You are on page 1of 10

Toward a New Understanding of Nineteenth-Century Cost Accounting

Author(s): H. Thomas Johnson


Source: The Accounting Review, Vol. 56, No. 3 (Jul., 1981), pp. 510-518
Published by: American Accounting Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/246912 .
Accessed: 15/06/2014 02:37

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Accounting Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
Accounting Review.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 185.44.78.143 on Sun, 15 Jun 2014 02:37:48 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE ACCOUNTING REVIEW
Vol. LVI, No. 3
July 1981

Toward a New Understandingof


Nineteenth- Century
Cost Accounting
H. Thomas Johnson

ABSTRACT: While accounting historians agree that cost accounting is a consequence


of the industrial revolution, they have not thoroughly explained the economic conse-
quence of the industrial revolution which prompted manufacturing firms to develop
actual cost accounting techniques in the nineteenth century. This paper presents an
explanation for the rise of nineteenth-century cost accounting which supplements the
traditional view that increased use of fixed capital and the resultant need to account for
costs of long-lived assets prompted industrial accountants to graft cost accounts onto the
double-entry system. The study concludes that not only changes in the temporal struc-
ture of their costs, but also changes in the way they organized economic activity, explain
the conditions which prompted manufacturers to develop cost accounting procedures
for gathering financial information needed by managers.

I. INTRODUCTION counting onto the double-entry system.


ACCOUNTING historians have long For example, Garner states that the
endorsed the view that cost ac- "relative simplicity" of late eighteenth-
counting is a product of the indus- century accounting in engineering, coal
trial revolution. Fifty years ago, Littleton mining, and textile firms did not suffice
explained that "cost accounting . . . is after 1800 when "problems arose mainly
one of the many consequences of the in connection with the large amounts of
industrial revolution" [1933, p. 321]. capital sunk in plant equipment and
Writing 20 years after Littleton, Garner transportation facilities" [1954, p. 28].
reinforced this claim when he pointed out The author gratefully acknowledges the comments
that while many industrial bookkeeping received from Charles T. Horngren, Elaine B. Johnson,
procedures existed long before 1800, cost Robert J. Lord, and three anonymous reviewers for this
journal. Earlier versions of this paper were presented to
accounting came into existence only after the 1979 Washington Community College Accounting
the late eighteenth century [1954, ch. 1.] Workshop and to the 1980 Western Regional Conference
In addition to agreeing about when of the American Accounting Association.
cost accounting was developed, account-
ing historians have long shared a particu- H. Thomas Johnson is Professor of
lar view of why cost accounting arose Accounting, Western Washington Uni-
when it did. This traditional view con- versity.
tends that the increased use of fixed Manuscript received May 1980.
capital prompted accountants during the Revision received August 1980.
industrial revolution to graft cost ac- Accepted October 1980.

510

This content downloaded from 185.44.78.143 on Sun, 15 Jun 2014 02:37:48 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Johnson 511

More recently, furthermore, Chatfield view that new methods for organizing
observes that "the main new fact con- economic activity-not just changes in
fronting both financial and cost ac- the temporal structure of their costs-
countants" at the beginning of the indus- explain why many nineteenth-century
trial era "was the presence of large industrial organizations developed cost-
amounts of capital sunk in plant and accounting procedures. Nineteenth-
equipment" [1974, p. 101]. century industrial firms were among the
This widely held belief, so ably ex- first in history to use internal administra-
pressed by Chatfield and Garner, does tive procedures to coordinate multiple
not seem to me to explain fully the condi- processes involving the conversion of
tions responsible for the rise of cost raw materials into finished goods. Al-
accounting. Various recent studies [John- though these firms often invested in fixed
son, 1972; Stone, 1973; Chandler, 1977; plant and equipment, their concern for
Wells, 1977; Porter, 1980] of how the internal cost accounting information was
managers of nineteenth-century manu- dictated not only by the need to account
facturing firms used accounting informa- for fixed costs, but also by the need to
tion to facilitate decision-making and evaluate and control internally-adminis-
control have resulted in some findings tered production processes.
which seem inconsistent with the tradi-
II. THE ORIGINOF COSTACCOUNTINGIN
tional explanation of why the industrial
NINETEENTH-CENTURY TEXTILE
revolution caused cost accounting to
FACTORIES
develop. For example, modem studies
have revealed that near the beginning of The first modem business organiza-
the nineteenth century textile factories tions to require internal accounting infor-
relied upon double-entry cost accounting mation for decision-making and control
information to control multi-process op- were the mechanized, multi-process, cot-
erations. This was, however, long before ton textile factories that appeared in
fixed assets consumed a manager's atten- England and the United States around
tion. Indeed, Chatfield [1974, p. 1011 1800. These textile factories used cost
observes that "investing in fixed assets accounts to ascertain the direct labor and
did not seem very different from buying overhead costs of converting raw ma-
inventories" in the minds of early nine- terial into finished yarn and fabric. These
teenth-century industrial managers.1 double-entry cost accounts, so far the
These investigations have further indi- earliest discovered, differ radically from
cated that some capital-intensive any accounting records used previously
manufacturing firms near the end of the
Chatfield's observation is supported by the limited
nineteenth century which used cost ac- empirical evidence on asset structures of early factories
counting information for decision- which economic historians frequently cite. For example,
making and control were not particularly Mathias [1969, p. 148], referring to conditions in late
eighteenth- and early nineteenth-century Britain, states
concerned with the problem of allocating that "even in the early factories, in textiles, breweries and
fixed costs to periods or to products. the like, amongst the most heavily capitalized less than
The pioneering work done in these one-seventh or one-eighth of total assets typically were
in buildings and plant; six-sevenths to seven-eights and
studies suggests that the demand for more still being absorbed by 'movables' or 'circulating
procedures with which to account for capital'...." Chandler [1977, p. 71], referring to early
fixed capital does not explain fully why nineteenth-century American textile manufacturers,
notes that "as labor and cotton were by far the major
cost accounting actually emerged when it costs, they had little incentive to compute indirect and
did. The following analysis offers the overhead costs."

This content downloaded from 185.44.78.143 on Sun, 15 Jun 2014 02:37:48 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
512 The AccountingReview,July 1981

in business organizations. From the Specifically, a merchant-entrepreneur


inception of double-entry bookkeeping bought raw materials such as cotton, silk,
until the advent of the modem factory, or wool in open markets and consigned
businesses had used accounts merely to these materials to independent household
record the results of market exchanges. artisans (i.e., "domestic" artisans). Using
With the arrival of the integrated, multi- equipment they owned or rented, the
process textile mill, however, accounts artisans transformed the raw goods into
were needed to synthesize information finished yarn or fabric. A merchant com-
about the cost of internal, administra- pensated an artisan according to market-
tively coordinated production activities.2 determined piece-rates, and he sold the
In 1931, D. R. Scott noted the conse- finished goods in open markets. Although
quence of factory developments for ac- the merchant kept accounts to record
counting in The Cultural Significance of past exchanges and to keep track of
Accounts: widely scattered inventories, obviously
Before the industrial revolution, accounting he did not need those accounts to provide
was mainly a record of the external relations information for decision-making and
of one business unit with other business units, and control.3 Market prices supplied all
a record of relations determined in the market. the managerial information he needed:
But with the advent of large scale productive
operations ... necessity arose for more em- namely, prices for finished goods and
phasis upon the accounting for interests prices for all the inputs going into his cost
within the competitive unit and upon the use of production. Input prices encompassed
of accounting records as a means of adminis- purchase prices of raw materials, market
trative control over the enterprise.... The
piece-rates paid to artisans, and market
appearance of cost accounts in manufacturing
. . . is [an] example [Scott, 1931, p. 143].
prices paid for inputs other than raw
materials and labor.
When it introduced a new mode of or- Market prices no longer supplied all
ganizing production, the modern factory the information needed for decision-
necessitated the development of a new making and control once merchant-
kind of accounting activity. entrepreneurs administered the coordi-
To understand why the early textile nation of textile-making processes in
factory's unique system of production centralized work places.4 In the domestic
required a new type of accounting infor- system, information about labor and
mation, consider the information re-
quired by merchants in the so-called 2 Loveday [1980] shows how managers used cost
"domestic" system, a market system that accounting information to coordinate multi-process
preceded the appearance of modern mills in the cut nail industry around 1870.
3 The Medici accounts, housed in the Baker Library
textile factories, pervaded economically at Harvard Business School, show how a pre-industrial
developed areas of Europe and North domestic organization could maintain excellent ac-
America, and coordinated textile produc- counts of external financial transactions and of physical
inventories but not require, apparently, cost accounts
tion as well as many other types of pro- per se. For a succinct discussion of the Medici accounts
duction [Pollard, 1965, p. 214; Holder- see Garner [1954, pp. 7-15].
4 In early proto-factories, such as Adam Smith's
ness, 1976, pp. 107-109; Wells, 1978, pp. famous pin factory, multiple processes could be central-
41, 44 and 46]. In general, the domestic ized without being coordinated administratively [Chap-
system consisted of merchants and arti- man, 1974]. Such organizations did not require cost
sans who coordinated the transformation records if all inputs, including labor, were paid at market
prices for output produced. Cost records became essen-
of raw materials into finished goods tial only after administrators assumed the task of coordi-
through autonomous market exchanges. nating the conversion of inputs into output.

This content downloaded from 185.44.78.143 on Sun, 15 Jun 2014 02:37:48 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Johnson 513

overhead conversion costs had been recording the pounds of cotton con-
automatically supplied to merchants by verted each day in processes such as
market prices. In the factory, because picking, carding, roving, spinning, warp-
wage contracts between employer and ing and weaving, and dyeing and finish-
employee were substituted for market ing. By combining data from these two
piece-rate contracts between merchant sets of records, it is possible to determine
and artisan, and because nonlabor con- the direct labor cost per unit of output by
version inputs were often supplied inter- process at least daily, although most
nally, managers found it necessary to firms seem to have reported this informa-
account for internal conversion costs. The tion once a month. Sometimes, more-
market wage they paid to workers, for over, these mills gathered periodic in-
instance, contained only part of the infor- formation about more than the direct
mation which managers needed to ascer- cost per unit of output for labor. For
tain labor conversion cost. The missing instance, they acquired information by
part of the information was, of course, process about direct cost per unit of out-
the worker's productivity during the time put for overhead items such as repairs,
he earned his wage. Whereas piece-rates maintenance, bleach, dyes, fuel, and
that automatically matched money and teaming.
output supplied the labor portion of It should be noted that the cost reports
conversion costs in the market-mediated just described were certainly an integral
domestic system, special accounts that part of the double-entry records [cf.
matched internally coordinated flows of Garner, 1954, ch. 6; Previts and Merino,
money and output were required to 1979, pp. 62-74]. Data on wages and
synthesize these labor conversion costs in other conversion expenses came from the
the administratively organized factory general accounts used to record the pay-
system. By making it necessary to account ment of liabilities. Furthermore, data on
for both labor and other conversion departmental flows of raw material quan-
costs, administrative coordination of tities were reconciled with physical in-
multiple processes in early textile factor- ventory counts every six months. Al-
ies thereby imposed internal cost ac- though these early textile mills did not
counting upon double-entry bookkeep- often keep perpetual inventory records
ing. as such, they did keep track of the weight
The earliest factory cost records so far of cotton flowing in and out of depart-
known to historians are from integrated, ments, and they kept an elaborate ac-
multi-process textile mills. This is true, count of cotton bales on order and
for instance, of the Charlton Mills in received.
England around 1800 [Stone, 1973]; it The managers of early textile mills used
applies to the Boston Manufacturing information from these nascent cost
Company by the 1820s [Porter, 1980];5 records to make short-run decisions and
and it is true of the Lyman Mills Com- to achieve control in the one aspect of
pany around 1850 [Johnson, 1972]. The their operation not governed by market
cost records in these firms indicate the exchange prices: namely, the conver-
labor portion of the conversion cost at sion of raw materials into finished goods.
each stage of a textile mill's production
cycle. Generally, these records include s Volumes 80, 84, and 90 of the Boston Manufacturing
Co. Payroll Records, filed in Baker Library at Harvard
both registers showing the daily or weekly University, indicate a shift from piece-rate to wage pay-
wages paid to workers and also log books ment around 1821.

This content downloaded from 185.44.78.143 on Sun, 15 Jun 2014 02:37:48 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
514 The Accounting Review, July 1981

Competitive market prices beyond the industrial organizations used double-


manager's control dictated, of course, entry systems to gather useful managerial
the exchange rates for finished goods, for cost information long before they used
raw materials, supplies, and the laborers' such systems to account for the costs of
time. The mill manager himself, however, long-lived assets.
could influence the rate at which laborers,
using other inputs, converted raw cotton III. COST ACCOUNTINGIN LATE NINE-
into yarn or fabric. Information from TEENTH-CENTURY, CAPITAL-INTENSIVE
accounts about the cost of that conver- MANUFACTURING FIRMS
sion activity aided the manager's task of Capital-intensive manufacturing oper-
evaluation and control. Such informa- ations conducted by the late 1800s in iron
tion included the conversion cost per and steel, foodstuffs, petroleum, chemi-
pound of output by department for each cals, machinery-making, and so forth,
worker and for each type of direct over- were vastly more complex and larger than
head expense. Moreover, correspondence were operations within the early nine-
between mill foremen and marketing teenth-century New England textile in-
officials in early cotton textile companies dustry. Nevertheless, at the end of the
indicates that they made short-run de- century most of these large manufactur-
cisions about special-order prices and ing organizations still conducted, as had
equipment modifications using contri- the early textile firms, only one basic
bution margin information that was activity: namely, the conversion of raw
derived from these direct conversion materials into finished goods [Chandler,
costs [Johnson, 1972, p. 474]. 1977, ch. 8]. It is plausible, therefore, that
Besides giving management short-run refined and elaborate versions of the
decision and control information, these conversion cost systems which originated
first cost accounts also provided incen- in early textile factories also supplied the
tives and controls that prevented em- management accounting information
ployee opportunism from dissipating the used to control operating activities in the
productivity gains inherent in mechan- giant descendants of the first textile mills.
ized, multi-process systems. Workers had And it is also possible that these capital-
a natural inclination, of course, to use intensive giants gave greater attention
their time efficiently when paid piece- than did early textile firms to the problem
rates; they had no automatic incentive to of allocating fixed costs to periods or to
pursue the same goal when being paid a products. Much research needs to be
wage. Managers of early textile mills done before we can say definitely how
could monitor employee performance managers of these giant organizations
with periodic cost information that com- used accounting information to adminis-
pared productivity among workers in the ter capital-intensive manufacturing ac-
same process at a specific time and that tivities during the late 1800s. Although
also compared productivity for one or accounting historians have assiduously
more workers over several periods of studied writings by late nineteenth-cen-
time [Chandler, 1977, p. 69]. The ca- tury authorities on cost accounting, they
pacity of managerial accounts such as have virtually ignored the managerial
these, then, to promote goal congruence accounting information actually used in
in a hierarchical system and to provide late nineteenth-century capital-intensive
cost information about internally-coordi- manufacturing firms.
nated processes clearly indicates that A glimpse into the use of management

This content downloaded from 185.44.78.143 on Sun, 15 Jun 2014 02:37:48 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Johnson 515

accounts by late nineteenth-century, capi- Carnegie then engaged in merciless price-


tal-intensive manufacturers is provided cutting during economic recessions.
in the accounting information used by While competing firms went under, he
one of the shrewdest entrepreneurs of still made profits. In periods of prosper-
that era, Andrew Carnegie. Historians ity, when customers' demands exceeded
[Krooss and Gilbert, 1972, p. 207] have the industry's capacity to produce, Car-
observed that Carnegie made a fetish of negie then joined others in raising prices.
using cost statements to manage his giant The information he had on his own and
steel company from 1872 to 1902. It his competitors' direct material and
seems surprising, therefore, that account- conversion costs also enabled Carnegie
ing historians have not described or to make rational investment decisions.
analyzed Carnegie's particular cost ac- The basic rule governing his investment
counting system. From brief descrip- decisions was to invest in new steel-
tions provided by Carnegie, by his making capacity whenever a new process
biographers, and by other historians, one appeared that offered lower direct costs
concludes that his system was not de- than did his present processes. In order
signed to account for fixed costs of long- to keep informed about the latest steel
lived assets [Wall, 1970, pp. 325-349, technology, Carnegie and his corps of
504-506, and 583-586; Livesay, 1975, highly trained experts travelled exten-
passim; Chandler, 1977, pp. 267-268]. sively in Europe and the United States.
What it did feature was a continuous When he decided, then, that a new invest-
gathering of data on all direct costs in ment embodied the lowest-cost technol-
every process of the manufacturing ac- ogy available, it was an informed de-
tivity, from blast furnace to rolling mill. cision. Moreover, his apparent reliance
With weekly data on direct material and on nothing more than differential direct
conversion costs for each process in his costs to evaluate long-term capital invest-
mills, Carnegie apparently had all the ment decisions was rational if one as-
accounting information he required in sumes that Carnegie believed the long-
order to invest more capital and to earn run demand for his product at his price
higher returns than any other steel- to be essentially infinite. Carnegie's
maker in the world before 1902. always bullish marketing attitude sug-
The only other financial information gests that he never thought otherwise.
which Carnegie seems to have relied Carnegie's example certainly demon-
upon to make both operating decisions strates that accounting easily kept pace
and investment decisions was informa- with the information needs of managers
about his competitors' direct production in large single-activity manufacturing
costs. Carnegie's operating strategy was concerns during the late 1800s. Historians
to push his own direct costs below those observe that accounting records used by
of all competitors so that he could managers of those capital-intensive
charge prices that would always ensure giants often gave inadequate attention
enough demand to keep his plants run- either to asset depreciation [Brief, 1965,
ning at full capacity. He therefore needed, pp. 21-30] or to full-absorption product
and got, frequent information showing costing [Chatfield, 1974, pp. 102 and
his direct costs in relation to those of his 160]. Nor did nineteenth-century indus-
competitors. With that information in trialists develop the forecasts or the
hand, and secure in the knowledge that return-on-investment data that one might
his costs were the lowest in the industry, expect a capital-intensive firm would need

This content downloaded from 185.44.78.143 on Sun, 15 Jun 2014 02:37:48 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
516 The Accounting Review, July 1981

[Johnson, 1975, pp. 448-449]. Appar- facturing costs to products [cf. Hudson,
ently, these single-activity organizations, 1977, p. 17]. This bias is evident in the
operating in the expansive market en- concern which accounting historians
vironment of late nineteenth-century show for: the integration of cost and
America, did not absolutely require financial accounts [Littleton, 1933, ch.
accounting information to select and 21; Garner, 1954, ch. 6; Chatfield, 1974,
plan investments. As Carnegie's case pp. 104-105, 159-160, and 162-163];
demonstrates, success often depended methods to cost inventories of goods
upon good information about direct finished and in process [Littleton, 1933,
operating costs. For that, accounting pp. 337-339; Garner, 1954, ch. 10;
systems mattered. For the rest, faith and Chatfield, 1971, p. 11]; procedures to
intuition sufficed. assign full costs of production to manu-
factured products [Littleton, 1933, ch.
IV. CONCLUSION 21; Chatfield, 1971, p. 12].
The records both of early nineteenth- The bias toward twentieth-century
century textile mills and of giant manu- financial reporting concepts of cost ac-
facturing firms operating later in the counting is also implicit in the conten-
century do not support the traditional tion of accounting historians that "true"
hypothesis that the increased use of fixed double-entry cost accounting did not
assets prompted the development of in- appear until very late in the nineteenth
dustrial cost accounting. Instead, the century, when accounting authorities
evidence seems to support the conclusion first wrote about integrated systems for
that changes in the way they organized costing products. Ironically, many of
economic activity, not just changes in the those authorities who wrote about prod-
temporal structure of their costs, uct costing from 1885 to 1914 were
prompted nineteenth-century industrial interested not in accounting, but rather
organizations to develop internal cost in estimating [Wells, 1978]. They were
accounting procedures. writing as engineers interested in de-
The definition of cost accounting used vising rational, uniform systems for
by most accounting historians "is nor- pricing unique products in non-competi-
mally reserved for integrated cost and tive markets. For this reason, they paid
financial accounting systems which in- attention to the problems of how to
volve the allocation of indirect and fixed allocate fixed costs to products in manu-
expenses" [Wells, 1977, p. 47].6 The facturing enterprises. They had no funda-
definition used in this paper is the mental interest in accounting per se.
equivalent of "direct costing," designed The evidence now available in com-
to provide financial information for pany records suggests that manufacturing
management decision-making and con- organizations used modern financial
trol. Although most historians clearly accounting procedures to account for the
distinguish between managerial and fi- costs of fixed assets only after the turn of
nancial uses of accounting information, the twentieth century [Johnson, 1975,
their commentaries on nineteenth-cen-
tury cost accounting practices show a 6 Although Littleton differentiated the prime cost
distinct bias toward those developments accounting information that early factories needed from
which foreshadowed the twentieth-cen- the cost allocation information that later capital-
intensive establishments needed, he reserved the title
tury concern for matching costs with "cost accounting" exclusively for the latter activity
realized revenue and for attaching manu- [Littleton, 1933, p. 322, last paragraph].

This content downloaded from 185.44.78.143 on Sun, 15 Jun 2014 02:37:48 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Johnson 517

pp. 448-49D Historians have not ascer- for American "superiority" might profit-
tained which businesses first used these ably search for differences in the way in
full cost procedures for financial report- which textile production was organized
ing purposes, nor have they explained in the two countries. Perhaps historians
what prompted the widespread adoption eventually will trace the difference be-
of such procedures after 1900. On closer tween English an'dAmerican accounting
study of actual company records, histori- procedures to the fact that American
ans may discover that legal reporting mills tended to be integrated, multi-
requirements, such as those embodied in process operations, whereas English
income tax statutes or in government con- mills, often much larger in size, tended to
tract regulations, caused the wide diffu- specialize in single processes [Mathias,
sion of financial accounting procedures 1969, p. 266]. Companies that specialize
for product costing. in one mechanical process do not need
The notion explored in this paper- accounting records to ascertain their
that the nonmarket coordination of costs; companies which integrate two or
economic activity necessitates the devel more processes in a continuous flow
opment of managerial cost accounting- cannot know their costs without such
can be used to explain more than just records. The so-called "failure" of nine-
the development of internal cost ac- teenth-century English textile companies
counting practices in nineteenth-century to adopt what are often considered as
manufacturing firms. By comparing how advanced American cost accounting pro-
various societies organize economic ac- cedures may have been a consequence of
tivity, historians may also gain valuable the effectiveness of market institutions in
insight into nineteenth- and twentieth- England. This very effectiveness would
century differences in cost accounting have made it beneficial for English mills
practice among nations [cf. Wells, 1977, to coordinate different production pro-
p. 52]. Nineteenth-century English cesses by means of market exchange.
writers, for instance, frequently remarked Effective market institutions, by elimi-
that England's textile industry paid less nating the economic advantages of ad-
attention to cost accounting than did ministratively coordinating different pro-
America's textile industry [Locke, 1979]. duction processes, made sophisticated
If that observation is correct, then his- internal cost accounting procedures un-
torians attempting to explain the reasons necessary.

REFERENCES
Brief, R. P. (1965), "Nineteenth Century Accounting Error," Journal of Accounting Research (Spring,
1965), pp. 12-31.
Chandler, A. D., Jr. (1977), The VisibleHand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business (Harvard
University Press, 1977).
Chapman, S. D. (1974), "The Textile Factory Before Arkwright: A Typology of Factory Development,"
Business History Review (Winter, 1974), pp. 451-478.
Chatfield, M. (1971), "The Origins of Cost Accounting," Management Accounting (June 1971), pp. 11 14,
(1974), A History of Accounting Thought(The Dryden Press, 1974).
Garner, S. P. (1954), Evolution of Cost Accounting to 1925 (University of Alabama Press, 1954).
Holderness, B. A. (1976), Pre-IndustrialEngland: Economy and Society, 1500 to 1750 (J. M. Dent and Sons,
Ltd., 1976).
Hudson, P. (1977), "Some Aspects of 19th Century Accounting Development in the West Riding Textile
Industry," Accounting History (November 1977), pp. 4-22.

This content downloaded from 185.44.78.143 on Sun, 15 Jun 2014 02:37:48 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
518 The Accounting Review, July 1981

Johnson, H. T. (1972), "Early Cost Accounting for Internal Management Control: Lyman Mills in the
1850's," Business History Review (Winter, 1972), pp. 466-474.
(1975), "The Role of Accounting History in the Study of Modern Business Enterprise," THE
ACCOUNTINGREVIEW(July 1975), pp. 444-450.
Krooss, H. E., and C. Gilbert (1972), American Business History (Prentice-Hall, 1972).
Littleton, A. C. (1933), Accounting Evolution to 1900 (American Institute Publishing Co., 1933).
Livesay, H. C. (1975), Andrew Carnegie and the Rise of Big Business (Little, Brown, and Company, 1975).
Locke, R. R. (1979), "Cost Accounting: An Institutional Yardstick for Measuring British Entrepreneurial
Performance, circa 1914," The Accounting Historians Journal (Fall, 1979), pp. 1-22.
Loveday, A. J. (1980), "Technology, Cost Accounting, and Management in the Cut Nail Industry of the
Upper Ohio Valley, 1865-1890," in P. J. Uselding, ed., Business and Economic History (University of
Illinois, 1980). pp. 41-50.
Mathias, P. (1969), The First Industrial Nation. An Economic History of Britain, 1700-1914 (Methuen &
Co., Ltd., 1969).
Pollard, S., (1965), The Genesis of Modern Management (Harvard University Press, 1965).
Porter, D. M. (1980), "The Waltham System and Early American Textile Cost Accounting, 1813-1848,'"
The Accounting Historians Journal (Spring, 1980), pp. 1-15.
Previts, G. J., and B. D. Merino (1979), A History of Accounting in America (The Ronald Press, 1979).
Scott, D R (1931), The Cultural Significance of Accounts (Henry Holt and Company, 1931).
Stone, W. E. (1 973), "An Early English Cotton Mill Cost Accounting System: Charlton Mills, 1810-1889,"
Accounting and Business Research (Winter, 1973), pp. 71-78.
Wall, J. F. (1970), Andrew Carnegie (Oxford University Press, 1970).
Wells, M. C. (1977), "Some Influences on the Development of Cost Accounting," The Accounting His-
torians Journal (Fall 1977), pp. 47-61.
(1978), Accounting for Common Costs (University of Illinois Center for International Research in
Accounting, 1978).

This content downloaded from 185.44.78.143 on Sun, 15 Jun 2014 02:37:48 AM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like