You are on page 1of 16

This essay will, firstly, review the background and historical context in which free trade arose and

then

proceed to look at some of the specific arguments which classical economists put forward in its cause.

It will then continue to review such arguments in the context of the modern age to evaluate how valid or

otherwise they may still be. Protectionist viewpoints will also be summarised and some common ground

between both schools of thought highlighted. Data will be provided to support the case that free trade

has historically improved economic growth and prosperity in the world, but also question how this has

been distributed within and between nations. The issue of rising protectionism will be raised and, finally,

the essay will conclude by contending that, although some free trade principles are still relevant in the

modern age, the greater complexity and interdependence of world economy render others redundant. It

is also proposed that, had Adam Smith, David Ricardo and others foreseen how capitalist economies

would have developed, they may have had a different view of state intervention.

Demands for free trade arose in an age when the world economy was radically different from that of the

modern age. When Adam Smith wrote The Wealth of Nations, Britain was dominated by landed

interests and a gentlemanly order, known as ‘Old Corruption’ (Cain and Hopkins, 1993: p.301). The

then mercantilist system was one of economic nationalism, government intervention and a pursuit of

wealth as a means of ensuring state security. Its emphasis was on ‘a favourable balance of trade to

generate an inflow of funds, and a favourable commodity composition of trade to promote economic

development and employment in manufacturing’ (Irwin, 1996: p. 34). As such, the home market was

protected by tariffs and duties, and characterized by domestic monopolies with the resultant effects on

productive inefficiency and higher prices. Also, as Heilbroner highlights, there had not yet been a

recognition of what we now know as business cycles (Heilbroner, 1967: p.65). Contrast with today’s

world of advanced technology and production methods, multinational corporations, a multitude of

international regulatory bodies, greater interdependency between nations, an established role of

government in economic affairs, and recurrent financial crisis.

The roots of free trade were as much philosophical as economic in that they placed the liberty of the

individual before that of the state: ‘every man, as long as he does not violate the laws of justice, is

perfectly free to pursue his own interest in his own way’ (Irwin,1996: p.84 quoting Adam Smith). In

1
economic terms, free trade was rooted in Ricardian comparative cost theory (Deane,1989: p.157) and

was seen as the best method for the efficient allocation of resources and maximization of national

income and the wealth of society (Irwin, 1996: pp. 79-80). The rise of free trade may also be seen as

the result of the emergence of the industrial classes to a position of superiority over the landed classes

(Helibroner, 1991: p.45) as the control of technological change shifted in their favour (Cole, Cameron

and Edwards, 1991: p.27). In political terms, this was reflected in the 1832 Reform Act. In the European

context, free trade developed with the support of French industrial and German agricultural interests

and, in Kindleberger’s second wave after 1850, elsewhere for ideological reasons (Kindleberger, 2000:

p.88). This then, was the backdrop to the rise of free trade.

Classical free trade principles were numerous but essential to them were a minimalist role by

governments with intervention only in specific areas and circumstances; individual liberty under the law;

the free flow of goods and capital; a freely competitive market; and the absence of monopolies. Their

aims were very much the maximisation of consumer interests as opposed to those of producers and

special interests. Legitimate government intervention would include the provision of public goods such

as ‘law, order, transport projects and the provision of elementary education’ (Cole, Cameron and

Edwards, p.31); reciprocity with regard to retaliation for foreign imposed tariffs; and the protection of

infant industries. In this respect, free traders shared common ground with later protectionists such as

Alexander Hamilton and Friedrich List, albeit they advocated such a policy only as a temporary

measure (Kenwood and Lougheed, 1999, p. 69). In opposing protectionism, free traders highlighted the

adverse effects of specific measures which distorted the natural flow of trade such as tariffs, subsidies

and import bans, and later associated policies including regulatory barriers, bureaucratic impediments

(red tape), and exchange controls. Effects of such policies, in addition to those mentioned earlier,

included the sub optimal allocation of capital to protected industries, and therefore a distortion of

opportunity costs, and the protection of special interests at the expense of society as a whole (Irwin,

1996: pp. 79-80)..

Fundamental to much of the arguments between free trade and protectionist positions are the roles of

the individual and the state. Frieden and Lake confirm that ‘liberals view economics and politics as

2
autonomous spheres, whereas realists assert that politics determines economics’ (Frieden and Lake,

2000:p.13). Protectionist policies were viewed as beneficial to domestic industry and employment and

also as a source of government revenue from tariffs. Their arguments included the protection and

support of national defence, strategic and infant industries and, as realists, they saw trade surpluses

conducive to national security and therefore the economy as something to be utilised in the interests of

state power.

An underlying assumption of the free trade case is that markets are perfect and therefore consumers

have full information, freedom of entry, and that competition is perfect. In promoting strategic trade

policy, protectionists argued that markets did not conform to these principles and may be characterised

by monopolistic or oligopolistic structures, imperfect information, and that governments and other actors

may distort markets to their own advantage. In effect, they viewed the market as an anarchic

environment and this underpinned their case for state intervention. Such arguments were, and still are,

often couched in terms of fair trade or of a ‘level playing field’ (Coughlin, Chrystal and Wood, 2000:

p.316) in that tariffs and other import barriers should be used in a reciprocal manner to coerce others to

compete fairly. Some free traders may not have disagreed with this on occasion, but with protectionists

such policies tended to be the rule rather than the exception. Protectionist arguments failed to take

account of the long-term effects and costs of their policies but, despite this, protectionism still persists

and, in recent times, has shown some signs of increasing (FT.com, 2009). Domestically, protectionist

policy choices are not always made for economic, but for political, reasons - what Coughlin, Chrystal

and Wood have highlighted as the ‘public choice’ argument (Coughlin, Chrystal and Wood, 2000:

p.316) - or what may otherwise be known as ‘pork barrel’ politics.

How applicable then, are such arguments and policies to the modern world trade system? Classical

liberal free traders would be alarmed at the extent and role of government involvement in today’s

modern economies. In Britain, for example, government spending has grown rapidly in recent decades

(Diagram One) and it has also risen as a percentage of GDP, from just under 16% in 1900 to almost

44% in 2009 (Diagram Two). This is projected to rise to over 47% by 2011, although this is distorted by

the current financial crisis.

3
Diagram One: UK Government Spending and GDP 1900 - 2010

1600

1400

1200

1000

£ billion
800

600

400

200

0
1900

1920

1930

1950

1960

1980

2000

2010
1910

1940

1970

1990
Year

GDP Total Govt Spending

Source: Diagram constructed from figures obtained from www.ukpublicspending.co.uk, (November 2009)
Actual figures included in Appendix One

Diagram Two: UK Government Spending as % of GDP, 1900 - 2010

60%

50%

40%
Percentage

30%

20%

10%

0%
1910

1930

1940

1960

1970

1980

1990

2010
1900

1920

1950

2000

Fiscal Year

% of GDP

Source: Diagram constructed from figures obtained from www.ukpublicspending.co.uk, (November 2009)
Note exception of high expenditure during WW2 years.
Actual figures included in Appendix One

However, as stated earlier, the modern economy differs radically from that of classical times and there

is a greater need for government intervention to facilitate the flow of products, capital and people and

for states to provide an increasing array of both national and international public goods. Classical

liberals would not argue with expenditure on law, education and transport, which account for over 22%

of current UK government expenditure (calculated from ONS Yearbook figures, 2005: p.367), and

perhaps not with expenditure on health and social protection in support of Adam Smith’s view that ‘No

4
society can surely be flourishing and happy, of which by far the greater part of the numbers are poor

and miserable’ (Heilbroner, 1967: p. 55, quoting Adam Smith in Wealth of Nations). These inclusions

would raise this figure 67% of total current expenditure (calculated from ONS Yearbook figures, 2005:

p.367). Classical economists could not have fully foreseen the necessity for such intensive government

involvement in the economic and social life of the nation, nor perhaps the need to balance the

requirements of the modern domestic and international economies. Neither may they have fully

imagined the multilateral character of post 1945 ‘embedded liberalism’ based as it was on domestic

interventionism (Ruggie, 1982: p. 393).

Classical liberals would baulk at the idea of state protection of an industry per se, but were it in support

of an infant industry, or one in transformation, then this would rank as one of the exceptions to their free

trade principles. Modern governments have often applied this measure as part of their industrial policy,

for example Japan and other south east Asian economies in recent decades, as does China currently in

support of its industrialisation policy. Defence of infant industries is also permitted by the WTO (World

Trade Organisation) with regard to the least developed countries, LDCs, through its system of GATT

preferences, therefore providing them time to adapt to world markets ( WTO Link 1). The lack of such

policies may make it more difficult for countries to compete on an equal footing against more advanced

economies, therefore classical liberal arguments could be seen to be relevant in the modern age with

particular relevance to LDCs and developing nations.

The debate over free trade is perhaps most visible and commonly understood in relation to import

tariffs, product bans, quotas and other versions of such policies such as voluntary agreements and

negotiated export restraints. Examples include the current spat between China and the USA over tyres

( WTO Link 2) and disagreements between developed and less developed nations over textiles and

clothing ( WTO Link 3). Tariffs in the industrialised world have reduced by more than 80% since GATT’s

creation in 1948 ( WTO Link 4), and by the 1990s had fallen to less than 4% of industrial goods in

developed countries ( WTO Link 5). Additionally, since January 2000, WTO negotiations have expanded

to cover non-tariff barriers, services and intellectual property ( WTO Link 6). However, many

imbalances in tariff structures still exist and, on balance, they disfavour developing nations. Although

5
exports of LDCs have been rising faster than developed economies in recent years (Diagram Three),

and now account for 33% of their GDP (Appendix Two), much still needs to be done to improve their

capabilities of competing fairly in the world economy. This aspect will be returned to later in the essay.

Diagram Three: Export Growth (exc. Services), 1970 - 2007

30.0

25.0
Percentage Growth

20.0

15.0

10.0

5.0

0.0
80

90

95

00

05

06

07
0-
0-

1-

0-

5-

20

20
7

0
19

19

19

19

20
Period/ Year

World Developing economies Economies in transition


Developed economies Least developed countries Heavily indebted poor countries

Source: Figures extracted from UNCTAD website, www.unctad.org, utilising the site’s statistical package. Figures then
summarised and chart constructed in MS Excel. See Appendix Three for actual figures.

Historically, free trade has proved to be a facilitator of world growth, greater productivity, and gains from

Ricardian comparative advantage. Kindleberger highlights that the period from 1820 to 1875 was one of

generally decreasing tariffs in Europe (Kindleberger, 2000: p.87). Between 1800 and 1830 international

trade grew from £300 million to £400 million, an increase of 30% (Hobsbawm, 1969: p.139); between

1830 and 1850 it doubled; and between 1850 and 1880 it trebled or quadrupled (Kenwood and

Lougheed, 1999: p.67). Hobsbawm also states that the growth by 1870 was five times what it was in

1840 (Hobsbawm, 1969: p.139). However, from the period 1880 to 1913 ‘only Britain, Holland and

Denmark steadfastly adhered to free trade’ but the tariffs that existed did not seriously hinder growth

and world trade grew steadily in this period (Kenwood and Lougheed, 1999: p.72). The inter-war years

saw British industry decline as it had become obsolete and inefficient (Hobsbawm,1969: p. 150)

culminating in the Great Depression of 1929-32. However, a period of economic nationalism followed

when protectionist measures were, in the short term, successful (Mazower, 1998: p.129) and

economies recovered aided by higher tariffs, state monopolies, the subsidisation of agriculture and

6
increased military expenditure. Classical liberalism appeared to have failed during this period

(Mazower, 1998: p.140).

Between 1945 and 1970 world economic growth averaged approximately 5% per year, partly as a result

of lower trade barriers, with world trade growing even faster, averaging about 8% during this period

(WTO Link 7). Therefore, in general, the data of the last two centuries support the view that free trade is

conducive to growth in world trade. Diagram Four illustrates the growth since the origin of GATT:

Diagram Four: World Trade and Production

1950 = 100. Trade and GDP: log scale


Source: WTO website, WTO Link 8

However, there exists an issue as to how this growth is distributed both between and within nations.

Although the WTO offers help to LDCs in the form of extra time to meet their WTO commitments, non-

reciprocity tariff agreements, safeguards when adopting international measures and technical help in

institution building, much still needs to be done to improve the structural weaknesses in their

economies. As Ruggie highlights: ‘the liberalisation produced by the GATT has benefited few

[developing countries]’ (Ruggie, 1982: p.414). Many LDCs especially need help with stabilizing food

production, building infrastructures, developing training, and improving policy making and economic

management and, as the WTO states, much of this depends on political stability in these countries

(WTO Link 9). Classical liberal arguments are relevant to this ‘progressive liberalisation’ and the role

7
states and international institutions might play in helping developing economies adapt their industries to

compete in world markets.

Although LDC exports, as well as those of developing economies and economies in

transition, are growing and are rising as a percentage of their GDP, they accounted for

only 0.6 per cent of world exports and 0.8 per cent of world imports in 2004. (WTO World

Report, 2006: p.25 Link 10). This is illustrated in Diagram Five:

Diagram Five: Share of World Exports, 1948 - 2007


80%

70%

60%

50%
Percentage

40%

30%

20%

10%

0%
48

58

68

78

88

98

07
19

19

19

19

20
19

19

Developing economies Economies in transition Developed economies


Year
Least developed countries Heavily indebted poor countries

Source: Figures extracted from UNCTAD website, www.unctad.org, utilising site’s statistical package. Figures then summarised
and chart constructed in MS Excel. See Appendix Three for actual figures.

Developed nations, particularly the USA and the EU as the largest export markets for LDCs (WTO

World Report, 2006: p.26 WTO Link 11), have a role to play in allowing them greater market

access by extending preferential non-reciprocal agreements and increasing duty-free and quota-free

agreements. Tariffs and subsidies in developed nations are, on average, higher then those in

developing countries and a sample of 31 developing countries showed the average ratio of subsidies

to GDP at 0.6%, whilst that for a sample of 22 developed countries was 1.4% (WTO Link 12). Also,

since the advent of the financial crisis in 2008, protectionist measures have been on the increase. As

stated on the Financial Times website in April 2009: ‘As economies have dived, ….The World Bank

has found 17 of the G20 have implemented 47 measures since the last G20 summit with the aim of

restrict[ing] trade at the expense of other countries’ (FT.com, 2009). This was supported six months

8
later by the Centre for Economic Policy Research which identified 280 state protectionist initiatives

implemented since November 2008, of which 192 tilted the balance in favour of domestic commercial

interests at the expense of foreigners. (CEPR Link 1).

Classical liberal arguments in favour of free trade principles have perhaps come under more scrutiny

and criticism recently with regard to the free flow of capital. Events in most developed economies

commencing in 2008 have illustrated the absence of Smith’s ‘invisible hand’ and the need for regulation

to protect individual investors and consumers. Adam Smith would certainly recognise the self interest

and ‘mean rapacity’ (Heilbroner, 1967: p.62, quoting Adam Smith in Wealth of Nations) of the financial

community and their eagerness ‘to take advantage of their neighbour’s greed’ (Heilbroner,1967: p.50,

quoting Adam Smith in Wealth of Nations). Keynes also recognised this in the 1930s when he

commented: ‘nothing less than the democratic experiment in self-government was endangered by the

threat of global financial market forces’ (Chomsky, 2003: p.138). But would Smith agree with

government intervention in such a case? Again, classical liberal points of view must be put in context of

their time which was a world of ‘atomistic competition’ (Heilbroner, 1967: p.53) where self regulation

was perhaps more possible. Classical liberals favour liberty under the law but, in view of how modern

financial markets operate, they might support amendments to the law in the form of regulation as the

provision of a public good and necessary for the protection of individuals. Debate over financial

regulation continues and differences remain between major nations, particularly the USA and UK over

such issues as a ‘Tobin Tax’ on financial flows. Classical liberals may perceive such a measure as a

tariff on the free flow of funds but may balance this against the requirement for consumer protection

against special interests and the orderly operation of markets.

Keynesian demand management, via deficit financing, fiscal measures and industry support, may be

seen as interference and a distortion of the free market by classical liberals, as it would be by

neoclassical economists. Their, perhaps naïve, belief that the market would self adjust according to

Adam Smith’s ‘natural order’ has been disproved by recent, and previous, events. However, as stated

earlier, knowledge of business cycles and recurring financial crises were not as advanced in the age of

Adam Smith as they are now and therefore classical arguments should, again, be viewed in context of

9
their time. In this respect, the classical liberal case for non-intervention, unless it affected free

competition, is not fully relevant in the present age. Government failures to intervene contributed to the

depth of Great Depression of 1929 onwards whereas recent involvement, in order that similar mistakes

were not repeated, has mitigated the effects of the global financial crisis of 2008-09.

Exchange rates between nations have a direct affect on trade and can be manipulated, via money

market operations, to distort normal trading patterns. The most obvious current example of exchange

rate management is that of the Chinese Yuan which is presently estimated to be 15% - 25%

undervalued against the US dollar (The Economist, 2009). This works both as a subsidy for exports and

a barrier to imports by making the former cheaper and the latter more expensive. As such, it would be

seen as interference in the free market and would be opposed by classical liberals. It may also be

viewed as a protectionist policy, in the Chinese case one of protecting its agricultural and infant

industries from the world market. However, with almost half of the Chinese population still employed in

this sector (Peoples Daily, 2000), such actions may be viewed as a necessary transitional policy until

the economy is more diversified in order to avoid severe problems in the short term. In view of this,

classical liberal arguments with regard to support of structural transition may be seen as relevant one,

but not in the longer term as it would be viewed as an aggressive and unfair means of driving exports.

As highlighted earlier, classical liberals would oppose monopolies that work against the interests of

consumers. In this respect government intervention, in the form of the Monopolies and Mergers

Commission in the UK, to prevent a merger which is considered detrimental to the public might be

viewed favourably. As Roll highlights: ’Preservation of free competition, if necessary by state action,

was the principal duty of economic policy’ (Roll, 1973: p.149, quoting views of Adam Smith and free

trade thinkers). Additionally, classical liberals may agree with recent proposals to demerge some of the

larger banks. Where they would stand on state monopolies is debatable, for example the Post Office

and national utility and transport companies. Perhaps they may view them as necessary providers of

national public goods, benefiting from Schumpeterian dynamic efficiencies (Samuelson,1976: p. 532),

and necessary for the efficient operation of the market. Alternatively, they may see them as a market

10
distortion, as detrimental, and therefore consider that consumers would be better served by

independent firms in a free, but regulated market.

In conclusion, this essay has illustrated the historical background and context in which free trade

philosophy originated and highlighted the key principles and arguments it espoused. It then reviewed

these in turn and considered their relevance in the modern era with some examples. Data were

provided to show that, in general terms, free trade principles are still valid in that, historically, they have

generally provided the increase in wealth predicted. The uneven distribution of that wealth was

discussed with particular reference to the LDCs and the developing world, an issue not fully considered

by classical free traders. In this respect, the protection of infant industries as proposed by Smith, and

later endorsed by J.S. Mill and Alfred Marshall (Deane, 1989:p.140) is highly relevant in helping such

countries develop the capacities to compete in modern markets. Elements of the mercantilist and

protectionist cause were also highlighted and, as some periods of history have shown, protectionist

measures have produced benefits in the short term for some economies and specific sectors within

them.

It was also contended that, at the time of writing, many classical liberal economists could not have

foreseen many of the developments and effects of modern capitalism with regard to its technological

sophistication, greater international interdependence, the complexity of modern society, and the greater

need for state intervention in the economy. Completely free markets do not have the natural regulating

mechanisms perceived by classical liberal economists and therefore require some element of

intervention to protect societies. Also, in current age of globalisation, it is difficult to perceive the

international system functioning without state intervention. In view of this, it has not always been clear

where they would have stood on some elements of contemporary government economic policy.

Finally, classical free trade proponents differed from protectionists, not in that the state should not

intervene in economic affairs, but to the extent that it should. Adam Smith was a realist in this respect

and recognised ‘that the freedom of trade should ever be entirely restored in Great Britain is as absurd

as to expect that…Utopia should ever be established’ (Deane,1989: p.70, quoting Adam Smith in

11
Wealth of Nations). Free trade is therefore a normative theory and its ideals are unlikely to be fully

achieved. Protectionist arguments persist and are likely to do so in future, particularly in times of

economic difficulty when their simplistic sounding solutions may appeal. The future of modern

economies, in view of the rise of protectionism in recent times, is perhaps best recognised by Underhill

when he states that the trade system will continue ‘to be a mixture of liberal principles with protectionist

reflexes’ (Underhill, 2006: p. 103).

Total words 3,697 excluding diagrams and appendices

12
Appendix One

Source figures used for construction of Diagrams One and Two

Total
Fiscal GDP % of
Spending
Year (£ bn) GDP
Total
1900 1.885 0.3 15.92%
1910 2.14 0.3 14.02%
1920 5.975 1.6 26.78%
1930 4.615 1.1 23.84%
1940 7.183 4 55.69%
1950 13.285 4.5 33.87%
1960 25.974 9.1 35.04%
1970 51.523 21.6 41.92%
1980 230.8 103.9 45.02%
1990 560.887 200.9 35.82%
2000 958.931 339.3 35.38%
2010 1411 654.7 46.40%

source: www.ukpublicspending.co.uk (November 2009)

13
Appendix Two: Ratio of exports of goods and commercial services to GDP of the least-
developed countries, 2007

Value Ratio to GDP (%)

Goods and Commercial


GDP ($M) commercial services Goods services

2007 2000 2007 2000 2007 2000 2007

LDCs 422700 24 33 21 30 4 3
Afghanistan 9658 ... ... ... ... ... ...
Angola 61403 90 73 87 72 3 1
Bangladesh 68415 14 19 14 18 1 1
Benin 5428 23 24 17 19 6 5
Bhutan 1096 30 52 26 47 4 5
Burkina Faso 6767 9 10 8 9 1 1
Burundi 974 7 6 7 5 0 1
Cambodia 8350 49 67 37 49 11 18
Central African Republic 1712 18 13 17 11 1 2
Chad 7085 15 53 13 52 2 1
Comoros 449 24 14 6 3 19 10
Congo, Dem. Rep. of 8953 22 ... 21 ... 2 ...
Djibouti 830 18 18 6 7 13 11
Equatorial Guinea 9923 100 50 100 49 1 0
Eritrea 1375 14 ... 6 ... 9 ...
Ethiopia 19395 11 13 6 7 5 6
Gambia 644 45 36 30 18 15 18
Guinea 4564 22 27 21 26 1 1
Guinea-Bissau 357 31 27 29 24 2 3
Haiti 6715 13 10 9 8 4 2
Kiribati 78 27 ... 13 ... 14 ...
Lao People's Dem. Rep. 4108 28 37 20 29 9 7
Lesotho 1600 29 55 25 50 4 4
Liberia 735 ... 48 ... 27 ... 22
Madagascar 7382 29 26 21 15 8 11
Malawi 3563 25 ... 23 ... 2 ...
Maldives 1055 72 81 17 22 55 59
Mali 6863 26 28 23 23 4 5
Mauritania 2644 36 ... 33 ... 3 ...
Mozambique 7790 16 36 9 31 8 5
Myanmar 19618 24 ... 19 ... 5 ...
Nepal 10315 22 12 14 9 7 3
Niger 4170 18 18 16 16 2 2
Rwanda 3339 6 9 4 6 2 4
Samoa 525 ... 29 ... 3 ... 26
Sao Tome and Principe 145 ... 8 ... 5 ... 3
Senegal 11165 27 25 20 15 7 10
Sierra Leone 1664 8 20 2 18 6 3
Solomon Islands 388 38 58 23 41 15 17
Somalia ... ... ... ... ... ... ...
Sudan 46228 15 20 15 19 0 1
Tanzania 16181 14 24 7 14 6 10
Timor Leste 395 ... ... ... ... ... ...
Togo 2499 31 35 27 27 3 8
Tuvalu ... ... ... ... ... ... ...
Uganda 11771 11 21 7 17 3 4
Vanuatu 452 59 47 11 7 48 39
Yemen 22523 42 34 40 31 2 3
Zambia 11363 27 43 23 40 4 2
5458380
World 0 25 32 20 25 5 6

Note: Trade in goods is derived from balance of payments statistics. Data are
estimated for most countries.
source:

14
http://www.wto.org/english/res_e/statis_e/its2009_e/section1_e
/i21.xls

Appendix Three
Source figures for Diagram Three

Annual average growth rates of exports (%)


Year/ Trading Group
1970-80 1981-90 1990-95 1995-00 2000-05 2006 2007

World 20.4 7.2 7.7 3.7 11.3 15.4 14.4


Developing economies 25.7 4.4 10.8 5.8 14.2 19.3 15.2
Economies in transition 20.2 3.5 4.8 1.8 19.6 25.1 18.7
Developed economies 18.8 8.5 6.8 2.8 9.5 12.5 13.7
Least developed countries 11.2 3.3 4.0 6.5 18.1 25.2 21.2
Heavily indebted poor countries 13.5 2.1 2.2 1.4 15.3 22.6 13.6

Source figures for Diagram Five

World Export Values and Group Shares


Year/ Trading Group
1948 1958 1968 1978 1988 1998 2007
World Total 50086 109115 242868 1321537 2870552 5503068 13833041

Developing economies 16235 29617 48859 326101 649960 1527890 5190026


32.41% 27.14% 20.12% 24.68% 22.64% 27.76% 37.52%
Economies in transition .. 4768 11898 57890 123480 117904 533684
4.37% 4.90% 4.38% 4.30% 2.14% 3.86%
Developed economies 33851 74729 182111 937546 2097112 3857273 8109330
67.59% 68.49% 74.98% 70.94% 73.06% 70.09% 58.62%
Least developed countries 1114 2093 3947 9359 15154 25686 125644
2.22% 1.92% 1.63% 0.71% 0.53% 0.47% 0.91%
Heavily indebted poor countries 1301 2266 4821 13887 17773 25921 73147
2.60% 2.08% 1.99% 1.05% 0.62% 0.47% 0.53%

15
Bibliography

1. Brittan, S. The changing economic role of government, Contribution to 50th Anniversary Vol.
Soc. of Bus. Economists 2003
2. CEPR website, www.cepr.org
3. Chomsky, N., (2003) Hegemony or Survival (London, Penguin)
4. Cole, K. Cameron J. and Edwards C, Why economists disagree, chapter 2 "Conflict and the
emergence of capitalism, from mercantilism to Adam Smith", (London: Longman 2nd ed.1991)
5. Coughlin., Chrystal, K.A., and Wood, G.E. "Protectionist trade policies: A Survey of Theory,
Evidence and Rationale " ch.19 in J.A. Frieden, D.A.Lake (eds), International Political
Economy; perspectives on global power and wealth (London: Routledge, 4th ed, 2000)
6. Deane, P. The state and the economic system, and introduction to political economy (Oxford,
Oxford U.P. 1989)
7. Economist .com, Hot air (Hong Kong, Oct 1st 2009)
8. Frieden, A. and Lake, D.A. (eds), International Political Economy; perspectives on global power
and wealth (London: Routledge, 4th ed, 2000)
9. FT.com “Harmony is main item on the agenda” by C.Giles (London, April 1 2009)
10. Heilbroner, R. The Worldly Philosophers; the lives, times and ideas of the great economic
thinkers, Penguin 1967
11. Hobsbawm, E. Industry and Empire, (Harmondsworth: Penguin Books, 1969)
12. Irwin, D. A. Ch. 5 (Adam Smith) & 6 (Free Trade) in Against the tide: an intellectual history of
free trade, (Princeton, N.J : Princeton University Press, 1996)
13. Kenwood, A.G & A.L. Lougheed. The growth of the international economy 1820-2000: an
introductory text, Ch. 4 (Britain adopts free trade), (London: Routledge, 4th edition, 1999)
14. Kindleberger, C.P. “Chapter 5: The Rise of Free Trade in Western Europe” in J.A. Frieden,
D.A.Lake (eds), International Political Economy; perspectives on global power and wealth
(London: Routledge, 4th ed, 2000)
15. Mazower, ch.4 “Crisis of capitalism” in Dark Continent: Europe’s 20th century. (London,
Penguin, 1998)
16. Office for National Statistics, UK 2005 The Official Yearbook of the United Kingdom and
Northern Ireland (TSO, London) 2005. Available from: ONS 2005 Link
17. Roll, E., A history of economic thought (4th ed. London Faber 1973)
18. Ruggie, J. G. International regimes, transactions, and change: embedded liberalism and the
postwar economic order, International Organization, Vol. 36, No. 2 (1982)
19. Samuelson, P.A. (1976) Economics (Tokyo: McGraw-Hill Kogakusha, 10th edition)
20. Underhill, R.D. “Global issues in historical perspective” in, Stubbs, R. Underhill, R.D. (eds)
Political Economy and the Changing Global Order, OUP, 3rd edition, 2006
21. UNCTAD website, http://www.unctad.org
22. WTO website, http://www.wto.org

16

You might also like