You are on page 1of 17

COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE, INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FACTOR MOBILITY 137

CHAPTER 8
COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE, INTERNATIONAL
TRADE AND FACTOR MOBILITY

In previous chapters we studied how


producers and households interact with each
8.1 Ricardo's Theory of
other in product and factor markets. We can
Comparative Advantage
think of such interaction as trade between

and Benefit from Trade


producers and households, in the sense that
each party has something to offer to the
8.2 Factor Endowment
other. Not only producers and consumers
Theory of International
within a country trade with each other, the

Trade
countries themselves, i.e., consumers and
producers across countries, trade/exchange

8.3 Factor Mobility


with each other in goods and services. This
is called international trade. As an example
of trade in goods, India exports tea to the
rest of the world and imports petrol. Many
foreign banks today offer banking services
in India, which is an example of trade in
services.
In this chapter, our objective is to learn
some fundamentals of international trade.
This is very important, because countries, in
general, are much more interdependent today
than they were 30 or 40 years ago.
In the process, we learn a very important
concept in economics, called comparative
advantage. Through this concept, we will
understand that promoting international
trade is not a bad thing, and, it is not true
that, if one country gains from it, some other
country has to lose. On the contrary, we will
138 INTRODUCTORY MICROECONOMICS

learn that trading with each other is, (a) producing more of the goods which
by and large, a mutually beneficial it can produce relatively cheaply and
activity. exporting part of them and (b)
The idea behind comparative producing less possibly none of the
advantage (to be defined in Section 8.1) goods which it cannot produce
and gains from trade can be relatively cheaply compared to other
understood through this example. countries and importing them. This is
Suppose that you are a very good pop the idea behind comparative
singer and a very good cook. But you advantage. Put differently, it implies
are much more productive as a singer that countries can trade and benefit
than as a cook. This is in the sense by exploiting their differences. In
that if you sing you get Rs. 5,000 per simpler language, it means that you
hour, whereas you can hire an and I are different, I have something
excellent cook at the rate of Rs. 300 which you want but cannot obtain that
per hour, i.e., if you cook, you save easily, and you have something that I
Rs. 300 per hour. One option for you want but cannot get that easily;
will be to pursue a singing career and both are better off by trading with
still cook for yourself be self- each other.
sufficient, so-to-speak. That is, you This principle was first
are capable of doing both and you demonstrated formally by a famous
actually choose to do both. Consider English economist, named David
now the alternative option of hiring a Ricardo. In what follows, we first
cook and engaging yourself full time discuss Ricardos theory of
in singing. Which option will you comparative advantage. It is the
prefer? Surely, the latter. Now think simplest and yet a very elegant
about this example in a different light. exposition of how international trade
The option to do both activities is like can be beneficial to a country.
choosing not to do trade between your Although Ricardo wrote about it
service as a cook and your service as almost two hundred years ago (in the
a singer. The latter option is like early 19th century), its relevance is felt
importing the service that you do not even today.
have comparative advantage in (that As we will see, Ricardos theory of
is, cooking) and, specialising and comparative advantage and trade is
exporting the service you have based on differences in technology
comparative advantage in (that is, across countries. We also consider
singing). another source (basis) of comparative
What applies for an individual in advantage, namely, differences in
the above example also applies to a factor supplies across countries. The
country. A country, in comparison next two sections study these
to producing all goods it can produce alternative sources of comparative
and not trading, is better off by advantage.
COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE, INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FACTOR MOBILITY 139

International trade refers to This is written more compactly in


movement of goods and services. In the Table 8.1.
real world, not only goods and services,
Table 8.1 Labour Coefficients
but also factors of production move
from one place to another. The chapter India Australia
ends with a discussion of movement
Cricket Bats 10 15
of factors.
Footballs 20 60
8.1 RICARDOS THEORY OF
COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE In terms of concepts introduced in
AND BENEFIT FROM TRADE Chapter 3, the average physical
product of labour is the inverse of the
We will make a number of simplifying
labour coefficient. Thus, labour
assumptions so as to clearly bring out
coefficient being given means constant
the essence of this theory. Assume that
average physical product of labour or
there are two countries in the world:
constant output per worker.1
India (N) and Australia (A). Each can
We are almost ready to define
produce two goods, say, cricket bats
comparative advantage.
and footballs. Perfect competition
prevails in the market for each good.
8.1.1 Absolute Advantage and
There is one factor of production, say,
Comparative Advantage
labour (L). Each country is endowed
with a given supply or what is called Between two countries, one is said to
endowment of labour, say LN = 100 have absolute advantage in a good if
and LA = 120 respectively for India and it can produce that good absolutely
Australia. Furthermore, the labour more efficiently than the other country.
required to produce one unit of output, A country is said to have comparative
or what is called the labour coefficient, advantage in a good if it can produce
is given in each sector. As a numerical it relatively more efficiently or relatively
example, suppose that less inefficiently, compared to the
Producing 1 cricket bat in India other country.
requires 10 units of labour We now apply these definitions to
Table 8.1 and say that India has
Producing 1 football in India absolute advantage in producing both
requires 20 units of labour goods, and Australia in none. Because,
Producing 1 cricket bat in Australia in the production of either good, labour
requires 15 units of labour. required to produce one unit is less
Producing 1 football in Australia in India than in Australia. More
requires 60 units of labour importantly for us, let us determine who

1
In turn, this means constant marginal physical product of labour.
140 INTRODUCTORY MICROECONOMICS

has comparative advantage in what. how much will the production of cricket
See that, in India, the labour coefficient bats fall? It is equal to 20 divided by
ratio of the football sector to the cricket the labour coefficient in producing
sector is 20/10 = 2, whereas, in cricket bats (that is, 10). This gives
Australia, the same ratio is 60/15 = 4. 20/10 = 2 cricket bats as the marginal
Hence, in India, labour is relatively more opportunity cost of football.
productive or efficient in the football Note that the marginal opportunity
sector. Therefore, India, has cost of football is constant (equal to 2
comparative advantage in producing cricket bats) at any initial allocation
footballs. Although Australia is less of resources, because the labour
efficient in producing both goods, it is coefficients are constant. You can
relatively less so in producing cricket similarly calculate that cost in
bat. Hence Australia has comparative Australia, which is also constant,
advantage in producing cricket bats. equal to 60/15 = 4. Thus labour
By definition, both countries cannot coefficients being given imply that the
have comparative advantage in marginal opportunity cost of either
producing the same good. good along the PPC is constant. In turn,
from Chapter 1, we know that constant
8.1.2 Production Possibility Curves
marginal opportunity cost implies a
Given the labour coefficients and the straight line PPC. Hence the PPC is a
labour endowment in each country, we straight line in a Ricardian economy.
can draw the Production Possibility Fig. 8.1 shows the PPCs of India and
Curve (PPC) for each country. This will Australia. Recall that Indias
serve as a background to analysing endowment of labour is 100, i.e.,
how international trade affects an LN =100. If all its labour resources are
economy. used in producing football, they will
Recall from Chapter 1 the concept produce 100/20 = 5 footballs. If,
of marginal opportunity cost along a instead, they are all used in producing
PPC. It says how much of one good has cricket bats, they will produce
to be sacrificed to ensure a unit 100/10 = 10. These points are
increase in the production of the other. respectively marked on the football axis
Consider India for instance. Suppose, and cricket bat axis in fig. 8.1(a). The
starting from a given allocation of straight line, DE, joining these two
labour between the football sector and points is the PPC of India. The PPC of
the cricket bat sector, the production Australia, GH, is derived in a similar
of football increases by one unit. From manner, which is shown in fig. 8.1(b).
Table 8.1, this requires additional
labour equal to 20 (since this is labour 8.1.3 No Trade
coeffcient in producing football). As 20 In order to see how international trade
units of labour leave the cricket bats makes a difference, suppose that
sector to produce one extra football, by initially there is no trade between the
COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE, INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FACTOR MOBILITY 141

(a) India (b) Australia

Fig. 8.1 The Production Possibility Curves

two countries. There are four important Thus, in each sector, price will be
points to note for the world economy, equal to the average cost. In this
in which there is no trade. economy, the average cost of a good
1. Since there is no opportunity to is equal to the wage rate times the
trade, in each country, the labour required to produce one unit
consumption of a good cannot of the good. For example, let WN be
exceed how much of that good is the wage rate in India. Then the
produced. In other words, the average cost of, say, football is Rs.
consumption possibilities are WN 20. This will be equal to the
limited to the PPC, i.e., the country
price of football, say PF. Similarly, PC
cannot consume at any point
= Rs. WN 10, where PC is the price
outside its PPC. We can say that
of cricket bats. Thus the relative
the PPC is equal to a countrys
consumption possibility curve. In price of football is equal to PF/PC =
our example, it is DE for India and WN 20/(WN 10) = 2. That is, if
GH for Australia. you have a football, sell it in the
2. It will also be useful to know the market and use the money to buy
relative price of one good in terms cricket bats, you will get 2 cricket
of the other in each country. What bats. The relative price of cricket
do we mean? Recall that both bats is the inverse of that of
goods are produced in competitive football, equal to 1/2. In general,
markets. From Chapter 6, we know the relative price of a good is
that, under perfect competition, defined in terms of some other good
free entry and exit imply zero profits. and is equal to the amount of the
142 INTRODUCTORY MICROECONOMICS

other good that one gets in export or import etc. Also, assume
exchange for one unit of the good that there is no transport cost of
in question. Put differently, it is an moving goods between the two
exchange ratio between goods. We countries. (We make these strong
then have the exchange ratio in assumptions, not because they are
India in the no-trade situation critical for our argument, but because
equal to they help us to see the effect of trade
2 cricket bats for 1 football. very clearly.)
You can similarly calculate the The above assumptions imply that
exchange ratio in Australia: the exchange ratios or the relative price
4 cricket bats for 1 football. of a good will be the same in the two
We can call these the domestic countries. It is because, if a good is
exchange ratios. cheaper in one country than in the
3. Notice that the relative price of a other, every one in both countries will
good in each country is equal to buy the product from the former
its marginal opportunity cost (as country and this will push its price up.
price is equal to marginal cost In equilibrium, the exchange ratios will
under competitive conditions). In be the same. We can call this the world
Australia for example, the exchange ratio or what is called the
relative price of football is 4 world terms of trade.
cricket bats and the marginal
opportunity cost of football is Range of World Terms of Trade
also 4 cricket bats. The next question is: what will be the
4. Also notice from the exchange equilibrium world terms of trade?
ratios that football is relatively Terms of trade, in general, refer to a
cheaper in India, which has relative price and we know from
comparative advantage in Chapter 5 that the equilibrium price
producing football, and cricket of a good is determined by supply and
bats are relatively cheaper in demand forces. The supply side of an
Australia, which has comparative economy is represented by the PPC of
advantage in producing cricket a country. But we do not have any
bats. This is intuitive. information on the demand side.
The stage is ready now to Hence, we cannot determine the world
understand the effect of international terms of trade exactly.
trade. We can, however, find its range: it
will lie in between the domestic
8.1.4 Effect of International Trade exchange ratios. In this example, it
Let India and Australia now open up means that the world relative price of
trade. Further, let there be free trade, football will be in between 2 and 4
i.e., no restrictions like trade taxes or cricket bats. It cannot exceed 4 or fall
any limits on how much a country can short 2. Why? Suppose it exceeds 4, say
COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE, INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FACTOR MOBILITY 143

1 football for 5 cricket bats. Then, in football only. Mark that football is the
both countries, a football fetches more good, in the production of which India
than it fetches in the no-trade situation has comparative advantage. By similar
and thus both would like to export argument, Australia specialises in
football. But this is not possible, since cricket bats, in which it has
there is no third country they can both comparative advantage. Specialisation
export to: by definition, the two occurs as the world terms of trade are
countries comprise the world economy. different from the domestic exchange
(When there are more than two ratio. This is shown in fig. 8.2, which
countries, you can group them into the graphs the same PPCs as in fig. 8.1
home country and the rest of the (shown by the dashed lines). Indias
world and the same argument holds.) and Australias production points in
You can similarly argue that if the world free trade are shown at points D and
terms of trade are 1 football for H respectively.
something less than 2 cricket bats, both We can then summarise that in the
countries would want to import football Ricardian world economy, as long as
and that is not possible. This proves the world terms of trade differ from the
that the equilibrium world terms of domestic exchange ratio, a trading
trade will lie between the domestic country specialises in the good, in the
exchange ratios. Assume that the world production of which it has comparative
terms of trade lie strictly in between advantage. This is how international
the two domestic exchange ratios. As trade affects production and resource
an example, suppose that they are allocation in an economy.
equal to
1 football for 3 cricket bats. Consumption Possibilities
Specialisation Now we come to the last stage of our
Now think about how much of each discussion. What are the consumption
good will be produced in the two possibilities facing the two countries
countries. From the viewpoint of India, and how do they benefit from trade? But
the relative price of football is 3 cricket before we address this question, we
bats, which is greater than its the should know what we mean by exports
marginal opportunity cost (equal to 2 and imports. Exports of a commodity
cricket bats). This will mean that there are equal to its production minus its
are abnormal profits in the football consumption, whereas imports of a
sector. Hence resources (labour) will commodity are equal to its
move out of the cricket bat sector to consumption minus its production. In
the football sector. This process will other words, if a good is exported
continue until there is no production (imported), then its production exceeds
of cricket bats in India. That is, India (falls short of) its consumption in the
specialises in football, i.e. produces country.
144 INTRODUCTORY MICROECONOMICS

(a) India (b) Australia


Fig. 8.2 Free International Trade in the Ricardian Economy

In fig. 8.2, since India produces at that lies to the left of or inside the line
D, one consumption possibility for her DE'. Alternatively, you can see that for
is the point D itself. But there are other every possible consumption point in the
possibilities. For instance, it can export no-trade situation, e.g., A, except the
one football in exchange for 3 cricket corner points on the PPC, there is at least
bats (all imported), or 2 footballs in one point on DE', which guarantees
exchange for 6 cricket bats (all more consumption of each good. Hence,
imported) and so on. These free trade must be preferred to no trade.
possibilities give rise to the heavy line By similar argument, Australias
DE', whose slope is 3, equal to the consumption possibility curve is now
relative price of football in the world the heavy line G'H, whose slope is also
market. 2 Put differently, the equal to 3, the relative price of football
consumption possibility curve for India in the world market. The line G'H lies
at the world terms of trade, equal to 1 outside Australias PPC. Thus
football for 3 cricket bats, is the heavy Australia also benefits from free trade.
line DE'. This situation is surely a Note that, irrespective of which
better proposition for India than no consumption points on DE' and G'H are
trade, which only offered the chosen, India exports footballs and
consumption possibilities along the PPC Australia exports cricket bats. That is,

2
The concept of slope of a straight line is explained in Appendix 2.
COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE, INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FACTOR MOBILITY 145

each country exports the good it that brings out this point is called the
has comparative advantage in. This factor endowment theory.3
is a very general principle of View the world as having two
international trade. countries once again, say, India (N) and
The lesson to be learnt from the America (A). They produce two goods:
Ricardian theory is that a country Chairs (C) and Medicine (M). Instead of
benefits from international trade by one factor of production, suppose that
specialising and exporting the there are two, labour and capital. They
products that it has comparative are required in producing each of these
advantage in. This is true even when two goods. There are constant returns
a country is more efficient in to scale. Furthermore, the technology
producing all goods in an absolute of producing either good is same
sense. between India and America and the
production of chairs is relatively labour-
8.2 FACTOR ENDOWMENT THEORY intensive and that of medicine is
OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE relatively capital-intensive.4 All markets
are perfectly competitive.
In the Ricardian theory, it is the Suppose that the supply of each
difference in technology that forms factor in each country is given. We can
the basis of comparative advantage call these factor endowments, just like
and mutually beneficial trade. labour endowment in the Ricardian
Otherwise, if the ratio of labour theory.
coefficients is the same between the
two countries, then the domestic 8.2.1 Factor Endowment Difference
exchange ratios will be the same; no Let LN and KN denote the endowments
country will have comparative of labour and capital in India.
advantage in producing any good Likewise, let L A and KA denote the
and there will be no reason to trade. endowments of labour and capital in
Even if international trade is opened America. These are absolute factor
between the two countries, nothing endowments. The ratio of absolute
will change in any country. endowments is called the relative
However, technology differences are factor endowment. For example,
not only basis for comparative LN/KN is the relative endowment of
advantage and trade. Differences in labour in India.
relative factor endowment (to be defined Having defined relative endowment,
in a moment) form another major basis we can always compare it between
for comparative advantage. The theory countries. In our example, we say that

3
It was formulated originally by two Swedish economists, Eli Heckscher and Bertil Ohlin, and is
called the Heckscher-Ohlin theory.
4
It is not that the technology cannot differ between countries. But the idea here is to suppress such
difference and focus on difference in factor endowments.
146 INTRODUCTORY MICROECONOMICS

India is the relatively labour-abundant something about relative factor price


country and America is the relatively difference, where relative factor price is
capital-abundant country, if defined as the ratio of factor rewards.
Suppose that, in America, labour
LN LA earns wage equal to Rs. 200 and capital
( A) .5
KN KA earn rental equal to Rs. 1,000. In India,
Let us assume this, since it is let the wage rate and the rental to
reasonable to suppose that India is a capital be Rs. 100 and Rs. 900
relatively labour-abundant country, respectively. Thus, the two absolute
compared to America. factor rewards are less in India. But,
relatively speaking, the wage/rental
8.2.2 Factor Price Difference ratio is greater in America. It is 1/5 there
What does this difference in relative and 1/9 in India. In this case, we say
factor endowment imply for factor that relative reward (price) of labour is
prices? We first define two terms: greater in America and the relative
absolute factor price difference and reward of capital is greater in India.
relative factor price difference. In Indeed, our relative factor ranking (A)
general, we say that there is an implies this. How?
absolute factor price dif ference Our analysis of factor price
between two regions or countries if the determination in Chapter 7 comes into
reward (price) of a factor dif fers play. Let us invoke a result from that
between the two regions or countries chapter which states that, greater the
in absolute terms. For instance, if supply of a factor, the lower is its reward.
labour earns wage equal to Rs. 50 per In the present context, it implies that,
day in India and Rs. 200 per day in since India (respectively America) is
America, we say that there is an relatively labour (respectively capital)
absolute wage difference and the wage abundant, the wage/rental ratio in India
rate is less in India than in America. will be less than that in America. In
Similarly, there can be an absolute other words, India is the relatively low-
difference in the rental rate of capital wage country and America is the
between the two countries. relatively high-wage country.
Given our ranking of the relative
8.2.3 Comparative Advantage
endowment in (A), can we say anything
about absolute factor price differences We now proceed to analyse how the
between India and America? The dif ference in the relative factor
answer is no, because the ranking (A) endowment and the resulting
does not say anything about absolute difference in the relative factor price
endowment levels. But it can say determine the flow of goods between the

5
For example, let LN = 1, 500, KN = 500, LA=2,000 and KA = 1000. Then LN/KN = 3, LA/KA = 2, and thus
L N/K N>L A/K A.
COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE, INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FACTOR MOBILITY 147

two countries. Ask yourself which good intensive good (chair) and the
will be produced more efficiently (i.e. relatively capital-abundant, high
with lower cost) in the low wage/rental wage/rental ratio, country (America)
ratio country and in the high wage/ will export the relatively capital-
rental ratio country. Remember that the intensive good (medicine). This is how
production technology of chairs (C) is the relative factor endowment difference
labour-intensive and that of medicines and the relative factor price difference
(M) is capital-intensive. The answer is are linked to international trade.
that the labour-intensive good C will be You can reflect back to see that the
produced relatively more efficiently in aforementioned result is quite
the relatively low-wage, labour - reasonable. This is the gist of the factor
abundant country, and, the capital- endowment theory. It emphasises
intensive good (M) will be produced relative factor endowment difference
relatively more efficiently in the relatively as the basis of comparative
high-wage, capital-abundant country. advantage and predicts that a country
We can state this in terms of will export those products which uses
comparative advantage. The relatively its relatively abundant factor more
labour-abundant, low wage/rental intensively.
ratio, country (India) will have Three remarks are in order.
comparative advantage in producing 1. Unlike the material in previous
the relatively labour-intensive good. chapters and our discussion of the
The relatively capital-abundant, high Ricardian theory, the factor
wage/rental ratio country (America) endowment theory has been
will have comparative advantage in merely sketched. A specialised
producing the relatively capital- course in international economics
intensive good. will deal with this theory in more
detail.
8.2.4 International Trade 2. In Chapter 7, we learnt that the
Thus far we have linked relative factor demand for a factor is called a
endowment difference and relative derived demand. This is because
factor price difference to comparative changes in product markets affect
advantage. We next link comparative the demand for a factor. In
advantage to international trade: contrast, the factor endowment
i.e.,compared to no trade, in free trade, theory illustrates how factor market
a country will produce more and differences influence the product
export the product, in which it has market the pattern of flow of goods
comparative advantage. between countries. Thus, a general
Joining the two links now, we can and an important point to be learnt
say that the relatively labour-abundant, is that, in an economy, factor and
low wage/rental ratio, country (India) product markets are very much
will export the relatively labour- interrelated.
148 INTRODUCTORY MICROECONOMICS

3. Recall the central prediction of the We now ask why factors move the
factor endowment theory. In our way they do? Here, unlike in the factor
example, India, the relatively endowment theory, the absolute factor
labour-abundant country, exports price difference (already defined) plays
relatively labour-intensive goods a role. As an example, we have already
and America, the relatively capital- noticed that in India daily labour
abundant country exports moves from rural to urban areas. Why
relatively capital-intensive goods. is this so? Because, there is an
We can look at this conclusion in a absolute factor price difference. Given
different light. India exporting such a difference, a factor moves from
relatively labour-intensive goods the low-reward region to a high-reward
can be thought of as India region. Daily labour earns more in an
exporting the services of labour. urban area on an average than in a
Likewise, America exporting rural area on an average. This induces
relatively capital-intensive goods it to move from rural to urban areas.
means that America is exporting However, the absolute factor price
capital services. Put differently, difference or in this case the rural-
international trade in goods can be urban wage differential, is just an
seen as international trade in factor immediate cause of factor/labour
services. This again shows how migration, not the underlying cause.
interrelated goods and factor This chapter and the book ends
markets are; it is as if factors are with an investigation of why a rural-
moving internationally, although urban wage differential exists.
they are not (in our analysis). We can think of this issue in terms
of demand and supply of a factor,
8.3 FACTOR MOBILITY
studied in Chapter 7. Indeed there are
The very last point made brings us to differences in both demand and supply
the very last topic to be analysed in sides, which explain the rural-urban
this book. That is, factors do move difference in daily wage.
between regions and countries. In our First, there are more nucleus
country daily labour moves typically families, as opposed to joint families,
from villages to towns. There are in urban areas than in rural areas. In
thousands of workers from India who many urban households, both
are working in middle-east countries husband and wife work outside the
like Kuwait and Yemen. home. Hence there is a greater demand
These are not the only instances for household services like cleaning,
of mobility. Unskilled labour moves cooking etc. Also, construction works
from Mexico to America. Skilled are more prevalent in urban than in
workers move typically from countries rural areas. Both these factors imply
like India and China to Europe and higher demand for daily labour in
America. urban areas, compared to rural areas.
COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE, INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FACTOR MOBILITY 149

Second, the urban cost of living is


higher than the rural cost of living, so
that families of many daily workers
prefer to live in rural areas. This
implies that, ceteris paribus, the
supply of daily labour in towns is less
than in villages.
Both these factors together imply
that the urban wage must be higher.
We can see this in terms of fig. 8.3.
There are two demand curves. The one
to the right, DDB, can be interpreted Fig. 8.3 Urban and Rural Wage for Daily
as the demand curve for daily labour Labour
in the urban area and the one to the
We note that this is true not just for
left, DDR, can be thought of as that in
unskilled labour but also for skilled
the rural area. There are also two
labour. Skilled workers want to move
supply curves. The one to the left, SSB, out of countries like India and China
marks the supply curve in the urban to the U.S. and Europe in order to earn
area and the one to the right, SSR, higher wage for their skill. Similarly,
marks that in the rural area. The capital, which earns less rental in
urban labour market equilibrium is capital-abundant developed countries,
shown at the point EB where DDB and has an incentive to move (through
SSB intersect. Likewise, the labour multinational firms) to capital-poor,
market equilibrium in the rural area high-rental, developing countries.
occurs at the point ER where the curves We should carefully note however
DDR and SSR intersect. As we can see that absolute factor price difference is
clearly, the urban wage, WB is greater only an immediate cause or an
than the rural wage, WR. indicator of factor movement.
Once we establish that there is an Regional differences or differences
absolute difference in wages, it is easy between countries in demand and
to predict that labour wants to move supply conditions of factors are the
from a low-wage region to a high-wage underlying cause of factor
region. movement.

SUMMARY
l The principle of comparative advantage implies that countries can benefit
from trade by exploiting their differences.
l In the Ricardian theory, differences in technology form the basis of
comparative advantage.
l Average physical product a factor is the inverse of its coefficient.
150 INTRODUCTORY MICROECONOMICS

l In the Ricardian economy, constant labour coefficients imply that the


marginal opportunity cost of a good, in terms of the other along the PPC,
is constant. This in turn implies that the PPC is a straight line.
l In the absence of trade, a countrys PPC is same as its consumption
possibility curve.
l The world terms of trade lie in between the domestic exchange ratios.
l In the Ricardian economy, a country specialises, in free trade, in the good
in which it has comparative advantage, as long as the world terms of
trade are different from the domestic exchange ratio.
l In the Ricardian economy, as long as the world terms of trade are different
from the domestic exchange ratio, the consumption possibility curve in
free trade lies outside its PPC.
l The Ricardian theory illustrates that a country benefits from international
trade by specialising and exporting the products that it has comparative
advantage in. This is true even when a country is more efficient in
producing all goods in an absolute sense.
l The differences in relative factor endowment also form a basis of
comparative advantage. This is captured by the factor endowment theory.
l A difference in the relative factor endowment causes a difference in the
relative factor price.
l A relatively labour (capital) abundant country will have comparative
advantage in relatively labour (capital) intensive goods.
l Factor endowment theory of trade predicts that a country will export the
products which use its relatively abundant factor more intensively.
l This prediction can also be interpreted as that a country exports the
services of its relatively abundant factor and imports the services of its
relatively scarce factor.
l Absolute factor price difference is the immediate cause, not the underlying
cause, of factor mobility. In turn, absolute factor price difference arises
because of variations in demand and supply factors in respective regions.
l Compared to rural areas, in urban areas, the daily wage rate is higher.
This is because of greater demand for daily labour and less supply of
daily labour in the urban areas.
l The greater demand for daily labour in urban areas stems from higher
demand for household work and construction projects. Higher cost of
living in urban areas implies less supply of daily labour in these areas, as
families of many daily workers prefer to live in rural areas.
COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE, INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FACTOR MOBILITY 151

EXERCISES

Section I
8.1 What is meant by international trade?
8.2 Give one example of international trade in services.
8.3 What is meant by labour coefficient?
8.4 Give the meaning of absolute advantage.
8.5 Give the meaning of comparative advantage.
8.6 What does the Ricardian theory emphasise as a basis of
comparative advantage?
8.7 In the Ricardian theory, which good does a country specialise
in free trade?
8.8 In the no-trade situation, what is the relationship between a
countrys PPC and its consumption possibility curve?
8.9 In the Ricardian theory, in the free-trade situation, what is the
relationship between a countrys PPC and its consumption
possibility curve?
8.10 What does the factor endowment theory emphasise as a basis
of comparative advantage?
8.11 What is meant by relative factor endowment difference?
8.12 What is meant by relative factor price difference?
8.13 What is meant by absolute factor price difference?

Section II
8.14 Give two examples of international trade in services.
8.15 Explain the concept of comparative advantage by using a
suitable example.
8.16 Explain that, in a two-country Ricardian world economy, both
countries cannot have comparative advantage in producing the
same good.
8.17 Explain how, in the Ricardian world economy, constant labour
coefficients imply that the PPC is a straight line.
8.18 In an economy, there is one factor of production, labour. Two
goods are produced: sitar and guitar. 5 units of labour is
required to produce one sitar and 12 units of labour is required
to produce one guitar. Determine the domestic exchange ratio
between sitars and guitars in this country.
8.19 The following table gives labour coefficients in the two sectors
in two countries. Determine which country has absolute
advantage and comparative advantage in which good.
152 INTRODUCTORY MICROECONOMICS

Popland Rockland
Sitar 50 60
Guitar 60 50

8.20 Refer to the previous question. Suppose technological progress


occurs in Popland. As a result, the labour coefficients are now
40 and 30 respectively for the sitar sector and the guitar sector.
Determine which country now has absolute and comparative
advantage in which good.
8.21 A Ricardian economy can produce two goods: tooth brush and
shoe brush. The labour coefficients in these two sectors are
respectively 30 and 90. Its labour endowment is equal to 1,800.
If the world terms of trade facing this country are 1 tooth brush
for 4 shoe brushes, determine how many tooth brushes and
shoe brushes this country will produce in free trade.
8.22 Differentiate (with example) between a capital-intensive good
and a labour-intensive good.
8.23 Explain absolute factor price difference. Why may it arise?
8.24 Explain relative factor price difference. Why may it arise?
8.25 Name two commodities which are relatively labour-intensive in
production.
8.26 Name two commodities which are relatively capital-intensive in
production.
8.27 Name two relatively labour-abundant countries.
8.28 Name two relatively capital-abundant countries.
8.29 The world consists of two countries: Blueland and Yellowland.
There are two factors, labour and land. They produce two
goods, apples and grapes. The production of apples is relatively
more land intensive compared to grapes. Suppose the
endowments in the two countries are as given in the following
table. If both countries engage in free trade with each other,
determine which country will export what.

Blueland Yellowland
Labour 50 60
Land 70 140

8.30 Give two instances where factors are mobile.


8.31 Name two labour-intensive commodities in India.
COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE, INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND FACTOR MOBILITY 153

8.32 Suppose the supply of workers for household services declines


in the economy. How will it affect the urban and rural wage for
these services?

Section III
8.33 Explain why a relatively labour-abundant country will export
relatively labour-intensive goods.
8.34 Analyse why daily wage is higher in urban areas than in rural
areas.
8.35 Suppose that many of our computer professionals migrate to
foreign countries. Ceteris paribus, how will it affect the salary
of computer professionals in India and abroad?

You might also like