You are on page 1of 2

INSIGHTS | P E R S P E C T I V E S

C O M P L E X SYST E M S

Complexity theory and financial regulation


Economic policy needs interdisciplinary network analysis and behavioral modeling

By Stefano Battiston,1* J. Doyne Farmer,2,3 Recent research has revealed generic em- a whole. Despite on-going efforts, these ef-
Andreas Flache,4 Diego Garlaschelli,5 pirical quantitative indicators of resilience fects are unlikely to be routinely considered
Andrew G. Haldane,6 Hans Heesterbeek,7 that may be used across complex systems to anytime soon.
Cars Hommes,8,9† Carlo Jaeger,10,11,12 detect tipping points. Markers include rising Information asymmetry within a net-
Robert May,13 Marten Scheffer14 correlation between nodes in a network and work—e.g. where a bank does not know
rising temporal correlation, variance, and about troubled assets of other banks—can

T
raditional economic theory could not skewedness of fluctuation patterns. These be problematic. The banking network typi-
explain, much less predict, the near indicators were first predicted mathemati- cally displays a core-periphery structure,
collapse of the financial system and its cally and subsequently demonstrated experi-
long-lasting effects on the global econ- mentally in real complex systems, including
omy. Since the 2008 crisis, there has living systems (1). A recent study of the
been increasing interest in using ideas Dutch interbank network (2) showed that “…policies and financial
from complexity theory to make sense of eco-
nomic and financial markets. Concepts, such
standard analysis using a homogeneous net-
work model could only lead to late detection
regulation [that] weaken

Downloaded from on February 27, 2016


as tipping points, networks, contagion, feed- of the 2008 crisis, although a more realistic positive feedback…
back, and resilience have entered the finan- and heterogeneous network model could
cial and regulatory lexicon, but identify an early warning signal 3 years be-
stabiliz[e] experimental
POLICY actual use of complexity models fore the crisis (see the chart). macroeconomic systems…’’
and results remains at an early Ecologists have developed tools to quan-
stage. Recent insights and techniques offer tify the stability, robustness, and resilience with a core consisting of a relatively small
potential for better monitoring and manage- of food webs and have shown how these number of large, densely interconnected
ment of highly interconnected economic and depend on the topology of the network and banks that are not very diverse in terms of
financial systems and, thus, may help antici- the strengths of interactions (3). Epidemi- business and risk models. This implies that
pate and manage future crises. ologists have tools to gauge the potential for core banks’ defaults tend to be highly cor-
events to propagate in systems of interacting related. That, in turn, can generate a col-
TIPPING POINTS, WARNING SIGNALS. Fi- entities, to identify superspreaders and core lective moral hazard problem (i.e., players
nancial markets have historically exhibited groups relevant to infection persistence, and take on more risk, because others will bear
sudden and largely unforeseen collapses, at to design strategies to prevent or limit the the costs in case of default), as banks recog-
a systemic scale. Such “phase transitions” spread of contagion (4). nize that they are likely to be supported by
may in some cases have been triggered by Extrapolating results from the natural the authorities in situations of distress, the
unpredictable stochastic events. More of- sciences to economics and finance presents likelihood amplifies their incentives to herd
ten, however, there have been endogenous challenges. For instance, publication of an in the first place.
underlying processes at work. Analyses of early warning signal will change behavior Estimating systemic risk relies on granu-
complex systems ranging from the climate and affect future dynamics [the Lucas cri- lar data on the financial network. Unfortu-
to ecosystems reveal that, before a major tique (5)]. But this does not affect the case nately, business interactions between banks
transition, there is often a gradual and un- where indicators are known only to regula- are often hidden because of confidentiality
noticed loss of resilience. This makes the sys- tors or when the goal is to build better net- issues. Tools being developed to reconstruct
tem brittle: A small disruption can trigger a work barriers to slow contagion. networks from partial information and to
domino effect that propagates through the estimate systemic risk (7) suggest that pub-
system and propels it into a crisis state. TOO CENTRAL TO FAIL. Network effects licly available bank information does not al-
matter to financial-economic stability be- low reliable estimation of systemic risk. The
1
Department of Banking and Finance, University of Zurich, cause shock amplification may occur via estimate would improve greatly if banks
8032 Zürich, Switzerland. 2Institute for New Economic strong cascading effects. For example, the publicly reported the number of connec-
Thinking, Oxford Martin School, and Mathematical Institute, Bank of International Settlements recently tions with other banks, even without dis-
University of Oxford, Oxford OX1 2JD, UK. 3Santa Fe Institute,
Santa Fe, NM 87501, USA. 4Department of Sociology, developed a framework drawing on data on closing their identity.
University of Groningen, 9712 TG Groningen, Netherlands. the interconnectedness between banks to In addition to data, understanding the ef-
5
Lorentz Institute for Theoretical Physics, University of Leiden, gauge the systemic risk posed to the finan- fects of interconnections also relies on in-
2333 CA Leiden, Netherlands. 6Bank of England, London,
EC2R 8AH, UK. 7Faculty of Veterinary Medicine, University of
cial network by Global Systemically Impor- tegrative quantitative metrics and concepts
Utrecht, 3512 JE Utrecht, Netherlands. 8Amsterdam School of tant Banks. Recent research on contagion in that reveal important network aspects, such
Economics, University of Amsterdam, 1018 WB Amsterdam, financial networks has shown that network as systemic repercussions of the failure of
Netherlands. 9Tinbergen Institute, 1082 MS Amsterdam,
Netherlands. 10Beijing Normal University, 100875 Beijing,
topology and positions of banks matter; the individual nodes. For example, DebtRank,
China. 11Potsdam University, 14469 Potsdam, Germany. global financial network may collapse even which measures the systemic importance
12
Global Climate Forum 10178 Berlin, Germany. 13Department when individual banks appear safe (6). Cap- of individual institutions in a financial net-
of Zoology, University of Oxford, Oxford OX1 2JD, UK.
14
turing these effects is essential for quanti- work (8), shows that the issue of too-central-
Environmental Sciences, Wageningen University 6708 PB
Wageningen, Netherlands. *Authors are in alphabetical order. fying stress on individual banks and for to-fail may be even more important than
†Corresponding author. E-mail: C.H.Hommes@uva.nl looking at systemic risk for the network as too-big-to-fail.

818 19 FEBRUARY 2016 • VOL 351 ISSUE 6275 sciencemag.org SCIENCE

Published by AAAS
AGENTS AND BEHAVIOR. Agent-based Laboratory experiments with human monetary and fiscal policies and financial
models (ABMs) are computer models in subjects can provide empirical validation regulation designed to weaken positive feed-
which the behavior of agents and their in- of individual decision rules of agents, their back are successful in stabilizing experimen-
teractions are explicitly represented as de- interactions, and emergent macro behav- tal macroeconomic systems when properly
cision rules mapping agents’ observations ior. Recent experiments studying behavior calibrated (16). Complexity theory provides
onto actions. Although ABMs are less well of a group of individuals in the laboratory mathematical understanding of these effects.
established in analyzing financial-economic show that economic systems may deviate
systems than in, e.g., traffic control, epide- significantly from rational efficient equi- POLICY DASHBOARD. It is an opportune
miology, or battlefield conflict analyses, they librium at both individual and aggregate time for academic economists, complex-
have produced promising results. Axtell (9) levels (14). This generic feature of positive ity scientists, social scientists, ecologists,
developed a simple ABM that explains more feedback systems leads to persistent devia- epidemiologists, and researchers at finan-
than three dozen empirical properties of tions of prices from equilibrium and emer- cial institutions to join forces to develop
firm formation without recourse to external gence of speculation-driven bubbles and tools from complexity theory, as a comple-
shocks. ABMs provide a good explanation crashes, strongly amplified by coordination ment to existing economic modeling ap-
for why the volatility of prices is clustered on trend-following and herding behavior proaches (17). One ambitious option would
and time-varying (10) and have been used (15). There is strong empirical evidence of be an online, financial-economic dashboard
that integrates data, methods, and indica-
16 tors. This might monitor and stress-test the
Crisis
Homogeneous global socioeconomic and financial system
14 in something close to real time, in a way
similar to what is done with other complex
12
systems, such as weather systems or social
networks. The funding required for essential
10
policy-relevant and fundamental interdis-
8 ciplinary progress in these areas would be
trivial compared with the costs of systemic
6 financial failures or the collapse of the global
financial-economic system. ■
z-score

4
Precrisis REF ERENCES AND NOTES
1. M. Scheffer et al., Science 338, 344 (2012).
2
2. T. Squartini et al., Sci. Rep. 3, 3357 (2013).
Heterogeneous 3. R. M. May et al., Nature 451, 893 (2008).
0 4. H. Heesterbeek et al., Science 347, aaa4339 (2015).
Normal 5. R. E. Lucas Jr., Carnegie-Rochester Conf. Ser. Public Policy 1,
z-score range 19 (1976).
-2
6. S. Battiston et al., J. Econ. Dynam. Control 36, 1121 (2012).
7. G. Cimini et al., Sci. Rep. 5, 15758 (2015).
-4 8. S. Battiston et al., Sci. Rep. 2, 541 (2012).
9. R. Axtell, “Endogenous dynamics of multi-agent firms”
-6 (Working paper version 1.5, Univ. of Oxford, Oxford 2014);
www.css.gmu.edu/~axtell/Rob/Research/Pages/Firms.
1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 html.
10. B. LeBaron, in Handbook of Computational Economics,
Early-warning signals of the 2008 crisis in the Dutch interbank network. The figure portrays a temporal analysis vol.2, Agent-Based Computational Economics, L.
of two loops, pairs of banks that are at the same time debtor and creditor to each other. Although the raw number of Tesfatsion, and K. L. Judd, Eds. (North-Holland,
Amsterdam, 2006), pp. 1187–1233.
two loops is not very informative about possible ongoing structural changes, its comparison with a random network
11. S. Thurner et al., Quant. Finan. 12, 695 (2012).
model benchmark is. A z-score represents the number of standard deviations by which the number of two loops in 12. C. Aymanns, J. D. Farmer, J. Econ. Dyn. Control 50, 155
the real network deviates from its expected value in the model. Small magnitude z-scores (<3) indicate approximate (2015).
consistency with the model, whereas larger magnitudes indicate statistically significant deviations. Two different 13. A. Flache, M. W. Macy, J. Conflict Resolut. 55, 970 (2011).
14. T. Bao, C. Hommes, T. Makarewicz, “Bubble forma-
random network models were used: a homogeneous network with the same total number of links as in the real network tion and (in)efficient markets in learning-to-forecast
(top) and a heterogeneous network where every bank has the same number of connections as in the real network and –optimize experiments” (TI 2015-107/II Working
(bottom). The homogeneous model, often used in standard analyses, highlights only a late and abrupt structural paper, Tinbergen Institute, Amsterdam, 2015);
http://papers.tinbergen.nl/15107.pdf
change (2008). The more realistic heterogeneous model also identifies a gradual, early-warning “precrisis” phase 15. C. H. Hommes, Behavioral Rationality and Heterogeneous
(2005–2007). [Modified from (2)] Expectations in Complex Economic Systems (Cambridge
Univ. Press, Cambridge, 2013).
16. T. Bao, C. H. Hommes,“When speculators meet construc-
to test systemic risk implications of reforms these behaviors in financial markets in prac- tors: Positive and negative feedback in experimental housing
developed by the Basel Committee on Bank- tice, and these controlled laboratory experi- markets” (CeNDEF Working paper 15-10, University of
ing Supervision, which show how dynami- ments provide more detailed understanding Amsterdam, Netherlands, 2015); http://bit.ly/WP15-10.
17. A. G. Haldane, “On microscopes and telescopes,” Workshop
cally changing risk limits can lead to booms of mechanisms, causality, and conditions for on Socio-Economic Complexity, Lorentz Center, Leiden, 23
and busts in prices (11, 12). ABMs of market emergence of macro phenomena.
ILLUSTRATION: C. SMITH/SCIENCE

to 27 March 2015 (Bank of England, London, 2015); http://


dynamics can be linked with ABM work on A simple behavioral model, with agents bit.ly/1VIJlvX.
opinion dynamics in the social sciences (13) gradually switching to better performing
ACKNOWL EDGMENTS
to understand how propagation of opinions heuristics, explains individual, as well as We acknowledge financial support from The Netherlands
through social networks affects emergent emergent, macro behavior in these laboratory Institute of Advanced Studies in the Humanities and Social
macro behavior, which is crucial to manag- economies. The experiments also provide Sciences, The Netherlands Organisation for Scientific Research,
the Lorentz Center, and the Tinbergen Institute.
ing the stability and resilience of socioeco- a general mechanism for managing social
nomic systems. contagion in such systems. For example, 10.1126/science.aad0299

SCIENCE sciencemag.org 19 FEBRUARY 2016 • VOL 351 ISSUE 6275 819


Published by AAAS

You might also like