You are on page 1of 20

2006 Conyon 25

Executive Compensation and Incentives


Martin J. Conyon*

Executive Overview
The objective of a properly designed executive compensation package is to attract, retain, and motivate
CEOs and senior management. The standard economic approach for understanding executive pay is the
principal-agent model. This paper documents the changes in executive pay and incentives in U.S. firms
between 1993 and 2003. We consider reasons for these transformations, including agency theory, changes
in the managerial labor markets, shifts in firm strategy, and theories concerning managerial power. We show that
boards and compensation committees have become more independent over time. In addition, we demonstrate
that compensation committees containing affiliated directors do not set greater pay or fewer incentives.

Introduction compensation is the principal-agent model.6 The

E
xecutive compensation is a complex and con- theory maintains that firms seek to design the most
troversial subject. For many years, academics, efficient compensation packages possible in order to
policymakers, and the media have drawn atten- attract, retain, and motivate CEOs, executives, and
tion to the high levels of pay awarded to U.S. managers.7 In the agency model, shareholders set
chief executive officers (CEOs), questioning pay. In practice, however, the compensation com-
whether they are consistent with shareholder in- mittee of the board determines pay on behalf of
terests.1 Some academics have further argued that shareholders. A principal (shareholder) designs a
flaws in CEO pay arrangements and deviations contract and makes an offer to an agent (CEO/
from shareholders interests are widespread and manager). Executive compensation ameliorates a
considerable.2 For example, Lucian Bebchuk and moral hazard problem (i.e., manager opportunism)
Jesse Fried provide a lucid account of the mana- arising from low firm ownership. By using stock
gerial power view and accompanying evidence.3 options, restricted stock, and long-term contracts,
Marianne Bertrand and Sendhil Mullainathan too shareholders motivate the CEO to maximize firm
provide an analysis of the skimming view of CEO value. In other words, shareholders try to design
pay.4 In contrast, John Core et al. present an optimal compensation packages to provide CEOs
economic contracting approach to executive pay with incentives to align their mutual interests. This
and incentives, assessing whether CEOs receive is the contract approach to executive pay. Following
inefficient pay without performance.5 In this pa- Core, Guay, and Larcker,8 an efficient (or optimal)
per, we show what has happened to CEO pay in contract is one that maximizes the net expected
the United States. We do not claim to distinguish economic value to shareholders after transaction
between the contracting and managerial power costs (such as contracting costs) and payments to
views of executive pay. Instead, we document the employees. An equivalent way of saying this is that
pattern of executive pay and incentives in the . . . contracts minimize agency costs.
United States, investigating whether this pattern Several important ideas flow from this defini-
is consistent with economic theory. tion. First, the contract reduces manager oppor-
tunism and motivates CEO effort by providing in-
The Context: Who Sets Executive Pay? centives through risky compensation such as stock

B
efore examining the empirical evidence pre- options. Second, the optimal contract does not im-
sented in this paper, it is important to consider ply a perfect contract, only that the firm designs
the pay-setting process and who sets executive the best contract it can in order to avoid opportun-
pay. The standard economic theory of executive ism and malfeasance by the manager, given the
* Martin Conyon is an Assistant Professor of Management at the Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania. Contact: conyon@wharton.upenn.edu
26 Academy of Management Perspectives February

contracting constraints it faces.9 Third, in this ar- clined. The paper ends by offering some conclu-
rangement, the firm does not necessarily eliminate sions about whether the current pattern of exec-
agency costs, but instead evaluates the (marginal) utive pay and incentives in the United States is
benefits of implementing the contract relative to the consistent with economic theory.
(marginal) costs of doing so. Improvements in regu-
lation or corporate governance can possibly alter Executive Compensation

T
these costs and benefits, making different contracts here is substantial disclosure about U.S. exec-
desirable. Moreover, what is efficient at one point in utive compensation. The Securities and Ex-
time may not be at another. Improvements in board change Commission (SEC) expanded and en-
governance, for example by adding independent di- hanced disclosure rules for U.S. executives in
rectors, may lead to different patterns of compensa- 1992. As a result, the proxy statements of firms
tion, stock, and option contracts that are desirable (DEF 14A) contain considerable detail on stock
for one firm but not another.10 ownership, stock options, and all components of
An alternative theory is that CEOs set pay. compensation for the top five corporate execu-
This is the managerial power view, exemplified tives.12 The evidence on U.S. executive compen-
recently by Bebchuk and Fried.11 In this theory, sation provided here was extracted from Standard
the board and compensation committee cooperate and Poors (S&Ps) ExecuComp database, which
with the CEO and agree on excessive compensa- includes proxy-statement data for top executives
tion, settling on contracts that are not in share- in the S&P 500, S&P Mid-Cap 400, S&P Small-
holders interests. This excess pay constitutes an Cap 600, and other supplemental S&P indices.
economic rent, an amount greater than necessary We focus on CEO and non-CEO executives sep-
to get the CEO to work in the firm. The con- arately. We used information on share ownership,
straints the CEOs face are reputation loss and current and prior option grants, salaries, annual
embarrassment if caught extracting rents, what bonuses, benefits, and restricted stock awards, in
Bebchuk and Fried call outrage costs. Outrage order to observe component growth.
matters because it can impose on CEOs both There are four basic components to executive
market penalties (such as devaluation of a man- pay, each having been the subject of much re-
agers reputation) and social coststhe social search.13 First, executives receive a base salary,
costs come on top of the standard market costs. which is generally benchmarked against peer
They argue that market constraints and the social firms. Second, they enjoy an annual bonus plan,
costs coming from excessively favorable pay ar- usually based on accounting performance mea-
rangements are not sufficient in preventing con- sures. Third, executives receive stock options,
siderable deviations from optimal contracting. which represent a right, but not the obligation, to
This paper begins by demonstrating what has purchase shares in the future at some pre-specified
happened to executive pay in the United States. exercise price. Lastly, pay includes additional
The next section provides evidence on the growth compensation such as restricted stock, long-term
of executive pay and equity incentives in U.S. incentive plans, and retirement plans.
publicly traded firms between 1992 and 2003. Stock options are an important element of ex-
Specifically, we focus on the importance of stock ecutive pay and are valued at the firms cost of
and options and the link between pay and perfor- making the grant.14 Options are valued as the
mance. We consider explanations for why CEO economic cost to the firm of granting an option to
pay and incentives increased remarkably during an employee. This is the opportunity cost forgone
the 1990s. Then, the paper considers the gover- by not selling the option in the open market. A
nance of executive pay, especially the role of good approximation of this value is the price of
independent boards and compensation commit- the option given by the Black-Scholes (1973)
tees. We show that compensation committees formula.15 The value of a European call option
have become more independent over time and the paying dividends is: option value c Se-qt
fraction of affiliated directors on boards has de- N(d1) Xe-rt N(d2), where d1 {ln(S/X) (r
2006 Conyon 27

q 2/2)t}/t, d2 d1 t, where S is the stricted stock grants worth approximately $75 mil-
stock price; X the exercise price; t the maturity lion. These cases show that the way in which CEOs
term; r the risk-free interest rate; q the dividend are paid can differ across firms and that some pay
yield; the volatility of returns; and N(.) the packages are riskier than others. Options and stock
cumulative probability distribution function for a provide powerful incentives to focus on increasing
standardized normal variable. In general, options shareholder wealth. If a CEO is paid in options, then
granted to executives have an expected cost to the as the share price increases, the value of their hold-
company of about 30 to 40 percent of the fair ings also increases; if the share price declines, so too
market value of the stock. For instance, given does the CEOs wealth. Salaries, in contrast, are
some plausible assumptions about inputs, an op- unrelated to firm performance.
tion on a stock with face value of $100 has an As noted above, this paper examines the gen-
expected value of about $37.16 eral pattern of U.S. executive pay using the pop-
However, some of the assumptions underlying ulation of firms in the ExecuComp data set.20
the Black-Scholes method are unlikely to hold in Total CEO compensation is measured as salary,
practice, meaning that employees will value an bonus, long-term incentive payouts, the value of
option differently from the firm. Employees are stock options granted during the year (valued on
typically risk averse, undiversified, and may be the date of the grant using the Black-Scholes
disallowed from trading the options or hedging method), and other cash payments (including
their risk by selling short the company stock. In signing bonuses, benefits, tax reimbursements, and
consequence, they will place a lower value on the above-market earnings on restricted stocks). This
stock option compared to the Black-Scholes cost
is a flow measure of executive pay, capturing
to the company.17 This gap is an estimate of the
compensation received by the executive in a given
premium that firms must pay employees to accept
year. It is consistent with other executive pay
the risky option versus cash compensation. Firms
research.21 However, it is different from CEO
will want to make sure that the increase in exec-
wealth, which would include not only the value of
utive performance from using options exceeds this
stock and options granted during a given period,
premium.18 Understanding how employees value
but the value of previosuly granted options and
options is an important challenge for future com-
pensation research, especially since stock options other equity as well. The importance of CEO firm
are an increasingly significant component of pay.19 wealth in providing incentives is discussed below.
Before considering the general pattern of exec- Figure 1 plots the CEO pay distribution of
utive compensation, consider a few examples. ExecuComp firms in 2003.22 Average annual re-
Many CEOs, such as Jack Welch of General Elec- muneration is approximately $4.5 million, with a
tric, receive large pay awards. In 2000, he received median of $2.5 million. The distribution has two
total compensation of about $125 million, includ- important characteristics: considerable pay disper-
ing a $4 million salary, a $12.7 million bonus, $57 sion and a positive skew (hence the long right
million in options, and $48.7 million in restricted tail). This means that most CEOs earn relatively
stock grants. Welch managed a large and complex low compensation, and a few CEOs in the right
organization and, under his leadership, General tail receive excessively generous rewards. The no-
Electrics share price soared. However, in the wake tion that all CEOs receive stratospheric sums is
of U.S. corporate scandals, like Enron and Tyco, incorrect. It is possible to show the same effect in
even CEOs with stellar performance records have S&P 500 firms. Average annual remuneration for
faced criticism: the media censured Welch for CEOs in the S&P 500 firms was $9 million, with
alleged non-disclosure of lavish retirement bene- a median of $6.7 million in 2003. Total compen-
fits. Another example indicates a somewhat un- sation in S&P 500 firms is, of course, much higher
usual pay arrangement. In 2003, Steve Jobs of than firms in the entire ExecuComp dataset. This
Apple Computer received a salary of just $1 and reflects the well-known positive correlation be-
no annual bonus or options, instead receiving re- tween CEO pay and firm size. Larger firms require
28 Academy of Management Perspectives February

managers who are more talented, and therefore Table 2 shows the dollar value of the main
they award greater compensation.23 components of CEO (top panel) and non-CEO
Table 1 shows the total pay and the compo- (bottom panel) executives total compensation,
nents of total compensation of CEOs and other including base salary, options granted (using the
non-CEO top executives between 1993 and 2003. Black-Scholes value method), and restricted stock
Over the ten-year period, both CEO and non- granted. The base salary of CEOs has grown 2.6
CEO executive pay increased. In 2003, the me- percent per year, just under the rate of inflation.
dian pay for CEOs was $2.5 million, compared The noticeable increase in CEOs total compen-
with $1.3 million in 1993, a growth rate of 7.1 sation over the ten-year period can be attributed
percent per year. However, the means for these to increases in option grants and restricted stock.
years are $4.5 million and $2.0 million, respec- These have grown by 10.6 percent and 11.0 per-
tively, exhibiting the positive skew discussed ear- cent annually. The salary of non-CEO executives
lier. Overall, non-CEO executives earn approxi- increases slightly more, at 3.9 percent per year. For
mately 40 percent of the CEOs compensation. all years, CEOs earn a salary that is twice that of
Since 1993, the percentage of option pay has non-CEO executives. The non-CEO executives
increased, while the percentage of salary pay has also receive more stock options and restricted stocks,
decreased. Since 2001, restricted stock pay has which have grown 8.6 percent and 9.4 percent re-
become a more important component of CEO pay spectively. The empirical evidence suggests the
and options have become slightly less important. growth in total pay is due to an increase in option
Across all years, however, non-CEO executives and restricted stock compensation rather than salary.
receive a larger amount of their compensation These findings are partially consistent with contract
from salary than CEOs do, while CEOs receive a theory, which emphasizes incentive pay over sala-
larger amount of their compensation from options. ries. Alternatively, the evidence seems slightly less
In summary, the total pay growth rate for CEOs consistent with the managerial power theory, since
and other executives is about 7.0 percent annu- risk-averse managers would prefer cash compensa-
ally. Over time, salaries have become less impor- tion to more risky option compensation. In addition,
tant as a fraction of total pay, the annual bonus if managerial power were increasing over time, one
fraction has remained constant (approximately 20 might have expected to see greater growth in salaries
percent), and stock options and restricted stock as than the evidence here suggests. However, Bebchuk
a fraction of pay have increased. and Grinstein24 argue that, once one controls for
firm characteristics, both equity and non-equity pay
Figure 1
grew throughout this period. Since there is no sub-
The Distribution of CEO Compensation in S&P
stitution effect, they contend this is inconsistent
Firms, 2003
with contract theory. In summary, the evidence
from Tables 1 and 2 indicates that the total level of
CEO pay is increasing mainly due to stock option
grants.

Executive Incentives

W
e now turn to executive incentives and the
link between pay and firm performance.25
The evidence demonstrates that executive
compensation and the fraction of pay accounted
for by option grants increased during the 1990s.
Principal-agent theory predicts that a firm designs
contracts in order to yield optimal incentives,
Source: ExecuComp. Data plotted for variable TDC1 (total compen- therefore motivating the CEO to maximize share-
sation) with values less than $60 million. holder value. In designing the contract, the firm
2006 Conyon 29

recognizes the CEO is risk averse. Thus, imposing at odds with the notion that executive pay and
greater incentives requires more pay to compen- performance are decoupled.26 It is, however, con-
sate the agent for increased risk. In the previous sistent with other economic evidence, showing
section, the paper demonstrated that CEO pay has that the link between pay and performance has
increased. Next, we examine what has happened been increasing in the United States.27
to CEO incentives. The analysis shows that exec- Executives receive incentives from several
utives have considerable equity incentives that sources. They receive financial incentives from
create a strong and increasing link between CEO salary and bonus, as well as new grants of options
wealth and firm performance. This finding seems and restricted stock, which together measure flow

Table 1
Executive Compensation and its Components in the United States 19932003
Base Annual Option Restricted
Year N Total Pay Total Pay Salary Bonus Grants Stock Other
Median Mean
CEOs ($thous) ($thous) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%)
1993 1153 1258.8 2045.4 43.4 20.3 22.9 4.3 9.1
1994 1541 1255.9 2151.4 41.9 20.4 26.5 3.7 7.6
1995 1596 1311.6 2279.8 41.0 20.7 25.0 4.3 9.0
1996 1641 1587.6 3145.0 36.9 20.0 29.2 4.6 9.2
1997 1664 1923.3 3828.9 33.8 20.2 32.3 4.4 9.3
1998 1724 1962.9 4494.5 33.0 18.1 35.6 4.7 8.7
1999 1799 2188.4 5224.0 31.2 18.0 38.8 4.0 8.0
2000 1782 2443.5 6694.8 30.9 17.4 38.7 4.7 8.2
2001 1655 2527.0 6324.3 30.6 14.5 42.3 5.1 7.4
2002 1651 2604.8 4909.8 30.4 17.4 38.5 6.0 7.7
2003 1664 2498.6 4544.8 31.5 19.4 32.3 8.4 8.4
Annual Growth Rate (%) 7.1 8.3 3.2 0.5 3.5 6.9 0.8

Non-CEO Executives
1993 7177 478.0 777.8 49.9 18.9 19.7 3.5 8.0
1994 7486 508.3 852.9 47.7 19.4 22.3 3.2 7.5
1995 7715 528.8 913.9 47.2 19.5 20.9 3.6 8.8
1996 8193 618.2 1141.2 42.9 19.0 25.9 3.9 8.3
1997 8428 690.2 1388.1 40.3 19.2 28.5 3.9 8.1
1998 8695 730.7 1511.5 39.9 17.4 30.7 4.2 7.8
1999 8428 829.1 1931.2 37.5 17.7 33.9 3.6 7.3
2000 8010 922.5 2417.7 36.4 17.3 34.8 4.2 7.3
2001 7652 937.7 2094.0 37.0 15.1 36.6 4.3 6.9
2002 7490 940.9 1841.8 37.6 17.5 32.3 5.2 7.3
2003 7137 931.7 1651.6 38.3 18.4 28.2 7.1 8.0
Annual Growth Rate (%) 6.9 7.8 2.6 0.3 3.7 7.3 0.0
Source: ExecuComp
This table shows the total compensation of CEO and non-CEO executives between 1993 and 2003. Total pay is the sum of salary, bonus,
long-term incentive payouts, total value of stock options granted (using Black-Scholes), and other cash payments (includes compensation
such as signing bonuses, benefits, tax reimbursements, and above market earnings on restricted stocks). This is variable TDC1 in the
ExecuComp data set. Base salary is the percentage of an executives total compensation that is attributed to salary for a given year; bonus,
the percentage attributed to bonus; option grants, the percentage attributed to the value of options granted; restricted stock, the
percentage attributed to the value of restricted stock holdings granted.
30 Academy of Management Perspectives February

compensation. They also receive incentives from nomicsfocuses on compensation and equity
changes in their aggregate holdings of stock and incentives, leaving aside career concerns and the
options in the firm, as described in detail below. labor market for managerial talent. In other words,
Finally, the probability of termination because of it restricts attention to financial incentives.
poor performance gives the CEO an incentive to The key to understanding financial incentives
pursue strategies that maximize firm value. In this is recognizing that they arise from the entire port-
case, if terminated, an executive suffers reputation folio of equity holdings and not simply from cur-
loss and human capital devaluation in the mana- rent pay. Equity incentives, then, are the incen-
gerial labor market. However, this paper consis- tives to increase the stock price arising from the
tent with other recent research in financial eco- managers ownership of financial securities in the
Table 2
Value of Components of Executive Compensation in the United States 19932003
Option Grants Restricted Stocks
Base Salary ($thousands) ($thousands) ($thousands)
Year Median Mean Median Mean Median Mean
CEOs
1993 500.0 544.1 462.7 1057.7 328.9 762.7
1994 456.8 516.1 590.4 1312.0 333.3 726.6
1995 472.3 533.0 534.6 1277.5 389.5 822.1
1996 500.0 552.1 746.5 2093.1 440.2 1014.1
1997 519.8 567.6 931.3 2692.7 525.0 1339.3
1998 525.0 582.9 1108.9 3043.7 513.0 3315.2
1999 531.5 587.9 1341.3 4188.6 574.4 1675.6
2000 554.2 612.6 1547.3 5946.8 750.0 2177.7
2001 583.3 651.8 1765.4 5269.7 847.3 2211.8
2002 609.8 670.8 1546.0 3359.5 811.1 2296.6
2003 645.4 694.7 1268.2 2469.6 932.0 2383.5
Annual Growth Rate (%) 2.6 2.5 10.6 8.8 11.0 12.1

Non-CEO Executives
1993 208.8 242.9 162.9 367.6 107.4 302.4
1994 210.0 244.2 194.7 463.1 99.0 282.3
1995 217.0 252.3 179.1 465.6 123.3 319.4
1996 222.8 258.2 252.0 652.1 137.5 394.76
1997 228.0 266.2 297.0 890.4 147.2 536.4
1998 236.6 276.4 353.6 953.2 169.0 744.0
1999 247.5 289.4 425.5 1420.9 176.9 683.4
2000 257.3 304.0 465.6 1897.8 235.8 781.2
2001 273.0 319.0 516.2 1565.8 219.6 640.1
2002 287.3 333.3 443.3 1044.0 25.16 647.4
2003 306.7 354.5 372.7 791.7 262.8 678.0
Annual Growth Rate (%) 3.9 3.9 8.6 8.0 9.4 8.4
Source: ExecuComp.
This table shows the dollar value of the main components of CEO and non-CEO executives total compensation. The main components
include base salary, options granted (using the Black-Scholes value), and restricted stock granted. Growth rate is the average annual
growth over the ten-year period. Note that the median and means were calculated for each component only if the executive had the
component in a given year. For example, if an executive was not granted restricted stocks in a given year, his observation was not included
when calculating the summary statistics for restricted stocks that year.
2006 Conyon 31

firm.28 For example, a CEO may receive 100,000 the Black-Scholes method), and restricted hold-
options this year, which might add to 400,000 ings (the value of the restricted stock holdings at
options granted in previous years, for a total of the fiscal year end). In 2003, median CEO wealth
500,000 options held. If the stock price decreases, was approximately $22 million, whereas non-CEO
then the value of the 100,000 options granted this executive wealth was just under $4 million, indi-
year declines but so does the value of the op- cating that CEOs have more wealth in the firm
tions accumulated from previous years. Since the than other top executives. Agency theory predicts
CEO will care about the whole stock of 500,000 this result: an efficient contract will allocate more
options, not simply this years 100,000, executive incentives to individuals who have the greatest
compensation received in any given year provides impact on firm value. The results are consistent
only a partial picture of CEO wealth and incen- with CEOs critical roles in formulating and im-
tives. To understand CEO incentives fully, it is plementing firm strategy and change.35 In addi-
important to focus on the aggregate amount of tion to annual compensation, as shown earlier,
shares, restricted stock, and stock options that the the wealth distribution of CEOs and non-CEO
CEO owns in the firm. executives is right-skewed. For instance, average
The analysis begins by noting that the CEOs CEO wealth is about $128 million compared to
wealth from ownership of firm equity is the value the median of $22 million. CEO and non-CEO
of the CEOs stock and option portfolio. We cal- executive wealth had similar growth rates over the
culate the wealth as the value of shares and re- period of 9.1 percent and 9.4 percent each year,
stricted stock plus the Black-Scholes value of the respectively. Additionally, the value of options
aggregate amount of stock options owned. Follow- has increased significantly, with an average an-
ing Core and Guay,29 executive portfolio incen- nual growth rate around 15 percent each year for
tives are defined as the dollar change in the value both groups, once again illustrating the impor-
of the CEOs stock and option portfolio arising tance of options in driving changes in executive
from a one percent change in the stock price.30 compensation.
This equity stake measure31 defines incentives as How does the estimate of CEO wealth change
the dollar change in managerial wealth from a 1 as the stock price changes? To illustrate, consider
percent increase in shareholder wealth and can be the incentives of the median CEO in 2003. CEO
written as the following: 1% (share price) wealth from owning firm stock and options is
(the number of shares held) 1% (share approximately $22.2 million, about nine times
price) (option delta) (the number of options greater than current flow pay (from Table 1,
held).32 Notice that by focusing on equity incen- roughly $2.5 million). CEO incentives total ap-
tives, we are ignoring the incentives arising from proximately $287,000. If the stock price at this
salary and annual bonus awards. Research shows CEOs firm fell by 10 percent, his portfolio wealth
that the correlation between salary, bonus, and would decrease in value by $2.87 million. This
stock price performance is low, suggesting these $2.87 million decline is greater than median CEO
elements of flow compensation contribute little to compensation in this year ($2.5 million) indicat-
aggregate equity incentives.33 ing that half of CEOs would lose more than an
Table 3 provides preliminary estimates of entire years pay. The important point to stress is
wealth and incentives34 for the set of ExecuComp that executive wealth can decline precipitously as
firms. It shows the value of shares owned, the the stock price falls.36 It seems that relative to
value of all options, total wealth, and equity in- flow compensation, the incentives received by
centives of CEO and non-CEO executives be- CEOs in the form of stock and options are con-
tween 1993 and 2003. Wealth is defined as the siderable.
value of an executives equity portfolio. Also in- The evidence shows that CEOs have plenty of
cluded are stock owned (calculated as the number financial incentives, arising primarily from CEO
of shares owned times the value of the stock at the ownership of stock and options in their firms.
fiscal year end), value of options (calculated using Again, we would stress that such financial incen-
32 Academy of Management Perspectives February

tives are only one factor motivating executives. principal. In a classic paper, Steven Kerr37 high-
Agents are as likely to be motivated by intrinsic lighted the folly of rewarding A while hoping for
factors of the job, career concerns, social norms, B. In short, he articulated the notion that one gets
tournaments, and the like. One problem with what one pays for. If one rewards activity A and
stock options and other forms of incentive pay is not B, then people will exert effort on A, while
not that they provide too few incentives, but that de-emphasizing B. Kerr illustrates his point with
they may lead to unintended consequences. It is an array of examples from politics, industry, and
well known that incentives can bring about be- human resource management. In general, this is a
havior by the agent that was unanticipated by the problem of providing appropriate incentives to

Table 3
Wealth and Incentives of Executives in the United States 19932003
Value of options Incentives
Equity ($millions) ($millions) Wealth ($millions) ($thousands)
Year Median Mean Median Mean Median Mean Median Mean
CEOs
1993 4.8 56.9 2.1 5.3 9.3 63.0 121.9 662.5
1994 4.2 43.5 2.0 5.5 8.9 49.4 112.5 523.9
1995 4.8 58.8 2.5 7.4 10.5 67.1 134.6 714.1
1996 5.6 70.7 3.5 10.5 12.9 82.4 165.0 882.4
1997 6.9 101.5 5.2 15.5 17.9 120.3 230.8 1284.6
1998 6.5 138.5 4.7 19.2 17.1 161.7 217.3 1704.6
1999 6.9 177.6 5.1 29.8 18.8 211.7 243.4 2208.0
2000 5.7 125.1 6.4 29.1 18.5 155.8 234.9 1660.2
2001 5.5 109.4 7.7 22.8 19.8 133.7 255.8 1440.7
2002 4.4 94.6 6.1 16.4 16.4 112.4 217.0 1213.4
2003 6.1 103.4 9.1 22.6 22.2 128.0 287.4 1404.3
Annual Growth Rate (%) 2.4 6.2 15.8 15.6 9.1 7.3 9.0 7.8

Non-CEO executives
1993 0.4 5.5 0.5 1.5 1.5 7.2 19.9 80.1
1994 0.3 4.7 0.5 1.5 1.3 6.3 17.0 72.1
1995 0.3 6.2 0.6 2.1 1.5 8.5 20.8 98.0
1996 0.4 7.9 0.9 2.8 1.9 11.0 26.5 125.8
1997 0.5 10.0 1.2 4.2 2.5 14.7 34.3 168.3
1998 0.5 12.9 1.1 4.7 2.4 18.0 32.7 202.3
1999 0.5 15.1 1.3 7.6 2.7 23.3 36.7 256.7
2000 0.4 16.7 1.5 7.5 2.9 24.7 38.2 275.0
2001 0.5 14.6 1.8 5.9 3.1 21.0 41.3 238.0
2002 0.4 10.6 1.4 4.2 2.4 15.2 33.0 175.9
2003 0.6 12.4 2.1 5.6 3.7 18.5 49.8 216.5
Annual Growth Rate (%) 4.1 8.5 15.4 14.1 9.4 9.9 9.6 10.5
Source: ExecuComp
This table shows the equity, value of options, wealth, and incentives of CEO and non-CEO executives between 1993 and 2003. It relates
to holdings in their own firm. Equity is the value of stocks owned (calculated as the number of shares owned times the value of the stock
at the fiscal year end). Value of options is the value of exercised and unexercised stock options (calculated using the Black-Scholes
equation). Wealth is the value of a CEOs portfolio, which includes equity, options, and restricted holdings. Incentives are defined as 1
percent change in the value of the portfolio (stocks options are weighted by the delta of the option). The growth rate is the growth of
components over the ten-year period.
2006 Conyon 33

agents engaging in multiple tasks.38 More re- the optimal amount of incentives given to the
cently, Robert Gibbons has discussed the design of CEO are increasing in the (marginal) productivity
incentive programs recognizing such problems.39 of the agent.45 If CEOs become more productive,
Another problem with incentive compensation or labor services relatively scarce, then optimal
is that it may encourage opportunistic behavior by CEO incentives increase. Similarly, agency theory
managers, manipulation of performance measures, predicts the use of more incentives if agents are
or cheating. The powerful and often unantici- less risk-averse. If CEO risk tolerance falls over
pated effects of financial incentives on economic this period, this might also contribute to increases
outcomes have been documented in diverse con- in incentives. Standard agency theory, however,
texts such as classroom teaching, real estate mar- predicts an inverse relationship between incen-
kets, vehicle inspection markets, and the behavior tives and the variation in firm performance. This
of physicians.40 In the corporate context, David relationship is the incentive-risk trade-off. How-
Yermack demonstrates that CEOs opportunisti- ever, studies often show a positive relation be-
cally time the award of option grants around earn- tween incentives and firm risk (see below). In
ings announcements in order to increase their addition, Prendergasts46 review of the empirical
compensation.41 Other studies find that private literature shows that the trade-off between incen-
information is used by executives to engineer ab- tives and risk is tenuous. He develops a contract
normally large option exercises and hence the model that reconciles the theory with the empir-
payouts from those options. In addition, studies ical evidence, showing incentives are provided in
show that firms with more incentives are associ- more risky environments when authority is dele-
ated with greater earnings manipulation.42 Recent gated to the agent. In addition, the standard
studies show that the likelihood of a firm being agency model predicts greater expected compen-
the target of fraud allegations is positively corre- sation when incentives are greater. This increase
lated with option incentives.43 In short, options is required to compensate the CEO for the impo-
and incentive pay may motivate managerial be- sition of greater risk and the increased effort in-
havior that is not always anticipated or ideal. duced by higher incentives. Suppose that efficient
When designing compensation plans, boards must contracting requires an increase in CEO incen-
be aware of the unwanted as well as beneficial tives over time. This would lead to an increase in
effects of incentives. risk borne by the CEO. Given that both incen-
tives and compensation increased in the 1990s,
this trend is consistent with the agency model. If
Explanations for Changes in compensation had increased without an increase
U.S. Compensation in incentives, it would have indicated problems

T
he empirical evidence suggests fundamental with pay setting.47
shifts in compensation and incentives. Incen- The second potential explanation for changes
tive pay such as stock options have increased in U.S. executive compensation is related to shifts
in importance. What accounts for these changes? in the managerial labor market. Changes in the
The answers are complex, varied, and the subject demand and supply of managerial talent can have
of contemporary research. Therefore, this section profound effects on executive pay. An increase in
simply outlines some important candidate expla- the demand for skilled CEOs will increase com-
nations, centering on agency explanations, the pensation. Himmelberg and Hubbard48 argue that
managerial labor market, the board of directors, the supply of highly skilled CEOs who are capable
technological shocks driving corporate strategy of running large complex firms is relatively inelas-
and change, misperceptions about stock options, tic; therefore, shocks to aggregate demand in-
and managerial power and rent extraction.44 crease both the value of the firm as well as the
The first potential explanation for changes in marginal value of the CEOs labor services to the
compensation and incentives is due to principal- firm. They show that, in equilibrium, such shocks
agent theory. A standard agency model shows that lead to greater executive compensation. Murphy
34 Academy of Management Perspectives February

and Zabojnik49 present a theoretical model ex- this response, the CEOs equilibrium utility will
plaining CEO pay based on changes in the relative have decreased; thus, he will demand more com-
importance of general and specific managerial pensation for this decrease. Therefore, Hermalin
capital. General managerial capital (such as develops a theory that more-diligent boards will
knowledge of finance, accounting, or manage- have CEOs who receive a greater compensation to
ment of human capital) is valuable and transfer- explain the trend in recent years of an increase in
able across companies, whereas specific manage- both independent directors on compensation
rial capital skills (such as knowledge of firm committees and CEO pay.
suppliers or clients, etc.) are only valuable within The fourth explanation for changes in execu-
the organization. In their model, the firm decides tive compensation is a shift in corporate strategy
whether to fill a CEO vacancy by choosing an brought about by technology and other environ-
incumbent or external candidate. A company hir- mental shocks. As firms adapt to or change with
ing externally forgoes valuable firm-specific skills their environment, different compensation con-
but selects from a larger set of managers allowing tracts may become necessary. Dow and Raposo52
better matching of managers to firms. Firms will develop a contracting model demonstrating the
increasingly appoint external CEO candidates as link between corporate strategy and CEO com-
general managerial capital becomes increasingly pensation, predicting greater executive compensa-
valuable relative to firm-specific managerial capi- tion in highly changeable environments. Dra-
tal. Labor market competition for talent, espe- matic corporate change has abounded in the
cially for CEOs with general transferable skills, United States since the 1980s. Major U.S. indus-
then determines CEO pay. Murphy and Zabojnik
tries were deregulated, and fundamental techno-
argue that general managerial skills have become
logical developments led to pressure for U.S. firms
more important in the modern firm, driving up
to reconsider their corporate strategies and fo-
pay. Empirically, they show external CEO hires as
cus.53 These developments acted as important cat-
a percentage of all CEO appointments increased
alysts behind the merger, restructuring, and take-
from 15 percent in the 1970s to 27 percent during
over waves of the 1980s and 1990s.54 For example,
the 1990s. In addition, external appointments to
the value of U.S. mergers and acquisitions as a
the CEO position receive a compensation premi-
umand this premium has increased during the percentage of GDP has been increasing since the
1990s. 1970s.
The third explanation for changes in U.S. ex- The Dow and Raposo paper55 outlines a model
ecutive compensation is the growth of more dili- where the CEO has discretion over the firms
gent boards. Recently, there has been an increase strategy, and that different strategies require dif-
in theoretical research on boards of directors.50 In ferent levels of effort. For example, a strategy for
the context of CEO, pay one might initially be- dramatic change would require more effort than
lieve that more diligent boards would award lower maintaining the status quo. To extract a greater
compensation, but this is only the case if pay is surplus from shareholders, CEOs select excessively
excessive. Benjamin Hermalin51 provides a model ambitious strategies whose success depends
to explain trends in corporate governance. Be- heavily on their own performance. Greater incen-
cause the percentage of outsiders on compensa- tives result in overly dramatic strategy choices.
tion committees is increasing (see the evidence in Anticipating this distortion, shareholders could
the next section), we can conclude that boards are commit to handing over large pay packages at the
becoming more diligent. Hermalin theorizes that outset. Dow and Raposo show that, in highly
the more diligent a board is, the more likely it will changeable environments, where dramatic strate-
be to monitor the CEO (seek information about gic change is possible and CEOs are better in-
his ability). This, in turn, will give the CEO formed about strategy than the shareholders, such
incentives (directly proportional to board dili- a contract may be optimal for shareholders. The
gence) to work harder in equilibrium. Because of model helps interpret the 1990s as a period of
2006 Conyon 35

great corporate change where firms committed to whether CEOs are selecting the right actions. The
high CEO compensation. argument suggests that monitoring technology
Inderst and Mueller56 also link strategy to com- and equity incentives are substitute instruments
pensation by addressing how to induce a CEO to used to achieve the firms goals. Several studies
reveal information to shareholders. They articu- show that firms with growth opportunities have
late that the firm should alter its corporate strat- greater equity incentives.58 Demsetz and Lehn59
egy especially if the change in strategy leads to also argue that more risky and uncertain environ-
the dismissal of the incumbent CEO. In their ments require greater incentives, because share-
model, the firm faces a decision between change holder-monitoring costs increase. Rather than en-
and continuation of its current strategy, which during the greater monitoring costs to determine if
in turn depends on the firms business environ- the CEO has taken the right actions, shareholders
ment (the state of nature). In low states of instead use equity incentives to motivate manag-
nature, the firms expected future profits under the ers. If the firms operating environments have
continuation strategy are low, meaning become more uncertain, or growth opportunities
change is optimal. In high states of nature, con- more valuable, we would expect to see incentive
tinuation is optimal. In practice, the CEO typi- pay becoming more prevalent.
cally knows the ideal strategy before others. Be- The fifth explanation for changes in executive
cause the CEO is likely to favor the continuation compensation is misperceptions about the cost
strategy, even when change is optimal, the trick is and value of options. Murphy60 develops the per-
to get the CEO to reveal private information. ceived cost hypothesis to explain the growth in
Inderst and Mueller derive an optimal contract executive pay. The accounting treatment of U.S.
that consists of options, a base wage, and sever- options during the 1990s means it was effectively
ance pay. The role of severance pay is to encour- free for boards to grant them to executives since
age the CEO to reveal information that might cost no cost appears in the profit and loss account. The
the CEO his job. When deciding between con- perceived cost to the board is less than the
tinuation and change strategies, the CEOs economic cost of the option measured by its
tradeoff is on-the-job pay (i.e., options) against Black-Scholes value. In addition, as we showed
severance pay. The optimal on-the-job pay earlier, a risk-averse and non-diversified employee
scheme is one that minimizes the amount of sev- will value an option less than its economic cost.
erance pay required to select the change strategy According to Jensen et al.,61 this means too many
in low states of nature when change is the best options are granted to too many people, and op-
choice. Inderst and Mueller show that, as the tions with favorable accounting treatment will be
likelihood that change is desirable for the firm preferred to better incentive plans with less favor-
increases, there will be increases in the size of the able accounting treatment.
option grant, as well as the severance pay. More- The final explanation for the growth in exec-
over, the likelihood that change will happen also utive compensation is the managerial power hy-
increases. The model is therefore consistent with pothesis. Bebchuk and Fried62 develop a model
major governance events of the 1990s, such as the where CEOs control the pay-setting process, sug-
large increases in executive compensation, the gesting managerial power and rent extraction are
increased frequency of forced CEO turnovers, and occurring. For example, research has indeed dem-
dramatic corporate change. onstrated that CEO pay is greater when boards are
Other research has also argued that incentives weak.63 A board is weak or powerless if it is too
and firm growth opportunities are positively re- large, and therefore it is difficult for directors to
lated. Smith and Watts57 argue that the existence oppose the CEO, or if the CEO has appointed the
and prevalence of growth opportunities (or the outside directors, who are beholden to the CEO
firms investment opportunity set) make it diffi- for their jobs. In addition, it is weak when direc-
cult for owners to know the correct value maxi- tors serve on too many other boards, making them
mizing strategies. In addition, they are uncertain too busy to be effective monitors. Finally, it is
36 Academy of Management Perspectives February

weak if the CEO is also chair of the board, since mance (or reduced-windfall options) is incom-
conflicts of interest arise. When board governance plete. In part, this is because management lobbied
is poor, excess pay as an agency cost is to be against expensing options and did not exert effort
expected. However, during the 1990s boards be- to get non-expensing for indexed options.67 In
came less weak because boards increasingly added addition, not only is explicit indexing in compen-
independent directors and strengthening gover- sation contracts rare, studies also find little evi-
nance arrangements. In these circumstances, rent dence of relative performance evaluation in the
extraction becomes less, not more, likely.64 estimated relationship between pay and perfor-
Bebchuk and Fried also claim that important mance.68 However, this may not be due to man-
features of stock option plans are inconsistent agerial power. For instance, more complicated
with optimal contracting and reflect managerial agency models suggest the value of a CEOs hu-
power. Simple agency models predict that the man capital changes with market fortunes. If so,
market component of firm performance be re- CEO compensation also moves with the market.
moved from the CEOs compensation package Specifically, Paul Oyer69 develops a model where
since CEO actions do not influence the market, it is optimal to pay the CEO for industry level
incentives are not improved, and the pay contract performance if that sector performance is corre-
is riskier.65 Such market indexing is called rela- lated with the CEOs outside opportunities. In
tive performance evaluation. Bebchuk and Fried addition, recent empirical evidence shows that
argue that, since option contracts lack explicit this hypothesis has validity.70
relative performance evaluation, executives re- The managerial power theory advanced by Beb-
ceive windfall gains as market value increases. In chuk and Fried and Bebchuk and Grinstein also
short, they are paid for observable luck, not their provides a potential explanation for why pay has
performance or skill. The typical stock option changed over the recent decade. One reason for
plan does not explicitly filter out general stock the growth in executive pay is the increased ac-
price increases that are attributable to market or ceptance by shareholders of equity-based compen-
industry trends and therefore unconnected to the sation. This enabled the compensation plan de-
executives own performance. This means that, in signers (the board and compensation committees)
rising markets, the value of a CEOs options in- to take advantage of this willingness to provide
creases even if firm performance is worse than the large payoffs to executives. They also argue that
market. the bull market made investors more forgiving and
Using indexed options would be one way to weakened constraints on pay allowing it to grow.
explicitly introduce relative performance evalua- Bebchuk and Grinstein also argue that during this
tion into the contract66 and provide incentives at period the barriers to takeovers increased. Manag-
lower cost. However, the lack of indexed options ers became more entrenched and enjoyed greater
and the near ubiquity of so-called fixed price op- compensation. These power explanations for the
tions, where the fixed exercise price of the option growth in pay contrast with other economic based
grant is usually set equal to the stock price, does explanations. A challenge for future research is to
not necessarily reflect managerial power. Instead, distinguish between the competing theories to
the accounting treatment of options in the last explain the growth in executive pay.
decade means that indexed options would attract
an accounting charge. Thus, faced with a decision The Governance of Executive Pay

C
to use a potentially superior option that would ontract theory shows that pay can ameliorate
decrease costs, versus using a standard fixed price the agency problem by providing incentives
option, which attracts no charge, firms choose the that motivate managers to optimize the long-
latter. This choice is not necessarily because of term value or earnings potential of the firm. How-
managerial power, but because of an accounting ever, if the CEO controls the contracting process
anomaly. However, Bebchuk and Fried argue the then, as Bebchuk and Fried have argued, compen-
accounting explanation for lack of relative perfor- sation can be part of the problem rather than the
2006 Conyon 37

solution. It is impossible to evaluate whether pay As such, perquisites are not managerial excess, but
outcomes are optimal without better understand- instead form part of the complex contracting be-
ing the pay-setting process. In this section, we dig tween the CEO and the board. In contrast, Yer-
a bit deeper into what boards and compensation mack75 focuses on the use of company planes. He
committees do to shed light on that relationship. shows that when the use of aircraft is disclosed
The job of the board is to hire, fire, and com- publicly to shareholders, there is a drop in stock
pensate the CEO.71 When appointing the CEO, prices of about one percent. The optimal provi-
the board can choose to offer him an explicit sion of pension and perquisite arrangements in
employment contract or not (and, if not, the firms promises to be an important topic for future
contract is implicit). Gillan et al.72 and Schwab research.
and Thomas71 describe the characteristics of ex-
plicit employment contracts. These contracts Compensation Committees and Executive Pay

A
specify the CEOs salary, bonus, and incentive potential problem with pay arrangements
(option) package. The employment contracts typ- highlighted by the managerial power theory is
ically have a fixed duration. They are not so- that compensation committees are inefficient.
called employment-at-will contracts, but are This section evaluates the effectiveness of this
typically 2-to-3 year renewable. The contracts usu- committee. Specifically, what incentives does the
ally contain information about termination proce- committee face to promote shareholder interests?
dures, and provisions and non-compete and arbitra- Do compensation committee member incentives
tion clauses. Schwab and Thomas73 show that align with shareholders or, as managerial power
employment contracts generally do not contain re- theorists predict, with managers? Conyon and
strictions on the CEOs ability to hedge stock op- He76 explicitly test the effectiveness of compen-
tions. In addition, the employment contract con- sation committees using three-tier agency theory77
tains information about perquisites (such as and contrast it to a managerial power model. At
company car, country club membership, pension the heart of the three-tier agency model is the idea
advice, company aircraft, and spouse travel). Gil- that shareholders (the principal) delegate moni-
lan et al. show that less than half of S&P 500 toring authority to a separate supervisor (e.g., a
CEOs have explicit contracts; the rest have im- compensation committee) who evaluates the
plicit contracts. They demonstrate that contract agent (e.g., CEO). Whether the supervisor will
theory explains whether the employment contract work in the principals best interest, or instead
is explicit or not. For example, the contract is more collude with the agent, is dependent on whether
likely to be explicit when there is greater potential the supervisors interests are more tightly related
for opportunistic behavior post-contracting by the with those of shareholders (principal) or manage-
firm, where the CEO is making large firm-specific ment (agent). The value of the three-tier agency
investments or where there are greater informa- model is that it focuses attention on the supervi-
tion asymmetries between the parties. sors incentives to promote shareholder welfare.
We showed earlier that boards and compensa- To test the model, Conyon and He78 use data on
tion committees furnish CEOs with important 455 U.S. firms that went public in 1999. The
incentives via stock and options. The evidence on study finds support for the three-tier agency
explicit CEO contracts documented by Gillan et model. The presence of significant shareholders
al. and Schwab and Thomas shows that boards on the compensation committee (i.e., those with
consider other elements of compensation, such as share stakes in excess of 5 percent) is associated
pensions and perquisites. Rajan and Wulf74 di- with lower CEO pay and higher CEO equity in-
rectly address whether perquisites represent man- centives. Firms with higher paid compensation
agerial excess. They use proprietary data on a committee members are associated with greater
number of company perquisites and conclude that CEO compensation and lower incentives. The
firms offer perquisites in situations where they are managerial power model receives little support.
most likely to facilitate managerial productivity. They find no evidence that insiders or CEOs of
38 Academy of Management Perspectives February

other firms serving on the compensation commit- mittees to which a director belongs, board affilia-
tee raise the level of CEO pay or lower CEO tion, demographic characteristics, and other infor-
incentives. mation. Table 4 shows board and compensation
A number of other studies have addressed the committee composition by year. The IRRC clas-
effectiveness of compensation committees as well. sifies a directorship as either Employee,
The balance of evidence suggests that the compo- Linked, or Independent. A linked director is
sition of the committee does not lead to severe a director who is linked to the company through
agency problems. Studies show that executive pay certain relationships, and whose views may be
is no greater if compensation committees contain affected because of such links, for example a
affiliated directors.79 Compensation committees, former employee.84 A director is independent if
though, have mixed effects on executive incen- elected by the shareholders and not affiliated with
tives. Anderson and Bizjak80 and Vafeas81 find no the company. In 2003, 18 percent of directors are
evidence that CEO incentives are lower when employees, 13 percent are linked directors, and 69
affiliated directors are on the compensation com- percent are independent directors. The percent-
mittee. However, Newman and Mozes82 conclude age of independent directors has been increasing
that pay for performance is more favorable to the annually, coinciding with a decrease in the num-
CEO when the compensation committee contains ber of employees and linked affiliated directors on
insiders. In addition, Conyon and Peck83 show the the board. Boards, then, are becoming more inde-
link between pay and performance is greater in pendent over time. The lower part of the table
firms adopting compensation committees. focuses on those members of the board of directors
We use the Investor Responsibility Research who are part of the compensation committee.
Center (IRRC) Directors database to further test Compensation committees are becoming more in-
the efficiency of compensation committees be- dependent over time as well. The percentage of
tween 1998 and 2003. The data is of annual affiliated directors on the committee fell from 12.8
frequency and covers board members of the S&P percent in 1998 to 7.7 percent in 2003, and at the
500, S&P MidCap, and S&P SmallCap firms. The same time independence increased.
dataset includes information on the board com- One can hypothesize that affiliated directors

Table 4
Directors in the Investor Responsibility Research Center (IRRC) Data Set
Director Type on Board of Directors 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003
Director Type Employee (%) 22.3 21.9 21.8 21.3 19.7 18.4
Director Type Linked/affiliated (%) 17.4 17.3 16.6 15.7 13.9 12.8
Director Type Independent (%) 60.3 60.8 61.6 63.0 66.4 68.8
Total 17,048 17,420 16,675 16,669 13,499 13,792

Directors on the Compensation 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003


Committee by Director Type
Director Type Employee (%) 1.4 1.7 1.4 1.3 0.7 0.4
Director Type Linked/affiliated (%) 12.8 12.8 11.9 11.5 9.4 7.7
Director Type Independent (%) 85.8 85.6 86.7 87.2 90.0 91.9
Total number of directors on 6,238 6,375 6,088 6,165 5,085 5,188
Compensation Committee
Table 4 (upper part) shows the composition of the board of directors for firms by year. A director is considered an employee if he is
currently working for the firm, considered independent if he is elected by shareholders, having no affiliation with the firm, and considered
linked if he is affiliated with the company in such a way that his views may be biased and unfavorable to shareholders for example, a
former employee or a person providing professional services to the firm. Table 4 (lower part) includes only members of the board of
directors who are part of the compensation committee (therefore firms without a compensation committee are excluded), showing the
percentage of each director type composing compensation committees.
2006 Conyon 39

are more likely to set contracts that are more larger firms require more talented managers,88
favorable to CEOs relative to shareholders. For who themselves are relatively wealthy compared
example, one might predict that CEO compensa- to managers in smaller firms.89 In addition, Core
tion would be greater and that the CEO would and Guay90 argue that owners find it more difficult
receive fewer incentives when the compensation to monitor managers in larger firms and so are
committee contains affiliated directors. Such em- more likely to use equity incentives as a substitute
pirical evidence would be consistent with the for monitoring. The results in Table 5 confirm this
managerial power perspective. To test this we prediction and are consistent with other studies
performed some simple fixed-effects pay regres- also showing a positive relation between incen-
sions. We defined an independent binary variable tives and firm size.91
equal to one if the compensation committee con-
tains any affiliated directors and zero, otherwise. Conclusions

E
The measure is consistent with previous re- xecutive compensation is a controversial and
search.85 The regression results are contained in complex subject that continues to attract the
Table 5. The results show that, after controlling attention of the media, policymakers, and aca-
for firm size, performance, macroeconomic shocks, demics. Contract theory predicts that sharehold-
and unobserved firm heterogeneity, there is no ers use pay to provide incentives for the CEO to
relation between CEO pay and a compensation focus on maximizing long-term firm value. Since
committee containing affiliated directors. The co- CEOs have relatively low ownership of firm
efficient of interest (affiliated compensation com- shares, they might otherwise behave opportunis-
mittee) is negative and insignificant in both re- tically. An alternative theoretical perspective, the
gressions, indicating no effect on total CEO managerial power view, is that CEOs control the
compensation or incentives. The results are con- pay-setting process and set their own pay. This
sistent with the findings of Anderson and Bijack86 theory predicts that compliant compensation
and Daily et al.,87 who also find no relation be- committees and boards provide CEOs with excess
tween measures of CEO compensation and the pay (or compensation rents) and that contracts
composition of the compensation committee. The are suboptimal from the shareholders perspective.
relation between incentives and firm size is also Distinguishing between these two theories is an
interesting. We expect firm size to relate posi- important challenge for future research.
tively to dollar equity incentives. This is because This paper provides evidence on what has hap-

Table 5
Compensation Committee Structure and CEO Pay
Log Log
Dependent variable log(total compensation) (CEO compensation) (CEO incentives)
Affiliated compensation committee (1) 0.008 0.022
(0.031) (0.026)
Log(market value) 0.34** 0.83**
(0.029) (0.24)
Stock returns (103) 1.32** 4.77**
(0.52) (0.43)
Time effects Yes Yes
Firm fixed effects Yes Yes
Observations 7024 6994
R2 0.74 0.90
** significant at 1%; * significant at 5%; significant at 10%.
Table 5 summarizes the coefficients for each regression model. The dependent variables used are log (total compensation) and log
(aggregate CEO incentives).
40 Academy of Management Perspectives February

pened to CEO pay between 1993 and 2003. It may be beneficial. Furnishing CEOs with appro-
shows that total compensation increased signifi- priate compensation and incentives is desirable
cantly over this period. Grants of stock options to for a healthy economy. However, ensuring that
CEOs and executives are the main driver of CEO the contracting process is not corrupted is an
pay gains. The paper also documents that CEOs important goal for corporate governance.
have important financial incentives. These arise
from the portfolio of firm stock and options owned Acknowledgements
by the CEO. The important point is that, if the I would like to thank Peter Cappelli, John Core, James Dow,
stock price declines significantly, the value of the Wayne Guay, Roman Inderst, Mark Muldoon, Lina Page,
CEOs assets falls. Analogously, if asset prices in- Graham Sadler, and Steve Thompson for comments when
crease, so does CEO wealth. In consequence, the preparing this paper. I am especially grateful to Lucian
wealth of the CEO varies with the stock price Bebchuk for his comments and suggestions. Finally, I would
like to thank Danielle Kuchinskas for excellent research
performance of the firm. An important research assistance.
challenge is to fully understand the potentially
unintended consequences of providing greater in- Endnotes
centives to agents. 1
Jensen, M.& Murphy, K.J. 1990. Performance pay and top
In practice, CEO compensation contracts are management incentives. Journal of Political Economy, 98:
determined by compensation committees that 225264.
2
may have conflicting incentives to align with the Bebchuk, L. & Fried, J. 2003. Executive compensation as
CEO (leading to suboptimal contracts and excess an agency problem. Journal of Economic Perspectives,
17(3): 7192; Bebchuk, L. & Fried, J. 2004. Pay without
pay) or with shareholders (leading to optimal con- performance: The unfulfilled promise of executive compen-
tracts and appropriate pay). The analysis in this sation. Harvard University Press.
3
paper illustrates that U.S. boards and compensa- Bebchuk, L. & Fried, J. 2004. Pay without performance: The
unfulfilled promise of executive compensation. Harvard Uni-
tion committees are becoming more independent versity Press. See also their article, Pay without
(measured by fewer insider directors and a greater performance: Overview of the issues. 2006. Academy
number of outside directors). The evidence shows Management Perspectives, this issue.
4
that the presence of affiliated directors on the See Bertrand, M. & Mullainathan, S. 2000. Agents with-
out principals. American Economic Review, 90:203208;
compensation committee (an instance where Bertrand, M. & Mullainathan, S. 2001. Are CEOs re-
greater managerial power is expected) does not warded for luck? The one without principals are. Quar-
lead to greater CEO pay or fewer CEO incentives. 5
terly Journal of Economics, 116: 901932.
In summary, high pay itself is not evidence of On equity incentives see Core, J., Guay, W., & Larcker, D.
2003. Executive equity compensation and incentives: a
inefficient contracts but may simply reflect the survey. FRBNY Economic Policy Review, April: 27-44. On
market for CEOs and the pay necessary to attract, evaluating pay for performance see Core, J., Guay, W. &
retain, and motivate talented individuals. Boards Thomas, R. 2004. Is S&P 500 CEO compensation ineffi-
cient pay without performance? A review of Pay without
of directors need to design compensation con- Performance: The unfulfilled promise of executive compen-
tracts to align the interests of owners with man- sation. Vanderbilt Law and Economics Research Paper No.
agers. One test of whether the corporate gover- 05-05; U of Penn, Inst for Law & Econ Research Paper
nance system is working appropriately, including 05-13. http://ssrn.com/abstract648648.
6
For an impressive technical account of contract and in-
executive compensation arrangements, is to eval- centive theory, see Laffont, J. & Martimort, D. 2002. The
uate economic performance. Holmstrom and theory of incentives: The principal-agent model. Princeton
Kaplan92 investigate the state of U.S. corporate University Press. See also Bolton, P. & Dewatripont, M.
governance in the wake of corporate scandals. 2005. Contract Theory. MIT press. Agency theory has
been a very powerful tool for understanding the modern
They conclude that the U.S. economy has per- firm. The theoretical foundations of executive compen-
formed well, both on an absolute basis and relative sation contracts can traced to: Mirrlees, J. 1976. Optimal
to other countries over about two decades. Impor- structure of incentives and authority within an organi-
zation. Bell Journal of Economics, 7: 105131; Holmstrom,
tantly, the economy has been robust even after B. 1979. Moral hazard and observability. Bell Journal of
the scandals were revealed. This is not to deny Economics, 10: 74 91; Holmstrom, B. 1982. Moral haz-
that improvements in governance arrangements ard in teams. Bell Journal of Economics, 13: 324 40;
2006 Conyon 41

Holmstrom, B. & Milgrom, P. 1987. Aggregation and executive stock options. Quantitative Finance, 5: 113;
linearity in the provision of intertemporal incentives. Ingersoll, J. 2002. The subjective and objective evalua-
Econometrica, 55: 30328. tion of incentive stock options. Journal of Business, Yale
7
Jensen, M., Murphy, K.J., & Wruck, E. 2004. ICF Working Paper No. 02-07. http://ssrn.com/
Remuneration: where weve been, how we got to here, abstract303940; Cai, J. & Vijh, A. 2005. Executive
what are the problems, and how to fix them. Finance, stock and option valuation in a two state-variable frame-
Harvard NOM Working Paper No. 04-28. http://ssrn work. Journal of Derivatives, 12: 9-27; Kadam, A., Lakner,
.com/abstract561305. P., & Srinivasan, A. 2005. Executive stock options:
8
Core, J., Guay, W., & Larcker, D. 2003. Executive equity value to the executive and cost to the firm. http://
compensation and incentives: a survey. FRBNY Eco- ssrn.com/abstract353422. Currently, however,
nomic Policy Review, April: 27-44. Black-Scholes remains the most popular valuation
9
Core, J., Guay, W. & Thomas, R. 2004. Is S&P 500 CEO method. For example, it is frequently used by firms when
compensation inefficient pay without performance? A reporting option compensation in SEC proxy filings.
20
review of Pay without performance: The unfulfilled promise Many studies use only S&P 500 firms. This will cause an
of executive compensation, Vanderbilt Law and Economics upward bias in the estimate of economy wide CEO pay.
Research Paper No. 05-05; U of Penn, Inst for Law & This is because S&P 500 firms are larger than other
Econ Research Paper 05-13. http://ssrn.com/abstract firms, and larger firms have greater executive pay. The
648648. elasticity of executive pay to firm size is typically in the
10
As in Hermalin, B. 2004. Trends in corporate gover- range 30% to 40% (Murphy, 1999, supra note 13).
21
nance, Journal of Finance (forthcoming). See for instance, Murphy, 1999, supra note 13. Total
11
Bebchuk &. Fried, 2004, supra note 2. compensation is variable TDC1 in ExecuComp. Note it
12
Some information on perquisites and deferred compensa- excludes the value of retirement benefits. Murphy argues
tion is not fully disclosed (see Bebchuk & Fried, 2004). it is difficult or arbitrary to convert future payments to
13
Murphy, K. 1999. Executive compensation, in Ashen- annual pay. Strong cases for researching executive pen-
felter, O. & David Card, D. (Eds.), Handbook of labor sions are made in Yermack, D. 2005. Flights of fancy:
economics, Vol. 3. New York: Elsevier. Corporate jets, CEO perquisites, and inferior shareholder
14
Core, J. & Guay, W. 1999. The use of equity grants to returns. AFA 2005 Philadelphia Meetings. Journal of
manage optimal equity incentives. Journal of Accounting Financial Economics. http://ssrn.com/abstract529822;
and Economics, 28: 151184; Murphy (1999) supra note Bebchuk, L. & Jackson. 2005. Putting executive pen-
13; Conyon, M. & Murphy, K.J. 2000. The prince and sions on the radar screen (March). Harvard Law and
the pauper? CEO pay in the US and UK. Economic Economics Discussion Paper No. 507. http://ssrn.com/
Journal, 110: 640 671. abstract694766. They show for the two-thirds of CEOs
15
Black, F. & Scholes, M. 1973. The pricing of options and with defined benefit plans, the value of the plan adds a
corporate liabilities. Journal of Political Economy, 81: 637 third to the total career compensation for the median
59. CEO. http://ssrn.com/abstract694766.
16 22
Typically, stock options are granted at the money with We simply report pay information from the ExecuComp
a maturity term of 10 years and vest after 3 years. Sup- database and do not adjust for inflation, purchasing
pose we define a standard option where S the share power etc.
price $100; X the exercise or strike price $100; T 23
Murphy, 1999, supra note 13.
the time to maturity 10 Years; q the dividend yield 24
Bebchuk, L. & Grinstein, Y. 2005. The growth of exec-
2 12 %; r the risk free rate of interest 7%; and the utive pay, NBER working paper 11443. Forthcoming in
standard deviation of returns on the share 25%. These Oxford Review of Economic Policy.
25
parameters correspond reasonably well to those of an The material discussed in this section is based largely on
option an executive receives (Murphy (1999), supra note Core, Guay, & Larcker, 2003, supra note 8; Core, Guay,
13; Hall, B. 2000. What you need to know about stock & Thomas, 2004, supra note 9.
26
options. Harvard Business Review, March-April: Note that Bebchuk & Fried, 2004 (note 2) do not claim
121-129). This standard option has an expected (Black- that there is complete decoupling of pay and perfor-
Scholes) value of about $37. mance but rather less linkage between pay and perfor-
17
See Lambert, R., Larcker, D., & Verrichia, R. 1991. mance than firms could have easily accomplished and
Portfolio considerations in valuing executive compensa- than investors appreciate. Also, they recognize incen-
tion. Journal of Accounting Research, 29: 129 149; Hall, tives arising from equity holdings but stress that much of
B. & Murphy, K.J. 2002. Stock options for undiversified the gains here come form market-wide and industry-wide
executives. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 33: movements, as well as from short-term spikes that do not
3 42. last, and that firms could have designed equity compen-
18
Jensen et al., 2004, supra note 7. sation in a much more cost-effective way (see chapters
19
Recent research has proposed alternative methods to 11-14 of their book).
27
value options given to risk-averse and undiversified ex- For example, Hall, B. & Liebman, J. 1998. Are CEOs
ecutives. These include Hall & Murphy (2002), supra really paid like bureaucrats? Quarterly Journal of Econom-
note 16; Henderson, V. 2005. The impact of the market ics, 113: 653 691; Murphy, 1999; Core et al., 2004, supra
portfolio on the valuation, incentives, and optimality of note 5.
42 Academy of Management Perspectives February

28 42
Hall & Liebman, 1998, supra note 16; Core et al., 2003, See Bartov, E. & Mohhanram, P. 2004. Private informa-
supra note 8. tion, earnings manipulations and executive stock option
29
Core & Guay, 1999, supra note 14. exercises, The Accounting Review, 79: 889 920. Berg-
30
The literature discusses two broad incentive measures stresser, D. & Philippon, T. 2005. CEO Incentives and
(Core et al., 2003, note 8). Portfolio incentives are the Earnings Management. Journal of Financial Economics,
dollar change in CEO wealth from a percentage change Forthcoming (see http://ssrn.com/abstract640585) A
in stock price. The Jensen &Murphy (1990, supra note classic article on the relation between inventive pay and
1) measure is the dollar change in CEO wealth from a accounting outcomes is Paul Healy 1985. The effect of
dollar change in firm value. It is proportional to the bonus schemes on accounting decisions, Journal of Ac-
fraction of firm shares owned by the CEO. For a given counting and Economics, 7: 85107.
43
firm the measures are simple transformations of each See Denis, D., Hanouna, P., & Sarin, A. 2005. Is there a
other but they can give rise to different rank orderings in dark side to incentive compensation, Journal of Corporate
a cross section of firms. For a discussion of the merits of Finance, forthcoming.
44
each measure, see Baker, G. & B. Hall, B. 1998. CEO Bebchuk A& Grinstein also review alternative explana-
incentives and firm size. Journal of Labor Economics. tions for the growth in CEO pay albeit from the mana-
NBER Working Paper Series, No. 6868. gerial power perspective. See Bebchuk, 2005, supra note
31
Baker & Hall, 1998, supra note 30; Core & Guay, 1999, 24.
45
supra note 14. An often-used agency model involves the principal offer-
32
The option delta (hedge ratio) is calculated as the deriv- ing the agent a linear contract (Holmstrom & Milgrom,
ative of Black-Scholes call option value with respect to 1987, supra note 6). The first order condition for optimal
the share price. In this context the option delta can be incentives (b) is: b*P(e)/[1 r 2 c(e)], where
thought of as a weight, which varies between 0 and 1, P(e) is the CEOs marginal productivity of effort, r is
reflecting the likelihood that the stock option will end agent risk aversion, 2 is variance in performance (risk)
up in the money. and c(e) measures how incentives respond to the cost of
33
Murphy, 1999, supra note 13. effort. Incentives are lower for more risk-averse execu-
34
In calculating portfolio wealth and incentives, we need to tives (b/r 0), and when there is more uncontrollable
make estimates of the exercise price and maturity term noise in firm value (b/2 0). Expected CEO com-
for previously granted options. We use the algorithm pensation is E[w] s bE[q], where s is a fixed salary,
described by Core & Guay (1999, appendix A, supra b is incentives, and q is firm value.
46
note 14) to arrive at the Black-Scholes value of the Prendergast, C. 2002. The tenuous trade-off between risk
portfolio of options. and incentives. Journal of Political Economy, 110: 1071
35
See Dow, J. & C. Raposo, C. 2003. CEO compensation, 1102.
47
change, and corporate strategy. Journal of Finance (forth- This issue is further explored by Conyon, M., Core, J., &
coming). Guay, W. 2005. How high is US CEO pay? A compar-
36
See Hall & Liebman, 1998, supra note 16. ison with UK CEO pay, University of Pennsylvania work-
37
See Kerr, S., 1975. The folly of rewarding A while hoping ing paper.
48
for B., Academy Management Journal, 18: 769 783. Himmelberg, C. & Hubbard, R. 2000. Incentive pay and
38
See Holmstrom, B. & Milgrom, P. 1991. Multitask prin- the market for CEOs: An analysis of pay-for-performance
cipal-agent analyses: Incentive contracts, asset owner- sensitivity (June 2000). Presented at Tuck-JFE Contem-
ship and job design. Journal of Law, Economics and Or- porary Corporate Governance Conference. http://ssrn
ganization 7: 24 52. .com/abstract236089.
39 49
See Gibbons, R. 2005. Incentives between firms (and Murphy, K. & Zabojnik, J. 2003. Managerial capital and
within). Management Science, 51: 217. the market for CEOs. Marshall School of Business
40
See Jacob, B. & S. Levitt, S. 2003. Rotten apples: An (working paper).
50
investigation of the prevalence and predictors of teacher For example, see Hermalin, B. 2004. Trends in corporate
cheating, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 843 877; governance, Journal of Finance (forthcoming); Harris, M.
Levitt, S. & C. Syverson, C. 2005. Market distortions & Raviv, A. 2005 A theory of board control and size,
when agents are better informed: The value of informa- University of Chicago working paper; Singh, R. 2005.
tion in real estate, NBER working paper 11053; Hubbard, Board independence and the design of executive com-
T. 1998. An empirical examination of moral hazard in pensation, EFA 2005 Moscow Meetings Paper. http://ssrn.
the vehicle inspection market, Rand Journal of Econom- com/abstract673741; Hermalin, B. & Weisbach, M.
ics, 29: 406 26; Gruber, J. & Owings. M. 1996. Physi- 1998. Endogenously chosen boards of directors and their
cian financial incentives and caesarian section delivery, monitoring of the CEO, American Economic Review, 88:
Rand Journal of Economics, 27: 99 123. 96 118.
41 51
Yermack, D. 1997. Good timing: CEO stock option Hermalin, B. 2004. Trends in corporate governance, Jour-
awards and company news announcements, Journal of nal of Finance (forthcoming).
52
Finance, 52: 449 476. See also, Aboody, D. & Kasznik, Dow & Raposo, 2003, supra note 35.
53
R. 2000. CEO stock option awards and the timing of Jensen, M. 1993. The modern industrial revolution, exit
voluntary disclosures, Journal of Accounting and Econom- and the failure of internal control systems. Journal of
ics, 29: 73100. Finance, 48: 831 830.
2006 Conyon 43

54
Holmstrom, B. & Kaplan, S. 2001. Corporate governance employment contracts. Cornell Law School Research
and merger activity in the United States: Making sense Paper No. 04-024; Vanderbilt Law and Economics Re-
of the 1980s and 1990s. Journal of Economic Perspectives, search Paper No. 04-12. http://ssrn.com/abstract
15(2): 121144. 529923.
55 74
Dow & Raposo, 2003, supra note 35. Rajan, R. G. & Wulf, J. 2004. Are perks purely manage-
56
Inderst, R. & Mueller, H. 2005. Keeping the board in the rial excess? NBER Working Paper No.W10494. http://
dark. CEO compensation and entrenchment. London ssrn.com/abstract546291 (forthcoming Journal of Fi-
School of Economics (working paper). nancial Economics).
57 75
Smith, C. & Watts, R. 1992. The investment opportunity Yermack, D. 2005. Flights of fancy: Corporate jets, CEO
set and corporate financing, dividend and compensation perquisites, and inferior shareholder returns. AFA 2005
policies. Journal of Financial Economics, 32: 263292. Philadelphia Meetings. (forthcoming Journal of Finan-
58
Core et al., 2003, supra note 8. cial Economics). http://ssrn.com/abstract529822.
59 76
Demsetz, H. & Lehn, K. 1985. The structure of corporate Conyon, M. & He, L. 2004. Compensation committees
ownership: causes and consequences. Journal of Political and CEO compensation incentives in US entrepreneur-
Economy, 93: 11551177. ial firms. Journal of Management Accounting Research, 16:
60
Murphy, K. 2002. Explaining executive compensation: 3556.
77
managerial power versus the perceived cost of stock Antle, R. 1982. The auditor as an economic agent. Jour-
options. University of Chicago Law Review, 69: 847 869. nal of Accounting Research, 20: 503527; Tirole, J. 1986.
61
Jensen et al., 2004, supra note 7. Hierarchies and bureaucracies: on the role of collusions
62
Bebchuk & Fried, 2003; 2004, supra note 2. in organizations. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organi-
63
Core, J., Holthausen, R., & Larcker, D.. 1999. Corporate zation, 2:181214.
78
governance, chief executive officer compensation and Conyon & He, 2004, supra note 76.
79
firm performance. Journal of Financial Economics, 51: Daily, C., Johnson, M., Ellstrand, J., & Dalton, D. 1998.
371 406. Compensation committee composition as a determinant
64
Bebchuk & Fried (2004, supra note 2) and Bebchuk & of CEO compensation. Academy of Management Journal,
Grinstein (2005, supra note 24) contend that even if 41: 209 220; Newman, H. & Mozes, H. 1999. Does the
boards have become more independent in this period, composition of the compensation committee influence
firms have also become more insulated from takeover CEO compensation practices? Financial Management, 28:
threats, insulating boards from shareholders and leading 4153; Vafeas, N. 2003. Further evidence on compensa-
to increased managerial power. tion committee composition as a determinant of CEO
65
See Holmstrom 1979, supra note 6. compensation. Financial Management, 32: 5370; Ander-
66
Rapapport, A. 1999. New thinking on how to link exec- son, R. & Bizjak, J. 2003. An empirical examination of
utive pay with performance. Harvard Business Review, 77: the role of the CEO and the compensation committee in
91101. structuring executive pay. Journal of Banking and Finance,
67
Firms are now expensing options due to changes in ac- 27 (7): 13231348.
80
counting rules. It remains to be seen whether alterative Anderson Bizjak, 2003 supra note 79.
81
types of options are used in the future. Vafeas, 2003, supra note 79.
68 82
See for instance Gibbons, R. & Murphy, K. 1990. Rela- Newman & Mozes, 1999, supra note 79.
83
tive performance evaluation for chief executive officers, Conyon, M. & Peck, S. 1998. Board control, remunera-
Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 43:S30 S51; Ber- tion committees, and top management compensation.
trand, M. & Mullainathan, S. 2001. Are CEOs rewarded Academy of Management Journal, 41:146 157.
84
for luck? The ones without principals are. Quarterly The IRRC data defines an affiliated director as follows.
Journal of Economics, 116: 901932; Garvey, G. & Mil- The director may be a former employee who previously
bourn, T. 2003. Incentive compensation when execu- worked either for the firm of interest or for a majority-
tives can hedge the market: Evidence of relative perfor- owned subsidiary. A director may provide services, such
mance evaluation in the cross section, Journal of Finance, as legal or financial, have been provided by the director
58:15571581. personally or by his employer. The director may be a
69
See Oyer, P. 2004. Why do firms use incentives that have designated director who is a significant shareholder or a
no incentive effects? The Journal of Finance, 59: 1619 documented agreement by a group, for example, a
1650. union. A director may be a customer or supplier and is
70
See Rajgopal, S., Shevlin, T., & Zamora, V. 2005. CEOs affiliated unless the transaction was deemed not mate-
outside employment opportunities and the lack of rela- rial in the firms proxy materials. A director may be
tive performance evaluation in compensation contracts. interlocked defined as a situation in which two firms
Journal of Finance, (forthcoming). each have a director who sits on the board of the other.
71
Jensen, 1993, supra note 53. A director may be a family member of an executive
72
Gillan, S., Hartzell, J., & Parrino, R.. 2005. Explicit vs. officer. In practice, former employees and providing pro-
Implicit Contracts: Evidence from CEO Employment fessional services are the leading source of affiliation.
Agreements. http://ssrn.com/abstract687152. 85
For example, Anderson & Bizjak, 2003, supra note 79;
73
Schwab, S. & Thomas, R. 2004. What do CEOs bargain Daily et al., 1998.
86
for? An empirical study of key legal components of CEO Anderson & Bijack, 2003, supra note 79.
44 Academy of Management Perspectives February

87
Daily et al., 1998, supra note 79. shares owned are negatively correlated with firm size
88
Smith & Watts, 1992, supra note 57. because the value of providing incentives for effort does
89
Baker, G. & Hall, B. 1998. CEO incentives and firm size. not increase with size as fast as the cost of risk bearing by
Journal of Labor Economics. NBER Working Paper Series, the executive. See Schaefer, S. 1998. The dependence of
No. 6868. pay-performance sensitivity on the size of the firm, Re-
90
Core, J. & Guay, W. 1999. The use of equity grants to view of Economics and Statistics, 80: 436 443.
92
manage optimal equity incentives. Journal of Accounting Holmstrom, B. & Kaplan, S. 2003. The state of S&P 500
and Economics, 28: 151184. corporate governance: Whats right and whats wrong?
91
See Core et al., 2003, supra note 8. In contrast, Schaefer European Corporate Governance Institute Finance
argues that incentives measured as a fraction of common Working Paper No. 23/2003.

You might also like