You are on page 1of 10

ECONOMICS OF RELIGION: THE ROLE OF RELIGION ON ECONOMIC

PERFORMANCE
A Review of Literature

Davood Manzoor, Assistant Professor, Imam Sadiq University

' It will not perhaps surprise people that economists have something
to say about the economics of religion, since economists believe
they have something to say about everything; what is surprising is
that religion has something to say about economics.’
Deirdre N. McCloskey, University of Illinois, Chicago

Introduction 
Can belief in heaven or hell be a competitive advantage for nations? It's not the sort of
question that many economists ask. With exceptions like Adam Smith, the giants of 
economic theory have had little to say on matters of faith. 
Most of economists have tended to accept the secularization thesis advanced by Max 
Weber in "The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism,"­ as economies become 
more advanced and as technology progresses, religion will decline as a force.
But the wall separating religion and economics is being breached. In the past 5 to 20 
years, more and more scholars have been using conventional economic methods to 
understand the way in which religion relates to the rest of society and to the economy 
in particular.
Douglass North (1971, 1991) has proposed—and a steadily growing body of 
empirical literature has confirmed—that institutions, more than any other factor, 
determine economic performance.  For a long time, economists were of the opinion 
that institutions were at best peripheral to economic performance for most of the 
twentieth century, but the failure of more conventional models to account for 
economic performance through time has induced many economists to look to more 
non­ traditional explanations of economic performance.  In other words, physical 
capital accumulation, human capital accumulation, and technological change as such 
only account for a fraction of economic growth through time. Something more elusive
must be responsible for the earth­shattering economic growth of the last two and a 
half centuries.  
Standing on the shoulders of North, many economists have re­oriented their focus 
away from the material forces of production and toward the “rules of the economic 
game” embodied in institutions.
Institutions are the formal rules, informal norms, and enforcement mechanisms that 
comprise the “rules of the game” and determine the incentives to which people 
respond.  Institutions should give people an incentive to produce and exchange which 
in turn results to “economic success”. It is the incentive structures that determine 
whether or not an economy will stagnate or succeed, and it is changes in these 

1
incentive structures that determine whether or not stagnation or success will persist 
over time.  A country’s institutional constellation has its foundation in the beliefs and 
ideologies of the polity, beliefs and preferences shape the performance of economies 
through time. Religions share a body of common ethical propositions that govern 
human behavior.  It is uncontroversial to assert that we are to help those who cannot 
help themselves, that we are to love our neighbors as ourselves, and that we are to 
refrain from theft, murder, adultery, covetousness, and false witness.
Economic theory teaches us that people do not act in a vacuum. The fundamental
lesson of economics is that people respond to incentives, and a change in formal
institutions (such as redistributive intervention) necessarily changes the structure of
incentives in the long run and may, in fact, work to frustrate the entrepreneurial
mechanisms.

Theoretical Approaches
Regarding the conceptual or theoretical approaches to the
connection between religion and economy, there are two causal
directions that analysts tend to think about. This work has appeared
especially in the literature on the sociology of religion. One
important line of research posits that religion (or measures of
religiosity) is dependent upon developments in the economic and
political aspects of contemporary life. This research suggests that
events in an economy—levels and standard of living or
governmental market interference—influence such things as
attendance at religious services or religious beliefs. The second
theoretical approach looks at the connection between religion and
economic and social life from the other direction. Religion is thought
of as being the independent variable, influencing something about
outcome on the economic, political, and social side. For example,
Max Weber’s famous theory about capitalism is in that line:
Religiosity influences economic performance, and perhaps political
institutions.

Secularization Hypothesis
Going back to the first type of model, in which religion is seen as
being dependent on social and economic factors. There are two
important sociological theories about how religion responds to these
factors. One approach is called the “Secularization Hypothesis.” It’s
a part of what is often called “Modernization Theory,” which looks at
how the economies of developing countries develop institutional
capabilities to alleviate poverty and rationalize markets.
The Modernization theory posits that as an economy develops and
gets richer, certain societal institutions and features change in a
regular way. The "Secularization Hypothesis" applies this theory to
religiosity: As economies develop and get richer, people supposedly
become less religious. “Less religious” is measured either by
participation in organized religion or by certain indicators of
religious belief.

2
The “Secularization Hypothesis” is widely held among analysts.

Religion Market Model
The second important approach in the sociology of religion literature
is often called the “Religion Market Model.” It speaks about the way
government interacts with religion and influences the extent of
participation in religion—or even the extent of religious beliefs.
Thus, sometimes the government regulates the market, possibly
promoting a monopoly religion or making it difficult for other
religions to flourish.
Under this theory, the government might make it difficult for people
to practice their religion by going to services. On the other hand, it
might subsidize religious activity. Yet, in one way or another, the
government will be influencing the amount of formal religious
activity. One example of this influence is the establishment of an
official religion in a country. There are, however, different views in
the literature about whether such governmental action will promote
religiosity or detract from it. The argument that it might detract
from religiosity is as follows: If you have an established religion, you
tend to have a monopoly, and monopolies tend to function
inefficiently.
For example, it is thought that a monopoly church— such as the
Catholic Church in predominantly Catholic countries or the Anglican
Church in England— doesn’t perform efficiently and is not attractive
to practitioners. In response, people are thought to participate less.
On the other hand, established religion tends to go along with
government funding of religious activities. The government might be
paying for religious buildings or religious personnel. In this case, one
might predict that subsidizing something might result in greater
religious participation. In general, this Religion Market Model argues
that the way state and church interact is quite central. Extreme
examples are communist regimes, including the Soviet Union and
China. But many Eastern
European countries also tried very hard to eradicate organized
religion and apparently had some degree of success.

Adam Smith
In Wealth of Nations, Adam Smith argued that participation in religious sects could 
potentially convey two economic advantages to adherents (Anderson 1988). The first 
could be as a reputational signal: membership in a “good” sect could convey a 
reduction in risk associated with the particular individual and ultimately improve the 
efficient allocation of resources. Second, sects could also provide for extra­legal 
means of establishing trust and sanctioning miscreants in intragroup transactions, 
again reducing uncertainty and improving efficiency, especially where civil remedies 
for failure to uphold contracts were weak.
A variant of this notion offered by modernization theorists such as Hoselitz (1960), 
McClelland (1961), and Hagen (1962) is that traditional societies resist change, and 

3
innovative groups can be important in the process of modernization. Religious 
affiliation could serve as the base for group cohesion necessary to successfully 
challenge established institutions and practices. For example, according to Lal (1998),
Buddhism and Jainism played just this sort of role in ancient India. 

Max Weber
In a second line of argumentation, most prominently associated with Max Weber, it is 
the content of religious belief that is essential. In The Protestant Ethic and the ‘Spirit’
of Capitalism, Weber (1905/2002) contended that the Protestant Reformation was 
critical to the rise of capitalism through its impact on belief systems. Weber argued 
that the Calvinist doctrine of predestination and the associated notion of the “calling” 
were essential for transforming attitudes toward economic activity and wealth 
accumulation. In John Calvin’s view, individuals were predestined to salvation or 
damnation, and “good works” were a means of self­assurance and demonstration to 
others of one’s fate. Each had a “calling,” and the successful completion of this 
religious mission on a daily basis was pleasing to God and a mark of His blessing. In 
contrast to Catholicism’s glorification of monasticism (self-denial and active self-
restraint), this conception projected economic activity into the center of religious life 
and replaced the Catholic cycle of sin, repentance, atonement, and release, followed 
by more sin. The result was a “this­worldly asceticism,” which focused adherents on 
diligent, efficient economic activity, thrift, and non­ostentatious accumulation of 
wealth, which he saw as the bedrock of modern capitalism. This development was not
predetermined—Weber was explicit that the development of ideas and institutions 
congenial to capitalism was endogenous, path­dependent, and not determined by any 
iron laws of history. Such an extraordinary thesis was sure to attract critics, and it did.
Weber stands accused of mischaracterizing Protestant theology, misinterpreting 
Catholicism, ignoring nonreligious sources of intellectual ferment, misunderstanding 
the economic antecedents of industrial capitalism, thoroughly confusing the historical 
record with respect to the rise of capitalism in Catholic and Protestant communities in 
Western Europe, and even mishandling the statistical data he had at his disposal.
Blum and Dudley (2001) provide another version of the Weber thesis, arguing that the
Calvinist doctrine of predestination (in contrast to the Catholic practice of ritual 
penance), in game­theoretic terms, increased the cost of contractual defection (i.e., 
breaking contracts was a bigger deal for Protestants). This Protestant reluctance to 
break contracts contributed to greater trust and willingness to honor contracts with 
strangers and thereby contributed to the spread of more extensive information 
networks in the Protestant lands of Northern Europe, and it was these network 
externalities that promoted growth and the rise of industrial capitalism.

Arthur Lewis

4
Until recently, economists have paid little attention to this issue; Nobel Laureate W. 
Arthur Lewis, is one of the few who expressed skepticism that religious beliefs had 
any significant impact on economic behavior and indeed argued that the causality 
probably ran the other direction: Despite religion’s claim to be the ultimate primal, 
changes in economic circumstances spurred theological adaptation (Lewis 1955). In 
this regard, Lewis, in asserting the primacy of economics over religion, followed the 
common practice of elevating one’s own scholastic specialty to the primal. Hofstede 
(1997), a sociologist, also wrote “If we trace the religious histories of countries, we 
find that the religion a population has embraced seem to have been a result of 
previously existing cultural value patterns”.
This puzzles —how to sort out the pattern of causality among economics, culture, and
religious belief—is a central challenge. 

Robert J. Barro and Rachel M. McCleary 
The scholars now include Robert J. Barro and Rachel M. McCleary, a husband­and­
wife team based at Harvard. Professor Barro is a prolific economist who has long 
been interested in studying how and why economic growth rates differ among 
countries. Professor McCleary, who directs the Project on Religion, Political 
Economy, and Society at Harvard's Weatherhead Center for International Affairs, 
gained an appreciation of the importance of religion in economic life while studying 
in Guatemala.
In order to get a broad cross-country sample of the extent of
religiosity, the things they are measuring come from six important
international surveys of values and other activities. These were
carried out from the early 1980s through 1999. Three of these
surveys are waves of the so-called World Value Survey: 1981, 1990,
and 1995.
The World Value Survey now covers around 50 countries and
surveys 1,000 to 2,000 individuals in each country to get an idea of
their values in various respects. They use data about attendance at
formal religious services in addition to a number of specific religious
beliefs. The data they are looking at concern beliefs—related, for
example, to an afterlife or whether people believe in heaven/hell.
There are some more general questions, such as belief in God, and
there are also questions that are more robust across religions: for
example, whether or not you consider yourself to be a religious
person. There exist these three waves from the World Value Survey,
and there are two waves from the International Social Survey
program in the 1990s.In a paper published last year in the American 
Sociological Review, the couple set out to investigate the correlation between 
variables like church attendance and belief in heaven and hell and comparative 
economic growth rates from 1965 to 1995. "We thought there might be a positive 
relationship between certain religious beliefs and economic performance," Professor 
Barro said.

5
Investigating such a hypothesis can be difficult, in part because different religious 
systems have starkly different practices when it comes to their mode of participation 
and belief in the afterlife.
But over all, the study confirmed the assumption that greater economic development 
is associated with less religiosity. In their results, which Dr. McCleary notes are 
preliminary and need further investigation, the two also reached some counterintuitive
conclusions. First, in two countries where religious service attendance is essentially 
the same, the one whose people have a greater belief in heaven and hell would 
experience faster economic growth. Second, in two countries where the populations 
have similar rates of belief in heaven and hell, the one in which church attendance is 
greater would have slower growth.
Why? This "quantitative approach to the study of religion," as Professor McCleary 
calls it, rests on the assumption that religion can affect economics by fostering beliefs 
that influence productivity­enhancing traits like thrift, hard work and honesty. A 
widespread feeling that such behavior may ultimately be rewarded (a belief in 
heaven), or that a lack of such behavior may be punished (a belief in hell) may 
therefore spur economic growth. And if more people and resources are devoted to 
holding religious services without producing the desired output (a higher level of 
belief), that would tend to lessen productivity in an economy. 
In other words, countries' economies may perform best when people have relatively 
higher levels of religious belief than religious participation. Among the nations falling
into this category are Japan, South Korea, Singapore and some Scandinavian 
countries ­ all of which performed well economically in the period studied. Countries 
in which belief was low compared with religious participation included India and 
many in Latin America.
Another finding was that belief in hell proved to be a more significant economic 
factor than belief in heaven. "The stick of punishment may be more powerful 
compared with the carrot," Professor Barro said.
INDEED, while Adam Smith's "Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of 
Nations" has been the bible for generations of economists, signs indicate that some 
older sacred texts matter to them as well. In December 2002, when Vernon L. Smith, 
a pioneer in experimental economics, accepted the Nobel in economic science, he 
noted that "the strictures against stealing or coveting a neighbor's possessions provide 
the property­right foundations for markets. And the prohibition against murder, 
adultery and bearing false witness provide the foundations for cohesive social 
exchange". 

Larry Iannaccone
Iannaccone, an economics professor at George Mason University who studied at 
Chicago under Becker and who heads a new academic group, the "Association for the 
Study of Religion, Economics & Culture" says that while academics ignored religion 
in part out of a belief that it would fade under the onslaught of secularization we 

6
finally figured out that religion remains a very powerful force in contemporary 
society. While noting that "we need a lot more and better data before we can be 
confident about the results" of such studies, Professor Iannaccone says economists 
should pay more attention to the intersection of religion and economics. According to 
him "It's almost impossible to live in the 21st century and look around and say that 
religion has no impact anymore".  Abundant evidence affirms that religious belief 
affects a wide range of behavioral outcomes and religious activity can affect 
economic performance at the level of the individual, group, or nation through at least 
two channels.

Marcus Noland
He is a senior fellow at the Institute for International Economics. In
his paper (2004)"Religion, Culture, and Economic Performance"he
tries to test the hypothesis that religious attitudes affect national economic 
performance. 
For some time, economists have been troubled by the fact that the actual growth 
trajectories of national economies seem to contradict both implications of the model. 
Romer (1986), Lucas (1988), Robelo (1991), and others launched the endogenous 
growth literature that sought to explain the first empirical anomaly through various 
mechanisms that would temper the tendency of declining marginal returns to slow the 
growth rate of rich economies; Barro (1991), Barro and Sala­i­Martin (1992, 1995), 
and Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (1992) set off the now vast literature on the 
determinants of long­run growth across countries. 
In addition to the accumulation of physical and human capital, attention has focused 
on indicators of macroeconomic stability, trade openness, political institutions, and 
geography. Solow (2001) questioned the role of the many right­hand­side variables 
that have been included in the long­run growth literature and instead argued for 
focusing on national differences in the level and growth of total factor productivity or 
TFP  across countries as the left­hand­side variable to be explained. The problem, of 
course, is that empirical estimates of TFP are themselves derived as the residuals from
growth­accounting exercises, and can be very sensitive to assumptions about the 
underlying aggregate production function (Pack 2001) and the measurement of inputs 
(Hsieh 2002). Setting aside these operational issues, Solow (2001) argues that non­
technological phenomena including “the security of contracts, the intensity of 
competition, and the respect for instrumental rationality as a mode of behavior” could 
have a major impact on resource allocation and hence TFP. 
He has concluded that the theoretical literature on the subject is indeterminate. 
Empirically, he has found correlations between religious affiliation, the intensity of 
religious belief, and indicators of cultural tendencies. However, the national cultural 
measures have no explanatory power with respect to national economic performance 
once conventional economic fundamentals are taken into account.

7
In contrast, in both cross­country and within­country regressions, the null hypothesis 
that religious affiliation is uncorrelated with performance can frequently be rejected, 
though the regressions do not yield a robust pattern of coefficients with respect to 
particular religions.
Some commentators have claimed that Islam is inimical to growth. He has found that 
in general this is not borne out by the econometric analysis either at the cross­country 
or within­country level.
He has also found that predominately Muslim countries are seldom outliers (either 
positively or negatively) in the cross­country regressions. In most cases, the 
coefficient on the Muslim population share is statistically insignificant. With one 
exception, where it is significant, it is always positive. The only case of a statistically 
significant negative coefficient is in the sub­national regression for Malaysia. Islam 
does not appear to be a drag on growth or an anchor on development as alleged. If 
anything, the opposite appears to be true. If one is concerned about economic 
performance in predominately Muslim regions or countries, conventional economic 
analysis may yield greater insight than the sociology of religion.

REFERENCES 
Anderson, Gary M. 1988. “Mr. Smith and the Preachers: The Economics of Religion 
in the Wealth of Nations,” Journal of Political Economy 96, no. 5: 1066–88. 
Barro, Robert J. 1991. “Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries,” 
Quarterly Journal of  Economics 106, no. 2: 407–43. 
Barro, Robert J. 1999. “Determinants of Democracy,” Journal of Political Economy 
107, no. 6: S158–83. 
Barro, Robert J., and Rachel M. McCleary. 2002. “Religion and Political Economy in 
an International Panel,” NBER Working Paper 8931. Cambridge: National Bureau of 
Economic Research. 
Barro, Robert J., and Rachel M. McCleary. 2003. “Religion and Economic Growth,” 
NBER Working Paper 9682. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research. 
Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala­i­Martin. 1992. “Convergence,” Journal of Political
Economy 100, no. 2: 223–51. 
Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala­i­Martin. 1995. Economic Growth. New York: 
McGraw­Hill. 
Bhalla, Surjit S. 2002. Imagine There’s No Country: Poverty, Inequality, and Growth 
in the Era of Globalization. Washington: Institute for International Economics. 
Blum, Ulrich and Leonard Dudley. 2001. “Religion and Economic Growth: Was 
Weber Right?” Journal of Evolutionary Economics 11, no. 2: 207–30.
Easterly, William, and Ross Levine. 2001. “It’s Not Factor Accumulation,” World 
Bank Economic Review 15, no. 2: 177–219. 
Gellner, Ernest. 1992. Postmodernism, Reason, and Religion. London: Routledge. 

8
Greif, Avner. 1994. “Cultural Beliefs and the Organization of Society: A Historical 
and Theoretical Reflection on Collectivist and Individual Societies,” Journal of 
Political Economy 102, no. 5: 912–50. 
Guiso, Luigi, Paola Sapienza, and Luigi Zingales. 2002. “People’s Opium? Religion 
and Economic Activities,” NBER Working Paper 9237. Cambridge, MA: National 
Bureau of  Economic Research. 
Hofstede, Geert. 2001. Culture’s Consequences: Comparing Values, Behaviors, 
Institutions, and Organizations Across Nations (second edition). Thousand Oaks, CA:
Sage Publications. 
Hofstede, Geert and Michael Harris Bond. 1988. “The Confucius Connection: From 
Cultural Roots to Economic Growth,” Organizational Dynamics 16, no. 4: 4–21. 
Iannaccone, Laurence R. 1998. “Introduction to the Economics of Religion,” Journal 
of  Economic Literature 36, no. 3: 1465–96.
Kuran, Timur. 1992. “The Economic System in Contemporary Islamic Thought,” in 
K.S. Jomo ed., Islamic Economic Alternatives. London: Macmillan. 
Kuran, Timur. 1993. “The Economic Impact of Islamic Fundamentalism,” in M.E. 
Marty and R.S. Appleby, eds., Fundamentalisms and the State: Remaking Polities, 
Economies, and Militance. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. 
Kuran, Timur. 1997. “Islam and Underdevelopment: An Old Puzzle Revisited,” 
Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 153: 41–71. 
Kuran, Timur. 2002. “The Islamic Commercial Crisis: Institutional Roots of 
Economic Underdevelopment in the Middle East,” Los Angeles: USC Center for 
Law, Economics, and Organization Research Paper No. C01­12. 
Lal, Deepak. 1998. Unintended Consequences: The Impact of Factor Endowments, 
Culture, and Politics on Long­Run Economic Performance. Cambridge, MA: MIT 
Press. 
LaPorta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez­de­Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny. 
1997. “Trust in Large Organizations,” American Economic Review 87, no. 2: 333–38.
Levine, Ross, and David Renelt. 1992. “A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross­Country 
Growth Regressions,” American Economic Review 82, no. 4: 942–63. 
Lewis, Bernard. 1982. The Muslim Discovery of Europe. New York: W.W. Norton. 
Lewis, Bernard. 1993. Islam in History (second edition). Chicago: Open Court.
Lewis, W. Arthur. 1955. The Theory of Economic Growth. Homewood, IL: Richard 
D. Irwin. 
Lucas, Robert E. 1988. “On the Mechanics of Economic Development,” Journal of 
Monetary Economics 21, no. 1: 3–42.
McClelland, David C. 1961. The Achieving Society. New York: The Free Press. 
McClelland, David C. 1976. “New Introduction,” in The Achieving Society. New 
York: Wiley.
Mankiw, N. Gregory, David Romer, and David N. Weil. 1992. “A Contribution to the
Empirics of Economic Growth,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 107, no. 2: 407–37. 

9
Martin, David. 1978. A General Theory of Secularization. New York: Harper and 
Row. 
Martin, David. 1999. “The Evangelical Protestant Upsurge and Its Political 
Implications,” in Peter L. Berger, The Desecularization of the World: Resurgent 
Religion and World Politics. Grand Rapids, MI: William B. Eerdmans Publishing 
Company.
Metcalf, Barbara D. 1999. “Weber and Islamic Reform,” in Toby E. Huff and 
Wolfgang Schluchter eds., Max Weber and Islam. London: Transaction Publishers. 
Pack, Howard. 1994. “Endogenous Growth Theory: Intellectual Appeal and Empirical
Shortcomings,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 8, no. 1: 55–72.
Pack, Howard. 2001. “Technological Change and Growth in East Asia: Macro versus 
Micro Perspectives,” in Joseph E. Stiglitz and Shahid Yusuf, eds., Rethinking the East
Asian Miracle. New York: Oxford University Press. 
Robelo, Sergio. 1991. “Long­run Policy analysis and Long­run Growth,” Journal of 
Political Economy 99, no. 3: 500–21.
Rodinson, Maxime. 1973. Islam and Capitalism. New York: Pantheon Books. 
Rodrik, Dani. 1999. “The New Global Economy and Developing Countries: Making 
Openness Work,” Policy Essay No. 24. Washington: Overseas Development Council. 
Romer, Paul M. 1986. “Increasing Returns and Long­run Growth,” Journal of 
Political Economy
94, no. 5: 1002–37. 
Solow, Robert M. 2001. “Applying Growth Theory across Countries,” World Bank 
Economic Review 15, no. 2: 283–88.
Turner, Bryan S. 1974. Weber and Islam: A Critical Study. London: Routledge & 
Kegan Paul. 
Verweij, Johan, Peter Ester, and Rein Nauta. 1997. “Secularization as an Economic 
and Cultural  Phenomenon,” Journal of the Scientific Study of Religion. 36:2 309­24. 
Weber, Max. 1905/2002. The Protestant Ethic and the “Spirit” of Capitalism and 
Other Writings, New York: Penguin Books. 

10

You might also like