You are on page 1of 4

econstor

A Service of

zbw
Leibniz-Informationszentrum
Wirtschaft

Make Your Publication Visible


Leibniz Information Centre
for Economics

Graham, John R.

Article
A summary of recent corporate tax research

NBER Reporter Online

Provided in Cooperation with:


National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), Cambridge, Mass.

Suggested Citation: Graham, John R. (2011) : A summary of recent corporate tax research,
NBER Reporter Online, National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), Cambridge, Mass.,
Iss. 4, pp. 5-7

This Version is available at:


http://hdl.handle.net/10419/61976

Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use:

Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your
Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes.

Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial
Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them
machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise
use the documents in public.
Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen
(insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open
gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you
genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated
licence.

www.econstor.eu
Research Summaries

A Summary of Recent Corporate Tax Research

John R. Graham*

Taxes are thought to influence cor- ern corporate finance research by dem- Capital Structure Choices
porate decisions in many ways. For that onstrating that when capital and infor- and Simulating Corporate
reason, in the past decade a number of mational markets are perfect, firm value Marginal Income Tax Rates
changes (or proposed changes) to the is not affected by financial decisions.
U.S. tax code have been made in an Five years later they showed that the In my early work, I simulated dynamic
attempt to affect corporate behavior. existence of taxation can create an envi- corporate marginal income tax rates that
For example, U.S. and European author- ronment in which financial decisions could explain the probability that a firm
ities have raised the possibility of elimi- affect firm value. In particular, M&M will be nontaxable and that allow it to
nating or reducing the ability of compa- demonstrated that when corporate carry losses forward and backward. I then
nies to deduct interest payments from income is taxed and debt interest is a used these simulated tax rates to docu-
taxable income, because the tax-favored deductible expense, firm value can be ment that firms respond to tax incentives
status of debt has reduced tax revenue increased by using debt financing rather when they make incremental financing
collection and allegedly encouraged a than funding entirely from equity. choices,1 and when they choose the level
“debt bias” of corporations. It is believed Several branches of research ema- of debt and the level of leasing.2 These
that by using too much debt financ- nated from these basic insights. The corporate tax incentives hold up even in
ing, firms may have exacerbated eco- first addresses whether the tax environ- the presence of high personal tax rates on
nomic downturns. Also, during the last ment leads to firm-specific optimal capi- interest income.3
two recessions, in an attempt to stimu- tal structures and value enhancement. Most tax and capital structure
late the corporate sector, the U.S. gov- If there are costs to using too much research, including the work just men-
ernment has temporarily granted com- debt (for example, expected financial tioned, uses data drawn from financial
panies the ability to carry current-year distress costs or personal taxes on inter- statements, not data from actual tax
losses back five years, in order to receive est income), then firms with the greatest returns. Given that financial statements
a refund on taxes paid during the past benefit to shielding taxes (for example, consolidate worldwide income statements
five years. Further, equity tax rates have firms facing higher income tax rates) and balance sheets for multinational
been decreased for retail investors in an should be the ones with the greatest firms, but that tax rules and tax incentives
attempt to reduce the corporate cost of incentives to use debt financing. Much vary by country, one might wonder how
capital, and these changes are thought of my tax research focuses on how to closely financial-statement-based research
to have increased dividend payout. And, measure these tax incentives in the con- mirrors tax return data.4 In recent work,
there have been proposals to disallow text of a dynamic tax code. Lillian Mills and I access confidential tax
multinational companies from avoid- One important feature of the tax returns to explore how closely tax rates
ing income taxes on profits earned over- code is that a firm can “carry back” cur- estimated from financial statement data
seas by their reinvesting those profits rent losses (by refiling past tax returns) parallel those based on tax return data.5
overseas. In this report, I summarize to receive a tax refund for taxes paid in Fortunately, we find that simulated tax
academic research on these and related recent years. Alternatively, if carrying rates based on financial statement data are
issues. back losses is not attractive, then firms very highly correlated with tax variables
In 1958 Modigliani and Miller can carry forward losses to offset tax- based on tax return data.
(M&M) laid the groundwork for mod- able income in future years. Therefore,
because the dynamic tax code allows Capital Structure – Debt Bias
* John Graham is a Research Associate in the firms to move income through time, it
NBER’s Corporate Finance Program and a is necessary to forecast future taxable Documenting that tax rates are cor-
professor of Finance at Duke University. income to estimate current-period tax related with corporate capital structure
His Profile appears later in this issue. rates and tax incentives. choices suggests that firms may increase

NBER Reporter • 2011 Number 4 5


value by choosing debt optimally. However, this important issue in general, and with Hyunseob Kim and I examine the eco-
some argue that an increased use of debt respect to financial firms in particular. nomic impact of the stimulus during the
in response to tax incentives leads to neg- most recent recession.8 Companies were
ative outcomes. After all, the extent to Capital Structure – Tax given the option to carry back losses from
which firms are able to increase value occurs Benefit Functions either their 2008 tax year or their 2009 tax
directly because deducting interest expenses year to receive a refund for taxes paid dur-
deprives the government of tax revenues. One way to measure how much inter- ing the previous five years. Had the carry-
More than just reducing tax revenues, a est tax savings contribute to firm value back period remained at two years, we esti-
“debt bias” — using extra debt in response involves estimating marginal tax benefit mate the carryback feature of the tax code
to tax incentives — could result in too functions — that is, measuring the marginal would have provided $77 billion in tax
much debt in the system, increasing the tax benefit of each incremental dollar of refunds; allowing losses to be carried back
probability that firms will become finan- tax deduction. By adding up the value cre- an additional three years added an incre-
cially distressed, and thereby exacerbating ated by each incremental dollar of interest mental $54 billion in tax refunds to cor-
or perhaps even causing economic down- deduction, one can estimate the contribu- porate coffers (this estimate ignores TARP
turns. Critics of debt bias argue that the tion to firm value associated with the tax recipients and the tax benefits granted to
ability to deduct interest should be elimi- savings that flow from a given level of inter- them). Interestingly, the increased bene-
nated or at least reduced. For this argument est deductions. Two co-authors and I follow fit was particularly valuable to sectors that
to have its greatest force, it should be the this approach and estimate that the equilib- were hugely profitable during the economic
case that 1) tax incentives lead to a large rium, gross tax benefit of interest deductions boom of the mid-2000s but then suffered
increase in the use of debt, and that 2) the (ignoring all costs) equals about 10.5 percent the greatest losses during the recession:
“extra” debt that firms use in response to tax of value across all firms, and about twice that housing, finance, and autos. That is, the U.S.
incentives should lead to a material increase much for the top decile of companies.7 government supported firms in these indus-
in the probability of experiencing financial Analogous to using supply shifts to tries via changes to the tax code.
distress. identify demand curves, we use exogenous
Regarding whether taxes have a first- variation in benefit functions to deduce the Payout Policy
order effect on the use of debt, I have doc- cost-of-debt function that justifies the capital
umented that a tax rate that is 10 percent- structure choices that firms make. By sum- One feature of the famous 2003 “Bush
age points higher (for example, 34 percent ming the area under the cost functions up tax cuts” was to reduce the maximum tax
instead of the mean 24 percent) leads to to a given amount of debt, we estimate that rate on both qualifying dividends and capi-
debt usage that is 0.7 percent higher. Thus, the equilibrium all-in expected cost of debt tal gains to 15 percent, from 38 percent and
while taxes do affect capital structure, the equals about 7 percent of firm value. By sum- 20 percent, respectively. This relative reduc-
effect is moderate, providing only partial ming up the area between the cost and ben- tion in dividend taxation thus made divi-
evidence of the first debt bias consideration. efit functions, we estimate that the equilib- dends more attractive to taxable individual
Regarding whether the extra debt usage rium net benefits of debt (net of all costs) are investors.9 Given this increased investor
increases the odds of encountering distress, about 3.5 percent of firm value. Again, these preference for dividends, one might expect
two co-authors and I search for these effects numbers are fairly moderate and do not sug- companies to begin to pay out a larger pro-
when one might expect the negative effects gest pervasive high leverage caused by severe portion of profits via dividends. Research
of excess leverage to be at their worst: dur- debt bias. shows that there was a surge of dividend
ing the severe economic contractions dur- initiations following the May 2003 imple-
ing the Great Depression and during the Tax-Loss Carrybacks and mentation of these tax breaks and that
years 2008–9.6 In the first stage of our Economic Stimulus dividend hikes were largest at the compa-
analysis, we show that firms did in fact use nies that had the greatest net tax incentive
more debt because of tax incentives during For the most part, U.S. companies in to increase dividends, such as firms with
the Depression. However, we do not find recent decades have been able to carry back proportionally more individual investors
any evidence that this extra debt increased current-period losses to receive a refund for (which makes sense given that the tax cut
the probability of encountering distress. taxes paid in the past two years. This feature was focused on individuals). Chetty and
Similarly, we do not find any evidence that of the tax code serves as an economic stabi- Saez show that the dividend increases were
debt bias led to negative outcomes during lizer by providing an infusion of liquidity less likely to occur in firms for which the
the recent recession. It is important to note to (previously profitable) companies that executives owned substantial stock options
that our failure to find negative effects of are currently struggling. During the last two (which makes sense because options are
debt bias could be attributable to noise in recessions, the carryback period was tempo- not dividend protected, meaning that pay-
the data (especially during the Depression rarily lengthened to five years in an attempt ing a dividend reduces the value of existing
era) and to our focus on nonfinancial firms. to stimulate the corporate sector during an options). 10
Clearly, there needs to be more research on economic downturn. Thus, investor-level taxes affect cor-

6 NBER Reporter • 2011 Number 4


porate payout choices. However, are taxes 2004, Congress passed the American Jobs January 2010, and Journal of Accounting
the dominant force driving payout policy? Creation Act, which allowed firms to repa- and Economics forthcoming
Based on surveys and one-on-one inter- triate profits to the United States subject to 5 J. R. Graham and L. Mills, “Using
views, three co-authors and I document that a tax rate of no more than 5.25 percent and Tax Return Data to Simulate Corporate
CFOs agree with the general conclusion often much lower. Our research documents Marginal Tax Rates,” NBER Working
that firms increased dividends in response that many firms embraced this tax break Paper No. 13709, December 2007, and
to the reduction in retail investor dividend and bought profits home to the United Journal of Accounting and Economics,
tax rates — but we conclude that the 2003 States. Perhaps surprisingly, we also show 446:2–3, 2008, pp.366–88.
tax effect on corporate payout decisions that some firms did not repatriate earnings, 6 J.R. Graham, S. Hazarika, and K.
was overall moderate.11 Executives indicate even at low repatriation tax rates, and even Narasimhan, “Financial Distress during the
that non-tax conditions (such as generat- though repatriation would have a posi- Great Depression,” NBER Working Paper
ing long-run, sustainable earnings or facing tive effect on actual cash flows, because it No. 17388, August 2011, and Financial
lower growth prospects) are the first-order would lead to a reduction in reported earn- Management, forthcoming.
factors that determine payout policy and ings. That is, even at low tax rates repatria- 7 J. van Binsbergen, J. R. Graham, and J.
also determine whether a particular firm tion is at times avoided by firms because Yang, “The Cost of Debt,” NBER Working
is at a margin where taxes would affect its it reduces earnings per share, which finan- Paper No. 16023, May 2010, and Journal
payout decisions. In summary, most CFOs cial executives believe in turn hurts stock of Finance 65:6, 2010, pp.2089–136.
say that tax considerations matter but taxes price. Interestingly, Senator Kay Hagen 8 J.R. Graham, and H. Kim, “The Effects
are not the dominant factor in their deci- recently proposed instituting another “one of the Length of the Tax-Loss Carry back
sions about whether to increase dividends time” reduction in taxes owed on repatri- Period on Tax Receipts and Corporate
or choose dividends over share repurchases. ated profits. Justification for such a pro- Marginal Tax Rates,” NBER Working
posal is unclear given that, overall, academic Paper No. 15177, July 2009, and National
Taxes on Foreign Profits research into the 2004 reduction in repatri- Tax Journal, 62, 2009, pp.413–27.
ation taxes does not provide clear evidence 9 Alok Kumar and I find that individual
Economics and politics have merged that on net firms used the funds brought investors form clienteles based on tax prefer-
into a contentious debate related to the home to increase investment or hiring. ences of holding dividends and that indi-
extent to which U.S. firms should pay U.S. In summary, the tax code is constantly vidual investors shift holdings to tax-deferred
taxes on profits earned by their foreign divi- under revision, in part in an attempt by accounts in response to higher income tax
sions and subsidiaries. Under current law, authorities to alter corporate behavior. rates. See J.R. Graham and A. Kumar, “Do
taxes are paid to foreign authorities as the Recent research documents that tax incen- Dividend Clienteles Exist? Evidence on
profits are earned — but taxes are not paid tives do affect corporate behavior, but the Dividend Preferences of Retail Investors,”
to the U.S. tax authority until the profits effects are often modest. I look forward Journal of Finance 61, 2006, pp. 1305–336.
are returned home (“repatriated “) to the to future research that helps explain why 10 R. Chetty and E. Saez, “Dividend
domestic parent. By surveying tax execu- tax effects are not always as large as we Taxes and Corporate Behavior: Evidence
tives, two-coauthors and I learn that the might expect, whether the reason be mea- from the 2003 Dividend Tax Cut,” NBER
ability to defer paying U.S. taxes is in fact surement issues, offsetting nontax influ- Working Paper No. 10841, October 2004;
one of the most important reasons that U.S. ences, or unanticipated changes in corpo- J. Poterba, “Taxation and Corporate Payout
companies invest overseas.12 Opponents rate behavior that occur as the economy Policy,” NBER Working Paper No. 10321,
of these tax rules argue that evidence like re-equilibrates. February 2004; J. Bouin, J. Raedy, and
this is proof that U.S. firms shift jobs over- D. Shackelford, “Did Dividends Increase
seas to the detriment of domestic employ- Immediately After the 2003 Reduction in
ment. (Supporters of the repatriation tax 1 J. R. Graham, “Debt and the Marginal Tax Rates?” NBER Working Paper No.
rules argue that they help U.S. firms com- Tax Rate,” Journal of Financial Economics, 10301, February 2004.
pete overseas.) 41, 1996, pp. 41–74. 11 A. Brav, J. R. Graham, C. R. Harvey,
If foreign profits are repatriated home, 2 J. R. Graham, M. Lemmon, and J. and R. Michaely, “Payout Policy in the
they are then taxed at a rate essentially equal Schallheim, “Debt, Leases, Taxes, and 21st Century,” NBER Working Paper No.
to the degree to which the U.S. tax rate the Endogeneity of Corporate Tax Status,” 9657, April 2003, and Journal of Financial
exceeds the tax rate in the foreign jurisdic- Journal of Finance, 53, 1998, pp. 131–62. Economics, 77:3, 2005, pp. 483–527.
tion in which they were earned (for exam- 3 J. R. Graham, “Do Personal Taxes Affect 12 J.R. Graham, M. Hanlon, and T.
ple, profits earned and taxed at an Irish cor- Corporate Financing Decisions?” Journal of Shevlin, “Real Effects of Accounting Rules:
porate tax rate of 13 percent would be taxed Public Economics, 73, 1999, pp. 147–85. Evidence from Multinational Firms
an additional 22 percent when returned 4 For details, see J. R. Graham, J. Raedy, Investment Location and Profit Repatriation
to the United States because the U.S. cor- and D. Shackleford, “Accounting for Income Decisions,” Journal of Accounting Research,
porate income tax rate is 35 percent). In Taxes,” NBER Working Paper No. 15665, 49, 2011, pp.137–85.

NBER Reporter • 2011 Number 4 7

You might also like