You are on page 1of 31

No.

514 April 14, 2004

Can Tort Reform and Federalism


Coexist?
by Michael I. Krauss and Robert A. Levy

Executive Summary

Critics of federal tort reform have usually come correct to rein in punitive awards.
from the political left and its allies among the trial Most important, we recommend reforms that
lawyers, who favor a state-based system that can are compatible with the tenets of federalism.
be exploited to redistribute income from deep- Some reforms can be implemented at the state
pocketed corporations to “deserving” individuals. level—including solutions to excessive punitive
We offer a totally different criticism—constitu- awards, curbs on joint and several liability, pay-
tional in origin—that embraces the need for ment of attorneys’ fees when government is the
reform but reaffirms this principle: The existence losing party in a civil lawsuit, the prohibition of
of a problem, however serious, does not justify fed- contingency fee contracts between government
eral remedies outside the scope of Congress’s enu- and private lawyers, and restraints on litigation
merated powers. by government to recover expenditures made on
We begin with the Commerce Clause but find behalf of private parties.
that interstate trade does not, by itself, justify At the federal level, we endorse two procedural
federalizing tort law. On the basis of examples reforms. The first involves state “long-arm” juris-
involving fast food, guns, and medical malprac- diction, which determines whether an out-of-state
tice, we argue that substantive federal reforms entity can be sued in a local court. Currently, out-
are neither necessary nor proper. If states persist of-state businesses find it exceedingly difficult to
in imposing unjust rules on out-of-state defen- avoid oppressive state tort laws. A second federal
dants, federal procedural remedies are available. reform concerns “choice-of-law” rules that deter-
Next, we consider the Due Process Clause of mine which state’s laws control a multistate suit.
the Fourteenth Amendment and dissect the A federal choice-of-law rule would prevent states
Supreme Court’s recent State Farm decision cov- from exporting discriminatory tort regimes.
ering punitive damages. We also discuss the con- Taken together, state substantive reforms and
troversies over judicial activism and substantive federal procedural reforms can curtail abuses
due process. Despite the limitations of substan- while respecting time-honored notions of dual-
tive due process, we conclude that the Court was sovereignty federalism.

_____________________________________________________________________________________________________
Michael I. Krauss is professor of law at George Mason University. Robert A. Levy is senior fellow in constitutional
studies at the Cato Institute. This paper will appear in Levy’s forthcoming book, Shakedown: How
Corporations, Government, and Trial Lawyers Abuse the Judicial Process (Cato Institute, November 2004).
We must Introduction ed 2.23 percent of the U.S. gross domestic
find a source of product.5 Over the next 10 years, the total
“A billion here, a billion there, and pretty “tort tax” will likely be $3.6 trillion.6
constitutional soon you’re talking about real money.” When When costs explode, proposals for reform
authority for each the late Sen. Everett M. Dirksen from Illinois are never far behind—especially when the
offered that famous quip 40 years ago about electoral season is upon us. Thus, we have
proposed tort government spending, no one imagined that been deluged by congressional schemes to
reform. the same words might be used today to curb class action litigation, ban lawsuits
describe damage awards in tort cases. Yet last against gun makers and fast food distribu-
year a Florida jury somehow conjured up tors, cap medical malpractice awards, and
punitive damages of $145 billion for a class otherwise enlist the federal government in
of plaintiffs. The year before, a California jury the battle against allegedly biased state
recommended a $28 billion treasure trove for judges and juries.
a single claimant. And in 1998 four major Our primary objective in this paper is not
cigarette companies agreed to the grand- to document that tort reform is necessary or
mother of all awards—a quarter-trillion-dol- desirable. That task has been ably and effec-
lar settlement supposedly to reimburse the tively performed by several others.7 Instead,
states for the Medicaid costs of smoking- we seek to explore the methods by which
related illnesses. reforms might be implemented—especially
So it goes. Not just tobacco; but guns, the extent to which various proposals are
asbestos, and a cross section of American compatible with our system of dual-sover-
industry that has morphed into the Mass Tort eignty federalism. Our underlying premise is
Monster: “DDT, Bendectin, DES, swine flu straightforward: No matter how worthwhile
vaccine, Copper-7, PCBs, the Dalkon Shield, a goal may be, if there is no constitutional
Shiley heart valves, heart catheters, pickup- authority to pursue it, then the federal gov-
truck fuel tanks, blood products, silicone ernment must step aside and leave the matter
breast implants, pedicle screws, penile to the states, or to citizens in the private
implants, intraocular lenses, . . . lead pigment, ordering of their affairs.
latex, dietary supplements, fen-phen, Rezulin, Congress can proceed only from constitu-
L-tryptophan, Duract, Parlodel, Synthroid, tional authority, not from good intentions
Propulsid and so forth almost ad infinitum.”1 alone. That means we must find a source of
According to the U.S. Chamber of constitutional authority for each proposed
Commerce, our tort system is wrecking our tort reform. One possible source, which we
economy. Since 1930 growth in litigation examine in the next section, is the all-encom-
costs has been four times that of the overall passing Commerce Clause. As the country
economy. The chamber reports that federal grew and some people believed that all of its
class actions tripled over the past 10 years, problems required national regulatory solu-
while similar filings in state courts ballooned tions, Congress sought to earmark a speci-
by more than 1,000 percent.2 One chamber fied constitutional power that would justify
official estimates that the annual cost of the an ambitious federal agenda. The Commerce
tort system translates into $809 per person— Clause became the vehicle of choice.
the equivalent of a 5 percent tax on wages.3 Yet the central reason that the clause
The share going to trial lawyers—roughly $40 appeared in the Constitution was quite dif-
billion in 2002—was half again larger than ferent. Under the Articles of Confederation
the annual revenues of Microsoft or Intel and of 1776, the national government lacked the
twice those of Coca-Cola.4 The estimated power to regulate interstate commerce. Each
aggregate cost of the tort system in 2002 was state was free to advance local interests and
$233 billion, says Tillinghast-Towers Perrin, a to create barriers to trade, without regard to
respected actuarial firm. That cost represent- possible prejudice to out-of-state interests.

2
That process devolved into what Justice defendants of due process. If so, federal reme-
William Johnson characterized as a “conflict dies might be in order. Perhaps, for example,
of commercial regulations, destructive to the a damage award is so excessive that it breach-
harmony of the States.”8 The solution: a con- es constitutional safeguards. Then again, per-
stitutional convention at which, according to haps “due process” imposes no substantive
Justice Johnson, “If there was any one object limits on state tort awards, just procedural
riding over every other in the adoption of the guarantees such as advance notice of the exis-
constitution, it was to keep the commercial tence of a rule and an opportunity to defend
intercourse among the States free from all oneself against a claim. Or perhaps substan-
invidious and partial restraints.”9 tive and procedural protections merge when
Today, instead of serving as a shield damage awards are so capricious and unpre-
against interference by the states, the com- dictable that defendants cannot know with
merce power has become a sword wielded by any assurance how to conform their conduct
the federal government in pursuit of a to the dictates of the law.
boundless array of socioeconomic programs. In our section on the Fourteenth
But the mere fact that goods and services Amendment, we weigh those issues by ana-
subject to tort litigation are transported lyzing the Supreme Court’s recent decision in
across state lines and sold to customers in State Farm Mutual Automobile Insurance Co. v.
States
several states does not justify federal inter- Campbell.10 That case specifically addressed should serve as
vention under the Commerce Clause. To punitive damages, although many of the experimental
legitimately invoke the commerce power, principles debated by the Court are applica-
Congress must show that federal tort reform ble to tort reform more broadly. In dissecting laboratories of
is “necessary” and that it is “proper”—that is, State Farm, we discuss the purpose of punitive competing tort
it does not violate other constitutional prin- damages, the need for reform, past efforts at
ciples—to ensure the free flow of interstate reform, and the current controversy over so-
systems.
commerce. As we shall see—on the basis of called judicial activism and substantive due
examples involving fast food distributors, the process.
firearms industry, and medical malpractice— Although we recognize the limitations of
substantive federal reform is neither neces- what is known as substantive due process, and
sary (procedural remedies would do the in fact urge the Court to reconsider the
trick) nor properly harmonized with tradi- Privileges or Immunities Clause of the
tional concepts of federalism. Fourteenth Amendment as an alternative jus-
Following our look at the Commerce tification for striking down certain state laws,
Clause, we turn to an alternative source of we nonetheless conclude that the majority in
constitutional authority, the Due Process State Farm was correct in curbing punitive
Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment. damages. That said, we proceed in the follow-
Ratified in 1868, the Fourteenth Amend- ing section, “Reconciling Tort Reform and
ment states, in relevant part, that no state Federalism,” to recommend a series of reforms
shall “deprive any person of life, liberty, or that avoid the inconsistencies of substantive
property, without due process of law.” If con- due process while respecting the notion that
fiscatory state court decisions have the effect states should serve as experimental laborato-
of denying due process to defendants in tort ries of competing tort systems.
litigation, federal courts are empowered by First among our suggested reforms are
the Fourteenth Amendment to intercede. those that can be implemented at the state
And section 5 of the amendment authorizes level. We begin by offering several solutions to
Congress “to enforce, by appropriate legisla- the problem of excessive punitive awards.
tion” the Due Process Clause. Then we advocate state-based reforms in
The question, then, is whether state other areas, like curbing joint and several lia-
courts have gone so far as to deprive tort bility, shifting attorneys’ fees when govern-

3
ment is the losing party in a civil lawsuit, pro- 1. Legislation that would cap medical mal-
hibiting contingency fee contracts between practice awards and limit attorney fees
government and private lawyers, and restrain- cleared the House 229 to 196 on March
ing litigation by government to recover 13, 2003.12 That was the seventh attempt
expenditures made on behalf of private par- at federal malpractice reform since
ties. Republicans took over the House in
Switching to federal reforms, we support 1995.13
two changes that are procedural in nature.11 2. In the aftermath of the September 11,
The first change is federal reform of state 2001, terrorist attacks, Congress passed
“long-arm” jurisdiction—the rules that deter- the Air Transportation Safety and
mine whether an out-of-state entity can be System Stabilization Act, which created
sued in a local court. A sensible application a federal cause of action for property
of the Due Process Clause would exempt and personal injury claims related to
businesses from local court jurisdiction 9/11. At the same time, the act capped
unless they have sufficient dealings within the airlines’ liability at the amount of
the state. Currently, out-of-state businesses their insurance coverage.14
find it exceedingly difficult to avoid oppres- 3. In 2001 the House and Senate passed
On the subject sive state tort regimes. separate versions of the Patients’ Bill of
of tort reform, The second federal reform that we Rights, which provided for an expan-
hypocrisy on both endorse is a change in “choice-of-law” rules, sion of patients’ right to sue health
which determine which state’s laws control a plans in state courts while limiting
sides of the aisle suit involving litigants from more than one damages for pain and suffering and
is thick enough state. Frequently, tort defendants will be dis- punitive damages.15
advantaged when plaintiffs select jurisdic-
to slice. tions that have plaintiff-friendly choice-of- On the subject of tort reform, hypocrisy on
law rules. The concern is that the tort laws of both sides of the aisle is thick enough to slice.
some states discriminate against out-of-state Democrats opposed to federal tort reform
corporate defendants. If that were to happen suddenly profess abiding faith in federalism.
on a large scale, it could impede interstate Yet those same Democrats were beside them-
commerce—the very problem that the selves when the Supreme Court held in 1995
Commerce Clause was intended to redress. that federal power to create criminal law is
By establishing a federal choice-of-law rule— not plenary.16 Meanwhile, Republicans, self-
a procedural solution that does not intrude styled ardent defenders of decentralization,
on state sovereignty, because it leaves under- now argue that malpractice (for instance) is a
lying state substantive law in place—the fed- “national problem.” But under our federal
eral government can effect meaningful tort system, every national problem does not ipso
reform without trampling on principles of facto become a federal problem.
federalism. Several commentators have proposed that
state tort rules should give way to uniform
national rules in order to help federal courts
Tort Reform, Federalism, cope with ever-increasing mass tort cases.17
and the Commerce Clause Legislators have proposed several bills that
would alter “diversity jurisdiction,” allowing
Background federal courts to hear tort class actions even if
Our review of the federal government’s some plaintiffs reside in the same state as
venture into tort reform starts with recent some defendants.18 Some observers have sug-
efforts by Congress to expand its already gested that federal law alone should govern
copious power to regulate interstate com- punitive damages.19 Federalization of tort law
merce. A few examples: is also occurring indirectly through executive

4
branch agencies. That means defendants in police power that doesn’t directly affect inter-
tort suits may be able to avoid liability by argu- state trade.25 But if California tried to regu-
ing that they have complied with all applicable late catalytic converters on every car that
federal statutes and regulations, which would crossed its state boundary, that would pro-
preempt irreconcilable state rules.20 voke stronger Commerce Clause questions.
In the face of those pressures to federalize Cars traveling interstate would have to stop
tort law, our constitutional principles must be at the border and turn back—clearly a burden
recalled and enforced. The general principle on interstate commerce.
cannot be repeated often enough: Our federal Can federalism be squared with Washing-
government is one of limited and enumerated pow- ton’s current tort reform proposals? In a word,
ers. The making of tort law is not one of those no. Federal intervention is rarely authorized
powers. The Constitution does provide, as we for the purpose of altering substantive rules of
have noted, that Congress can “regulate state tort law. Most tort suits involve “inter-
Commerce . . . among the several States.”21 nal” activities, like negligent driving,26 doctor-
Over the past 65 years, courts have read the ing, lawyering, and so forth, and pit an in-state
Commerce Clause very broadly, using it to individual plaintiff against an in-state individ-
uphold federal legislation concerning non- ual defendant. When litigated in a state court
commercial activity.22 In so doing, the courts before a local jury, that type of case creates no
have allowed Congress to turn the commerce intrinsic predisposition against either party.
power on its head. Instead of using it to strike What is sometimes termed a “public choice”
down state barriers to interstate trade, problem27 is absent: The plaintiff cannot per-
Congress has in fact erected federal barriers suasively ask the jury to bring “outside”
that prevented free trade. money into the locality without harming any-
To be sure, state laws, including tort rules, one locally. Even when parties are insured,
often “affect” commerce. But that is not both in-state and out-of-state insurance com-
enough to justify federal intervention unless panies are exposed to the same liability regime.
the flow of trade among the states is imped- Other, noncommercial kinds of bias
ed by such laws. In 1995 the Supreme Court (against the social class or race of either party,
took a step toward reaffirming that impor- for example) are of course possible in those
tant principle. In United States v. Lopez, the cases, as in all lawsuits. Such biases might
Court held that the Gun-Free School Zones raise Fourteenth Amendment concerns.
Act of 1990, which purported to ban the pos- However, race and class biases are not intrin-
session of guns within 1,000 feet of any sic to a party’s status as plaintiff or defen-
school, exceeded Congress’s authority under dant. In any case, parties can attempt to
the Commerce Clause, in part because guard against those biases through chal-
Congress made no finding that the posses- lenges to the jury venire.28 Thus, there is no
sion of firearms near schools affected inter- valid structural reason for the federal govern-
state trade.23 In 2000 the Court extended ment to intervene in the ordering of behavior
Lopez in U.S. v. Morrison, which held that a through state tort law. Our federal
statutory federal tort suit for sexual battery A second type of tort suit—exemplified by government is
under the Violence Against Women Act was negligence claims invoking respondeat superior
unconstitutional, even though Congress had (suits against an employer for damages one of limited
issued fig-leaf findings that sexual assaults caused by wrongful behavior by its employ- and enumerated
affected interstate commerce.24 ee)29—usually sets in-state individual plaintiffs
State laws regularly affect interstate com- against in-state corporate defendants. Because
powers. The
merce without raising constitutional con- juries are always composed of individuals making of tort
cerns. California, for example, requires spe- and never of corporations, corporate defen- law is not one of
cial catalytic converters on cars sold in that dants might experience systemic prejudice
state. That’s a permissible use of California’s here: A jury may be tempted to transfer those powers.

5
When voters wealth from an entity that does not “feel every incentive to respond. The same types of
realize that they pain” to a suffering real person with whom it incentives that dissuade states from imposing
can identify. But such temptations may be exorbitant income or sales taxes can operate
pay a price if offset by the jury’s desire to maintain to create a rational tort system.
their state persists employment and economic activity in its Early product liability suits tended to be
own locality, especially if the defendant cor- of the intrastate kind. Most products were
in applying poration maintains a large local presence. It manufactured near their place of consump-
dysfunctional tort is hard to predict how those offsetting incen- tion, as transportation costs made far-flung
rules, state tives will ultimately unfold in a specific markets unreachable. Thus, many lawsuits
case.30 In any event, those problems derive concerning allegedly defective products were
lawmakers have from the corporate nature of the defendant, filed by local individual plaintiffs against
every incentive to not its state of domicile. Thus, state tort law local corporate defendants.34 But with the
respond. can alleviate any anti-corporate biases that advent of “paradigm shifters”35 such as
may exist. Few states want existing employers assembly-line production, interstate high-
to pack up and leave. ways, and electronic auctions, markets for
To the extent that abusive state tort rules goods (though not yet services) have today
operate like a tax on productive activity, the become largely national. Modern product lia-
greater the abuse, the greater the decline in bility suits characteristically set in opposition
productivity or wealth. Customers will pay an in-state individual plaintiff and a corporate
more for in-state services if the providers of out-of-state defendant.36
those services have to pay for injuries they did In a typical product liability suit today, a
not wrongfully cause. Physicians will avoid consumer purchases a product, is allegedly
practicing in jurisdictions with unreasonable injured while using it, and sues its far-off
malpractice rules. Local children and their manufacturer37 to recover damages. Most
parents will suffer if playgrounds cannot be purchases take place close to home; almost
built without the park authority being held all product use takes place near the home or
liable for inevitable accidents. Those costs the workplace;38 and no state is home to a
produce powerful in-state lobbies for tort majority of manufacturers’ head offices or
reform. Predictably, since the so-called torts factories. The confluence of those factors
crisis of the mid-1980s, almost all 50 states means that a plaintiff ordinarily files a prod-
have enacted some form of tort reform for uct liability suit in her home state, which is
intrastate activity.31 also the state where she was injured and
The reforms have varied substantially— where she purchased the allegedly defective
from caps on punitive damages to the cre- product. In the vast majority of cases, howev-
ation of statutes of repose (limiting the time er, the product was designed and manufac-
period within which claims can be filed) to tured in another state.
the modification of joint and several liability Assume for a moment that the victim sues
(whereby each one of multiple defendants is in her home state. There, the court agrees it
held liable for the entirety of a plaintiff’s dam- has jurisdiction to try the suit and concludes
ages, irrespective of the extent of the individ- that its own product liability law applies to
ual defendant’s culpability).32 Some state resolve the dispute. Such a suit would now
reforms have arguably been misguided—and pit a local individual against an out-of-state
more than a few have been declared by state corporation, in the local plaintiff’s court and
supreme courts to violate state constitu- subject to the local plaintiff’s state law. That
tions33—but misguided or nonexistent state situation creates a risk of bias that is unlikely
reform is no justification for federal lawmak- to be remedied by political and economic
ers to intervene. When voters realize that they forces within the state. Such a situation is
pay a price if their state persists in applying ripe for federal tort reform. Even then we will
dysfunctional tort rules, state lawmakers have conclude that substantive (as opposed to pro-

6
cedural) federal tort legislation is neither lawsuits against fast food manufacturers?
needed nor beneficial. According to McConnell’s bill, the answer
First, however, we look at pending federal is—to no one’s surprise—the all-purpose
tort reform proposals in three industry-spe- Commerce Clause. In a nutshell, fatty food
cific areas—fatty foods, guns, and medical suits are said to hinder interstate commerce
malpractice. None of those reforms is author- in ingredients, and therefore to invite federal
ized by the Commerce Clause, and each intervention. Undoubtedly, frivolous law-
offends basic tenets of federalism. suits against food manufacturers would
jeopardize legitimate businesses that may be
The Case against Substantive Federal important to our national economy. The
Tort Reform: Three Examples geographic scope of the problem does not,
Fatty Foods. The most recent area where however, demand that it be resolved by
preemptive federal legislation has been pro- Congress. Lawsuits against food manufac-
posed is that of fatty foods. Sen. Mitch turers affect commerce in multiple states.
McConnell (R-KY) drafted a bill that would But so does just about every state regulation
ban certain liability suits against food sellers or court decision. The Commerce Clause
and manufacturers.39 In the House, Rep. Ric would not permit the federal government to
Keller (R-FL) introduced the Personal override state minimum wage laws, for exam-
Lawsuits
Responsibility in Food Consumption Act.40 ple, even if high in-state wages discourage against food
His bill would forbid civil suits, in both feder- out-of-state employers from setting up shop. manufacturers
al and state courts, against food manufactur- Procedural choice-of-law rules, as we will
ers, distributors, or restaurateurs for obesity or explain below, can resolve interstate prob- affect commerce
other supposed deleterious effects of eating lems that might be caused by baseless state in multiple states
noncontaminated food. The bill has 108 fatty food liability decisions—without sacri-
cosponsors and, of course, the backing of ficing state sovereignty over the substantive
But so does just
industry groups. rules of tort law. The fatty food legislation about every state
Because the fatty food lawsuits are must be trimmed. regulation or
groundless,41 we understand and sympathize Guns. The same considerations underlie
with the objectives of both bills. Still, good our view of federal proposals to ban state and court decision.
intentions are not a substitute for constitu- local suits against firearm manufacturers.
tional authorization. Moreover, it’s easy to But here there is one additional factor: The
exaggerate the litigation problem. A 2003 right of individual and collective self-defense,
case brought by obese New York teenagers enshrined in the Second Amendment, may
against McDonald’s claimed that the restau- be undermined by undue state interference
rant should be responsible for the plaintiffs’ with firearms manufacturers. Accordingly,
health problems.42 In another case, Oreo we distinguish between federal intervention
cookies and Big Daddy ice cream were alleged under Commerce Clause auspices, which
to have misled customers about their prod- would not be justified, and federal interven-
ucts’ nutritional content.43 But those suits tion to secure the rights guaranteed by the
have not succeeded.44 Indeed, every court Second Amendment—as applied to the states
that has considered similar litigation has through the Fourteenth Amendment—which
refused to allow it to go forward.45 Nonethe- may be justified, depending on the specific
less, one day a sympathetic state court will provisions of the legislation authorizing the
likely be found, perhaps in one of America’s intervention.
“judicial hellholes.”46 Senator McConnell’s Let us make clear at the outset that most
and Representative Keller’s bills are meant to lawsuits against firearms manufacturers for
nip those future decisions in the bud. anything other than manufacturing defects47
Yet where in the Constitution does the are barely disguised extortion attempts. Here
federal government find authority to ban are the two principal legal theories recently

7
asserted by dozens of municipalities against intended to ensure free trade, not to establish
gun makers: a federal police power. How do we know that
would be the NRA’s view? Because in 1995,
1. “Negligent Marketing.” According to after Congress enacted the Violent Crime
this newfangled theory of tort law, gun Control and Law Enforcement Act of 1994,51
manufacturers “flood” suburban juris- the NRA sued, contending that Congress
dictions with more guns than are “legit- exceeded its powers under the Commerce
imate” for local suburban demand, Clause when it prohibited the manufacture,
knowing that dealers will connive to sell transfer, and possession of semiautomatic
illegally the excess supply to criminals weapons.52 It cannot be that the Commerce
from the inner city, where gun laws are Clause did not authorize a federal ban on the
typically more restrictive. sale and manufacture of assault weapons in
2. “Design Defect.” Under this theory, 1995—a position we certainly endorse—while
guns are defective and unreasonably in 2004 that same Commerce Clause permits
dangerous because they do not have the federal government to commandeer state
design features that would minimize courts and tell them what kind of product
their use by criminals. liability suits they can entertain.
Federal intervention is not needed to rein
Both theories are shot full of holes.48 in municipal litigation against gun makers.
Courts across the nation—without the help of Since the first of the state firearms suits was
Congress—have concluded that gun makers filed, 33 states53 have enacted legislation that
are not the proximate cause of, and therefore prevents them. In those jurisdictions where
not responsible for, the criminal misconduct the suits have not been barred, the firearms
of a very small percentage of their cus- industry has not lost a single case.
tomers.49 Those are the right results. But On October 7, 1999, Ohio Judge Robert
wrong results might one day occur.50 Would Ruehlman dismissed with prejudice Cincin-
that justify federal intervention? Yes, it nati’s suit, calling it “an improper attempt to
might—unlike the fatty food example—but have this court substitute its judgment for
only if one condition were satisfied. If the fed- that of the legislature, something which this
eral government declared forthrightly that court is neither inclined nor empowered to
gun ownership by law-abiding citizens was a do.”54 On December 10, 1999, Superior Court
guaranteed Second Amendment right, which Judge Robert F. McWeeny threw out the city of
Congress could therefore protect from undue Bridgeport’s suit, writing, “[T]he court finds
state encroachment by virtue of the as a matter of law that the plaintiffs lack
Fourteenth Amendment, federal intervention standing to litigate these claims; thus, the
could be appropriate. But if protection of court is without jurisdiction to hear this
Courts across the firearm manufacturers is premised on case.”55 On December 13, 1999, Florida
nation—without Commerce Clause grounds, then the idea of Circuit Judge Amy Dean dismissed Miami-
the help of federal intervention is flawed. If Congress’s Dade County’s lawsuit against the industry
Commerce Clause authority is misused to with a similar decision, stating, “Public nui-
Congress—have allow the federal government to impose rules sance does not apply to the design, manufac-
concluded that that restrict state gun lawsuits, it could one ture, and distribution of a lawful product.”56
day similarly be misused to impose federal Here are three other examples of state
gun makers are rules that impose more severe liability on gun supreme court rulings against frivolous
not responsible manufacturers and distributors. firearms lawsuits:
for the criminal The National Rifle Association, which has
vigorously backed a federal ban on firearms 1. On April 3, 2001, the Louisiana Supreme
misconduct of lawsuits, would not like that. NRA attorneys Court voted 5 to 2 to dismiss the City of
their customers. would argue that the Commerce Clause was New Orleans’ suit, the first of its kind to

8
be filed, upholding the state law that for- Congress, the Second Amendment justifica- An outright ban
bids municipalities in Louisiana from tion was preserved in S. 659,62 along with the on selected state
bringing those types of suits. In October original Commerce Clause rationale. S. 659
2001 the U.S. Supreme Court allowed contained this finding, which reflects both tort lawsuits is
the Louisiana court’s decision to stand, sources of constitutional authority: not a regulation
by refusing to review the case on
appeal.57 The possibility of imposing liability on
of interstate
2. On August 6, 2001, the California an entire industry for harm that is sole- trade.
Supreme Court issued a 5-to-1 ruling ly caused by others is an abuse of the
that gun manufacturers cannot be held legal system, erodes public confidence
responsible when their products are in our Nation’s laws, threatens the diminu-
used to commit crimes. The decision tion of a basic constitutional right and civil lib-
referred to a 1983 California law pro- erty, invites the disassembly and destabi-
hibiting that type of lawsuit.58 lization of other industries and eco-
3. On October 1, 2001, the Connecticut nomic sectors lawfully competing in the
Supreme Court upheld the 1999 ruling free enterprise system of the United
that dismissed Bridgeport’s suit States, and constitutes an unreasonable
because the city lacked “any statutory burden on interstate and foreign com-
authorization to initiate . . . claims” of merce of the United States.63
liability against the firearms industry.59
After the rejection of the New Orleans Because our focus is on the Commerce
suit, Bridgeport’s mayor Joseph Ganim Clause, we do not intend to parse the specif-
told the Associated Press that an appeal ic provisions of S. 659 to determine whether
of his city’s suit to the U.S. Supreme each type of lawsuit that it attempts to ban
Court was “probably not a likely route would, if litigated, offend the Second
for us” and “[i]t’s not likely we’re in a Amendment. Yet we do argue that securing
very strong position.”60 Second Amendment rights is the only legiti-
mate basis on which federal intervention
Clearly, state legal and political processes might be justified.
have produced the correct outcomes—both With respect to the Commerce Clause
in the courts and in the legislatures. To the rationale, it’s time for Congress, the NRA,
extent that the mere filing of lawsuits, and and the Supreme Court to draw a line in the
the attendant cost of litigation, is a burden sand. Plain and simple, an outright ban on
on the firearms industry, that problem can selected state tort lawsuits is not a regulation
be remedied by procedural reforms, which we of interstate trade.
discuss at greater length in our section on Interestingly, at this writing, the Senate
“Reconciling Tort Reform and Federalism.” has done the right thing; it has overwhelm-
When the bill to ban selected lawsuits ingly rejected S. 659. The bill’s own sponsors
against the gun industry was first introduced turned against it, as did its NRA supporters.
in the 107th Congress,61 its only constitu- But, sad to say, the senators were not sud-
tional pedigree was the Commerce Clause. By denly concerned about the bill’s Commerce
the time the bill was reported in the House Clause or federalism implications. Rather,
nearly 17 months later, it included a finding they voted the bill down because opponents
that “[c]itizens have a right, under the had added “poison pill” amendments,
Second Amendment . . . to keep and bear including one that would have extended a
arms.” And one of the expressed goals of the soon-to-expire ban on so-called assault
legislation was to “preserve a citizen’s access weapons.64
to a supply of firearms and ammunition for Very likely, the industry’s supporters in
all lawful purposes.” Later, in the 108th Congress will mount another effort to

9
immunize gun makers from unfounded liti- ings of at least $25 billion a year if its pro-
gation. That may be warranted from a public posed medical malpractice reforms are put in
policy perspective. But public policy argu- place. “[A]ny time a malpractice lawsuit drives
ments cannot confer federal authority where up the cost of health care, it affects taxpayers.
none exists. Under our Constitution, the It is a federal issue,” the president declared in
commerce power was meant to ensure the a North Carolina speech.68
free flow of interstate trade, not to dictate In essence, the argument is that
substantive product liability rules in each Washington pays the states for a lot of health
and every state. Yes, municipal lawsuits care; therefore Washington can enforce state
against gun makers have been baseless and malpractice reform, which would affect how
extortionate. But that, in and of itself, does all health care money is spent. But the
not make the substantive rules of state tort Supreme Court has invalidated conditions
law the business of Congress. imposed on the recipients of federal spend-
Medical Malpractice. When it comes to ing unless, among other things, the condi-
federal incursions into traditional state func- tions are unambiguous and reasonably relat-
tions, it’s not only the legislative branch that ed to the aim of the expenditure.69 In this
has overreached. President Bush used his instance, Congress has not linked the receipt
The fact that a support for federal malpractice tort reform of federal health funding to malpractice
problem exists in measures to distinguish himself from Al reform, nor has the federal government
more than one Gore during the 2000 presidential campaign. shown that the goals of Medicare and
And he’s doing so against his Democratic Medicaid depend on such reforms. Moreover,
state does not opponents in 2004. Of course, the president the scope of proposed federal malpractice
make it a federal is a former governor who says he is commit- intervention extends, though it need not log-
ted to principles of federalism. Yet he defends ically do so, to all health care lawsuits—not
responsibility. the federalization of malpractice law: “People just those brought by or against parties who
say, well, is [medical malpractice] a federal receive federal funds.
responsibility?” “It’s a national problem,” he Second, the administration posits a
responds, “that requires a national solution. Commerce Clause argument.70 Physicians
The federal government ought to set a mini- are “forced” to move to another state, or to
mum federal standard to reform the medical retire from practice altogether (thus remov-
liability system.”65 Again, however, the fact ing their services from the “stream of inter-
that a problem exists in more than one state state commerce”), by hikes in malpractice
does not make it a federal responsibility. premiums.71 At the margin, malpractice
The administration’s legal strategy in abuse has surely steered some patients across
defense of federal intervention appears to be state lines to find better health care. But
twofold.66 First, federal limitations on med- intrastate regulation of in-state conduct is
ical malpractice suits are supposedly warrant- simply not interference with interstate com-
ed because the federal government spends merce—otherwise there is no area immune
money on health care, and the Constitution’s from federal jurisdiction. Naturally, there’s
spending power67 presumably allows an effect on commerce when any individual
Congress to impose conditions on parties or company withdraws from a state. But if
that benefit from those expenditures. Not the withdrawal is related to unjust in-state
only does the federal government fund negligence claims, absent discrimination
Medicare and Medicaid, it also provides direct against out-of-state defendants, then the
care to members of the armed forces, veterans, effect is not uniquely related to the interstate
and patients served by the Indian Health aspect of commerce.
Service, as well as tax breaks to workers who In objecting to the president’s assertion of
obtain health insurance through their federal jurisdiction, we do not dismiss poten-
employers. The administration projects sav- tial problems associated with excessive med-

10
ical malpractice decisions in certain states. unconvincing. Shocking malpractice damage
Fear of malpractice liability may lead doctors awards, if indeed they are systemically too
to order redundant and expensive diagnostic high, are not commerce and seldom inter-
tests72 and operations.73 High malpractice state.
insurance premiums may encourage compe-
tent physicians to retire prematurely, leaving
whole geographic areas underserved.74 On Tort Reform, Federalism,
the other hand, those allegations are disput- and the Fourteenth
ed. Indeed, some well-respected academic
sources suggest that there may be too little
Amendment
medical malpractice liability.75 Because the Commerce Clause has been
But we need not enter the substantive distended to accommodate all manner of
debate on medical malpractice reform here. federal mischief, some proponents of federal
It is sufficient to show that federal interven- tort reform have endorsed an alternative
tion is neither necessary nor proper. The two source of constitutional authority, the
litigants in a medical malpractice suit are Fourteenth Amendment. Here’s their argu-
usually a local (in-state) plaintiff and a local ment: Advocates of states’ rights too often
(in-state) physician. As a result, excessive lia- have a crabbed, essentially mistaken concep-
bility will be directly felt in the local state, tion of federalism. Federalism is not just
where it will translate into high insurance about states’ rights. To be sure, the framers
premiums for doctors and high costs for originally established a federal government
patients. Doctors can of course retire from of enumerated powers. And the Tenth
practice or relocate to other states if they find Amendment, ratified in 1791, provides that
liability too onerous. That will exert pressure those powers not delegated to the United
on both juries and legislatures to temper States are reserved to the individual states or
excesses. to the people. But in 1868, when the
State medical malpractice reform is ubiq- Fourteenth Amendment was ratified, the
uitous.76 More than three dozen states have relationship between federal and state gov-
passed damage caps. All 50 states have passed ernments was fundamentally restructured.
or considered some kind of medical malprac- And those politicians who rail against federal
tice reform.77 If a state legislature has chosen legislative incursions and judicial activism
not to enact medical malpractice reform— may not have fully grasped the significance
and to suffer an increase in the cost or a of the post–Civil War transformation.
decline in the quantity of medical care, or The Fourteenth Amendment to the feder-
both, from a presumed “optimal” level—that al Constitution addresses the violation of
is not a federal crisis. Rather, that is a matter constitutionally guaranteed rights by state
for the state’s voters to resolve. governments. Both the legislative and judi-
Nonetheless, H.R. 5 and S. 607, the Help cial branches of the federal government are
Efficient, Accessible, Low-Cost, Timely Health- empowered to remedy those violations. And
care (HEALTH) Act,78 set damage caps and within that framework, the U.S. Supreme
limited attorney fees, among other things. Rep. Court may prevent a state court from deny-
Tom Feeney (R-FL), usually a defender of fed- ing rights to citizens inside and, a fortiori, Shocking
eralism, claims to have “wrestled with the outside the state. That is not mere activism—
issue.”79 But he and his fellow Republicans at least not in the sense of fabricating entitle-
malpractice
seem to have concluded that a partial federal ments never grounded in the Constitution. damage awards
takeover of state tort law is necessary. Rather, it is judicial responsibility, allegiance are not commerc
Yet there is no constitutional right to to the law and to the Constitution, rooted in
health care. Moreover, the Commerce Clause a theory of rights. Arguably, one of those and seldom
rationale invoked by H.R. 5 and S. 607 is rights, enshrined in the Due Process Clause interstate.

11
The Court of the Fourteenth Amendment, is protection over the Court’s substantive due process
had to grapple against grossly excessive or arbitrary punish- jurisprudence.
ments. We turn next to that topic, in the con- Our conclusion: State Farm was a close
with federal text of punitive damage awards. call, but the majority successfully made its
intervention, via case for federal judicial intervention.
Punitive Damages: A Case for Federal Nevertheless, there are better approaches to
the Fourteenth Reform tort reform. We will address those approach-
Amendment’s Perhaps the most business-friendly of the es in a later section on “Reconciling Tort
Due Process Supreme Court’s recent opinions was its Reform and Federalism.”
2003 reversal of a bloated $145 million puni- Nature of Punitive Damages. Compensa-
Clause, to prevent tive damages award against State Farm tory damages are supposed to redress any loss
states from Insurance.80 Ironically, that holding over- that the plaintiff suffers because of the defen-
violating came separate dissents from the Court’s con- dant’s wrongful conduct. Punitive damages
servative stalwarts, Justices Antonin Scalia serve a different purpose. They “are aimed at
substantive and Clarence Thomas. Justice Ruth Bader deterrence and retribution.”82 The logic goes
rights. Ginsburg also dissented. The same three jus- like this: A defendant whose misbehavior
tices had dissented from the Court’s 1996 causes injury will neither be adequately pun-
decision overturning a punitive damage ished nor deterred from similar misbehavior
award against BMW.81 In that case, Chief in the future if he is held accountable only for
Justice William H. Rehnquist dissented as the losses he causes. That’s because some
well. But in State Farm, he switched sides wrongful acts, especially premeditated and
without explanation. intentional ones, are concealed or for some
The odd lineup of the justices is a healthy other reason never litigated. Therefore, proper
sign, say many Court watchers. It suggests deterrence requires hiking up the compen-
that law and politics operate within separate satory award.83 Still, advocates of tort reform
realms. An alternative explanation, however, argue that judges and juries have allowed
is that the current Court has no coherent punitive damage awards to explode without
jurisprudential compass. State Farm may sim- regard to their harmful impact on the econo-
ply be the latest case in which the Court has my and without a rational link to the real need
struggled to reconcile traditional state-based for deterrence. The evidence seems to support
lawmaking—in this instance, tort law—and that view.
federalism. Once again, the Court had to Need for Reform. Consider the recent Engle
grapple with federal intervention, via the tobacco class action litigation,84 in which an
Fourteenth Amendment’s Due Process inflamed Florida jury resolved to assess $145
Clause, to prevent states from violating sub- billion in punitive damages against cigarette
stantive rights that some people believe are manufacturers. Trial judge Robert Kaye,
secured by the U.S. Constitution. notwithstanding an advisory opinion to the
Contrasting the majority opinion in State contrary from the state’s attorney general,
Farm with the terse dissents by Scalia and permitted the jury to quantify punitive dam-
Thomas, we hope to shed light on the battle ages for the entire class, after hearing evi-
between conservatives who want to rein in dence on only three of the claimants and
runaway punitive damage awards and other before any tort liability to the remaining
conservatives who reluctantly find no federal claimants had been established.85
judicial power to do so. First, we set the stage No one knew the names of the other class
with a few comments on the nature of puni- members. No one even knew how many
tive damages, the need for reform, and the smokers were in the class; estimates ranged
Court’s major stab at the problem in the case from 30,000 to nearly a million. No one knew
of BMW v. Gore. Then we analyze the State anything about their alleged injuries or how
Farm opinion and explore the controversy much if any compensatory damages might

12
be warranted. Yet Judge Kaye approved an sales should have been considered, then
award of punitive damages in the aggregate, reduced the punitive award to a “mere” $2 mil-
as if it did not matter whether 50,000 plain- lion, without explaining how it arrived at that
tiffs had a raspy throat or 500,000 died from figure. The U.S. Supreme Court declared that
lung cancer, whether they started smoking as state sovereignty and comity prevented one
kids or as consenting adults, and whether state from imposing its policy choices on
they were ever influenced by the industry’s other states. In remanding the case, the Court
so-called deceptive ads. Ultimately, a Florida held that the punitive award violated BMW’s
appellate court decertified the class and rights under the Due Process Clause of the
reversed the punitive damages award because Fourteenth Amendment.
there had been no prior determination of The Court noted, first, that Gore’s loss
compensatory damages. The Engle case was purely economic. None of the aggravat-
demonstrates the enormous potential for ing factors associated with reprehensible
mischief when local juries impose punitive conduct causing physical injury was present.
damages on out-of-state defendants. Second, the ratio of punitive damages to
But the Engle fiasco is not the only evi- compensatory damages was 500 to 1, which
dence that punitive damage awards are dan- the Court felt was clearly outside any accept-
gerously out of control. According to the able range. Third, Alabama’s statutory penal-
The Engle case
National Law Journal, the largest punitive ty for retailer fraud was only $2,000—an demonstrates
award in 2002 was $28 billion. Five verdicts amount so much lower than the punitive the enormous
exceeded $500 million and 22 exceeded $100 award that out-of-state defendants would
million. The total of the top 100 verdicts for not have had fair notice of their exposure to potential for
2002 was nearly three and a half times the a multi-million-dollar sanction. mischief when
total for 2001. Longer term, 38 verdicts Gore’s three-part test—“the degree of repre-
topped $20 million in 1991; 66 verdicts were hensibility . . .; the disparity between the harm
local juries
over $20 million in 1996. But in 2002, $20 . . . suffered [and the] punitive damages award; impose punitive
million did not make the top 100 list.86 No and the difference between this remedy and damages on
doubt nine U.S. Supreme Court justices were the civil penalties authorized or imposed in
aware of that general trend. Perhaps that’s comparable cases”87—provided the business out-of-state
why, seven years ago, the Court took a first community with some minimal predictability defendants.
step toward reform. and offered hope that the punitive damages
BMW v. Gore. When Dr. Ira Gore discov- crisis was defused. Regrettably, it did not turn
ered that his new BMW had been repainted out that way. During the seven years after Gore,
before delivery, he sued BMW of North punitive awards continued their upward spi-
America for fraud. The distributor conceded ral. State Farm v. Campbell was a poster child for
that its policy was not to notify consumers if what could go wrong.
repairs for predelivery damage to a new car State Farm v. Campbell. Curtis Campbell,
cost less than 3 percent of the suggested retail trying to pass six vans on a two-lane highway,
price. Gore’s car, scratched during shipment faced a head-on collision with an oncoming
and touched up at a cost of approximately car driven by Todd Ospital. To avoid a colli-
$600, had sold for $40,000. On the basis of tes- sion, Ospital swerved, lost control of his car,
timony that a repainted car loses 10 percent in and hit Robert Slusher, who suffered perma-
value, an Alabama jury found BMW liable for nent disabling injuries. Ospital was killed.
$4,000 in compensatory damages, then Campbell was unharmed. Slusher and
imposed an additional $4 million in punitive Ospital’s estate sued.
damages, computed by multiplying the com- Campbell’s insurer, State Farm, rejected
pensatory award by roughly 1,000 similar settlement proposals for the policy limit of
repairs nationwide. On appeal, the Alabama $50,000. Instead, State Farm decided to liti-
Supreme Court concluded that only in-state gate, assuring Campbell and his wife that

13
their “assets were safe,” they had “no liabili- The reinstatement was short-lived. Justice
ty,” and they did not need separate counsel.88 Anthony Kennedy, writing for a six-member
The jury had other ideas, however, and found majority of the U.S. Supreme Court, put it
the Campbells liable for roughly $186,000. bluntly: “[T]his case is neither close nor diffi-
Initially, State Farm refused to cover the cult. It was error to reinstate the jury’s $145
excess liability of $136,000; Campbell had, million punitive damages award.”91 The high
after all, purchased only $50,000 of coverage. court returned the case to Utah with this
Somewhat callously, State Farm advised the advice: “An application of the Gore guide-
Campbells to “put for sale signs on your posts to the facts of this case, especially in
property to get things moving.”89 The light of the substantial compensatory dam-
Campbells then hired their own lawyer to ages awarded (a portion of which contained a
appeal the jury verdict against them. They punitive element), likely would justify a puni-
lost in the Utah Supreme Court. At that tive damages award at or near the amount of
point State Farm changed its mind and compensatory damages.”92
agreed to pay the entire judgment. Then Kennedy proceeded to address in
Still, the Campbells sued State Farm for bad some detail the first two guideposts of BMW
faith, fraud, and intentional infliction of emo- v. Gore—the reprehensibility of the conduct
tional distress. Because State Farm had ulti- and the ratio of punitive to compensatory
mately paid the full $186,000 award, a Utah damages. He also discussed at length the pro-
trial court threw out Campbell’s new suit. That priety of evidence related to the defendant’s
ruling was overturned on appeal, however, and out-of-state conduct and net worth. As to
the case was returned to the trial court, which Gore’s third guidepost, comparable fines,
then determined that State Farm’s refusal to Kennedy dismissively noted, “The most rele-
settle had been unreasonable. vant civil sanction under Utah state law for
Next, the trial court was to address fraud, the wrong done to the Campbells appears to
emotional distress, and damages. But mean- be a $10,000 fine.”93
while the U.S. Supreme Court had decided Regarding reprehensibility, Kennedy con-
Gore. In that case, to recall, the Court disal- cluded that the Utah courts were justified in
lowed evidence of out-of-state conduct that awarding punitive damages, but “a more mod-
was lawful where it occurred and had no est punishment for this reprehensible conduct
impact on in-state residents. On the basis of could have satisfied the State’s legitimate
Gore, State Farm asked the trial court to objectives.”94 That conclusion stemmed in
exclude evidence of conduct in unrelated major part from the state courts’ misplaced
cases outside Utah. The court denied that reliance on State Farm’s dissimilar out-of-
request and proceeded to weigh State Farm’s state conduct. Such conduct should not itself
Justice Anthony alleged fraudulent practices nationwide. The be punished, declared Kennedy, even if it was
jury awarded the Campbells $2.6 million in unlawful.95 Nonetheless, he added, it may
Kennedy put compensatory damages and $145 million in assist the judge or jury in assessing the repre-
it bluntly: “[T]his punitive damages, which the judge reduced hensibility of similar in-state conduct for
case is neither to $1 million and $25 million, respectively. which the defendant may be liable.96 The key
That satisfied no one; both the Campbells to Kennedy’s reprehensibility analysis is the
close nor and State Farm appealed to the Utah similarity between in-state and out-of-state
difficult. It was Supreme Court. acts. The Campbells had shown no conduct by
Purporting to apply Gore’s three guide- State Farm similar to that which harmed
error to reinstate posts, relying on evidence about State Farm’s them.
the jury’s $145 nationwide practices, and considering State Turning to the 145-to-1 ratio of punitive-
million punitive Farm’s “massive wealth,” the Utah Supreme to-compensatory damages, Kennedy made it
Court reinstated the $145 million punitive clear that the Utah courts had overreached.
damages award.” damages award.90 He did not impose a bright-line ratio, but he

14
did volunteer that “in practice, few awards dence of a defendant’s net worth creates the Concern over
exceeding a single-digit ratio between puni- potential that juries will use their verdicts to federal judicial
tive and compensatory damages . . . will satis- express biases against big business, particular-
fy due process.”97 That guideline is somewhat ly those without strong local presences.”100 He usurpation of
elastic. “[R]atios greater than those we have also noted that State Farm’s assets are what state authority
previously upheld may comport with due other insured parties in Utah and elsewhere
process where ‘a particularly egregious act must rely on for payment of claims.
is more often
has resulted in only a small amount of eco- Accordingly, he concluded, “The wealth of a associated with
nomic damages.’ . . . When compensatory defendant cannot justify an otherwise uncon- conservatives
damages are substantial, then a lesser ratio, stitutional punitive damages award.”101
perhaps only equal to compensatory dam- By declaring that a defendant’s wealth who rail
ages, can reach the outermost limit of the cannot justify an “otherwise unconstitution- against “judicial
due process guarantee.”98 al” punitive damages award, the Court left activism.”
Applying that framework to the injuries ample wiggle room for trial courts and juries.
suffered by the Campbells, Kennedy wrote: Even if Kennedy’s 10-to-1 ratio of punitive-
to-compensatory damages were a rigid upper
The compensatory award in this case constraint, an award somewhere between
was substantial; the Campbells were zero and ten times a dollar amount that
awarded $1 million for a year and a half included both economic losses and retribu-
of emotional distress. This was complete tion for pain and suffering might still be
compensation. The harm arose from a deemed constitutional. Within that expan-
transaction in the economic realm, not sive range, evidence of net worth can legiti-
from some physical assault or trauma; mately be used by a jury to decide on a spe-
there were no physical injuries; and State cific punitive award.
Farm paid the excess verdict before the Judicial Activism? That brings us to the
complaint was filed, so the Campbells dissenting opinions. We begin with Justice
suffered only minor economic injuries Ginsburg, who balked at the Court’s substi-
for the 18-month period in which State tution of its judgment for that of Utah’s deci-
Farm refused to resolve the claim against sionmakers.102 If the Utah legislature or the
them. . . . Much of the distress was Utah Supreme Court had decided to set sin-
caused by the outrage and humiliation gle-digit and 1-to-1 punitive damage bench-
the Campbells suffered. . . . Compensa- marks, that would have been within their
tory damages, however, already contain purview, she stated. But “a judicial decree
this punitive element.99 imposed on the States by this Court . . .
seem[s] to me boldly out of order.”103
Future plaintiffs will find little to cheer Concern over federal judicial usurpation of
about in Kennedy’s explanation. But he did state authority is more often associated with
hint at one qualification: The Court was deal- conservatives who rail against “judicial
ing with a case in which only economic, not activism.” Columnist George Will, for exam-
physical, harm had occurred. That suggests ple, put it this way: “What, other than the jus-
the Court might condone a more generous tices’ instincts, provides criteria of proportion-
allowance for punitive damages in product ality and arbitrariness? . . . And what principle
liability cases involving injury or death. makes the justices’ instincts superior to the
One other aspect of the State Farm opinion jury’s . . .? Furthermore, even if the jury’s award
has especially cheered defense attorneys: the was unjust, the idea that ‘unjust’ and ‘uncon-
Court’s reluctance to consider the defendant’s stitutional’ can be synonymous gives [the
net worth as an appropriate ground for mea- Court] a license to legislate.”104
surement of punitive damages. As Justice Literally applied, the Ginsburg-Will formu-
Kennedy wrote, “[T]he presentation of evi- lation could preclude judicial review. Obvi-

15
ously, some unjust outcomes are unconstitu- doctrine was echoed by Justices Thomas and
tional. Judicial restraint does not consist in Scalia, both of whom cited Scalia’s earlier dis-
deferring to a legislature that has exceeded its sent in Gore.
constitutional authority. Statutes that are Thomas’s State Farm dissent is little more
unconstitutional cannot stand, nor should than one sentence: “[T]he Constitution does
unconstitutional outcomes imposed by trial not constrain the size of punitive damage
judges or juries. Intervention by the U.S. awards.”106 Scalia’s dissent, in relevant part, is
Supreme Court is our final shield against not much longer: “[T]he Due Process Clause
abuse of government power and our final bul- provides no substantive protections against
wark against violation of individual rights. ‘excessive’ or ‘unreasonable’ awards of puni-
The crucial question, therefore, is whether tive damages.”107
the legislative enactment or the common- In short, Scalia believes the U.S. Consti-
law-based verdict of a federal or state court tution guarantees defendants that the process
violates the U.S. Constitution. In deciding followed in determining a punitive award,
such questions, Supreme Court justices including judicial review, will be reasonable
should not impose their own policy prefer- but not that the award itself will be reason-
ences; rather, they should apply the able. Assurances regarding the appropriate
Judicial restraint Constitution according to a proper theory of size of an award must come, if at all, from
does not consist that document grounded in the framers’ state courts, state statutes, and state constitu-
in deferring to a notions of limited government, separation of tions.
powers, federalism, and individual liberty. At first blush, the 1993 majority opinion
legislature that If an egregious punitive damages award by Justice John Paul Stevens in TXO Production
has exceeded its breaches constitutional safeguards, then the Corp. v. Alliance Resources Corp., upholding an
justices are authorized to do something enormous punitive damages award, seemed
constitutional about it. Their remedy might be couched in to agree.108 But Justice Stevens distinguished
authority. the broadest terms, as in Gore, or it might be semantically between “unreasonable” awards,
somewhat more concrete, as in State Farm. which are not foreclosed by the Constitution,
Indeed, State Farm affords a particularly and “grossly excessive” awards, which are fore-
strong argument for judicial benchmarks. closed.
No statute dictated the outcome—just an
unprecedented application of the common Justice Scalia’s assertion notwithstand-
law of tort by judge and jury. An appellate ing, we do not suggest that a defendant
court is uniquely qualified to review the com- has a substantive due process right to a
mon-law decision of a lower court. So the real correct determination of the “reason-
debate in State Farm centers not on separa- ableness” of a punitive damages award.
tion of powers but on federalism. And that . . . [S]tate law generally imposes a
debate, in turn, recalls the muddle over sub- requirement that punitive damages be
stantive due process—the doctrine intermit- “reasonable.” A violation of a state law
tently invoked by federal courts to prevent “reasonableness” requirement would
states from violating substantive rights pre- not, however, necessarily establish that
sumably secured by the U.S. Constitution the award is so “grossly excessive” as to
and applied to the states via the Due Process violate the Federal Constitution.109
Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment.
Stevens reminds us that “our cases have
Substantive Due Process recognized for almost a century that the Due
The Court should not have imposed its Process Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment
judgment on Utah “under the banner of sub- imposes an outer limit on such an award.”110
stantive due process,” insisted Justice Gins- Revealingly, Justice Kennedy’s TXO con-
burg.105 Her concern over the scope of that curring opinion rejected the distinction

16
between “reasonable” and “grossly excessive” remedies have as much to do with procedure
in no uncertain terms: as with substance, in the following sense:
Proper procedure requires advance notice of
To ask whether a particular award of the law. Private parties must be able to deter-
punitive damages is grossly excessive mine what behavior is required to comply with
begs the question: excessive in relation the law, and legal outcomes must be reason-
to what? . . . [W]e are still bereft of any ably predictable. As the Court stated in State
standard by which to compare the Farm, “Elementary notions of fairness
punishment to the malefaction that enshrined in our constitutional jurisprudence
gave rise to it. A reviewing court dictate that a person receive fair notice not
employing this formulation comes only of the conduct that will subject him to
close to relying upon nothing more punishment, but also of the severity of the
than its own subjective reaction to a penalty that a State may impose.”116 By violat-
particular punitive damages award in ing those norms, outrageous punitive dam-
deciding whether the award violates ages do not provide adequate notice and there-
the Constitution.111 fore offend procedural due process.
If the Court’s conservatives are serious
Instead of a “grossly excessive” standard, about resolving the substantive vs. procedur-
Kennedy preferred to focus on the jury’s rea- al quandary implicit in the Due Process
sons for an award—that is, whether the “award Clause, maybe it is time for them to revisit
reflects bias, passion, or prejudice on the part the Fourteenth Amendment’s nearly forgot-
of the jury, rather than a rational concern for ten Privileges or Immunities Clause. Indeed,
deterrence and retribution.”112 Fast forward Justice Thomas and Chief Justice Rehnquist
one decade. In State Farm, Kennedy now opts have indicated a willingness to do so “in an
for benchmark ratios and cites binding prece- appropriate case.”117 Other conservatives, like
dent that the “Due Process Clause of the former judge Robert Bork, demur because
Fourteenth Amendment prohibits the impo- “we do not know what the clause was intend-
sition of grossly excessive or arbitrary punish- ed to mean.”118 Yet that critique is no more
ments.”113 persuasive when applied to the Privileges or
Kennedy’s earlier apprehension about Immunities Clause than it would be if
unmanageable standards like “grossly exces- applied to the General Welfare Clause, the
sive” remains Scalia’s concern today, and Necessary and Proper Clause, or the Proper procedur
Thomas’s as well. Still, both Scalia and Commerce Clause. A compelling case can be requires advance
Thomas have by and large honored the doc- made that the Court has misinterpreted
trine of stare decisis—that is, respect for past every one of those clauses, but to our knowl- notice of the law.
decisions now well settled in law. In that edge, no one has suggested that they not be Private parties
light, their peremptory refusal to invoke sub- interpreted at all.
stantive due process in State Farm is difficult An excellent discussion of the Privileges or
must be able to
to square with a case dating back to 1907 Immunities Clause appears in a 1998 Cato determine what
holding that Due Process imposes substan- Institute monograph by professor Kimberly behavior is
tive limits “beyond which penalties may not Shankman and Cato scholar Roger Pilon.
go”114 or a 1915 case in which the Court actu- Here’s their recap of the rise and fall of the required to
ally set aside a penalty because it was so clause: comply with the
“plainly arbitrary and oppressive” as to vio-
late the Due Process Clause.115 Shortly after the Civil War, the American
law, and legal
Moreover, Scalia and Thomas might have people amended the Constitution in an outcomes must
sidestepped substantive due process by author- effort to better protect individuals be reasonably
izing federal intervention on procedural against state violations of their rights.
rather than substantive grounds. Arguably, Under the Privileges or Immunities predictable.

17
If the Privileges Clause of the new Fourteenth Amend- deferential review. But should the trial court
or Immunities ment, constitutional guarantees against exceed the guidelines, appellate review would
the federal government could be raised be more rigorous. The rationale for a dimin-
Clause is revived, for the first time against state govern- ished jury role, from a 1989 article by our cur-
a more coherent ments as well. . . . But . . . in 1873, in the rent solicitor general, goes like this:
infamous Slaughter-House Cases,119 a
doctrine of the deeply divided Supreme Court effectively Juries are well constituted to perform as
Fourteenth eviscerated the Privileges or Immunities factfinders and determiners of liability.
Amendment and Clause. Since then courts have tried to do But here they are being given in effect
under the Due Process and Equal the public function of sentencing—of
federalism is Protection Clauses of the amendment deciding how high a penalty someone
likely to emerge. what should have been done under the should pay for violating a public stan-
more substantive Privileges or Immu- dard. Juries are remarkably ill-equipped
nities Clause.120 for that task because they sit in only
one case, hear evidence only in that
If Slaughter-House is overturned and the case, and are then given very vague
Privileges or Immunities Clause is revived, a guidance with which to form a judg-
more coherent doctrine of the Fourteenth ment. . . . Jurors are drastically swayed
Amendment and federalism is likely to by such factors as the wealth, success,
emerge. Along the way, the debate over the or personal demeanor of a defendant,
substantive content of the Due Process even how far away the defendant lives
Clause will inevitably diminish. from the location of the litigation. The
jurors are frequently told to send a mes-
sage back to such and such a corporate
Reconciling Tort Reform headquarters. After being instructed to
and Federalism set aside emotion, bias, and prejudice,
juries are bombarded with arguments
While we wait patiently for an “appropri- that are based almost exclusively on
ate case” to revisit Privileges or Immunities, emotion, bias and prejudice.121
the general problem of tort reform and the
specific problem of confiscatory state puni- A similarly skeptical view of jurors’ com-
tive damage awards need not be irreconcil- petence to assess punitive damages comes
able with dual-sovereignty federalism. First, from attorney Mark Klugheit, who special-
various remedies can be implemented by the izes in class actions and mass tort litigation.
states themselves, without federal involve-
ment. Second, federal reform of long-arm Jurors are hardly expected to be experts
jurisdiction and choice-of-law rules will curb in social engineering or economic analy-
tort law abuse yet fit comfortably within a ses. They are not likely to understand, let
federalist regime. alone apply, any kind of reason-based
analyses to punitive damage determina-
State-Based Reforms tions. Yet in most jurisdictions the law
One cure for inflated punitive damage requires lay jurors to decide claims
awards might be to take the dollar decision involving millions, or sometimes bil-
away from the jury. For example, the jury lions, of dollars with virtually no guid-
might be instructed to vote yes or no on an ance about how to translate abstractions
award of punitive damages, with the amount like the need for punishment or deter-
then set by a judge in accordance with pre-set rence into an appropriate verdict.
guidelines. If the judge complied with the Instructions predicated on amorphous
guidelines, an appellate court would grant concepts like “punishment,” “deter-

18
rence,” and the “public good,” . . . make Fourth, the states could codify the Eighth
the imposition of punitive damages a Amendment’s prohibition of excessive fines
standardless, if not haphazard, exer- and apply it to punitive damages. At present,
cise.122 because the Eighth Amendment is primarily
directed at prosecutorial abuse, the excessive
A second suggestion for reform at the state fines provision does not cover civil damages.
level is to limit punitive damages to cases That principle was spelled out in the
involving intentional wrongdoing or gross Browning-Ferris case.128 But Justice Sandra
negligence. In fact, an even higher standard Day O’Connor’s dissent,129 covering the his-
has had a salutary effect in Maryland, where tory of fines, convincingly showed that puni-
punitive damages are permitted in a tort case tive damages, unless they were merely sym-
only if the plaintiff has proved that the defen- bolic, were always treated as fines. Moreover,
dant acted with actual malice.123 Whatever the after Browning-Ferris, several states modified
heightened standard, the idea is that acciden- their statutes to provide that punitive dam-
tal injuries arising out of ordinary, garden- ages would be, in part, payable to the state.130
variety negligence are unlikely to require the Indeed, making punitive awards payable
deterrence for which punitive damages are to the state is a fifth possible reform. Because
designed. the purpose of punitive damages is deter-
Much of the
Third, states might effect procedural rence, not compensation for injury, the iden- abuse that now
guarantees similar to those inherent in crim- tity of the recipient is irrelevant to that pur- exists can be
inal law. In State Farm, Kennedy observed that pose, and receipt by the plaintiff is beyond
punitive awards “serve the same purposes as what is necessary to make him whole. We rec- traced to
criminal penalties [but] defendants subjected ognize, of course, that states would become enormous
to punitive damages in civil cases have not an interested party in tort suits if they stood
been accorded the protections applicable in a to receive punitive awards. That could exacer-
contingency-
criminal proceeding.”124 Among the protec- bate the expansion of tort liability. Perhaps based fees paid to
tions that might be offered: the experience in states that are implement- “lawyers whose
ing this solution will help us determine
• A higher burden of proof than the usual whether that happens. only interest is
civil standard, which is preponderance If punitive damages are received by the the size of the
of the evidence. Thirty-one states now state rather than the plaintiff, adequate award they can
require clear and convincing evidence incentive must be provided for the plaintiff’s
for punitive awards.125 attorney to seek those damages. That incen- bring in.”
• No double jeopardy. Current rules allow tive might be in the form of court-ordered
“multiple punitive damages awards for attorneys’ fees with the amount set by a
the same conduct; for in the usual case judge. Much of the abuse that now exists can
nonparties are not bound by the judg- be traced to enormous contingency-based
ment some other plaintiff obtains.”126 fees paid not to “public officials, who are
Victor Schwartz, a noted torts scholar, accountable to the citizenry and have a long
has proposed that “punitive damage tradition of ethics and restraint, but private
awards be reduced by the sum of all pre- citizens and lawyers whose only interest is the
vious awards for the same misconduct. size of the award they can bring in.”131
The result would be what amounts to a Sixth—broadening our focus to cover not
single ‘rolling’ award.”127 just punitive damages but the larger area of
• No coerced self-incrimination, which tort law—states ought to dispense with joint
criminal defendants can avoid by plead- and several liability. That’s the “deep pock-
ing the Fifth Amendment. In civil cases, ets” rule that permits plaintiffs to collect all
however, compulsory discovery can be of a damage award from any one of multiple
self-incriminating. defendants, even if the paying defendant was

19
responsible for only a small fraction of the subcontracts his services to the government,
harm. The better rule is to apportion dam- he bears the same responsibility as a govern-
ages in accordance with the defendants’ ment lawyer. He is a public servant beholden
degree of culpability—especially if the state to all citizens, including the defendant, and
has adopted a comparative negligence stan- his overriding objective is to seek justice.
dard, which holds that the plaintiff himself is Imagine a state attorney paid a contingency
not “jointly liable” when he too is negligent. fee for each indictment that he secures, or
What’s sauce for the goose is sauce for the state troopers paid per speeding ticket. The
gander. potential for corruption is enormous. Still,
Seventh, government should pay attorneys’ the states in their tobacco suits doled out
fees when a governmental unit is the losing multi-billion-dollar contracts to private
party in a civil lawsuit. Coordinated actions by counsel—not per hour fee agreements, which
multiple government entities can impose might occasionally be justified to acquire
enormous legal fees on defendants. As a result, unique outside competence or experience,
those actions have been used to extort money but contingency fees, a sure-fire catalyst for
even when the underlying case is without abuse of power. And those contracts were fre-
merit. Listen to former Philadelphia mayor quently awarded—without competitive bid-
Edward G. Rendell (D) calling for dozens of ding—to lawyers who bankrolled state politi-
cities to file concurrent suits against gun mak- cal campaigns.133
ers: They “don’t have the deep pockets of the Government is the sole entity authorized,
tobacco industry,” Rendell explained, and in narrowly defined circumstances, to wield
multiple lawsuits “could bring them to the coercive power against private citizens. When
negotiating table a lot sooner.”132 Never mind that government functions as prosecutor or
that the suits were baseless; after five years of plaintiff in a legal proceeding in which it also
litigation, not a single claim has prevailed. dispenses punishment, adequate safeguards
Indeed, the cities were pursuing not law but against state misbehavior are essential. That is
extortion parading as law. why in civil litigation we rely primarily on pri-
One effective way to stop unwarranted lit- vate remedies with redress sought by, and for
igation is to implement a “government pays” the benefit of, the injured party and not the
rule for legal fees if a state or municipality or state. As the Supreme Court cautioned more
other government agency loses a civil lawsuit. than 60 years ago, an attorney for the state “is
In the criminal sphere, defendants are the representative not of an ordinary party to
already entitled to court-appointed counsel if a controversy, but of a sovereignty whose
needed; they’re also protected by the require- obligation to govern impartially is as com-
ment for proof beyond reasonable doubt and pelling as its obligation to govern at all.”134 Put
by the Fifth and Sixth Amendments to the bluntly, contingency fee contracts between
Constitution. No corresponding safeguards government and a private attorney should be
against abusive public-sector litigation exist illegal. We cannot in a free society condone pri-
Government in civil cases. By limiting the rule to cases vate lawyers enforcing public law with an
involving government plaintiffs, access to the incentive kicker to increase the penalties.
should pay courts is preserved for less affluent, private From a federalism perspective, it’s instruc-
attorneys’ fees plaintiffs seeking redress of legitimate griev- tive to examine an alternative proposal to deal
when a ances. Yet defendants in government suits with scandalous attorneys’ fees—almost all of
will be able to resist meritless cases that are which were contingency based—that were col-
governmental brought by the state solely to ratchet up the lected by private lawyers who represented the
unit is the losing pressure for a large financial settlement. states in their Medicaid recovery suits against
Eighth, contingency fee contracts between the major cigarette companies. The Hudson
party in a civil private lawyers and government entities Institute’s Michael Horowitz reports that
lawsuit. should be prohibited. When a private lawyer some attorneys stood to make $200,000 an

20
hour for late-filed, copycat suits that never proposed by the American Legislative Federalism
went to court.135 To reclaim some of that Exchange Council.137 The act provides that would be dealt a
money for the taxpayers, Horowitz would the same legal rules applicable to a private
treat all attorneys receiving contingency fees in claim by an injured party will also be applica- body blow if
large class action litigation as fiduciaries ble if the government sues to recover indirect conservatives
under the Internal Revenue Code, then limit economic losses related to the same injury.
their fees to amounts that are “reasonable and Recall the states’ lawsuits against the tobacco
vested the
risk-based”—perhaps as high as six times nor- industry to recoup Medicaid outlays for national
mal hourly rates. Any excess would be either smoking-related illnesses. For more than 40 government with
refunded to the states or taxed by the federal years, cigarette companies had regularly pre-
government at a 200 percent rate. vailed against smokers’ claims—by disputing extended powers
However well-intentioned, that remedy that tobacco was the cause of a particular merely because
raises more problems than it solves.136 Most person’s ailment and by demonstrating that the outcome
important for purposes of this paper, the plaintiffs had assumed the risk of smok-
Horowitz’s scheme would flout principles of ing, in which case they were personally might be
federalism. Some 70 years after the New Deal responsible for the adverse health effects. congenial to
Court eviscerated the constitutional doctrine That set the stage for some legal legerde-
of enumerated powers, the Rehnquist Court main—a fresh wave of litigation by state
business
has begun reviving it. That revival, long over- attorneys general, beginning in 1994, interests.
due, would be dealt a body blow if conserva- grounded in a new claim that gave the states
tives, supposed champions of federalism, more legal rights than any aggrieved smoker.
vested the national government with extend- Florida became the first state to codify the
ed powers merely because the outcome might new claim by amending its Medicaid Third-
be congenial to business interests and Party Liability Act in 1990 and 1994.138 First,
adverse to the hated trial lawyers. Where in “causation and damages . . . may be proven by
the Constitution is there an express or use of statistical analysis” without showing
implied power to manipulate the Internal any link between a particular smoker’s illness
Revenue Code to punish disfavored groups? and his use of tobacco products. Second,
Moreover, why should the federal govern- “assumption of risk and all other affirmative
ment—or even state government for that defenses normally available to a liable third
matter—be regulating contingency fees paid party are to be abrogated to the extent neces-
by private parties? If the right to contract and sary to ensure full recovery by Medicaid from
respect for free markets mean anything, they third-party resources.”
mean that private parties should be able to Before the new dispensation, the state
negotiate fee arrangements for legal repre- could assert only those theories of recovery
sentation without government interference. against cigarette makers that an injured
Otherwise we should not be surprised when patient could assert. But that had not worked
fiduciary standards are extended to the fees for smokers, so the states simply wiped that
charged by doctors, accountants, architects, rule off the books and then, for good measure,
investment managers, you name it. The con- made the new rules apply retroactively to ill-
tingency fee contracts that must be regulat- nesses supposedly caused by cigarettes sold
ed—indeed prohibited—are those between decades earlier. As the president of the
government and private lawyers. And the pur- Maryland Senate blurted to the Washington Post
pose of the prohibition is to remove incen- in an unguarded moment: “We agreed to
tives that might otherwise lead to the abuse change tort law, which was no small feat. We
of public power. changed centuries of precedent in order to
Finally, in the area of state-based tort assure a win in this case.”139
reform, legislators should consider the Under the proposed Fairness in Litigation
Fairness in Litigation Act, a model statute Act, the same rules of evidence, the same

21
standards of responsibility, and the same An overhaul of the Court’s jurisdictional
burden of proof would apply to the state rules would entail a significant shift in its
standing in a plaintiff’s shoes as to a plaintiff prior case law. First, under International Shoe
suing on his own behalf. Co. v. Washington,141 the Court held that an
out-of-state corporation could be sued with-
Federal Reform of Long-Arm Jurisdiction in the state if the corporation had “mini-
In addition to state-imposed tort reforms, mum contacts” in state. International Shoe
there are at least two areas where the federal was sued in Washington even though it had
government can intervene without intruding no office and made no contracts there to buy
on long-established state prerogatives. A or sell merchandise. Because the company
guiding principle is that the federal legisla- employed salesmen who resided and solicited
ture and courts are authorized to act when business in Washington, it was subject to the
there is a high risk that state legislatures or jurisdiction of the state’s courts.
courts will systematically appropriate wealth Encouragingly, 35 years later, in World-
from the citizens of other states. One federal Wide Volkswagen Corp. v. Woodson,142 the Court
reform that is consistent with that principle signaled that state jurisdiction triggered by
is to amend the rules that control state exer- nominal ties might violate the Due Process
The federal cise of so-called long-arm jurisdiction over Clause. The Robinsons purchased an Audi
legislature and out-of-state businesses. from a New York dealership that had
courts are Rather than apply the Due Process Clause acquired the car from a regional distributor.
to control, for example, the size of a punitive Later, the Robinsons were injured when their
authorized to act damages award, a federal court could instead car was involved in an accident in Oklahoma,
when there is a use that same clause to preclude a local court where neither the dealer nor the distributor
from hearing a case unless the defendant did business. The Court said the defendant
high risk that engages directly in business activities within might have foreseen that an automobile
state legislatures the state. Sensible rules should protect a firm bought in New York would be driven through
or courts will from being hauled into court unless the firm Oklahoma, but noncommercial contact with
does in-state business. Those rules would Oklahoma was insufficient to confer jurisdic-
systematically give firms an exit option—that is, if they with- tion on that state’s courts.
appropriate drew from a state, they could avoid the risk of That hopeful outcome was mostly undone
wealth from the an unrestrained in-state jury. Unfortunately, by the Court’s 1987 opinion in Asahi Metal
federal limits on state long-arm statutes Industry Co., Ltd. v. Superior Court of California.143
citizens of other remain lax or ambiguous. Valves made by Asahi, a Japanese corporation,
states. Law and economics scholars Paul Rubin, were installed by another company on
John Calfee, and Mark Grady outline the Taiwanese tires that were involved in a
problem: California accident. The Court refused to con-
fer jurisdiction on the California courts, main-
If Alabama juries demonstrate bad ly because the burden on Asahi of litigating in
judgment in pharmaceutical cases, California outweighed the state’s interest in
manufacturers might refuse to sell in adjudicating the case. But Justice O’Connor
Alabama, denying Alabamians drugs could not command a majority of the Court
that expose the manufacturer to inap- to support this more restrictive proposition:
propriate punitive damages awards. “[A] defendant’s awareness that the stream of
Middlemen, however, might fill this commerce may or will sweep the product into
lacuna by purchasing and reselling the forum State does not convert the mere act
drugs in Alabama at a higher cost to of placing the product into the stream into an
compensate for liability, and manufac- act purposefully directed toward the forum
turers might not be able to escape liabil- State.”144 If that rule had won the day, exit
ity under existing long-arm statutes.140 from a state with a confiscatory tort regime

22
would be feasible. But only three other justices there are a number of different and complex
agreed with O’Connor. rules used by that court to decide choice-of-
Rubin, Calfee, and Grady conclude that law questions. If the suit is filed in federal
“the economically harmful effects of exces- court, or removed to federal court at the
sive punitive damages awards by unre- request of the defendant, the federal court
strained juries in particular states could . . . will apply the choice-of-law rules of the state
largely be ameliorated by a clear and realistic in which the federal court is sitting. Federal
‘minimum contacts’ doctrine. Justice courts may exercise so-called diversity juris-
O’Connor’s opinion in Asahi suggests how diction over tort suits even when they involve
such a doctrine could be formulated, but the questions of state law. Basically, the prerequi-
Court has not accepted her approach.”145 sites for diversity jurisdiction are that the
By tightening state long-arm jurisdiction, plaintiffs be from different states than every
the national government would simultane- defendant and that the amount in controver-
ously be broadening the procedural guaran- sy exceed $75,000 per plaintiff.148
tees of the Due Process Clause and encourag- Whether the forum turns out to be a fed-
ing nondiscriminatory tort laws that promote eral court or a state court, the underlying
interstate commerce. substantive tort law will be state law, not fed-
Regrettably, because the Supreme Court eral.149 The Supreme Court recognized that it
continues to apply capacious jurisdictional must preserve state law even in federal diver-
rules, oppressive state tort laws remain a sity cases. Otherwise, diversity jurisdiction
threat to out-of-state defendants. Thus, the would effectively nationalize areas of law that
expansion of product liability arises in part, were meant to be left to the states. In other
not because of increased wrongdoing by words, federal diversity jurisdiction provides
defendants or increased risk aversion on the procedural protection to out-of-state liti-
part of plaintiffs, but because some states’ gants but not substantive uniformity across
legal arrangements are intrinsically biased in states. A citizen of one state is not immune
favor of local plaintiffs suing nonresident from the laws of another state, but his out-of-
defendants.146 state citizenship should not subject him to
If manufacturers could avoid unfair tort prejudice from a state court.150
regimes—for example by not doing business That still means that plaintiffs will select
in a particular state—juries would not be able the most favorable forum state, basing their
to impose liability and damage awards choice in part on the choice-of-law rules of
extraterritorially. Then consumers in each each state. The resultant tort law will no
state would decide whether they wanted con- doubt be least hospitable to the defendant By tightening
fiscatory tort law or plentiful goods and ser- and might even be contrary to the defen- state long-arm
vices. But to the extent that manufacturers dant’s home-state law in important respects. jurisdiction,
cannot avoid a state’s jurisdiction—because The defendant, in essence, will be at the
long-arm statutes overreach—a different rem- mercy of the plaintiff. the national
edy is necessary. The remedy that raises the Of course, there would be no involuntary government
fewest federalism concerns is a federal choice- extraterritoriality and less of a liability crisis if
of-law rule,147 which would allow manufac- consumers and sellers could choose both
would be
turers to exert some control over governing their forum and their law by contract. encouraging
law. Transacting parties should be able to desig- nondiscriminato
nate the state whose laws will govern any dis-
Federal Choice-of-Law Rules putes arising out of their agreements. ry tort laws
Basically, choice of law is the doctrine that Unfortunately, however, many transactions that promote
determines which state’s laws control litiga- are not covered by written agreements, and
tion when litigants from more than one state choice-of-law clauses in consumer contracts
interstate
are involved. If a suit is filed in state court, are generally unenforceable.151 commerce.

23
The choice-of-law Accordingly, if the forum state’s rules call ism as an excuse for failing to arrive at a solu-
inquiry is a for applying the law of the state where injury tion.
occurred, out-of-state manufacturers will In any event, as federalism scholar Michael
federal question; have difficulty avoiding oppressive regimes. Greve has observed, it might be impossible to
no state has the But suppose a federal choice-of-law rule were precisely mimic a neutral, competitive world
enacted for those cases in which the plaintiff in which each state structures its legal arrange-
authority to and defendant are from different states. ments as if it were a self-sufficient and inde-
create binding Suppose further that the applicable law were pendent nation.154 The search for perfection is
law for a based on the location where the product was beside the point. “The sensible question,” con-
originally sold. A manufacturer could thus tinues Greve, “is whether a competitive prod-
neighbor state. stamp products by state of sale and price ucts-liability world, operating under approxi-
them differentially to allow for anticipated mately efficient (if imperfect) choice of law
product liability verdicts. rules, will be preferable to the existing game of
Naturally, prices would be higher in plain- mutually assured regulatory aggression and,
tiff-friendly states than in defendant-friendly at the other extreme, to any set of monopolis-
states. The price premium would be similar tic, national rules that are likely to emerge.”
to buying product liability insurance—but Greve concludes that “the answer to that ques-
instead of paying for an insurance policy that tion is almost certainly in the affirmative.”
would reimburse the buyer for injuries suf- The central constitutional concern,
fered, the higher price would pay for a “bet- according to Greve, is not the prospect of fed-
ter” set of legal rules if a dispute over such an eral intervention to resolve the choice-of-law
injury were to arise. Of course, differential question but rather the prospect of federal
pricing may be costly and cumbersome to abdication. He finds it anomalous, as do we,
manufacturers, and the federal government “that the field should have been ceded in the
would have to mandate common labeling first place to state courts and their choice-of-
requirements so that original and subse- law rules, which are systematically biased
quent purchasers would know where the against sister-states and their citizens.”155
product was first sold. In essence, the choice-of-law inquiry is,
To bypass those complexities, the applica- Whose law governs in disputes involving
ble law might instead be that of the state more than one state? By its very nature, that
where the manufacturer was located or had inquiry is a federal question; no state has the
the largest number of employees.152 That authority to create binding law for a neigh-
would obviate the need to price differentially bor state. Moreover, the Privileges and
or to identify where the sale occurred. A man- Immunities Clause of Article IV forecloses
ufacturer would decide where to locate, and discrimination by a state in favor of its own
its decision would dictate the applicable legal citizens. The Full Faith and Credit Clause,
rules. Consumers, in turn, would evaluate also in Article IV, gives Congress the authori-
those rules when deciding whether to buy a ty to prescribe the effect that each state’s
particular manufacturer’s product. public acts and judicial proceedings will have
Would there be a race to the bottom by in every other state. And the Commerce
manufacturers searching for the most defen- Clause of Article I authorizes federal choice-
dant-friendly tort law? Perhaps. Then again, of-law rules in multistate litigation if states
states might balance their interest in attract- use tort law in a manner that impedes the
ing manufacturers against the interest of in- free flow of trade across state borders.
state consumers who want tougher product Each of those constitutional pedigrees cir-
liability laws to ensure adequate redress for cumvents the difficult controversy over sub-
injuries.153 In effect, healthy competition stantive due process. And each is perfectly
among the states would enlist federalism as consistent with time-honored principles of
part of the solution rather than raise federal- federalism.

24
The touchstone of federalism is not states’ federal government may and should enact
rights but dual sovereignty—checks and bal- procedural reforms that tighten state long-
ances designed to promote liberty by limiting arm jurisdiction and implement federal
excessive power in the hands of either state or choice-of-law rules.
federal government. When a state exercises
jurisdiction beyond its borders to impose
grossly excessive damages on out-of-state busi- Notes
nesses, and applies tort laws that deny both 1. Martin F. Connor, “Taming the Mass Tort
procedural and substantive protection against Monster,” National Legal Center for the Public
quasi-criminal punishment, the federal gov- Interest, October 2000, p. 4.
ernment not only may but must intervene.
2. See Tresa Baldas, “Verdicts Swelling from Big
Otherwise, federalism becomes a pretext for to Bigger,” National Law Journal, November 25,
constricting rather than enlarging liberty. 2002, pp. A1, A6.

3. David Hechler, “Study Sees Rise in Cost of Tort


System. Is It Right?” National Law Journal,
Conclusion December 22, 2003, p. 12.

Defenders of modern tort law would have 4. Center for Legal Policy, “Trial Lawyers Inc.,”
nearly every “victim” compensated by corpo- Manhattan Institute, 2003, p. 2.
rate America. Such theories have penetrated 5. Hechler, “Study Sees Rise in Cost of Tort
deeply into the psyches of many judges and System,” p. 12.
jurors. As a result, the cost of insurance and of
goods and services now includes a “tort pre- 6. Center for Legal Policy, p. 5.
mium” that far exceeds the true costs of cor- 7. See, e.g., Walter K. Olson, The Rule of Lawyers:
porate misbehavior. And those who produce How the New Litigation Elite Threatens America’s Rule of
the goods and services that make the Law (New York: St. Martin’s, 2003); Catherine
American economy strong have come to Crier, The Case against Lawyers (New York: Broadway
Books, 2002); and Philip K. Howard, The Death of
believe that no matter what they do, no mat- Common Sense: How Law Is Suffocating America (New
ter how responsibly they behave, they are York: Warner Books, 1994).
going to be held liable for the negligence of
others. 8. Gibbons v. Ogden, 9 Wheat. 1, 224 (1824)
(Johnson, J., concurring in the judgment).
Those problems are indeed real. But how-
ever real the problem, if there is no constitu- 9. Ibid. at 231.
tional authority, Congress may not intercede.
States have reformed, and can continue to 10. 123 S. Ct. 1513 (2003).
reform, their own tort law. When and where 11. Class action reform is a third procedural
they have not done so, the federal govern- change that we would support at the federal level.
ment may occasionally act, but only if state We exclude that important topic from this paper
substantive rules violate a substantive federal only because Cato senior fellow Mark Moller will
soon be publishing a Policy Analysis devoted
constitutional right, or are so capricious that exclusively to that subject.
they rise to the level of a due process viola-
tion—that is, they deny to defendants suffi- 12. Help Efficient, Accessible, Low-cost, Timely
cient notice of the law to conform their con- Healthcare (HEALTH) Act of 2003, H.R. 5, 108th
Cong., 1st sess. (March 13, 2003).
duct to its dictates.
Otherwise, time-honored principles of fed- 13. Juliet Eilperin, “House Struggles to Find Its
eralism command that the states continue to Place on Hill; Feeling Ignored, Members Say Most
exercise dominion over the substantive rules High-Profile Issues Are Decided in Senate,”
Washington Post, April 4, 2003, p. A4.
of tort law. To ensure that state sovereignty
does not extend beyond a state’s borders, the 14. Air Transportation Safety and System

25
Stabilization Act of 2001, Pub. L. No. 107-42 28. Batson v. Kentucky, 476 U.S. 79, 88 (1986)
(2001), codified at 49 U.S.C. § 40101 (2003). (racial bias in jury selection violates Equal
Protection Clause).
15. Bipartisan Patient Protection Act, H.R. 2563,
107th Cong., 1st sess. (August 2, 2001); and S. 29. Respondeat superior holds an employer vicari-
1052, 107th Cong., 1st sess. (June 29, 2001). ously liable for negligent behavior by an employee
while on the job. Hern v. Nichols, 91 Eng. Rep. 256
16. See United States v. Lopez, 514 U.S. 549 (1995). (Ex. 1708).

17. Betsy J. Grey, “The New Federalism Jurispru- 30. See Neal Miller, “An Empirical Study of
dence and National Tort Reform,” Washington and Forum Choices in Removal Cases under Diversity
Lee Law Review 59 (2002): 477 and accompanying and Federal Question Jurisdiction,” American
footnotes. University Law Review 41 (1992): 408–9 (attorneys
responding to a survey indicated that out-of-state
18. Ibid. Currently, under 28 U.S.C. § 1332 (2002), status was more frequently the cause of jury bias
federal courts can exercise “diversity jurisdiction” than corporate status or type of business); and
over litigation even if state legal questions are at Alexander Tabarrok and Eric Helland, “Court
issue, but only when each and every plaintiff is Politics: The Political Economy of Tort Awards,”
from a different state than each and every defen- Journal of Law and Economics 42 (1999): 161–64.
dant, and more than $75,000 per plaintiff is in dis-
pute. 31. For a summary of state tort reform laws, see
American Tort Reform Association, “Tort Reform
19. Grey, p. 477. Record,” December 2003, http://www.atra.org/
files.cgi/7668_Record12-03.pdf.
20. Ibid.
32. Ibid.
21. U.S. Const. Art. I, § 8, cl. 3.
33. Ibid.
22. See Ronald D. Rotunda and John E. Nowak,
Treatise on Constitutional Law: Substance and 34. See, e.g., Osborne v. McMasters, 41 N.W. 543
Procedure, vol. 1, 3d ed. (St. Paul: West Group, (Minn. 1889) (early product liability suit against a
1999), § 4.8. local apothecary, who had mislabeled a drug,
resulting in poisoning of the victim). See also
23. Lopez at 562–63. Michael I. Krauss, “Product Liability and Game
Theory: One More Trip to the Choice-of-Law
24. United States v. Morrison, 529 U.S. 598, 614 Well,” Brigham Young University Law Review (2002):
(2000). 772–84 and accompanying footnotes.
25. See Gene Healy and Robert A. Levy, 35. See Thomas J. Kuhn, The Structure of Scientific
“Federalism under the Gun,” Human Rights 29 Revolutions (Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
(Fall 2002): 24. 1970).
26. According to a Department of Justice study, 36. See Theodore Eisenberg, “Judicial Decision-
31.9 percent of all state tort trials in the nation’s making in Federal Products Liability Cases,
75 largest counties involved automobile acci- 1978–1997,” DePaul Law Review 49 (1999): 326
dents. Carol J. DeFrances and Marika F. X. Litras, (“Plaintiffs, their lawyers, and most other observers
“Civil Trial Cases and Verdicts in Large Counties, of the legal system believe the jury to be more sym-
1996,” Bureau of Justice Statistics Bulletin (U.S. pathetic to plaintiffs, on average, than the judge.
Department of Justice), September 1999, p. 2. Plaintiffs therefore route a weaker set of cases to
juries.”).
27. Public choice problems often arise when
money is transferred from “the many” to “the 37. The retailer may also be sued, but recovery is
few.” Those transfers provoke more intense sup- typically against the manufacturer. Because the
port from the few who reap the benefits than they retailer is usually local, its inclusion as a codefen-
do opposition from the many who bear the bur- dant may be designed to foreclose federal court
den. As a result, inefficient transfers from the jurisdiction, which requires that all plaintiffs
many to the few typify public policy in mass reside in a different state than all defendants. See,
democracies. See James M. Buchanan and e.g., Guerrero v. Gen. Motors Corp., 892 F. Supp. 165,
Gordon Tullock, The Calculus of Consent: Logical 166 (S.D. Tex. 1995).
Foundations of Constitutional Democracy (Ann Arbor:
University of Michigan Press, 1965): pp. 31–39. 38. This is true even for automobiles, most driv-

26
ing almost certainly takes place near one’s home Richardson, 743 F.2d 1200 (7th Cir. 1984);
and in one’s state of residence. Hamilton v. Accu-tek, 935 F. Supp. 1307 (E.D.N.Y.
1996); Delahanty v. Hinkley, 564 A.2d 758 (D.C.
39. Commonsense Consumption Act of 2003, S. 1989); Rhodes v. R.G. Indus., 325 S.E.2d 469 (Ga.
1428, 108th Cong, 1st sess. (July 17, 2003). 1985); Forni v. Ferguson, No. 132994/94, slip op.
(N.Y. Sup. Ct. Aug. 2, 1995), aff’d, 648 N.Y.S.2d 73
40. H.R. 339, 108th Cong., 1st sess. (January 27, (N.Y. App. Div. 1996); and Burkett v. Freedom Arms,
2003). Inc., 704 P.2d 118 (Or. 1985).
41. See Michael I. Krauss, “Suits against ‘Big Fat’ 50. A few trial court rulings, declining to dismiss
Tread on Basic Tort Liability Principles,” firearms suits and ordering a full trial, are still in
Washington Legal Foundation Legal Back- litigation.
grounder 18, no. 6 (March 14, 2003).
51. Pub. L. No. 103-322, 103 Stat. 1796 (September
42. Pelman v. McDonald’s Corp., 2003 WL22052778, 13, 1994).
Slip Op. (S.D.N.Y. 2003).
52. See Nat’l Rifle Ass’n v. Magaw, 132 F.3d 272
43. Emily Johns, “Living XX-Large: Pending Bill (6th Cir. 1997).
Fights Suits Filed against the Food Industry,”
Minneapolis Star Tribune, February 9, 2004, p. A6. 53. The 33 states are Alabama, Alaska, Arizona,
Ironically, the Big Daddy settlement allowed cus- Arkansas, Colorado, Florida, Georgia, Idaho,
tomers with receipts to receive a refund for ice Indiana, Kansas, Kentucky, Louisiana, Maine,
cream they had purchased—or two free cups of Maryland, Michigan, Mississippi, Missouri,
Big Daddy ice cream. Montana, Nevada, New Hampshire, North
Carolina, North Dakota, Ohio, Oklahoma,
44. Krauss, “Suits against ‘Big Fat’ Tread on Basic Pennsylvania, South Carolina, South Dakota,
Tort Liability Principles.” Tennessee, Texas, Utah, Virginia, West Virginia,
and Wyoming.
45. One settlement did arise when a group of veg-
etarian and Hindu students sued McDonald’s for 54. Cincinnati v. Beretta U.S.A. Corp., 1999 WL
not publicizing the beef flavoring in its french 809838 (Ohio C.P. Oct. 7, 1999), aff’d, 2000 WL
fries. See Sandra Guy, “24 Groups to Share $10 1133078 (Ohio Ct. App. Aug. 11, 2000), appeal
Mil. McD’s Vegetarian Award,” Chicago Sun-Times, allowed, 740 N.E.2d 1111 (Ohio 2001), rev’d, 768
May 20, 2003, p. 49. Allegedly, McDonald’s mis- N.E.2d 1136 (Ohio 2002).
represented that the fries were cooked in 100 per-
cent vegetable oil. The plaintiffs received a whop- 55. Ganim v. Smith & Wesson Corp., 26 Conn. L.
ping $10 million, with another $2.5 million going Rptr. 39 (Conn. Super. Ct. 1999), aff’d, 258 Conn.
to their lawyers. That litigation had nothing to 313 (Conn. 2001).
do, however, with the obesity claims that have
been the central focus of the suits that the 56. Penelas v. Arms Tech., Inc., 1999 WL 1204353
McConnell and Keller bills would ban. (Fla. Cir. Ct. Dec. 13, 1999), aff’d, 778 So. 2d 1042
(Fla. Dist. Ct. App. 2001).
46. The American Tort Reform Association has
characterized 13 jurisdictions as “judicial hellholes.” 57. Morial v. New Orleans, 785 So.2d 1 (La.), cert.
See http://www.sickoflawsuits.org/news/03_11_06. denied, 534 U.S. 951 (2001).
cfm; and American Tort Reform Association,
“Bringing Justice to Judicial Hellholes,” http:// 58. Merrill v. Navegar, Inc., 26 Cal. 4th 465 (Cal.
www.atra.org/reports/hellholes/report.pdf. 2001).

47. Lawsuits involving a manufacturing defect 59. Ganim v. Smith & Wesson Corp., 258 Conn. 313
(e.g., a gun explodes when fired and injures its (Conn. 2001), aff’g 26 Conn. L. Rptr. 39 (Conn.
user) are traditional tort actions that do not raise Super. Ct. 1999).
novel or bizarre legal theories.
60. “Bridgeport Mayor: Appeal of Gun Lawsuit
48. See Michael I. Krauss, Fire and Smoke: Decision Unlikely,” Associated Press Newswires,
Government Lawsuits and the Rule of Law (Oakland, October 9, 2001.
CA: Independent Institute, 2000), for a detailed
refutation of these suits. 61. Protection of Lawful Commerce in Arms Act,
H.R. 2037, 107th Cong., 1st sess. (May 25, 2001).
49. See, e.g., Moore v. R.G. Indus., 789 F.2d 1326
(9th Cir. 1986); Perkins v. F.I.E. Corp., 762 F.2d 62. Protection of Lawful Commerce in Arms Act,
1250 (5th Cir. 1985); Martin v. Harrington & S. 659, 108th Cong., 1st sess. (March 19, 2003).

27
63. Ibid. at § 2(a)(5) (emphasis added). torial, Charleston Gazette and Daily Mail, January 3,
2002, p. 4A (physicians are leaving West Virginia
64. See Edward Epstein, “Gun Liability Bill Shot because lawsuits are increasing the cost of insur-
Down in Senate; Defeat Comes after Assault-Ban ance coverage); Ovetta Wiggins, “Doctors to
Proposal Passes,” San Francisco Chronicle, March 3, Protest Premium Increases,” Philadelphia Inquirer,
2004. April 23, 2001, p. B1 (Pennsylvania Medical Society
asserts that 11 percent of Pennsylvania physicians
65. White House, “President Proposes Major “have either moved out of state, retired [prema-
Reforms to Address Medical Liability Crisis,” news turely], or scaled back their practices [due to] ‘sky-
release, July 25, 2002, http://www.white house.gov rocketing’ malpractice insurance rates.”); and
/news/releases/2002/07/20020725-1. html. Patricia Poist-Reilly, “Malpractice Maelstrom:
Skyrocketing Malpractice Insurance Premiums
66. Allison H. Eid, “Tort Reform and Federalism: Have Doctors and Healthcare Professionals Here—
The Supreme Court Talks, Bush Listens,” Human and Around the State—Clamoring for Reform,”
Rights 29 (Fall 2002): 10, 11. Lancaster New Era/Intelligencer Journal/Sunday News,
December 17, 2001, p. 1 (high jury awards pushing
67. Technically, there is no “spending power” in up insurance rates and forcing physicians to retire
the Constitution. Some authorities believe that early, move to more rate-friendly states, or limit
the spending power is implicit in the power to tax; patient access to medical care).
see U.S. Const. Art. I, § 8, cl. 1. Other authorities,
ourselves included, believe that spending is 75. See, e.g., David M. Studdert et al., “Can the
authorized only if it is necessary and proper; see United States Afford a ‘No-Fault’ System of
U.S. Const. Art. I, § 8, cl. 18, for executing powers Compensation for Medical Injury?” Law and
enumerated elsewhere in the Constitution. We Contemporary Problems 60 (1997): 33–34; Paul C.
need not resolve that controversy here; the consti- Weiler, “Fixing the Tail: The Place of Malpractice
tutionality of federal spending for medical care in in Health Care Reform,” Rutgers Law Review 47
the context of malpractice reform has not been (1995): 1165; Richard L. Abel, “The Real Tort
challenged. The dispute here is not whether fed- Crisis—Too Few Claims,” Ohio State Law Journal 48
eral medical spending is itself legitimate but (1987): 448; Paul C. Weiler et al., A Measure of
whether malpractice reform can be and has been Malpractice: Medical Injury, Malpractice Litigation, and
legitimately imposed as a condition on state Patient Compensation (Cambridge, MA: Harvard
recipients of the spending. University Press, 1993): pp. 61–76; and Philip
Slayton and Michael J. Trebilcock, eds., The
68. White House. Professions and Public Policy (Toronto: University of
Toronto Press, 1978).
69. See, e.g., South Dakota v. Dole, 483 U.S. 203
(1987). 76. See generally Nancy K. Bannon, AMA Tort
Reform Compendium (Chicago: American Medical
70. Eid, p. 11. Association, 1989) (detailing tort reforms then in
effect); and American Tort Reform Association,
71. White House. “Tort Reform Record,” June 30, 2002, http://www.
atra.org/wrap/files.cgi/7469_record602.htm.
72. See Laura-Mae Baldwin et al., “Defensive
Medicine and Obstetrics,” Journal of the American 77. See American Tort Reform Association, “Tort
Medical Association 274 (1995): 1606–10; and Reform Record,” December 2003, http://www.
Daniel Kessler and Mark McClellan, “Do Doctors atra.org/files.cgi/7668_Record12-03.pdf, for a
Practice Defensive Medicine?” Quarterly Journal of summary of state reforms enacted since 1986.
Economics 111 (1996): 359.
78. H.R. 5, 108th Cong., 1st sess. (February 5,
73. See Lisa Dubay et al., “The Impact of 2003); and S. 607, 108th Cong., 1st sess. (March 13,
Malpractice Fears on Cesarean Section Rates,” 2003).
Journal of Health Economics 18 (1999): 491–522.
79. Rebecca Adams, “Democrats Argue Federal-
74. See Gary M. Fournier and Melayne Morgan ism Case As Committee Approves Malpractice
McInnes, “The Case for Experience Rating in Bill,” Congressional Quarterly Daily Monitor, March
Medical Malpractice Insurance: An Empirical 5, 2003.
Evaluation,” Journal of Risk and Insurance 68 (2001):
274 (physicians, especially rural obstetricians, are 80. State Farm Mutual Automobile Insurance Co. v.
choosing to limit practice or self-insure rather than Campbell, 123 S. Ct. 1513 (2003). This section of the
pay soaring premiums unrelated to their own paper and the following sections through
claims experience); “Echo Malpractice Mess,” edi- “Reconciling Tort Reform and Federalism” are

28
extracted in major part from Robert A. Levy, “The 102. Ibid. at 1527 (Ginsburg, J., dissenting).
Conservative Split on Punitive Damages: State Farm
Mutual Automobile Insurance Co. v. Campbell,” 103. Ibid. at 1531.
Cato Supreme Court Review 2 (2003): 159–86.
104. George F. Will, “License to Legislate,”
81. BMW of North America, Inc. v. Gore, 517 U.S. Washington Post, April 17, 2003, p. A23.
559 (1996).
105. State Farm, 123 S. Ct. at 1531 (Ginsburg, J.,
82. Cooper Industries, Inc. v. Leatherman Tool Group, dissenting). Notably, Justice Ginsburg has been
Inc., 532 U.S. 424, 432 (2001). willing to invoke substantive due process in
other contexts. See, e.g., Lawrence v. Texas, 123 S.
83. In State Farm, for example, the Utah Supreme Ct. 2472 (2003), which she joined, holding that
Court relied on trial testimony indicating that substantive due process protects an unenumer-
“State Farm’s actions, because of their clandestine ated right to private conduct as a component of
nature, will be punished at most in one out of liberty.
every 50,000 cases as a matter of statistical proba-
bility.” Quoted in State Farm, 123 S. Ct. at 1519. 106. Ibid. at 1526 (Thomas, J., dissenting) (quot-
ing Cooper Inds., 532 U.S. at 443 (Thomas, J., con-
84. See Liggett Group v. Engle, 2003 Fla. App. LEXIS curring) (citing Gore, 517 U.S. at 599 (Scalia, J.,
7500 (Fla. Dist. Ct. App. May 21, 2003). joined by Thomas, J., dissenting))).

85. For further commentary on the Engle case, see 107. Ibid. at 1526 (Scalia, J., dissenting).
Robert A. Levy, “Tobacco Class Decertified in
Florida: Sanity Restored,” The Hill, June 11, 2003, 108. TXO Production Corp. v. Alliance Resources
http://www.thehill.com/news/061103/ss_tobac Corp., 509 U.S. 443 (1993).
co.aspx.
109. Ibid. at 458 n. 24 (internal references omitted).
86. David Hechler, “Tenfold Rise in Punitives,”
National Law Journal, February 3, 2003, p. C3. 110. Ibid.

87. Gore at 575. 111. Ibid. at 466–67 (Kennedy, J., concurring in


part and concurring in the judgment).
88. State Farm, 123 S. Ct. at 1518.
112. Ibid. at 467.
89. Ibid.
113. State Farm, 123 S. Ct. at 1519–20 (citing
90. Campbell v. State Farm Mutual Automobile Cooper Inds at 433; Gore at 562).
Insurance Co., 65 P.3d 1134 (2001).
114. Seaboard Air Line R. Co. v. Seegers, 207 U.S. 73,
91. State Farm, 123 S. Ct. at 1521. 78 (1907) (cited in State Farm, 123 S. Ct. at 454).

92. Ibid. at 1526. 115. Southwestern Telegraph & Telephone Co. v.


Danaher, 238 U.S. 482 (1915) (cited in State Farm,
93. Ibid. (citation omitted). 123 S. Ct. at 454).

94. Ibid. at 1521. 116. State Farm, 123 S. Ct. at 1520 (quoting Gore at
574).
95. Ibid. at 1522.
117. Saenz v. Roe, 526 U.S. 489 (1999) (Thomas, J.,
96. Ibid. dissenting, joined by Rehnquist, C.J.).

97. Ibid. at 1523. 118. Robert Bork, The Tempting of America: The
Political Seduction of the Law (New York: Free Press,
98. Ibid. (quoting Gore at 582). 1990), p. 180.
99. Ibid. at 1524–25. 119. Slaughter-House Cases, 16 Wall. (83 U.S.) 36
(1873).
100. Ibid. at 1520 (quoting Honda Motor Co. v.
Oberg, 512 U.S. 415, 432 (1994)). 120. Kimberly C. Shankman and Roger Pilon,
“Reviving the Privileges or Immunities Clause to
101. Ibid. at 1525. Redress the Balance among States, Individuals,

29
and the Federal Government,” Cato Institute 140. Paul H. Rubin, John Calfee, and Mark Grady,
Policy Analysis no. 326, November 23, 1998, p. 1. “BMW v. Gore: Mitigating the Punitive Economics
of Punitive Damages,” Supreme Court Economic
121. Theodore Olson, “Some Thoughts on Review 5 (1997): 203–4.
Punitive Damages,” Manhattan Institute Civil
Justice Memo, no. 15, June 1989, http://www.man 141. International Shoe Co. v. Washington, 326 U.S.
hattan-institute.org/html/cjm_15.htm. 310 (1945).

122. Mark A. Klugheit, “Where the Rubber Meets 142. World-Wide Volkswagen Corp. v. Woodson, 444
the Road: Theoretical Justifications vs. Practical U.S. 286 (1980).
Outcomes in Punitive Damages Litigation,” Syracuse
Law Review 52 (2002): 806 (footnotes omitted). 143. Asahi Metal Industry Co., Ltd. v. Superior Court of
California, 480 U.S. 102 (1987).
123. See, e.g., Darcars Motors of Silver Spring v.
Borzym, 818 A.2d 1159, 1164 (2003). 144. Ibid. at 112.

124. State Farm, 123 S. Ct. at 1520. 145. Rubin, Calfee, and Grady, p. 210.

125. Connor, p. 21. 146. See Krauss, “Product Liability and Game
Theory,” pp. 759, 761.
126. State Farm, 123 S. Ct. at 1523.
147. See, e.g., Michael McConnell, “A Choice-of-Law
127. Connor, p. 23. Approach to Products-Liability Reform,” in New
Directions in Liability Law, ed. Walter Olson (New
128. See Browning-Ferris Industries of Vermont, Inc. v. York: Academy of Political Science, 1988), p. 90.
Kelco Disposal, Inc., 492 U.S. 257 (1989).
148. See 28 U.S.C. § 1332 (2002).
129. Ibid. at 282 (O’Connor, J., concurring in part
and dissenting in part). 149. See Erie Railroad Co. v. Tompkins, 304 U.S. 64
(1938).
130. See, e.g., Roy C. McCormick, “Punitive
Damages Defined and Reviewed for Questions and 150. See Krauss, “Product Liability and Game
Changes Ahead,” Rough Notes, November 1995, p. 68. Theory,” pp. 775, 826. The Supreme Court has
limited the availability of federal diversity juris-
131. Olson. diction by interpreting federal statutes to require
“complete diversity”—i.e., that each plaintiff be
132. Quoted in Fox Butterfield, “New Orleans from a different state than each defendant. See
Takes on Gun Manufacturers in Lawsuit,” New Strawbridge v. Curtis, 7 U.S. (3 Cranch) 267, 267–68
York Times, November 4, 1998, online edition. (1806). As a result, plaintiffs have been able to
guarantee a state court forum by including an in-
133. Carolyn Lochhead, “The Growing Power of state defendant—typically a retailer in a product
Trial Lawyers,” Weekly Standard, September 23, liability suit—in the litigation. To get around that
1996, p. 21. problem, the Court’s holding in Strawbridge
would have to be reversed, or Congress would
134. Berger v. United States, 295 U.S. 78, 88 (1935). have to provide that “minimal diversity”—i.e.,
when any plaintiff is from a state different than
135. Michael Horowitz, “Can Tort Law Be any defendant—is sufficient to trigger federal
Ethical?” Weekly Standard, March 19, 2001, p. 16. jurisdiction in specified tort suits. (At this writing,
Congress is considering a minimal diversity pro-
136. See Robert A. Levy, “Twisted Tobacco Logic,” vision in connection with a federal class action
Washington Times, April 11, 2001, p. A12. reform package.)
137. Kristin Armshaw ed., “Disorder in the Court: 151. See Michael Greve, “Eulogy for a Lost
A Guide for State Legislators,” American Clause,” National Law Journal, May 26, 2003, p. 27.
Legislative Exchange Council, June 2003, especially
pp. 7–14. 152. See William Niskanen, “Do Not Federalize
Tort Law,” Regulation, no. 4 (1995): 18.
138. Fla. Stat. Ann. § 409.910 (1995).
153. One problem, not addressed here, is the
139. Sheila R. Cherry, “Litigation Lotto,” Insight on inequity that could arise if an innocent bystander is
the News, April 3, 2000, p. 10. injured by a defective product purchased in a juris-

30
diction with a defendant-friendly tort regime. The 154. Michael S. Greve, “Torts, Federalism, and the
bystander could neither decline to purchase the Constitution,” American Enterprise Institute,
product, nor pay less, to offset the prospect of undated, http://www.federalismproject.org/mas
uncompensated injury. See Krauss, “Product terpages/tort/torts,fed,cnt.html.
Liability and Game Theory,” p. 824, for a suggested
solution to this problem. 155. Ibid.

Published by the Cato Institute, Policy Analysis is a regular series evaluating government policies and offer-
ing proposals for reform. Nothing in Policy Analysis should be construed as necessarily reflecting the views
of the Cato Institute or as an attempt to aid or hinder the passage of any bill before congress. Contact the
Cato Institute for reprint permission. Additional copies of Policy Analysis are $6.00 each ($3.00 each for five
or more). To order, or for a complete listing of available studies, write the Cato Institute, 1000 Massachusetts
Ave., N.W., Washington, D.C. 20001, call toll free 1-800-767-1241 (noon - 9 p.m. eastern time), fax (202) 842-
3490, or visit our website at www.cato.org.

31

You might also like