You are on page 1of 8

Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 3125–3132

Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect

Journal of Banking & Finance


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jbf

Systemic risk, macroprudential policy frameworks, monitoring financial


systems and the evolution of capital adequacy
Bruce Arnold a, Claudio Borio b, Luci Ellis c, Fariborz Moshirian d,⇑
a
Australian Prudential Regulation Authority, Sydney, Australia
b
Bank for International Settlements, Basel, Switzerland
c
Reserve Bank of Australia, Sydney, Australia
d
Institute of Global Finance, University of New South Wales, Sydney, Australia

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: This paper analyses various issues that need to be tackled when promoting financial stability, reviewing
Available online 1 August 2012 the progress made in certain key areas and the remaining challenges. It explores the measurement of sys-
temic risk and of individual institutions’ contribution to it. It discusses aspects of macroprudential frame-
JEL classifications: works, including how the countercyclical capital buffer envisaged in Basel III takes into account the
G15 properties of the financial cycle and the strengths and weaknesses of macro-stress tests. It analyses some
G25 of the challenges of how best to monitor financial systems and the broader economy in order to detect
Keywords:
signs of vulnerability that might lead to future bouts of financial instability and of how to set prudential
Systemic risk policy accordingly. And it discusses the evolution of capital adequacy standards and the new emphasis on
Macroprudential polices liquidity standards in international regulation.
Monitoring financial systems Ó 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
Capital adequacy

1. Introduction This paper begins with a discussion of systemic risk. It focuses


on concerns associated with systemically important institutions
The recent financial crisis has highlighted the importance of which, through their size and influence, might influence the stabil-
promoting financial stability through better regulation and super- ity of the financial system. It discusses recent advances in the mea-
vision of financial institutions. Key aspects of recent regulatory re- surement of systemic risk, the difficulties in implementing such
forms include measuring and regulating systemic risk, and measures across multiple, different markets, and the need to
designing macroprudential policies appropriately. This has been a appropriately calibrate policies according to the risks posed by
focus of institutions such as the European Systemic Risk Board banks, so-called shadow banks, and other institutions across many
(in the EU) and the Financial Stability Oversight Council (in the jurisdictions.
US, as well as at the global level. The paper next situates financial institutions within the financial
This paper comes at a time of significant policy reform, designed cycle, with an emphasis on macroprudential policies. It discusses
to respond to the increasingly interconnected nature of financial the importance of the financial cycle within macroprudential frame-
institutions and the lessons of the Global Financial Crisis (GFC). works and the usefulness (or otherwise) of macroprudential stress
In recent years, the collapse of numerous financial institutions tests. Macroprudential factors can feed into the riskiness inherent
has imposed significant negative externalities on governments in systemically important institutions, though of course institu-
and the economy at large. This has increased the interest in mea- tion-specific factors such as risk appetite and business models mat-
suring the riskiness of financial institutions and appropriately allo- ter as well.
cating risks (and costs) across them in order to account for the The following section discusses barriers that might arise in
negative externalities associated with financial instability. Against monitoring and regulating issues associated with systemic risk
this backdrop, there is a growing awareness of the need for a mac- and macroprudential policies. The two main challenges are those
roprudential approach to regulation and of a better management of associated with monitoring and analyzing risk, and those
the financial cycle. Systemic risk is of the essence here. The chal- associated with practical policy making. The paper discusses the
lenges in implementing the resulting reforms should not be challenges in designing regulation appropriate to multiple jurisdic-
underestimated. tions, especially if these regulations are drawn too tightly in a rule-
based fashion.
⇑ Corresponding author. Tel.: +61 2 93855859; fax: +61 2 93854763. The paper goes onto analyze how understanding of adequate
E-mail address: f.moshirian@unsw.edu.au (F. Moshirian). capital requirements has changed over time, thereby highlighting

0378-4266/$ - see front matter Ó 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2012.07.023
3126 B. Arnold et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 3125–3132

one of the challenges involved in regulation: adapting to advances financial system (i.e. bank based versus market based) can influ-
in financial markets and research. The paper focuses on the evolu- ence the time required to recover from an economic downturn,
tion from the Basel I to the Basel III framework, the main lesson implying that financial-market-structure influences the nature of
being that regulation must continually evolve in light of changes banking risk within a country. Thus, more research needs to be
in our understanding of risk factors and in the risks that financial done to verify whether signals about systemic weakness in finan-
institutions face. cial firms are reliable from these markets.
The structure of this paper is as follows. Section 2 discusses Considerable work has been under way seeking to measure
some of the recent developments on measuring systemic risk, more precisely individual institutions’ contribution to overall sys-
including risks in large banks that could contribute to financial temic risk. Tarashev et al. (2010) propose the ‘Contribution Ap-
instability. Section 3 discusses the role of the financial cycle in proach’ (CA) method of attributing systemic risk to separate
shaping policy reforms. Section 4 highlights the difficulties in- institutions. The model is based on Shapley values, a game-theo-
volved in formulating policy and monitoring institutions, espe- retic concept initially applied to the measurement of the contribu-
cially in an international context. Section 5 reinforces the points tion of an individual to the output of a group. The idea is to
raised in Section 4 by discussing how our understanding of risk determine an institution’s incremental contribution to the overall
and monitoring has changed over time. Section 6 concludes. level of systemic risk, and is general enough to apply to a wide
variety of systemic risk measures (e.g., a system-wide Value at Risk
or Expected Shortfall). Tarashev et al. (2010) highlight that key
2. Systemic risk
drivers of an institution’s contribution include its relative size, its
probability of default, and its exposure to a common risk factor.
Achieving macroeconomic stability requires the identification
They suggest that regulatory tools could be calibrated with respect
of systemic risk in the financial system and of the factors that
to such contributions.
are driving it. In his speech at the 13th conference of the ECB-
Drehmann and Tarashev (2011) build on the framework in
CFS research network, Trichet (2010), President of the European
Tarashev et al. (2010) to propose a ‘Generalized Contribution Ap-
Central Bank, defined systemic risk as financial instability ‘‘so
proach’ (GCA) to apportioning systemic risk, taking explicitly into
widespread that it impairs the functioning of a financial system
account interbank networks, captured only implicitly through the
to the point where economic growth and welfare suffer materi-
exposures to common factors in the previous piece of work1 Specif-
ally’’. While there is no universally accepted definition, let alone
ically, Drehmann and Tarashev (2011) account for how a bank can
an accepted measure to quantify this risk, there is a consensus that
propagate shocks throughout a system by assuming that if losses
the regulatory and supervisory framework should have effective
are large enough, counterparties will also fail along a kind of domino
mechanisms to detect it and manage it.
chain. Relatedly, Billio et al. (2012) propose ways to measure this
interconnectedness, which could then feed into the analysis of
2.1. Measuring systemic risk risk-allocation.
Bisias et al. (2012) survey most of the issues related to systemic
There are at least three major issues in the field of measuring risk and analyze 31 quantitative measures of systemic risk. They
systemic risk. The first issue is how to measure the drivers of sys- discuss these issues from both a supervisory and a research per-
temic risk. Some recent studies have focused on individual mea- spective. They also analyze the critical role of data in this process.
sures of systemic risk, which seek to predict how much the
stocks of financial institutions fall in a major market downturn
(the stress event). Acharya and Richardson (2009) and Acharya 2.2. Banking crises and shadow banking
et al. (2010), and Acharya et al. (2012) lay the theoretical founda-
tions of such an approach. In a downturn, financial institutions Another area of research that could be promoted is testing
may fall short of capital, which can lead to a failure (and possible across multiple crises in different economic situations, because it
contagion) unless some other investor steps in. Governments usu- is not always clear what triggers a financial crisis. In the theory
ally want to minimize the resulting cost to the taxpayer, which on banking crises, several channels have been proposed including
Acharya et al. (2012) show to be a function of size, leverage and interconnectedness (Rochet and Tirole (1996)), liquidity spirals
expected equity losses during a crisis. While the first two compo- (Brunnermeir and Pedersen (2009)) and macro-uncertainty (Chari
nents are easily available, econometric techniques may be neces- and Jagannathan (1988)). Borio and Drehmann (2009) show that
sary to predict the expected equity loss in a financial crisis. it is possible to create indicators, such as the increase in credit
Acharya et al. (2012) propose a simple historical estimator. Brown- and asset prices that can help to detect the build-up of risk of fu-
lees and Engle (2010) suggest a bivariate model of returns that uses ture banking distress originating from a common source of pri-
asymmetric GARCH for volatility and an asymmetric DCC model for vate-sector excesses. In the recent crisis, US banks may have
correlation. A third method eschews modeling the entire return been affected because of large correlated holdings (Acharya and
process and only models the tail (as in De Jonghe (2010)). Richardson (2009) and Acharya et al. (2010)) but banks in the
These models have worked reasonably well in the United States, Euro-zone may have been impacted because of liquidity shortages
but might require enhancement for use in other markets. Brown- (Diamond and Rajan (2005)), a combination of both or other fac-
lees and Engle (2010) and Acharya et al. (2012) have shown that tors, as analyzed by Moshirian (2011). As research on systemic risk
their signal worked well in predicting which US major banks would continues, one has to ensure that eventually the measures of sys-
be severely affected in the 2007–2008 crisis. Their work is now temic risk are robust to a variety of different channels that may
being extended to other banks in Europe and in Asia. One of the have caused distress in financial institutions.
challenges of researchers and institutions is to determine which, Furthermore, modern financial institutions have a complex net-
if any, of these signals about systemic risk in the US work in an work of contracts. During the 2007–2008 financial crisis, AIG, one
international context over multiple crises while controlling for het- of the largest insurance companies in the US, had to be rescued
erogeneity in economic development, financial sector structure with $182.5 billion in loans. All the classic studies of financial
and regulations. For example, Griffin et al. (2010) show that stock
prices in emerging markets may reflect less idiosyncratic informa- 1
Some other researchers (e.g. Liu and Staum (2010)) have also used interbank
tion. Allen et al. (forthcoming) show that the structure of a network for this purposes, albeit with complex linear programming techniques.
B. Arnold et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 3125–3132 3127

crises, such as Reinhart and Rogoff (2009b), have only focused on surcharges adopted in Basel III seek to address these issues head-
banks. However, future research should also advance the literature on.
by considering systemic risk associated with major non-bank
financial players: these institutions can also contribute to systemic
3. The financial cycle: two lessons for macroprudential
risk but are often less regulated.
frameworks

Over the past two decades, the academic profession and policy-
2.3. Non-bank activities, bank concentrations, and systemic risk
makers have had a ‘‘crash course’’ in financial crises. But it was the
latest one, which broke out in 2007, that has done more than most
Another focus of financial market analysts and regulators in re-
to shape our understanding of financial instability. Not least, that
cent times has been the increasing reliance on non-interest income
crisis has dispelled the notion held in some quarters that financial
and non-deposit funding in banks. Demigurc-Kunt and Huizinga
crises with serious global financial and macroeconomic conse-
(2010) empirically corroborate this change in the balance sheet
quences could not occur in mature and highly sophisticated finan-
and revenue sources of banks by examining 1334 banks in 101
cial systems. By striking at the very nerve-centers of the Western
countries leading up to the 2008 crisis. Anecdotal evidence in the
economy, it was bound to trigger a major rethink of analytical
recent financial crisis would suggest that banks with large invest-
frameworks and policy.
ment banking units (Citibank) or trading books generally were sig-
The main analytical paradigm shift has been the rediscovery of
nificantly affected in the recent crisis. This is backed up by financial
the financial cycle as the factor that underlies severe financial cri-
theory, which has long shown the potential for moral hazard and
ses; that is, as the systematic factor hidden behind the myriad of
increased likelihood of failure as a bank expands into other lines
idiosyncratic elements that tend to cloud our understanding of
of business (Boyd et al. (1998).2 For example, Gennaioli et al.
the processes involved. The main policy paradigm shift has been
(2012) emphasize the risks that can arise in the presence of financial
the strengthening of the macroprudential, or systemic, orientation
innovation in non-commercial bank activities. This is not to say that
of regulatory and supervisory frameworks; that is, the recognition
all investment banking operations in financial institutions are dam-
that frameworks focused on seeking to ensure that individual insti-
aging, simply that an awareness of the potential risk associated with
tutions are sound on a stand-alone basis, as prevailed in many
them is necessary.
jurisdictions, were flawed. It could miss the wood for the trees.
Another important area of research has focused on whether
This section summarizes what we have learnt about the finan-
competition in the banking sector should be increased, whether
cial cycle in recent years and derives two implications for macro-
the size of large banks or the nature of their activities may have
prudential policy frameworks. In doing so, it draws largely on BIS
to be modified, and whether funding sources and activities should
research.
be regulated and corporate governance mechanisms altered. There
Three takeaway messages are worth highlighting. First, when
is a need for more research to analyze how these factors influence
the focus in on banking crises, the financial cycle is best character-
systemic risk. There are conflicting views in the academic literature
ized in terms of the behavior of private sector credit and property
about how competition in the banking industry affects fragility.
prices. Moreover, it is a medium-term phenomenon, with a dura-
Boyd and De Nicolo (2005) argue that a more concentrated banking
tion that extends well beyond traditional business cycles. Second,
sector allows banks to charge higher interest rates, which raises
the countercyclical capital buffer envisaged in Basel III takes fully
the risk profile of borrowers and consequently their vulnerability
into account the properties of the financial cycle. Finally, contrary
to default. By contrast, Hellman et al. (2000) posit that a more con-
to what is often believed, macro-stress tests – a popular tool in the
centrated banking sector offers more stability: bank owners reduce
emerging macroprudential frameworks – are ill-suited as early
risk because they want to earn monopoly profits and retain fran-
warning devices, i.e. as tools to identify vulnerabilities during
chise value. Engle et al. (2012) investigate the relationship be-
seemingly tranquil times. By contrast, if properly designed, they
tween business activities chosen by large banks and the
can be quite effective in crisis management and resolution.
concentration of banks within a country. They find that banks in
countries with low levels of concentration have higher levels of
non-interest income. The non-interest income generating activities 3.1. Characterizing the financial cycle3
of these banks improved risk adjusted profitability before the
2007–2008 financial crisis, but caused a sharp decrease in profit- In what follows, the term ‘‘financial cycle’’ denotes those self-
ability after the crisis. They find that non-interest income failed reinforcing fluctuations in perceptions and attitudes towards risk,
to provide diversification benefits for these banks during a finan- financing constraints and asset prices that tend to amplify business
cial crisis because it was more exposed to systemic risk in this fluctuations and that may lead to widespread financial distress and
episode. macroeconomic dislocations. These self-reinforcing fluctuations
A closely related issue is that of ‘Systemically Important Banks’ have also come to be known as the ‘‘procyclicality’’ of the financial
(SIBs) and ‘Global Systemically Important Banks’ (G-SIBs). G-SIBs system.
are banks that contribute a lot to systemic risk by virtue of their Empirical work suggests that the financial cycle, so defined, has
size, interconnectedness and/or other characteristics. A major con- five key properties.
cern is that the failure of a G-SIB can force a government to ‘bail First, the most parsimonious description of the financial cycle is
out’ the institution, thereby imposing significant negative external- in terms of the behavior of private-sector credit and property
ities on the public. One approach is to draw on the research, such prices. Equity prices can be a distraction: they exhibit shorter cy-
as that by Tarashev et al. (2010) and Drehmann and Tarashev cles and tend to be more closely related to short-term fluctuations
(2011), to calibrate regulatory tools with respect to an institution’s in GDP, which may leave the financial sector largely unscathed.
marginal contribution to systemic risk. However, such an approach This is most concretely illustrated by the experience of several
must necessarily work at a global level, requiring greater countries in the 1987-early 1990s and in 2001–2008. In each case,
coordination amongst the institutions’ home countries. The capital the crash in equity prices and the accompanying slowdown in eco-
nomic activity at the beginning of the period hardly made a dent in
2
By contrast, Barth et al. (2004) find that countries that restrict the activities of
3
banks are more prone to financial crisis. This section draws, in particular, on Drehmann et al. (2012).
3128 B. Arnold et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 3125–3132

the build-up of the financial cycle. Partly in response to the mone- have a single variable that could guide both the build-up and re-
tary easing that followed, the credit-to-GDP ratio and property lease phases of the buffer. But is this really possible? The problem
prices continued to climb, only to collapse a few years further is that the best variable for the build-up phase would be the best
down the road, generating a financial crisis and a much larger drop leading indicator of banking distress. Policymakers and market
in output. In fact, from a medium-term perspective, one could participants should have sufficient time to build the system’s de-
characterize the economic slowdowns that went hand-in-hand fenses. By contrast, the best variable for the release phase would
with the equity price crashes as ‘‘unfinished recessions’’. be the best contemporaneous indicator of banking distress. The
Second, and generalizing the previous point, the financial cycle buffer should be usable as soon as strains emerge. But it is hard
has a much lower frequency than the traditional business cycle. to imagine how the same variable could do both!
Since financial liberalization, the typical cycle length is of the order The design of the countercyclical buffer addresses this issue by
of 16–20 years. This compares with typical business cycle frequen- distinguishing between the indicators for the two phases. For the
cies of up to 8 years. In other words, the financial cycle is a med- build-up phase, the preferred reference guide described in the
ium-term phenomenon. BCBS documents is the credit-to-GDP gap, i.e. the deviation of
Third, peaks in the financial cycle tend to coincide with episodes the ratio from a medium-term trend that is in fact consistent with
of financial distress. For example, in a sample of seven industrial the average length of the financial cycle noted above. For the re-
countries4 examined in Drehmann et al. (2012), all post-financial lease phase, since it has not proved possible to identify any single
liberalization financial cycle peaks are associated with either full- variable that would work consistently across countries, the trigger
blown crises or serious financial strains. is based on an evaluation that stress has materialized, which could
Fourth, and conversely, few crises do not occur at such peaks. be rely on variables such as credit spreads, and bank losses.
And these crises turn out to reflect exposures to financial cycles Two additional issues concerning the design of the buffer are
abroad. Obvious recent examples include the recent crises in especially important.
Germany and Switzerland, in which banks incurred losses on their The first issue concerns the balance between rules and discre-
exposures to financial cycles rooted mainly in the United States tion. Ideally, rules are important as pre-commitment devices and
and United Kingdom. to help the authorities resist the huge political economy pressures
Fifth, it is possible to construct real-time indicators of banking to refrain from taking restrictive action during booms. But the
crises that provide fairly reliable signals with quite a good lead – scheme is necessarily a simplification. Thus, for the build-up phase,
between 2 and 4 years, depending on the calibration (e.g., Borio the credit-to-GDP gap acts purely as a reference guide, as a starting
and Drehmann (2009)). Not surprisingly, such indicators are based point for a richer, far from mechanical assessment of the risks. The
on (private-sector) credit-to-GDP and asset prices (especially prop- second issue concerns how to address cross-border exposures.
erty prices) jointly exceeding certain thresholds, which fall outside There is an identification problem: what happens if losses are in-
normal historical ranges. One can think of these indicators as prox- curred on exposures to financial cycles abroad? And there is a con-
ies for the build-up of financial imbalances, and as tools that help trol problem: how can national authorities offset the impact of
policymakers distinguish sustainable from unsustainable booms. international lending? This form of lending may take place directly
The indicators appear to perform also quite well out of sample. from abroad or through domestic branches, which are often pri-
Finally, the amplitude and length of the financial cycle are marily under the jurisdiction of the home authorities, i.e. those
regime-dependent: they do not reflect by any means ‘‘natural con- where the headquarters of the transnational banks are located.
stants’’. Arguably, three key factors support financial cycles: finan- Home authorities may have little incentive to take action because
cial liberalization, which weakens financing constraints; monetary of a natural size asymmetry: typically, the exposures involved are
policy frameworks focused on near-term inflation control, which small relative to the size of the transnational banks’ portfolios, but
can provide less resistance to the build-up of financial imbalances large relative to the host country’s financial system or GDP.
as long as inflation remains low and stable; and positive supply- The scheme tackles these two problems head-on. To address the
side developments (e.g., the globalization of real economy), which identification problem, the buffer is calculated in relation to the
provide fuel for the financial boom while at the same time putting weighted average of the exposures of a bank to the various juris-
downward pressure on inflation. It is not a coincidence, therefore, dictions. For example, based on the credit-to-GDP gap indicator,
that financial cycles have doubled in length since financial liberal- German and Swiss banks with large exposures to the United States
ization in the early and mid-1980s and that they have been espe- would have seen a significant increase in their capital buffer on
cially virulent since the early 1990s. those exposures ahead of the crisis. To address the control problem
the scheme envisages cooperative (reciprocity) arrangements. It is
3.2. Policy lesson: the countercyclical capital buffer5 the host authority that activates the buffer when signs of the build-
up in risks emerge in its jurisdiction; and the home authorities can
The countercyclical capital buffer envisaged in Basel III takes do more, but never less. All this implies a major shift in responsi-
fully on board the previous stylized facts (BCBS (2010a, 2010b), bility from home to host authorities. And it could work as a model
Caruana (2010)), The scheme is designed to build up buffers during of cross-border cooperation for a broader set of (macro-)prudential
the boom in the financial cycle and to draw them down as stress tools.
materializes. Its main goal is to protect banks from the bust of
the cycle, thereby limiting the risk of banking crises. A collateral
benefit is that it may also restrain the boom in the first place. How-
ever, since capital is both cheap and plentiful during booms, this 3.3. Policy lesson: macro-stress tests6
collateral benefit may prove to be elusive, at least for the typical
size of the buffer contemplated in the scheme. The nature of the financial cycle has important implications for
A constraint in the design of the scheme is that it should be sim- what macro-stress tests can and cannot be expected to do. Given
ple and easily understandable. Ideally, therefore, one would like to current technology, macro-stress tests are ill suited as early warn-
ing devices. In fact, none flashed red ahead of the current crisis.
4
That said, if properly designed, they can be quite effective as crisis
The countries are Australia, Japan, Germany, Norway, Sweden, the United
Kingdom and the United States.
5 6
This section draws, in particular, on Drehmann et al. (2011,2012). This section is based on Borio et al. (2012).
B. Arnold et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 3125–3132 3129

management and resolution tools. The recent US experience prob- has been made. And, not uncharacteristically, policies have moved
ably comes closest to the use of the tool in such a context. ahead of academic research: waiting was not an option. It is high
There are basically two reasons why macro-stress tests are inef- time for research to catch up and move ahead of the curve (Borio
fective as early warning devices: technical shortcomings and (2011)). The field is there for the taking.
context.
The technical shortcomings relate to the fact that the current
4. Challenges of monitoring and policy-making
generation of models that underlie stress tests is unable to provide
a realistic picture of the dynamics of financial distress. In particu-
This section considers the challenges associated both with mon-
lar, the models and procedures cannot meaningfully capture the
itoring financial systems and institutions and with constructing
relevant non-linearities and feed-backs, both within the financial
policy. Section 4.1 addresses the issue of monitoring. Section 4.2
system and between the financial system and the macroeconomy.
considers challenges involved in policy-making.
No matter how hard you shake the box, little falls out! This means
that the action is shifted to the size of the ‘‘shocks’’, which end up
being unreasonably large. More generally, the very structure of 4.1. Challenges of monitoring and analysis
macro-stress tests in the antithesis of what financial instability is
all about. The essence of financial instability is that normal-sized When implementing this array of policy proposals, financial sta-
shocks cause the system to break down. An unstable financial sys- bility policymakers have faced a number of practical challenges.
tem is a fragile system; it is not one that would break down only if First among these is how best to monitor financial systems and
hit by an extraordinarily large recession. The available empirical the broader economy to detect signs of vulnerabilities that might
evidence strongly supports this point. Financial crises occur before lead to future bouts of financial instability. Policymakers had argu-
output has contracted significantly and before asset prices (prop- ably been held back in this regard because the canonical models
erty) or credit growth have fallen significantly. used in mainstream macroeconomics in recent years have not been
The context is what might be called the ‘‘paradox of financial suitable guides for this work. The DSGE framework makes a
instability’’: the system looks strongest precisely when it is most number of micro-foundational assumptions that are singularly
fragile. Credit growth and asset prices are unusually strong, lever- unhelpful in framing analysis in support of financial stability poli-
age measured at market prices artificially low, profits and asset cymaking. In particular, the default assumption of a representative
quality especially healthy, risk premia and volatilities unusually agent makes it difficult to model the distributional issues that are
low precisely when risk is highest. What looks like low risk is, in so important when detecting vulnerabilities, and relaxing this
fact, a sign of aggressive risk-taking. In other words, if interpreted assumption meaningfully can make the model intractable. The
literally, these indicators show trouble far too late, only when the usual rationality assumption, of a particular definition of rational
risk that has built up during the boom materializes. All this com- expectations where the agents have full information about the
pounds the deficiencies in the models. Initial conditions look workings of the model, likewise tends to rule out crucial behaviors
unusually good. And, psychologically, the context fuels the ‘‘this- such as debt default and over-exuberance.
time-is-different’’ syndrome (Reinhart and Rogoff (2009a)), some- Instead, policymakers have looked to other parts of the litera-
thing to which not even the authorities are immune. ture for guidance on alternative models that could help frame their
The bottom line is that as early warning devices macro-stress monitoring and analysis. Three aspects of financial vulnerability
tests are more likely to be part of the problem than of the solution. have motivated a great deal of new research, as well as much of
They risk lulling policymakers into a false sense of security. And the post-crisis efforts to expand and enhance statistical collections
they did so in spades ahead of the recent crisis. (IMF, 2009).
For much the same reasons, macro-stress tests can do consider-
ably better as crisis management and resolution tools. Now the  Leverage: As became clear during the crisis, the most leveraged
deck is stacked in their favor, or at least not obviously against. banks and other players in the market are the most likely to
The crisis has already erupted. As a result, vulnerabilities and become distressed. Some of the banks at the center of the crisis
non-linearities have revealed themselves, balance sheets are weak, had increased their raw leverage significantly in the preceding
banks are incurring losses or recording low profits, and hubris has years, often in ways that the Basel II risk-weighted capital
given way to prudence. In addition, the shocks envisaged are not adequacy rules would not detect. Work by Geanokoplos and
such unrealistic extrapolations of actual historical experience, as his co-authors, among others, has emphasized the role of lever-
would be required to generate a severe crisis in a model for a juris- age in creating and propagating distress amongst investors and
diction where no crisis has occurred for some time. holders of financial products.
Macro-stress tests can then be helpful in identifying the need  Maturity transformation: Banks are in the business of transform-
for additional capital to prevent unnecessary credit crunches and ing maturity and taking on the attendant risks. In the years
in sorting out strong from weak institutions to resolve them prop- leading up to the crisis, however, a range of ‘shadow banks’
erly. This can help to address the excess capacity in the industry and market participants took on such risks without having
generated during the preceding unsustainable boom. either the capital or the access to central bank liquidity that
That said, for macro-stress tests to work it is essential to design have long been known to be necessary to avoid runs. Banks
them correctly. This means having the will to shake the system themselves also failed to allow for the possibility that funding
hard. It means seeing them as complements, and never as substi- markets could become disorderly, and some began to rely on
tutes, for a tough inspection of the value of banks’ assets. And it repo markets and other very short-maturity funding. The role
means having capital and liquidity backstops in place. These condi- of liquidity and short-term funding has been emphasized in
tions are necessary to get meaningful results and to secure the the work of Shin and his co-authors.
credibility of the tests.  Interconnectedness: One good example of work in this area is the
rapidly developing financial stability literature that borrows
3.4. Summary from the theory of networks developed by researchers in other
fields. The paper by Fukuda in this volume takes another view of
A better understanding of the financial cycle will help us devel- interconnectedness, in this case between interbank money mar-
op better analytical models and better policies. Belatedly, progress kets located in different countries.
3130 B. Arnold et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 3125–3132

Looking further back, four strands of older literature appear rel- assumptions of the mainstream DSGE literature. The first of these
evant for practical implementation of monitoring and policymak- emphasizes the role of emergent behavior from the interaction of
ing to promote financial stability.7 agents. Feedback effects pervade financial systems. These feedback
The first is careful accounting of stock-flow imbalances in the effects include the effects of decisions by lenders or borrowers on
style of Wynne Godley. This has been the backbone of traditional their counterparties, by suppliers of credit on asset prices and thus
macro-financial analysis, focused on saving–investment behavior owners of those assets (even when they are not customers of that
and its balance sheet counterparts, both of sectors and whole econ- lender), or by the creditors of a financial intermediary on that
omies. Analysis of the composition of household and business intermediaries’ borrowing customers in turn. In particular, lenders’
balance sheets, funding requirements of the financial sector and decisions can affect the economic situation of their borrower cus-
debt-servicing obligations all fall into this tradition, and are al- tomers, which if it reaches a point of sufficient economic distress,
ready frequently seen in central banks’ financial stability reviews can feed back onto the viability of those lenders. Examining the
and similar publications. behavior of one institution in isolation, or of a representative agent,
The second older analytical tradition can be traced to the histor- is therefore often not helpful in understanding or predicting out-
icism of Kindleberger, and related to that, Minsky’s insight that sta- comes at the level of the whole system, but neither is examining
bility can breed future instability. The notion of a credit cycle, the system without considering interaction effects.
somehow separate from the business cycle, that builds up as Since mainstream DSGE-type models become analytically
risk-taking and asset prices rise, stems from Minsky’s work, intractable with multiple agent types, some researchers have
although his taxonomy of borrowing phases is usually only implicit turned instead to agent-based modeling (ABM): see Tesfatsion
in more recent research. Policy-oriented analysis that belongs to (2006) for a survey and Leijonhufvud (2006) for some reflections
this tradition includes monitoring of credit flows by purpose, with on the usefulness of this methodology in macroeconomics and
specific attention to debt-funded speculative asset purchases. Ana- financial stability analysis specifically. This strand of literature
lysts and policymakers in this tradition would need information on and techniques emphasizes emergent behavior the possibility of
the fundamentals of different investment projects and asset mar- nonlinear phase transitions, for example between a ‘normal’ state
kets, to determine when ‘hedge’ finance has turned into the spec- and a distressed or ‘crisis’ state. An example of this nonlinearity
ulative or Ponzi kind. might be seen in the extent of the collapse in world trade in late
A third tradition focuses on governance, legal contract details 2008, and slow subsequent recovery, compared with the faster
and the scope for fraud. Galbraith (2009) has linked this perspective recoveries from the shocks to trade arising from natural disasters
to the work of Galbraith senior; some others in this broad tradition in Japan and Thailand in 2011. Although it is not explicitly an
include Akerlof and Stiglitz, including their work on default and ABM, the paper by Affinito (forthcoming) certainly puts relation-
asymmetric information. The paper by Aebi et al. (forthcoming) ships between different kinds of agents – in this case, banks and
with its focus on governance, falls partly into this strand of re- their customers – front and center.
search, as does much of the literature dissecting the specific failing The second strand of micro-level focus emphasizes less the
in the US mortagage market in the lead-up to the housing bust interactions between the agents as the diversity amongst them.
there. Losses on a segment of a leverage investor’s assets can lead to dis-
Aebi et al’s finding that corporate governance over risk manage- tress and failure even while the ‘median’ asset performs well. Tra-
ment was the most important element of governance determining ditional prudential stress-testing of every institution in an industry
banks’ performance during the crisis points to the crucial role of could be considered to fall into this stream of work, in a way that a
risk appetite and risk-taking behavior as an indicator of vulnerabil- stress-test based on macro-level variables does not. By examining
ities. Such a focus on behavior is another way of framing some of results for individual banks or portfolios, supervisors and other
the boom-bust dynamics that form the basis of the Minsky–Kind- policymakers can detect (cross-sectional) tail risk: vulnerabilities
leberger tradition of literature; some more recent attempts to that are not apparent in macro-level data. Here some of the work
quantify risk-taking as a key dynamic and source of vulnerability of the actuarial profession may be brought to bear, particularly
in economic systems include Borio and Zhu (2008) and Altunbas the parts of the risk-management literature focused on extreme va-
et al. (2009). The paper by Klomp and de Haan in this volume sug- lue theory (e.g., MacNeil et al. (2005) and other papers by these
gests that prudential regulation and supervision does indeed affect authors). While the mainstream finance literature has traditionally
risk-taking and thus the risk profile of banks, most significantly focused on pricing and thus the whole distribution of possible out-
amongst the higher-risk banks. comes, the actuarial literature by definition has focused on ex-
Another signal of governance issues that might lead to vulnera- treme outcomes and model risk.
bilities and future financial disruption is rent-seeking. Rent-seek-
ing is normally defined as using private information or other 4.2. Challenges of practical policymaking
advantages to obtain a private gain, without adding any economic
value. Such behavior thrives in complex, opaque markets or where As analytical models improve, policymakers will increasingly
there are long chains of agents between the ultimate principal and face the question of whether and how they should respond if those
the underlying transaction; a perfect example of such an environ- models imply that risks and vulnerabilities in the financial system
ment is the structured finance market during the years leading up have risen. Possible responses range from issuing warnings – for
to the crisis. Rent-seeking is hard to quantify, but can often be example in financial stability reviews or speeches – to more expli-
identified through careful analysis of contract terms, and supervi- cit policy interventions such as controls on the property market.
sory observation of market participants’ behavior and attitudes. Normal prudential supervision clearly can be included in the set
Two other, inter-related analytical perspectives in some senses of possible interventions. Inappropriate mandates have con-
bring the focus of attention back to the micro-level, on the strained supervisors in some countries from taking systemic issues
behavior of individual agents, but without making the strong into account – forcing them to take a purely ‘microprudential’ view
as noted above. However, supervisors in at least several countries
have shown a willingness to use the powers available to them in
7
The first three of these strands of literature were pointed out as being useful in
the interests of the stability of the whole system.
Galbraith (2009). Several other authors (e.g. White, 2008) have emphasized the While some supervisors have long been successfully manipulat-
Minsky–Kindleberger tradition over alternatives. ing microprudential tools for macroprudential reasons, designing
B. Arnold et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 3125–3132 3131

macroprudential policy rules seems more problematic. In large empirical research efforts, but subject to independent supervisory
part this is because of a lack of theoretical work that could be used evaluation.
to guide good practice. Policymakers find themselves relying on From a research perspective, there is still work to be done in
the experience of other countries, which might not be relevant to refining methodologies and quantifying risk, and in assessing the
their own systems. There is very little theoretical or other compar- effectiveness of the various aspects of the capital-adequacy regime.
ative work on whether and where institutional differences can af- Research of this kind is represented in studies such as Duan and
fect the optimal policy framework or setting for financial stability. Van Laereb (forthcoming) and Shi and Werkery (forthcoming).
In particular, there is nothing to suggest that ‘one size fits all’, and But if these are the issues that now concern regulators when cali-
that there is one set of best practice that all countries should brating capital, just consider how far we have come from the start-
adopt.8 ing point represented by Basel I.
A further difficulty lies in the fact that the ultimate goals of the The other area in which our knowledge has grown relates to the
policy are still the usual macroeconomic ones of output and wel- quality of capital. Due to ever greater creativity in the capital mar-
fare. Financial stability matters because the lack of it imposes enor- kets, the number of capital (or capital-like) instruments prolifer-
mous costs to society through output losses and impaired ated. As they did so, regulators felt compelled to make ever finer
economic functioning. Financial vulnerabilities, credit booms and distinctions. The original simple split between core and supple-
asset price imbalances are intermediate targets, which only matter mental capital became more complex, with a third tier added
for policy because of what they imply for (future) output. In this and ‘‘innovative residual Tier 1 capital’’ and other non-intuitive
sense, macroprudential policy targeting rules more closely resem- categories somehow accommodated. Then the global financial cri-
ble the monetary targeting regimes of the past than the more di- sis taught us that some capital is better than other capital, and lo
rect mapping of policy instrument to ultimate goal in modern Basel III: A global regulatory framework for more resilient banks and
inflation targeting. Attempts to specify macroprudential regimes banking systems. While Basel III is more complex than Basel I —
and rules too tightly are therefore likely to result in the same issues as it needs to be, given the evolution of the capital market — the
of parameter instability that Goodhart’s (1984) Law implied for ‘‘going-concern/gone-concern’’ conceit represents a return to first
monetary targeting. All these considerations suggest that it would principles.
be imprudent to organize macroprudential policy around precise In sum, we learned three lessons — more capital is good, the
quantitative rules or targets. amount of capital should be commensurate with the relevant risks,
and some capital is better than other capital — but it took us
20 years and a few false starts to do so.
5. Evolution of capital adequacy In this light, consider the stablemate to the Basel III directive on
capital: International framework for liquidity risk measurement, stan-
Financial-sector regulation has been focused on the idea of cap- dards and monitoring. In a phrase which echoes Basel I — even to
ital since the promulgation of the Basle Capital Accord (later reti- the point of italicizing the same word — ‘‘the standards establish
tled ‘‘International convergence of capital measurement and capital minimum levels of liquidity for internationally active banks’’ (par-
standards’’, and now referred to as Basel I). This focus has naturally agraph 6, emphasis in the original). What we know now about
shaped the research agenda over the last two decades. In turn, this liquidity is what we knew two decades ago about capital: More
research has given us insight into the workings of the financial cy- is good.9
cle; sophisticated approaches to modeling a highly interconnected There are other parallels between Basel I-on-capital and Base-
system of individual actors (an example of which is the work by l III-on-liquidity. Like Basel I, the new accord on liquidity asserts
Affinito (forthcoming)); and, at least in hindsight, how much capi- that liquidity requirements properly should be based on a formal
tal is actually required to cope with accumulated risk and unantic- measure of liquidity risk. It will be interesting to see whether the
ipated interaction effects. Basel III metrics — the inflow and outflow rates and ASF and RSF
We now seem to know a lot about capital and the banking sys- factors — will someday be perceived as arbitrary, just as the Basel I
tem — so much so that we sometimes forget how little we knew risk weights are perceived today. And the new accord, like Basel I,
20 years ago. An introductory paragraph of Basel I noted the pur- distinguishes between good liquid assets and better liquid assets. It
pose of the accord, ‘‘to establish minimum levels of capital for inter- will also be interesting to see how well the classifications of Level 1
nationally active banks’’ (paragraph 7, emphasis in the original). So and Level 2 high-quality liquid assets hold up to the creativity of
we knew that more capital was good (The inference was clear, the capital markets. Research efforts like that underpinning the
though, that the then-current levels of capital might not have been Klomp and de Haan (forthcoming) are a welcome start, so perhaps
good enough). We formed the consensus that capital requirements 20 years need not pass for our understanding of liquidity to catch
properly should be based on some measure of riskiness, rather up with our understanding of capital.
than ‘‘the simpler gearing ratio approach’’ (paragraph 28). That said, the most important difference between our relative
What we learned in the next decade was that the original scope understandings is not in the details of the models or the fine print
of the accord was too restrictive, and that the original methodology governing capital-market instruments. What has emerged over the
for quantifying risk was deficient. Basel I was supplemented by the past 20 years is an accepted narrative on capital, and in particular,
1996 Market Risk Amendment and superseded by Basel II: A Revised of procyclicality. When times are good, our regulatory approach
Framework, and so credit risk was joined by market risk, opera- and supporting models allow credit to expand, but when times
tional risk, and a host of so-called Pillar-2 risks. Credit risk weights
based on the obligor’s category type were replaced by weights
based on the obligor’s creditworthiness. More importantly, Basel II 9
(It should be noted however that there is one key difference between the
opened the door to banks’ substituting their own models for minimum capital requirements and the minimum liquidity requirements. Banks are
assessing risk, developed and validated through their own prohibited from operating if their capital falls below the minimum. However, the
buffer which the liquidity provisions create is intended to be used ‘‘in times of stress’’.
(See the press release of the Group of Governors and Heads of Supervision (the
8
See for example the discussion of the EU takeover directive in Humphery-Jenner oversight body of the BCBS), http://www.bis.org/press/p120108.htm.) In this regard,
(2012b), the discussion of regulatory harmonization in Humphery-Jenner (2012a) and the liquidity buffer is similar to the countercyclical capital buffer of the Basel III
Weatherill (2012), and the discussion of banking risk and regulation in Klomp and de capital initiative. Like the capital buffer, though, the exact circumstances under which
Haan (forthcoming). banks can use the liquidity buffer have not yet been specified).
3132 B. Arnold et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 36 (2012) 3125–3132

are bad, the same mechanism causes credit to contract, with brutal Borio, C., Zhu, H., 2008. Capital regulation, risk-taking and monetary policy: A
missing link in the transmission mechanism? BIS Working Paper No 268.
consequences.
December.
At present, the liquidity narrative has not yet been written. Boyd, J.H., De Nicolo, G., 2005. The Theory of bank risk taking and competition
Twenty years ago, a policy initiative — regulating capital — sparked revisited. Journal of Finance 60, 1329–1343.
a generation of research. Today sees another policy initiative — Boyd, J.H., Chang, C., Smith, B.D., 1998. Moral hazard under commercial and
universal banking. Journal of Money Credit and Banking 30, 426–468.
regulating liquidity — once again opening up a fertile and as of Brownlees, C., Engle, R., 2010. Volatility, Correlation and tails for systemic risk
yet largely unexplored field. measurement (Working Paper). New York University.
Brunnermeir, M.K., Pedersen, L.H., 2009. Market liquidity and funding liquidity.
Review of Financial Studies 22, 2201–2238.
6. Conclusion Caruana, J., 2010. Macroprudential policy: could it have been different this time?
(Speech at the People’s Bank of China seminar on Macroprudential Policy),
Shanghai.
This paper has explored various issues that need to be tackled to
Chari, V., Jagannathan, R., 1988. Banking panics, information, and rational
promote greater financial stability – one of the great challenges of expectations equilibrium. Journal of Finance 43, 749–760.
our time. It has highlighted that our understanding of financial De Jonghe, O., 2010. Back to the basics of banking? A micro-analysis of banking
system stability. Journal of Financial Intermediation 19, 387–417.
instability has made considerable progress in several areas: in
Demigurc-Kunt, A., Huizinga, H., 2010. Bank activity and funding strategies: the
the measurement of systemic risk and of individual institutions impact on risk and returns. Journal of Financial Economics 98, 626–650.
contribution to it; in the properties of the financial cycle and pro- Diamond, D., Rajan, R., 2005. Liquidity shortages and banking crises. Journal of
cyclicality; in the signals that point to the build-up of financial, at Finance 60, 615–647.
Drehmann, M., Tarashev, N., 2011. Measuring the systemic importance of
the level of both individual institutions and the system as a whole, interconnected banks (BIS Working paper No. 342). Bank for International
and in the role that capital and liquidity play in making the system Settlements.
more resilient. To varying degrees, this progress is being translated Drehmann, M., Borio, C., Tsatsaronis, K., 2011. Anchoring countercyclical capital
buffers: the role of credit aggregates. International Journal of Central Banking 7,
into policy, as most clearly indicated by Basel III. 189–240.
At the same time, there is still a lot we do not yet understand Drehmann, M., Borio, C., Tsatsaronis, K., 2012. Characterising the financial cycle: do
about systemic risk and about how best to design policy to address not lose sight of the medium term! (Working Paper No. 380). Bank for
International Settlements.
it. This will be a major challenge in the years ahead, for both Duan, J.C., Van Laereb, E., forthcoming. A public good approach to credit ratings:
researchers and policymakers. From conceptulalisation to implementation, Journal of Banking and Finance.
Engle, R., Moshirian, F., Sahgal, S., Zhang, B., 2012. Non-interest income and
systemic risk: The role of concentration (Working Paper). University of New
Disclaimer South Wales.
Galbraith, J., 2009. Who are these economists anyway? Thought and Action 2009,
The views expressed by Bruce Arnold, Claudio Borio, Luci Ellis in 85–97.
Gennaioli, N., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R., 2012. Neglected risks, financial innovation, and
this article are theirs and not necessarily those of the Australian financial fragility. Journal of Financial Economics 104, 452–468.
Prudential Regulatory Authority, the Bank for International Settle- Goodhart, C.W.L., 1984. Monetary Theory and Practice. Macmillan, London.
ments and the Reserve Bank of Australia respectively. Fariborz Griffin, J., Kelly, P.J., Nardari, F., 2010. Do market efficiency measures yield correct
inferences? A comparison of developed and emerging markets. Review of
Moshirian would like to acknowledge the support of the Australian Financial Studies 23, 3225–3277.
Research Council. He also would like to thank Mark Humphrey– Hellman, T., Murdock, K., Stiglitz, J.E., 2000. Liberalization, moral hazard in banking
Jenner for his editorial assistance and Sidharth Sahgal for his input and prudential regulation: are capital controls enough? American Economic
Review 90, 147–165.
on issues related to systemic risk. Humphery-Jenner, M.L., 2012b. The impact of the EU takeover directive on takeover
performance and empire building. Journal of Corporate Finance 18, 254–272.
References Humphery-Jenner, M., forthcoming. The desirability of ‘‘Weak’’ form legal
harmonization: Perspectives from statutory interpretation and legal
coherence. German Law Journal.
Acharya, V.V., Richardson, M., 2009. Restoring Financial Stability: How to Repair a
IMF, 2009. The Financial Crisis and Information Gaps (Report to G-20 Finance
Failed System. John Wiley and Sons, New York.
Ministers and Central Bank Governors by the IMF Staff and the FSB Secretariat).
Acharya, V.V., Pedersen, L.H., Philippon, T., Richardson, M., 2010. Measuring
International Monetary Fund.
Systemic Risk (Working Paper). New York University.
Klomp, J., de Haan, J., forthcoming. Banking risk and regulation: does one size fit all?
Acharya, V.V., Engle, R., Richardson, M., 2012. Capital shortfall: A new approach to
Journal of Banking and Finance.
ranking and regulating systemic risk. American Economic Review 102, 59–64.
Leijonhufvud, A., 2006. Agent-Based Macro. In: Handbook of Computational
Aebi, V., Sabato, G., and M. Schmid, M., forthcoming. Risk management, corporate
Economics. Elsevier Publisher, North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 1625–1637.
governance, and bank performance in the financial crisis. Journal of Banking and
Liu, M., Staum, J., 2010. Systemic risk components in a network model of contagion.
Finance.
Northwestern University.
Affinito, M., forthcoming. Do interbank customer relationships exist? And how did
MacNeil, A.J., Frey, R., Embrechts, P., 2005. Quantitative risk management: concepts,
they function. Journal of Banking and Finance.
techniques and tools. Princeton University Press, Princeton.
Allen, F., Gu, X., Kowalewski, O., forthcoming. Financial crisis, structure and reform.
Moshirian, F., 2011. Global financial crisis and the evolution of markets and
Journal of Banking and Finance.
institutions. Journal of Banking and Finance 35, 502–511.
Altunbas, Y., Gambacorta, L., Marques-Ibanez, D., 2009. An empirical assessment of
Reinhart, C., Rogoff, K., 2009a. This time is different: eight centuries of financial
the risk-taking channel. Available at SSRN: <http://ssrn.com/
folly. Princeton University Press, Princeton.
abstract=1459627>.
Reinhart, C.M., Rogoff, K., 2009b. The aftermath of financial crises. American
Barth, J., Caprio, G., Levine, R., 2004. Bank regulation and supervision: what works
Economic Review 99, 466–472.
best? Journal of Financial Intermediation 13, 205–248.
Rochet, J.C., Tirole, J., 1996. Interbank lending and systemic risk. Journal of Money,
BCBS, 2010a. Countercyclical capital buffer proposal – consultative document
Credit and Banking 28, 733–762.
(consultative document). Basel Committee for Banking Supervision.
Shi, Z., Werkery, B., forthcoming. Economic costs and benefits of imposing short-
BCBS, 2010b. Guidance for national authorities operating the countercyclical capital
horizon value-at-risk type regulation. Journal of Banking and Finance.
buffer (REPORT). Basel Committee for Banking Supervision.
Tarashev, N., Borio, C., Tsatsaronis, K., 2010. Attributing systemic risk to individual
Billio, M., Getmansky, M., Lo, A.W., Pelizzon, L., 2012. Econometric measures of
institutions (BIS Working Paper No. 308). Bank for International Settlements.
connectedness and systemic risk in the finance and insurance sectors. Journal of
Tesfatsion, L., 2006. Agent-based computational economics: a constructive
Financial Economics 104, 535–559.
approach to economic theory. In: Handbook of Computational Economics.
Bisias, D., Flood, M.D., Lo, A.W., Valavanis, S., 2012. A survey of systemic risk analytic
Elsevier Publisher, North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 831–880.
(US Department of Treasury, Office of Financial Research Paper No. 0001). US
Trichet, J.-C., 2010. Macroprudential regulation as an approach to contain systemic
Department of Treasury, Office of Financial Research.
risk: Economic foundations, diagnostic tools and policy instruments (Speech at
Borio, C., 2011. Rediscovering the macroeconomic roots of financial stability policy:
the 13th conference of the ECB-CFS Research Network). European Central Bank.
journey, challenges and a way forward. Annual Review of Financial Economics
Weatherill, S., 2012. The limits of legislative harmonization 10 years after tobacco
3, 87–117.
advertising: how the court’s case law has become a ‘‘Drafting Guide’’. German
Borio, C., Drehmann, M., 2009. Assessing the risk of banking crises – revisited. BIS
Law Journal 12, 827–864.
Quarterly Review, 29–46, March.
White, W.R., 2008. Globalisation and the determinants of domestic inflation (BIS
Borio, C., Drehmann, M., Tsatsaronis, K., forthcoming. Stress-testing macro-stress
Working Paper No. 250). Bank for International Settlements.
tests: does it live up to expectations? Journal of Financial Stability.

You might also like