Analysis. Environmental and Resource Economics 41:3, 289-313. [Crossref]
813. Panos Hatzipanayotou, Sajal Lahiri, Michael S. Michael. 2008. Cross-Border Pollution, Terms of
Trade, and Welfare. Environmental and Resource Economics 41:3, 327-345. [Crossref]
814. Paul Lanoie, Michel Patry, Richard Lajeunesse. 2008. Environmental regulation and productivity:
testing the porter hypothesis. Journal of Productivity Analysis 30:2, 121-128. [Crossref]
815. Giuseppe Di Vita. 2008. Differences in pollution levels among civil law countries: A possible
interpretation. Energy Policy 36:10, 3774-3786. [Crossref]
816. Wen Chen. An Empirical Test on the Environmental Kuznets Curve Hypothesis in China 1-5.
[Crossref]
817. Matthew A. COLE, Robert J.R. ELLIOTT, Shanshan WU. 2008. Industrial activity and the
environment in China: An industry-level analysis. China Economic Review 19:3, 393-408. [Crossref]
818. Victoria I. Umanskaya, Edward B. Barbier. 2008. Can Rich Countries Become Pollution Havens?*.
Review of International Economics 16:4, 627-640. [Crossref]
819. Lammertjan Dam, Bert Scholtens. 2008. Environmental regulation and MNEs location: Does CSR
matter?. Ecological Economics 67:1, 55-65. [Crossref]
820. Nektarios Aslanidis, Anastasios Xepapadeas. 2008. Regime switching and the shape of the emission–
income relationship. Economic Modelling 25:4, 731-739. [Crossref]
821. Colin Kirkpatrick, S. Serban Scrieciu. 2008. Is trade liberalisation bad for the environment? A review of
the economic evidence. Journal of Environmental Planning and Management 51:4, 497-510. [Crossref]
822. Gilbert E. Metcalf. 2008. An Empirical Analysis of Energy Intensity and Its Determinants at the State
Level. The Energy Journal 29:3. . [Crossref]
823. Astrid Fritz Carrapatoso. 2008. Environmental aspects in free trade agreements in the Asia-Pacific
region. Asia Europe Journal 6:2, 229-243. [Crossref]
824. Valeria Costantini, Francesco Crespi. 2008. Environmental regulation and the export dynamics of
energy technologies. Ecological Economics 66:2-3, 447-460. [Crossref]
825. Colin Kirkpatrick, Kenichi Shimamoto. 2008. The effect of environmental regulation on the locational
choice of Japanese foreign direct investment. Applied Economics 40:11, 1399-1409. [Crossref]
826. Hongyan Guo, Liyan Han. The Impact of Chinese Industrial Exports on Environment 4606-4609.
[Crossref]
827. Nikos Tsakiris, Panos Hatzipanayotou, Michael S. Michael. 2008. Pollution, Capital Mobility and Tax
Policies with Unemployment. Review of Development Economics 12:2, 223-236. [Crossref]
828. Shunsuke Managi, Pradyot Ranjan Jena. 2008. Environmental productivity and Kuznets curve in India.
Ecological Economics 65:2, 432-440. [Crossref]
829. Lisa A. Cave, Glenn C. Blomquist. 2008. Environmental policy in the European Union: Fostering
the development of pollution havens?. Ecological Economics 65:2, 253-261. [Crossref]
830. Junyi Shen. 2008. Trade liberalization and environmental degradation in China. Applied Economics
40:8, 997-1004. [Crossref]
831. Sonja Peterson. 2008. Greenhouse gas mitigation in developing countries through technology
transfer?: a survey of empirical evidence. Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for Global Change 13:3,
283-305. [Crossref]
832. Robert J. R. Elliott, Kenichi Shimamoto. 2008. Are ASEAN Countries Havens for Japanese Pollution-
Intensive Industry?. The World Economy 31:2, 236-254. [Crossref]
833. Arik Levinson, M. Scott Taylor. 2008. UNMASKING THE POLLUTION HAVEN EFFECT.
International Economic Review 49:1, 223-254. [Crossref]
834. Geraint Johnes. 2008. Trade in the Greenhouse: Efficient Policy in a Global Model. SSRN Electronic
Journal . [Crossref]
835. Sonia Ben Kheder, Natalia Zugravu. 2008. The Pollution Haven Hypothesis: A Geographic Economy
Model in a Comparative Study. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
836. Soham Baksi, Amrita Ray Chaudhuri. 2008. Transboundary Pollution, Trade Liberalization, and
Environmental Taxes. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
837. Jeffrey A. Frankel. 2008. Global Environmental Policy and Global Trade Policy. SSRN Electronic
Journal . [Crossref]
838. Jean-Marie Grether, Nicole A. Mathys, Jaime de Melo. 2008. Global Manufacturing SO2 Emissions:
Does Trade Matter?. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
839. Feng Helen Liang. 2008. Does Foreign Direct Investment Harm the Host Country’s Environment?
Evidence from China. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
840. Jean-Marie Grether, Nicole A. Mathys. 2008. Is the World's Economic Center of Gravity Already in
Asia?. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
841. Arsène Rieber, Thi Anh-Dao Tran. 2008. Dumping environnemental et délocalisation des activités
industrielles : le Sud face à la mondialisation. Revue d'économie du développement 16:2, 5. [Crossref]
842. Don Fullerton, Garth Heutel. 2007. Who bears the burden of a tax on carbon emissions in Japan?.
Environmental Economics and Policy Studies 8:4, 255-270. [Crossref]
843. Ka Zeng, Josh Eastin. 2007. International Economic Integration and Environmental Protection: The
Case of China. International Studies Quarterly 51:4, 971-995. [Crossref]
844. James B. Ang. 2007. CO2 emissions, energy consumption, and output in France. Energy Policy 35:10,
4772-4778. [Crossref]
845. A. K. M. Azhar, Robert J. R. Elliott. 2007. Trade and Specialisation in Pollution Intensive Industries:
North–South Evidence. International Economic Journal 21:3, 361-380. [Crossref]
846. Ann L. Owen, Stephen Wu. 2007. Is Trade Good for Your Health?. Review of International Economics
15:4, 660-682. [Crossref]
847. D. Asher Ghertner, Matthias Fripp. 2007. Trading away damage: Quantifying environmental leakage
through consumption-based, life-cycle analysis. Ecological Economics 63:2-3, 563-577. [Crossref]
848. Marie-Françoise Calmette, Isabelle Péchoux. 2007. Are environmental policies counterproductive?.
Economics Letters 95:2, 186-191. [Crossref]
849. Josh Ederington. 2007. NAFTA and the Pollution Haven Hypothesis. Policy Studies Journal 35:2,
239-244. [Crossref]
850. Silvina J. Vilas-Ghiso, Diana M. Liverman. 2007. Scale, technique and composition effects in the
Mexican agricultural sector: the influence of NAFTA and the institutional environment. International
Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics 7:2, 137-169. [Crossref]
851. Don Fullerton, Garth Heutel. 2007. The general equilibrium incidence of environmental taxes. Journal
of Public Economics 91:3-4, 571-591. [Crossref]
852. Breena E. Coates. 2007. Could CAFTA be the latest conduit for outsourcing pollution?. International
Journal of Sociology and Social Policy 27:1/2, 77-94. [Crossref]
853. Hein Roelfsema. 2007. Strategic delegation of environmental policy making. Journal of Environmental
Economics and Management 53:2, 270-275. [Crossref]
854. Roberto Ezcurra. 2007. Is there cross-country convergence in carbon dioxide emissions?. Energy Policy
35:2, 1363-1372. [Crossref]
855. Abul Quasem Al-Amin, Chamhuri Siwar, Abdul Hamid Jaafar. 2007. Trade Liberalization and
Environment: Malaysian Development Strategy, Policy & Experience. SSRN Electronic Journal .
[Crossref]
856. Jean-Marie Grether, Nicole A. Mathys, Jaime de Melo. 2007. Trade, Technique and Composition
Effects: What is Behind the Fall in World-Wide SO2 Emissions 1990-2000?. SSRN Electronic Journal
. [Crossref]
857. Michael J. Lamla. 2007. Long-Run Determinants of Pollution: A Robustness Analysis. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
858. Giuseppe Di Vita. 2007. Legal Families and Environmental Protection: Is there a Causal Relationship?.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
859. Jie He. 2006. Pollution haven hypothesis and environmental impacts of foreign direct investment:
The case of industrial emission of sulfur dioxide (SO2) in Chinese provinces. Ecological Economics
60:1, 228-245. [Crossref]
860. Michael Benarroch, Rolf Weder. 2006. Intra-industry trade in intermediate products, pollution and
internationally increasing returns. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 52:3, 675-689.
[Crossref]
861. Helmuth Cremer, Firouz Gahvari. 2006. Which border taxes? Origin and destination regimes with
fiscal competition in output and emission taxes. Journal of Public Economics 90:10-11, 2121-2142.
[Crossref]
862. Takumi Haibara. 2006. A NOTE ON TRADE LIBERALIZATION, PUBLIC ABATEMENT,
AND WELFARE. Review of Urban & Regional Development Studies 18:3, 179-191. [Crossref]
863. Diana M. Liverman, Silvina Vilas. 2006. Neoliberalism and the Environment in Latin America. Annual
Review of Environment and Resources 31:1, 327-363. [Crossref]
864. Matthew A. Cole, Robert J.R. Elliott, Kenichi Shimamoto. 2006. Globalization, firm-level
characteristics and environmental management: A study of Japan. Ecological Economics 59:3, 312-323.
[Crossref]
865. Ian Sheldon. 2006. Trade and Environmental Policy: A Race to the Bottom?. Journal of Agricultural
Economics 57:3, 365-392. [Crossref]
866. Matthew A. Cole. 2006. Does trade liberalization increase national energy use?. Economics Letters
92:1, 108-112. [Crossref]
867. Pandej Chintrakarn, Daniel L. Millimet. 2006. The environmental consequences of trade: Evidence
from subnational trade flows. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 52:1, 430-453.
[Crossref]
868. Robert C. Johansson, Joseph Cooper, Mark Peters. 2006. An agri-environmental assessment of trade
liberalization. Ecological Economics 58:1, 37-48. [Crossref]
869. Shunsuke Managi. 2006. Are there increasing returns to pollution abatement? Empirical analytics of
the Environmental Kuznets Curve in pesticides. Ecological Economics 58:3, 617-636. [Crossref]
870. Aseem Prakash, Matthew Potoski. 2006. Racing to the Bottom? Trade, Environmental Governance,
and ISO 14001. American Journal of Political Science 50:2, 350-364. [Crossref]
871. Rutger Hoekstra, Marco A. Janssen. 2006. Environmental responsibility and policy in a two-country
dynamic input–output model. Economic Systems Research 18:1, 61-84. [Crossref]
872. Nicolas Péridy. 2006. Pollution effects of free trade areas: Simulations from a general equilibrium
model. International Economic Journal 20:1, 37-62. [Crossref]
873. Takumi Haibara. 2006. TRADE LIBERALIZATION, PUBLIC ABATEMENT, AND
WELFARE. Review of Urban and Regional Development Studies 18:1, 11-24. [Crossref]
874. Mete Feridun, Folorunso Sunday Ayadi, Jean Balouga. 2006. Impact of Trade Liberalization on the
Environment in Developing Countries. Journal of Developing Societies 22:1, 39-56. [Crossref]
875. James A. Turner, Joseph Buongiorno, Shushuai Zhu. 2006. An economic model of international
wood supply, forest stock and forest area change. Scandinavian Journal of Forest Research 21:1, 73-86.
[Crossref]
876. Kakali Mukhopadhyay, Debesh Chakraborty. 2006. Pollution Haven and Factor Endowment
Hypotheses Revisited: Evidence from India. Journal of Quantitative Economics 4:1, 111-132. [Crossref]
877. I. Mongelli, G. Tassielli, B. Notarnicola. 2006. Global warming agreements, international trade and
energy/carbon embodiments: an input–output approach to the Italian case. Energy Policy 34:1, 88-100.
[Crossref]
878. Selim Cagatay, Hakan Mihci. 2006. Degree of environmental stringency and the impact on trade
patterns. Journal of Economic Studies 33:1, 30-51. [Crossref]
879. Thomas Bernauer, Vally Koubi. 2006. States as Providers of Public Goods: How Does Government
Size Affect Environmental Quality?. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
880. Jean-Marie Grether, Nicole A. Mathys, Jaime de Melo. 2006. Unraveling the World-Wide Pollution
Haven Effect. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
881. Dao-Zhi Zeng, Lex Zhao. 2006. Pollution Havens and Industrial Agglomeration. SSRN Electronic
Journal . [Crossref]
882. Marc Germain, Philippe Monfort, Thierry Bréchet. 2006. Allocation des efforts de dépollution dans
des économies avec spécialisation internationale. Revue économique 57:2, 219. [Crossref]
883. ANTON NAHMAN, GEOFF ANTROBUS. 2005. TRADE AND THE ENVIRONMENTAL
KUZNETS CURVE: IS SOUTHERN AFRICA A POLLUTION HAVEN?. The South African
Journal of Economics 73:4, 803-814. [Crossref]
884. Edward B. Barbier. Natural Resources and Economic Development 80, . [Crossref]
885. Matthew A. Cole, Robert J. R. Elliott. 2005. FDI and the Capital Intensity of "Dirty" Sectors:
A Missing Piece of the Pollution Haven Puzzle. Review of Development Economics 9:4, 530-548.
[Crossref]
886. Laixun Zhao, Zhihao Yu, Yoshiko Onuma. 2005. A theory of mutual migration of polluting firms.
Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'<html_ent glyph="@eacute;" ascii="e"/>conomique
38:3, 900-918. [Crossref]
887. Matthew A. Cole, Robert J.R. Elliott, Kenichi Shimamoto. 2005. Why the grass is not always
greener: the competing effects of environmental regulations and factor intensities on US specialization.
Ecological Economics 54:1, 95-109. [Crossref]
888. Matthew A. Cole, Robert J.R. Elliott, Kenichi Shimamoto. 2005. Industrial characteristics,
environmental regulations and air pollution: an analysis of the UK manufacturing sector. Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management 50:1, 121-143. [Crossref]
889. Kakali Mukhopadhyay, Debesh Chakraborty. 2005. ENVIRONMENTAL IMPACTS OF TRADE
IN INDIA. The International Trade Journal 19:2, 135-163. [Crossref]
890. Brian R. Copeland. 2005. Policy Endogeneity and the Effects of Trade on the Environment.
Agricultural and Resource Economics Review 34:1, 1-15. [Crossref]
891. Robert C. Johansson, Joseph Cooper, Utpal Vasavada. 2005. Greener Acres or Greener Waters?
Potential U.S. Impacts of Agricultural Trade Liberalization. Agricultural and Resource Economics
Review 34:1, 42-53. [Crossref]
892. Jared Creason, Michael Fisher, Svetlana Semenova, Susan F. Stone. 2005. The Environmental Impacts
of Trade Liberalization: A Quantitative Analysis for the United States Using TEAM. Agricultural and
Resource Economics Review 34:1, 90-103. [Crossref]
893. James A. Turner, Joseph Buongiorno, Shushuai Zhu. 2005. Effects of the Free Trade Area of the
Americas on Forest Resources. Agricultural and Resource Economics Review 34:1, 104-118. [Crossref]
894. Brian R. Copeland, M. Scott Taylor. 2005. Free trade and global warming: a trade theory view of the
Kyoto protocol. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 49:2, 205-234. [Crossref]
895. ANTON NAHMAN, GEOFF ANTROBUS. 2005. THE ENVIRONMENTAL KUZNETS
CURVE: A LITERATURE SURVEY. The South African Journal of Economics 73:1, 105-120.
[Crossref]
896. David I. Stern. 2005. Beyond the Environmental Kuznets Curve: Diffusion of Sulfur-Emissions-
Abating Technology. The Journal of Environment & Development 14:1, 101-124. [Crossref]
897. Joseph E. Aldy. 2005. An Environmental Kuznets Curve Analysis of U.S. State-Level Carbon Dioxide
Emissions. The Journal of Environment & Development 14:1, 48-72. [Crossref]
898. Jeffrey A. Frankel, Andrew K. Rose. 2005. Is Trade Good or Bad for the Environment? Sorting Out
the Causality. Review of Economics and Statistics 87:1, 85-91. [Crossref]
899. Jo Kwong. 2005. Globalization’s effects on the environment. Society 42:2, 21-28. [Crossref]
900. Michael Rauscher. Chapter 27 International Trade, Foreign Investment, and the Environment
1403-1456. [Crossref]
901. William A. Brock, M. Scott Taylor. Economic Growth and the Environment: A Review of Theory
and Empirics 1749-1821. [Crossref]
902. Jie HE. 2005. Estimating the economic cost of China's new desulfur policy during her gradual
accession to WTO: The case of industrial SO2 emission. China Economic Review 16:4, 364-402.
[Crossref]
903. Yang Haisheng, Jia Jia, Zhou Yongzhang, Wang Shugong. 2005. The Impact on Environmental
Kuznets Curve by Trade and Foreign Direct Investment in China. Chinese Journal of Population
Resources and Environment 3:2, 14-19. [Crossref]
904. Zhihao Yu. 2005. Environmental Protection: A Theory of Direct and Indirect Competition for
Political Influence. The Review of Economic Studies 72:1, 269-286. [Crossref]
905. Agnes C. Rola, Ian Coxhead. 2005. Economic development and environmental management in the
uplands of Southeast Asia: challenges for policy and institutional development. Agricultural Economics
32:s1, 243-256. [Crossref]
906. Ian Coxhead, Sisira Jayasuriya. 2005. Trade Reforms, Deforestation and Industrial Pollution in
Developing Countries: One Size Does Not Fit All. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
907. Matthew A. Cole, Robert J.R. Elliott, Kenichi Shimamoto. 2005. Why the Grass is Not Always
Greener: The Competing Effects of Environmental Regulations and Factor Intensities on US
Specialization. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
908. Matthew A. Cole, Robert J.R. Elliott, Kenichi Shimamoto. 2005. Industrial Characteristics,
Environmental Regulations and Air Pollution: An Analysis of the UK Manufacturing Sector. SSRN
Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
909. Soumyananda Dinda. 2004. Environmental Kuznets Curve Hypothesis: A Survey. Ecological Economics
49:4, 431-455. [Crossref]
910. David I Stern. 2004. The Rise and Fall of the Environmental Kuznets Curve. World Development 32:8,
1419-1439. [Crossref]
911. Matthew E Kahn. 2004. Domestic pollution havens: evidence from cancer deaths in border counties.
Journal of Urban Economics 56:1, 51-69. [Crossref]
912. Per G. Fredriksson, Herman R.J. Vollebergh, Elbert Dijkgraaf. 2004. Corruption and energy efficiency
in OECD countries: theory and evidence. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 47:2,
207-231. [Crossref]
913. 2004. Book Reviews. The World Economy 27:3, 473-477. [Crossref]
914. Smita B. Brunnermeier, Arik Levinson. 2004. Examining the Evidence on Environmental Regulations
and Industry Location. The Journal of Environment & Development 13:1, 6-41. [Crossref]
915. Brian R. Copeland, M. Scott Taylor. 2004. Trade, Growth, and the Environment. Journal of Economic
Literature 42:1, 7-71. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
916. Kazuharu Kiyono, Jota Ishikawa. Strategic Emission Tax-Quota Non-Equivalence under International
Carbon Leakage 133-150. [Crossref]
917. Matthew A Cole. 2004. Trade, the pollution haven hypothesis and the environmental Kuznets curve:
examining the linkages. Ecological Economics 48:1, 71-81. [Crossref]
918. Tisha L. N. Emerson, Linwood H. Pendleton. 2004. Income, Environmental Disamenity, and Toxic
Releases. Economic Inquiry 42:1, 166-178. [Crossref]
919. Marjan W. Hofkes, Reyer Gerlagh, Vincent Linderhof. 2004. Sustainable National Income: A Trend
Analysis for the Netherlands for 1990-2000. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
920. Slim Ben Youssef. 2004. R&D in Cleaner Technology and International Trade. SSRN Electronic
Journal . [Crossref]
921. Marzio Galeotti, Claudia Kemfert. 2004. Interactions Between Climate and Trade Policies: A Survey.
SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
922. Andreas Waldkirch, Munisamy Gopinath. 2004. Pollution Haven or Hythe? New Evidence from
Mexico. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
923. Jeffrey A. Frankel. 2004. Kyoto and Geneva: Linkage of the Climate Change Regime and the Trade
Regime. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
924. David I. Stern. 2004. Diffusion of Emissions Abating Technology. SSRN Electronic Journal .
[Crossref]
925. Carol McAusland. 2003. Voting for pollution policy: the importance of income inequality and openness
to trade. Journal of International Economics 61:2, 425-451. [Crossref]
926. Matthew A. Cole, Robert J.R. Elliott. 2003. Determining the trade–environment composition effect:
the role of capital, labor and environmental regulations. Journal of Environmental Economics and
Management 46:3, 363-383. [Crossref]
927. Richard Damania, Per G. Fredriksson, John A. List. 2003. Trade liberalization, corruption, and
environmental policy formation: theory and evidence. Journal of Environmental Economics and
Management 46:3, 490-512. [Crossref]
928. Richard Damania, Per G. Fredriksson. 2003. Trade policy reform, endogenous lobby group formation,
and environmental policy. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 52:1, 47-69. [Crossref]
929. Matthew A. Cole, Robert J. R. Elliott. 2003. Do Environmental Regulations Influence Trade Patterns?
Testing Old and New Trade Theories. The World Economy 26:8, 1163-1186. [Crossref]
930. Roberto Burguet, Jaume Sempere. 2003. Trade liberalization, environmental policy, and welfare.
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 46:1, 25-37. [Crossref]
931. Matthew E. Kahn. 2003. The geography of US pollution intensive trade: evidence from 1958 to 1994.
Regional Science and Urban Economics 33:4, 383-400. [Crossref]
932. Matthew A. Cole. 2003. Environmental Optimists, Environmental Pessimists and the Real State of
the World – An article examining The Skeptical Environmentalist: Measuring the Real State of the
World by Bjorn Lomborg. The Economic Journal 113:488, F362-F380. [Crossref]
933. Ian Coxhead. 2003. Development and the Environment in Asia. Asian-Pacific Economic Literature
17:1, 22-54. [Crossref]
934. Arnab K. Basu, Nancy H. Chau, Ulrike Grote. 2003. Eco-Labeling and Stages of Development. Review
of Development Economics 7:2, 228-247. [Crossref]
935. Werner Antweiler, Kathryn Harrison. 2003. Toxic release inventories and green consumerism:
empirical evidence from Canada. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue Canadienne d`Economique 36:2,
495-520. [Crossref]
936. Daniel M. Sturm. Trade and the Environment: A Survey of the Literature 119-149. [Crossref]
937. Rutger Hoekstra, Marco A. Janssen. 2003. Environmental Responsibility and Policy in a Two Country
Dynamic Input-output Model. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
938. Ian Coxhead, Sisira Jayasuriya. 2003. Trade Liberalization, Resource Degradation and Industrial
Pollution in Developing Countries: An Integrated Analysis. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
939. Roberto Roson, Barbara Buchner. 2002. Conflicting Perspectives in Trade and Environmental
Negotiations. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
940. Muthukumara Mani, Per G. Fredriksson. 2002. The Rule of Law and the Pattern of Environment
Protection. IMF Working Papers 02:49, 1. [Crossref]
941. Hannes Egli. 2001. Are Cross-Country Studies of the Environmental Kuznets Curve Misleading? New
Evidence from Time Series Data for Germany. SSRN Electronic Journal . [Crossref]
942. Muthukumara Mani, Per G. Fredriksson. 2001. Trade Integration and Political Turbulence:
Environmental Policy Consequences. IMF Working Papers 01:150, 1. [Crossref]
943. A. C. J. Vincent, A. D. Marsden, U. R. Sumaila. Possible contributions of globalization in creating
and addressing sea horse conservation problems 185-214. [Crossref]
944. Onno Kuik, Harmen Verbruggen. The Kyoto Regime, Changing Patterns of International Trade and
Carbon Leakage 239-257. [Crossref]
945. Chad P. Bown, Rachel McCulloch. Environmental Issues 1734-1767. [Crossref]
946. Arnab K. Basu, Nancy H. Chau, Ulrike Grote. Eco-labeling and Strategic Rivalry in Export Markets
111-132. [Crossref]
947. Éric Olszak. Chapitre 12. Localisation des activités et développement durable 155-165. [Crossref]
948. Yang Laike, Liao Chun. China-European Union Trade and Global Warming 18-28. [Crossref]
949. Ahmed Hussen. Biophysical limits to economic growth 274-306. [Crossref]

You might also like