You are on page 1of 13

Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 62 (2018) 31e43

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Socio-Economic Planning Sciences


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/seps

DEA-based Malmquist productivity indexes for understanding courts


reform
Greta Falavigna a, Roberto Ippoliti b, *, Giovanni B. Ramello c
a
CNR e IRCrES (National Research Council of Italy e Research Institute on Sustainable Economic Growth), Via Real Collegio 30, Moncalieri, Torino, Italy
b
National School of Administration, Presidency of the Council of Ministers (Prime Minister's Office), Via dei Robilant 11, Roma, ROMA, Italy
c
University of Eastern Piedmont, Institute of Public Policy and Collective Choices (POLIS), Via Cavour, Alessandria, AL, Italy

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Currently there is no clear empirical evidence as to which the most appropriate reform to improve
Received 21 December 2016 national judicial systems might be, i.e., whether it is better to implement a policy which focuses on
Received in revised form judges and their incentives or, alternatively, a policy aimed at reorganizing the courts' structure.
15 June 2017
The judicial system, like many other sectors of the public administration, is an industry producing a
Accepted 1 July 2017
Available online 3 July 2017
specific good e justice e and, accordingly, it can be studied by using the customary tools of production
theory. The paper applies the two-stage analysis by Simar and Wilson (2007) and the Malmquist index to
the judiciary, in order to better understand the impact of a specific policy on the productivity of the
Keywords:
Judicial efficiency
Italian tax judiciary.
Courts reform The results highlight strong heterogeneity among courts, depending on their geographical location,
Malmquist productivity indexes with North-West and North-East of Italy as the most efficient macro areas. Moreover, by decomposing
the index into change in efficiency and change in technology, this work provides a further glimpse into
the judiciary's production organization. Interestingly, the evidence shows that a reduction in the number
of active sections has had a negative impact on the overall performance of the courts (i.e., a negative
change in efficiency of 0.0103, with a p-value < 0.01), although the reorganization of the residual sections
has possibly determined a more effective use of the remaining resources (i.e., a positive change in
technology of 0.00285, with a p-value < 0.01). Hence, technology does not fully replace the productive
role of the judges.
The overall results suggest that adjudication is a labor-intensive activity and, although fine-tuning
their organization can indeed enhance the productivity of the courts, the role of the judges still re-
mains pivotal. There might indeed be ways to increase the efforts made by judges and a suitable policy
should create incentives aimed at boosting their productivity.
© 2017 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction the basis of beliefs rather than observation on how this system
actually works. This is even more relevant if we consider the Italian
Courts are dispute resolution technologies producing outputs judicial system, which is one of the most inefficient in Europe ac-
which are relevant to society and the economy in many respects. cording to the Organization for Economic Co-operation and
Despite this relevance, which in turn affects economic growth and Development [60] and the European Union [8], as well as the In-
well-being [28,29,40,44], judicial ‘production technology’ has been ternational Monetary Fund [25]. However, there is no clear
largely neglected and scholars have only recently tried to gain a empirical evidence as to which the best option among alternative
deeper understanding of it by conducting applied research reforms might be. How might policy-makers shape an effective
[20,48,69,77]. Moreover, policy elaboration hardly ever relies on policy aimed at reforming the judicial system? Is a policy aimed at
robust empirical evidence, so that decisions are very often made on reorganizing the courts appropriate? Alternatively, is it better to
consider a policy which focuses on judges and their incentives?
These are the main research questions, which are addressed by the
article to fill the current knowledge gap.
* Corresponding author. This study follows the above line of inquiry, focusing on a quasi-
E-mail address: roberto.ippoliti@unipmn.it (R. Ippoliti).

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.seps.2017.07.001
0038-0121/© 2017 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
32 G. Falavigna et al. / Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 62 (2018) 31e43

natural experiment occurred in the Italian tax judiciary, in order to Section 3 summarizes the production structure of tax courts in Italy
‘access the black box’ of judicial production and try to shed light on and briefly describes the policy in question. Section 4 explains the
its mechanisms. More precisely, it concentrates on a new policy methodology. Section 5 presents data and descriptive statistics,
devoted to fostering the productivity of courts e and to saving while Section 6 illustrates the results of the second stage analysis.
public money e by reducing the number of sections (the courts' Finally, Section 7 proposes some conclusions.
production lines). The main idea behind the aforementioned policy
is that, by reducing the sections and encouraging the reorganiza- 2. Courts organization and judicial productivity: an overview
tion of the remaining sections and relative resources, it is possible
to foster economies of scale, thus preserving and even enhancing A growing body of literature has recently tried to gain a deeper
productivity, while also reducing public expenditure. However, insight into the workings of courts, stimulated by the efforts of
adjudication is a labor-intensive activity and the role of the judges governments and international organizations to better understand
still remains pivotal, that is to say, the policy maker might increase and improve the performance of judicial systems.2 Building on the
judicial productivity by reorganizing the courts (change in tech- seminal contributions by Cooter [18] and Posner [62] on how in-
nology), as well as by using the main input (the judges' work) more centives affect the behavior of judges in terms of effort and choices,
effectively. This is exactly our main hypothesis: technology cannot other scholars have tried to identify the determinants of produc-
replace the pivotal role of judges in producing decisions, as adju- tivity in relation to courts and judges. The individual characteristics
dication mainly remains a labor-intensive activity. According to this of judges and the structural characteristics of courts have thus been
hypothesis, these two components might be complementary rather empirically investigated. Taha [75] applied the utility-maximizing
than substitutable and the policy-makers should necessarily look model to judicial decisions, focusing on federal district court
for new approaches to introduce productivity shocks. judges in the US and their habits regarding publishing decisions,
In this respect, the instruments provided by production theory with results highlighting the economic orientation of judicial
are a helpful and, we believe, unavoidable reference point to be choices. Landes et al. [50] and Choi et al. [13] analyzed the US courts
considered in policy decision-making in order to match expected and Ramseyer [65] concentrated on the Japanese system,
outcomes and policy aims. In details, the authors adopt the Data concluding that the educational background of judges (as a proxy
Envelopment Analysis (DEA) methodology and Malmquist indexes for their intellectual ability) greatly influences their performance.
to evaluate efficiency and productivity of the Italian judicial sys- Other studies show that courts and judges generally respond to a
tems, since they are recognized by the current literature as suc- heavier caseload by increasing their productivity (e.g. [3], on Israeli
cessful techniques to evaluate the performance of decision making courts and [21] on Slovenia).3 At the same time, the behavior of
units (e.g., [82e84]). The main positive feature of this methodology judges may also be characterized by inertia in their work habits,
concerns the relaxed assumptions on input-output data distribu- which cancels out the positive effects of policies designed to pro-
tion (i.e., non-parametric technique), as well as the non- mote efficiency. A number of studies have targeted the most
specification of the technological frontier [85]. Indeed, the effi- prominent ‘disease’ of the judicial system (at least from the citizens'
ciency score and the relative related frontier is are derived by point of view), i.e. ‘delay’, or the time required to reach a decision.
computing the radial distance from the origin for each decision The expertise of judges can speed up decision times, but there are
making units. Finally, differently from other econometric models, also organizational features which affect the overall result [6,52].
the DEA technique can be computed with a small sample of ob- Hence, a joint analysis of the behavior of judges on the one hand
servations and the interpretation of the collected (calculated?) and of the organization of courts on the other hand is crucial in
technical efficiency scores is extremely intuitive. order to grasp the whole picture.
Using key production theory tools, this paper adopts Data It is worth noting that all the above studies have investigated
Envelopment Analysis (DEA) to provide a measure of court per- specific court systems within national boundaries. Narrowing
formance before and after the implementation of the policy in down the research scope to a particular country or judiciary means
question. Yet, thanks to the application of the Malmquist index, our that the results cannot be immediately generalized. However, the
investigation goes one step further in assessing the effectiveness of advantage of this approach is that it eliminates any issues of
public policies by identifying the main components of changes in comparability among observations from different judicial systems.
efficiency. Following a consolidated stream of scientific literature Furthermore, studying specific, homogeneous judicial systems in
that has successfully used the Malmquist index to analyze several this way has enabled a number of scholars to test efficiency using a
production activities, the paper shows the policy relevance for the standard industrial measure for homogenous production units,
judiciary e and other production bodies of the public administra- known as Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA). DEA is a non-
tion e of breaking down changes promoted by exogenous in- parametric technique that makes it possible to comparatively
terventions into their primary elements.1 This is exactly what the assess the efficiency scores of several basic production components.
current study aims to do and, in this respect, it represents a step It has been extensively applied to many other production sectors
forward in the current literature. Indeed, this is the first study and can be used to investigate the workings of a particular courts
which applies the Malmquist index to the judiciary e and this is the system.4
main contribution of this work to the current literature on judicial A number of studies on the judiciary have successfully imple-
efficiency, supporting the evaluation of a structural reform aimed at mented the DEA methodology [9,48,51] and a few of these have
boosting the performance of the public administration.
The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 surveys the available
literature on judicial productivity and courts efficiency, while 2
Fostering judicial efficiency has entered the agenda of many national and in-
ternational organizations. The first noteworthy attempt was led by the World Bank
and has been followed in recent years by national (i.e., governments) or suprana-
tional authorities. An example of the latter is the European Commission for the
1 Efficiency of Justice.
See, for instance, Berg et al. [4] and Tortosa-Ausina et al. [76] focusing on the
3
banking sector, Maniadakis and Thanassoulis [55] and Ippoliti and Falavigna [43] on This is the motivation behind the recent bill submitted to the US congress (S.
the healthcare sector, Odeck [59] on vehicle inspection services, Kao and Hwang 699: Court Efficiency Act of 2013).
4
[47] on the non-life insurance industry, and Chavas [11] and Nin et al. [58] on See, e.g., applications to bank and credit risk [35,67,74], to energy and the
agriculture. environment [81], and to the healthcare sector [12,64].
G. Falavigna et al. / Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 62 (2018) 31e43 33

used the two-stage DEA approach [20,42,44,69] to analyze the administration. In effect, as will be shown below, this approach
determinants of inefficiency. More specifically, Lewin et al. [51] provides a deeper understanding of how the judiciary works, since
investigated the efficiency of criminal courts and judicial districts it makes it possible to investigate its production structure and to
in North Carolina, adopting the number of judgments and number observe the determinants of changes in productivity, thus also
of cases pending for less than 90 days as outputs, whereas the in- contributing to the development of policy guidelines.
puts considered were: caseload, number of district attorneys and
staff, days of court held, number of misdemeanors within the 3. The Italian tax judiciary and the new policy
caseload, and size of white population. Kittelsen and Førsund [48]
conducted a study on Norwegian district courts, taking the num- Before proceeding with the analysis, an overview of the features
ber of judges and staff as inputs and cases settled as output, clas- of the Italian tax courts system is presented, in order to better
sified according to judicial category (e.g., civil cases, criminal cases, understand their production organization and how to measure
etc.). Chaparro and Jimenez [9] assessed the technical efficiency of productivity changes and their components.5
the Administrative Litigation Division of the Spanish High Courts, Tax courts exercise special jurisdiction, since their subject
identifying the staff as input and the cases settled as output, matter is limited to tax controversies, that is to say fiscal allegations
considering cases resolved by means of a full legal process (i.e., with made by the Italian Revenue Service (Agenzia delle Entrate) against
a sentence) as well as cases resolved by other means (e.g., concili- individuals or corporations. They are organized according to three
ation, withdrawal, dismissal, etc.). Yeung and Azevedo [80] used vertically related levels: the first instance court is called Commis-
DEA to measure the efficiency of Brazilian state courts, taking the sione Tributaria Provinciale (hereinafter CTP), the court of appeal is
number of judges and staff as input and first/second instance court called Commissione Tributaria Regionale, and the court of last resort,
decisions as output. Corte Suprema di Cassazione, ensures the legitimacy of the decisions
A common feature of all the above works using DEA is the reached by the lower courts. Since the possibility of obtaining
assumption of constant returns to scale, since the observations are statistically significant results crucially depends on appropriate
supposed to be homogeneous. Hence, these studies assume that sample size, the data used here concern the first instance courts
there is no (positive or negative) relation between the size of a system (i.e., the CTPs), which comprises 103 units.
court and its productivity e in other words, that there are no The procedure to review tax cases in the CTPs is strictly regu-
economies of scale [9]. Of course, this assumption severely limits lated by law (Legislative Decree 546/92). According to this decree,
the analysis because it does not take into account the heterogeneity the judges collectively decide on the cases as a bench, while the
of court organization. More recently, Santos and Amado [68] administrative staff assists them in the decision-making process
refined previous analyses with a study on first instance courts in and deals with all the related bureaucracy. Moreover, every CTP can
Portugal which adopts variable returns to scale. Inputs are once be divided into one or more sections, and each section (made up of
again staff and judges, while an interesting step forward concerns a president, a vice-president, and at least four other judges) com-
disaggregation per case type, as the authors innovatively consider prises smaller production subunits e i.e., a bench including at least
43 outputs, representing the decisions reached in different judicial 3 judges e ruling on cases autonomously.
domains. With a Ministerial Decree issued on 11th April 2008, the Italian
For what concerns the two-stage DEA, Schneider [69] conducted government amended a policy aimed at fostering the productivity
an analysis focusing on the German Labor Courts of Appeal, taking of CTPs and at cutting public expenditure by reducing the number
the number of cases resolved as output and the number of judges of sections, which, as explained above, has affected the number of
and their caseloads as inputs. In the second stage, the author found production lines (i.e., the benches) and, in turn, the number of
evidence of a relation between judicial career incentives and court judges. However, it has also freed staff and other resources, thus
performance. Deyneli [20] studied the relationship between the leading to a partial reorganization of the remaining sections and of
efficiency of justice services and the salaries of judges in European the courts as a whole.
countries. The author considered the number of judges and of office Hence, a reasonable question which the paper tries to answer is
staff as inputs, while cases settled were the output in the first stage. whether the policy has had the overall consequence of increasing
In the second stage, technical efficiency scores were then regressed (or decreasing) productivity. Yet, as mentioned above, this may lead
for judges' salaries, judges' basic education, and number of courts to preliminary and somewhat rough results. In order to thoroughly
(i.e. explanatory variables). However, none of the aforementioned assess the effectiveness of the policy, it is useful to decompose the
contributions has adopted the bootstrap approach, which provides changes occurred in terms of use of inputs (change in efficiency) or
a more robust estimation of technical efficiency scores [73]. Fala- overhaul of the internal organization (change in technology). A
vigna et al. [30] propose a comparative study between DEA and the further breakdown of the effects of the policy can shed light on
Directional Distance Function (DDF) applying the bootstrap pro- which components are relevant for its success or failure, since the
cedure. More precisely, they compare the results obtained with the aggregate outcome e being the net results of many effects e might
two non-parametric techniques in order to assess the usefulness of prove to be misleading. This is very important for subsequent
DEA formulations including negative outputs when externalities, policy-making and equally fundamental for public finance. Indeed,
such as judicial delay, arise. the performance of the tax judiciary is key in combating tax fraud
All the above literature focuses on a static picture, without and evasion, which is a crucial element for both the protection of
considering policy effects on court performance. Thus far, no study national budget revenues and the confidence of citizens in the
has applied the Malmquist index or similar approaches extensively fairness and effectiveness of tax systems [26]. Considering the
used in production theory in order to gain further insights into the current age of austerity and the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP),
courts' production structure and the internal impact of structural with its limits for government deficit and debt, analyzing the
changes. This is exactly what the current study aims to do and, in impact of a policy aimed at boosting the efficiency of the national
this respect, it represents a step forward in the current literature. In tax judiciary can represent a priority for the Italian government.
other words, the adoption of the Malmquist indexes provides the This is even more significant if we consider Italy's compliance with
main contribution of this work to the current literature on judicial
efficiency, supporting the evaluation of a structural reform aimed at
5
improving the performance of this key sector of the public For an extensive description, see Falavigna et al. [30].
34 G. Falavigna et al. / Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 62 (2018) 31e43

the maximum limit for government deficit and debt outlined in the until the frontier is reached [19]. For what concerns VRS, since the
SGP [27]. organization of the CTPs is established by law and is thus funda-
As is well known, this kind of measurement is performed on a mentally the same throughout Italy, we can assume that any het-
regular basis in production studies by means of the Malmquist erogeneity among CTPs e hence, variable returns to scale e
index, a suitable tool for assessing changes in productivity and essentially depends on the performance of the various procedural
decomposing them into their main elements. It is worth noting that stages, which is in turn related to individual effort and overall
controlling for geographical location is crucial, since the first management. In other words, the key element to foster efficiency is
instance courts system (like many other bodies of the public the human factor, which determines how well each individual task
administration) is a production organization spread over the na- is completed and how well the overall procedure is managed. This
tional territory, with considerable heterogeneity among macro- assumption is in line with the findings of previous studies, which
areas due to idiosyncratic socio-economics factors. Similarly, ascribe heterogeneity in judicial efficiency to the characteristics of
since adjudication heavily relies upon the work of judges and each judges (e.g., education) and to their individual incentives. The
individual judge is different from the next, we will also try to innovative aspect of our approach is that, unlike the empirical
determine whether judges are the cause of further heterogeneity. literature on court efficiency mentioned above, we take VRS into
account.7
In accordance with Simar and Wilson [73]; we apply the boot-
4. Efficiency and productivity change estimates: methodology
strap procedure to the DEA approach to correct for the bias in the
efficiency scores and their confidence intervals. Basically, the
From a methodological viewpoint, this work estimates the
bootstrap procedure is a sub-sampling mathematical technique
courts' technical efficiency scores by using DEA and changes in
allowing more robust estimates. An algorithm extracts randomly
productivity by using the Malmquist index, as done in Ippoliti and
sub-samples from the whole initial sample and it replies results for
Falavigna [43]. The next step is to apply a two-stage approach in
a specific number of replications. The final value is equal to the
order to gain a deeper understanding of the matter.
mean of these results, which is more robust and correct than that
obtained with the non-bootstrapped method. In this case study,
4.1. Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA) authors apply a number of replications equal to 200.
In order to analyze the determinants of judicial efficiency, we
DEA is a non-parametric technique which allows efficiency also implement the two-stage approach, as suggested by the above
performance to be measured as a score [16]. The DEA approach lets authors. In the first stage, the output-oriented DEA procedure with
researchers build a deterministic, non-parametric production bootstrap is used to estimate the efficiency of each CTP. In the
frontier comparing the performance of several Decision Making second stage, a regression analysis, also with bootstrap, is carried
Units (DMUs), which in our case are the tax courts of first instance out in order to detect correlations between the efficiency scores
(i.e., the CTPs). Technical efficiency scores are computed based on and some key explanatory variables.
the radial distance of every DMU from the frontier.6 Here we have The output of the model is the number of cases settled (i.e., the
used the output-oriented model, as proposed by Farrell [34]; and number of cases resulting in a sentence or court order). The input
we have also assumed Variable Returns to Scale (VRS) [86]. variables of DEA are all the factors that might affect court pro-
The technical efficiency scores (TEi) connected to each tax court ductivity in this particular context (i.e., number of judges) and the
(Data Making Unit, DMU) are computed in this way: demand for justice (number of cases pending on January 1st of each
year and number of incoming cases).8 Staff numbers are not
TEi ¼ zi i ¼ 1; …; n available and, for this reason, they have not been introduced in the
model as input. Even if the absence of clerks might represent a limit
where n is the number of DMUs and 1  TEi  þ∞. of our analysis, the proposed approach is coherent with literature
TEi scores are computed by solving the following linear pro- on the Italian judicial efficiency [30,41,56].
gramming duality problem, on the basis of output-oriented DEA According to the proposed approach, the efficiency score of a
approach [34]: CTP is defined as its ability to meet the demand for justice, i.e. to
maximize the number of cases settled taking the available re-
Maxz;l zi
sources into account.
subject to:
N10 l ¼ 1
zyi  Yl  0
4.2. Malmquist index
xi þ X l  0
l0
The Malmquist index, is a method for assessing changes in
productivity and decomposing them into their main elements
where z is a scalar > 1, l is a vector of nx1 weights allowing for
[38,49,54,57], which has been applied in several fields such as, for
convex combination of inputs and outputs, Y is an sxn output
example, in education [46,61], energy efficiency [78] or health care
matrix, X is an input matrix and N1 is an Nx1 unitary vector.
[36,63].
Furthermore, z-1 indicates the output proportional increment,
This index is used to compute the ratio between outputs and
maintaining the input level constant.
€re and
inputs at different times. According to Fare et al. [32]; Fa
The output-oriented framework aims to maximize output levels
Grosskopf [31]; assuming the availability of data on a single input
while holding the inputs constant, on the assumption that the in-
puts cannot be easily changed, at least in the short run. This
orientation is also known as the “output-augmenting” approach: it 7
The null hypothesis of constant returns to scale (CRS) was tested according to
keeps the inputs bundle unchanged and expands the output level
Simar and Wilson [72]; and we can reject the hypothesis that there is no relation
between the size of courts and their performance. In other words, we can confirm
the hypothesis that court heterogeneity can affect their efficiency.
6 €re and
For an in-depth description of DEA, see also Charnes et al. [10]; Fa 8
In other words, the ‘caseload’ input consists of the backlog plus yearly incoming
Grosskopf [31] and Coelli et al. [15]. cases.
G. Falavigna et al. / Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 62 (2018) 31e43 35

(x) and output (y) over two periods (t and tþ1), the Total Factor to scale. It is possible to compute this index in the following
Productivity (TFP) can be defined as: manner:
!
 yVRS f VRS ðxt Þ
ytþ1 xtþ1 pure eff ¼ tþ1
$ t VRS
TFP ¼ VRS ðx
ftþ1 Þ yt
yt =xt tþ1

It is thus possible to determine how the Malmquist index of


productivity changes in the following manner:  Change in scale efficiency (scale), which considers the changes in

ytþ1 !    
1 =
  ytþ1 2
ytþ1 ft ðxt Þ f ðx Þ f ðxt Þ
1
=
2
ftþ1 ðxtþ1 Þ ft ðxtþ1 Þ
M0 x tþ1
;y tþ1 t
;x ;y t
¼ yt $ yt ¼ $ $ tþ1 tþ1 $ tþ1
ftþ1 ðxtþ1 Þ yt ft ðxtþ1 Þ ft ðxt Þ
ftþ1 ðxt Þ ft ðxt Þ ffl{zfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl} |fflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl{zfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl}
|fflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflfflffl
Change in Efficiencyðeff Þ Technical ChangeðtechÞ

Values of the Malmquist index higher than 1 represent im- efficiency by varying the returns to scale. It is possible to
provements in productivity. The components of the Malmquist compute this index in the following manner:
index are built as distance ratios. The first component describes
! !
changes in efficiency from t to tþ1; this factor is called Efficiency yCRS
tþ1
VRS ðx
ftþ1 tþ1 Þ yVRS
t ftCRS ðxt Þ
Change or Change in Efficiency (eff). The second component is scale ¼ CRS ðx
, , VRS ,
ftþ1 tþ1 Þ yVRS
tþ1 ft ðxt Þ yCRS t
referred to as Technical Change or Change in Technology (tech), and it
represents the shift in technology from the old to the new frontier
between t and tþ1. In particular, the first component (eff) repre-  Pure technical change (pure_tech), which measures the real shift
sents the ability of a production unit e in the tax judiciary, a CTP e in the technology between t1 and t2, it being the geometric
to reach the frontier of time t with the inputs of time tþ1. In other mean of the two ratios of technological changes from the
words, this index indicates the ability of a court to exploit the re- perspective of the DMU at time t1 and time t2. This index cor-
sources available at tþ1, leaving the other conditions at time t responds to Technologic change (tech) but considers variable
unchanged. The technical change component (tech) indicates im- returns to scale. It is possible to compute this index in the
provements in unit productivity moving from the frontier at t to the following manner:
current position. For the purposes of our study, this component
represents the ability of a court to rearrange the organization of its " ! !#1 2 =
VRS ðx VRS ðx Þ
work, i.e. to exploit the inputs at time tþ1 in a different way, ftþ1 tþ1 Þ ftþ1 t
pure tech ¼ , VRS
improving or worsening its position in relation to the frontier at t. ftVRS ðxtþ1 Þ ft ðxt Þ
Based on the above explanation, the Total Factor Productivity (tfp)
between t and tþ1 can thus be rewritten by using the product of
Change in Efficiency and Change in Technology:  Change in scale of technology (scale_tech), which is the residual
and is difficult to interpret. Simar and Wilson [71] conclude that
values > 1 indicate a flattening of the technology, whereas the
tfpt;tþ1 ¼ Mt;tþ1 ¼ eff t;tþ1 $techt;tþ1 index presents an increase in the curvature of the technology.
This is obtained as the product of Change in efficiency (eff) and
In general, the tfp computation presents limitations related to Change in pure efficiency (pure_eff). It is possible to compute this
the determination of technology, which can only be an index in the following manner:
approximation.
Following the current literature (e.g. [1,37,45,53], the aim of this " #1 2
=
CRS ðx VRS ðx Þ f CRS ðx Þ
paper is to focus on the most applied decomposition, i.e. Change in ftVRS ðxtþ1 Þ ftþ1 tþ1 Þ ft t tþ1 t
scale tech ¼ , , ,
Efficiency (eff) and Change in Technology (tech). Indeed, these in- ftCRS ðxtþ1 Þ ftþ1
VRS ðx
tþ1 Þ ft
CRS ðx Þ f VRS ðx Þ
t tþ1 t
dexes consider Constant Returns to Scale (CRS), which assume that,
by varying the time, the returns of each DMU do not change. This
allows the authors to consider – in the regression model – the ef-  SCH, which is the product of Change in scale efficiency and
fects on the dependent variable without noise due to changes in Change in scale of technology. It is possible to compute this index
returns to scale [39]. However, other factorizations have been in the following manner:
suggested by the literature: FGNZ [33], RD [66], SW [71] and WW
[79].9 In order to calculate these factorizations, we need to consider " #1 2 =

the following features:


yCRS
tþ1 yt
VRS f VRS ðx
t
CRS VRS
tþ1 Þ ftþ1 ðxt Þ ftþ1 ðxtþ1 Þ ft
CRS ðx Þ
t
SCH ¼ CRS , VRS CRS , VRS , CRS ,
yt ytþ1 ft ðxtþ1 Þ ftþ1 ðxt Þ ftþ1 ðxtþ1 Þ ftVRS ðxt Þ
 Change in pure efficiency (pure_eff), which captures the true
Once these factors are defined (i.e., Change in pure efficiency,
change in efficiency for the ith unit between t1 and t2. It is the
Change in scale efficiency, Pure technical change, Change in scale of
same as Change in efficiency (eff) but it considers variable returns
technology, SCH), the literature shows how to calculate the afore-
mentioned decompositions of the Malmquist indexes: FGNZ
9
These factorizations can shed light on why a DMU, in our case a CTP, changes its
(pure_eff * scale * tech), RD (pure_eff * pure_tech * SCH), SW (pure_eff
efficiency score, considering not only constant returns to scale but also variable * pure_tech * scale * scale_tech) and WW (pure_eff * pure_tech * scale
ones. * scale_tech). According to [39], even if these decompositions can
36 G. Falavigna et al. / Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 62 (2018) 31e43

Table 1
Descriptive statistics of efficiency scores, inputs and output. Italian 1st instance courts (2009e11).

Type Variable Obs. 2009 2010 2011

Mean St. Dev. Mean St. Dev. Mean St. Dev.

Inputs Judges 103 29 33 26 30 24 28


Pending cases 103 5323 12324 5609 12170 5767 12455
Incoming cases 103 2885 4897 2824 4773 2524 4093
Output Resolved cases 103 2591 4751 2640 4420 2384 4032

provide additional information, their interpretation is quite critical. only comparison that can be made regards efficiency across
Finally, note that the Malmquist indexes are calculated on DEA different regions in the same year. Hence, we cannot gather any
efficiency scores. Yet, when adopting another measure of radial significant information concerning the effects of the public policy.
distance such as, for example, the Directional Distance Function By contrast, the Malmquist index makes it possible to examine the
(DDF), the literature suggests revising these measures and applying results in greater depth and to obtain further indications about the
the Malmquist-Luenberger productivity indexes (e.g., [22,23,39]. effects of the policy.
According to Coelli et al. [15] and Cooper et al. [17]; frontiers are Table 3 illustrates the statistics on Total Factor Productivity,
computed via the Data Envelopment Analysis methodology with calculated through the Malmquist index (tfp) and decomposed into
output orientation. In this way, the calculated Technical Efficiency Change in Efficiency (eff) and Change in Technology (tech), over the
score measures the increase in output needed to achieve full effi- same time period (geometrical mean). The table clearly shows that
ciency.10 Finally, in order to calculate the Malmquist indexes and in a number of cases the new policy has indeed boosted produc-
their decompositions, this research uses the FEAR package for R- tivity e as also shown by the comparison of TE scores within each
statistics vers. 2.14.2 [70], applying the bootstrap procedure with a region in Table 2 e, since the Malmquist index is greater than 1 in
number of replications equal to 2000. Lombardy and Piedmont (North-West), Lazio and Tuscany (Center),
The next section presents data and some descriptive statistics Abruzzi, Molise, and Basilicata (South), and Sicily (Islands). Yet, the
regarding the computed indexes and scores, in order to assess the Malmquist index allows us to draw further conclusions and attain a
impact of the policy on the productivity and judicial efficiency of deeper understanding of what has happened. The policy has
CTPs. reduced the number of active sections, which implies that the
production structure of the courts in the abovementioned regions
5. Data and descriptive statistics was most likely oversized and not working at full capacity. Logi-
cally, a reduction in sections has indeed fostered a rationalization of
Table 1 presents descriptive statistics of inputs and output. Data the judges' tasks and possibly the reorganization of the courts
about judges, pending cases on January 1st of each year, incoming (when tech > 1). In most of the aggregated observations (13 out of
cases, as well as resolved cases are extracted from the annual report 21), however, the policy has not had the same effect, as confirmed
of the Italian Ministry of Economy and Finance (MEF) in charge of by the Malmquist index being smaller than 1. The decomposition
administering tax justice. Based on data availability, the 103 courts into change in efficiency and change in technology offers further
are analyzed in relation to the 2009e2011 period. Since the elements to understand the reasons behind this.
Malmquist index assesses changes, its estimation concerns two In most of the cases in which there has been an increase in
different years, i.e. 2009 and 2011, while the technical efficiency productivity (Malmquist index > 1), eff > 1 or both eff > 1 and
scores are estimated for every single year. tech > 1. This implies that a reduction in inputs has often deter-
In order to improve the readability of the results, although the mined a better use of the remaining resources. It is equally relevant
data are calculated at the provincial level (per CTP), they are here to note that the policy has led to generalized technical change e i.e.,
aggregated at the regional level, with the only exception of two a reorganization of the courts (14 out of 21 regional CTP systems).
autonomous provinces e i.e., Trento and Bolzano, which enjoy a Nevertheless, only in one case (Basilicata) has the change in tech-
quasi-regional status granted by the Italian Constitution. Moreover, nology been of such magnitude as to exceed the change in effi-
in order to help the reader interpret the maps reported below ciency and produce a net productivity increase (i.e., the Malmquist
(Fig. 1), the Italian regions are grouped into five macro areas (North- index is greater than 1).
West, North-East, Center, South, and Islands). Fig. 1 provides a disaggregated representation (court by court),
Hence, Table 2 reports the technical efficiency scores by region mapping the Malmquist index and its components across Italy. The
(that is to say, considering the average CTP for every Italian region) white areas correspond to the CTPs in which the values are lower
for each year analyzed. The range of the calculated Technical Effi- than 1, while the colored areas correspond to values greater than 1,
ciency scores (TE) is TE2½1; ∞Þ, where 1 means that the regional with two different degrees of intensity (pink indicates a moderate
CTPs system is on the efficiency frontier, while TE > 1 indicates that increase, while red indicates a substantial increase).
judicial inefficiency becomes proportionally worse. As easily seen, there is an almost perfect overlap between the
As easily seen, conclusions about the impact of the policy are not map showing the distribution of the Malmquist index and the map
straightforward. The figures for each region vary from year to year referring to efficiency change, which thus appears to be the main
and some adjustments in the production organization do seem to determinant of the former. 50 out of 103 CTPs (i.e., slightly less than
take place. However, it should be highlighted that the TE scores are 50%) display a Malmquist index higher than 1, and a similar pattern
estimated as the radial distance of every DMU from the production emerges for what concerns eff > 1 (48 out of 103 CTPs), although
frontier, and this changes every year. Accordingly, the values dis- there is a generalized shock in technical change since almost 77% of
played in the three columns are not directly comparable and the the CTPs (i.e., 79 out of 103) have scores higher than 1.
Indeed, reducing the number of sections has fostered a change
in technology almost everywhere, which confirms the policy's
10
The calculation of the Malmquist index starting from the DEA approach is effectiveness in triggering production organization improvements.
exhaustively discussed in Coelli [14].
G. Falavigna et al. / Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 62 (2018) 31e43 37

Fig. 1. Mapping of the Malmquist productivity index and its components (Change in Efficiency and Change in Technology) Italy, 2009e2011.

Table 2 productivity, since human work (thus, the number of judges) still
Descriptive statistics of the technical efficiency scores. remains a pivotal factor which can lead to an increase in produc-
Region Macro-area 2009 2010 2011 tivity, albeit only to a certain upper limit. Accordingly, a policy
aimed at enhancing productivity should focus on the judges and
Liguria North-West 1.3875 1.8919 1.6810
Lombardy North-West 1.2719 1.4031 1.1785 include appropriate incentives to be devised for each situation,
Piedmont North-West 1.5646 1.7045 1.3978 given that a generalized policy is unlikely to have the same effects
Aosta Valley North-West 1.2383 1.4369 1.2320 in different contexts.
Emilia Romagna North-East 1.4824 1.6587 1.5289
A complementary result is observed when testing the relation-
Friuli Venetia Giulia North-East 1.3049 1.7050 1.5699
Autonomous Province of Bolzano North-East 1.2066 1.3304 1.2476 ship between the reduction in sections, on the one hand, and the
Autonomous Province of Trento North-East 1.6775 2.2350 2.4240 Malmquist index (with its components) and technical efficiency
Veneto North-East 1.3119 1.6253 1.4648 scores, on the other hand. This is presented in the following section,
Lazio Center 1.5620 2.2382 1.5035 which tries more directly to determine whether improvements in
Marche Center 1.5966 2.2600 1.9849
the organization of the courts can foster productivity regardless of
Tuscany Center 1.4831 1.8751 1.4506
Umbria Center 1.1345 1.2105 1.1355 the role played by the judges, keeping the other resources (i.e., staff,
Abruzzi South 1.8258 1.4366 1.1020 ICT, etc.) unchanged.
Basilicata South 1.4010 1.8166 1.5308 Table 1 of the Appendix presents further descriptive statistics of
Calabria South 1.7610 2.6674 1.8033
Malmquist indexes, showing the other factors (i.e., Change in pure
Campania South 1.2026 1.3210 1.2641
Molise South 1.5985 1.6664 1.4803
efficiency, Change in scale efficiency, Pure technical change, Change in
Apulia South 1.5541 1.8085 1.5749 scale of technology, SCH).
Sardinia Islands 1.6683 2.8098 2.1435
Sicily Islands 1.7808 2.2912 1.2739
Total 1.4933 1.8420 1.4755 6. Second stage e regression models

The second stage analysis is aimed at testing the impact of the


However, in most cases, the policy has not led to an increase in policy on the productivity of the courts, also taking the judges'
productivity. When this has happened, the momentum impressed effort as well as geographical location into account. The Malmquist
by technology change has in general been softer than in the case of index is the dependent variable of a multiple regression model,
eff > 1. This clearly emerges, for instance, when looking at the two while the technical efficiency score obtained with the DEA is the
CTPs of Rome and Viterbo in Fig. 1. In these CTPs, tech > 1 (with high dependent variable of a truncated regression model. Table 4 pre-
values, confirmed by the red color) but eff < 1; therefore, the overall sents the descriptive statistics of the dependent and independent
effect is at best a slight increase in productivity (the two areas are variables, for both models.
pink in the Malmquist index map). The first independent variable (sections reduction) is the change
The overall picture seems to indicate that a more productive in the number of active sections, which is, of course, generally
organization of the CTPs has been attained and that, in a number of negative. It is computed by averaging the number of active sections
cases, a better use of the main input (i.e., the judges) was also on January 1st and December 31st of each year and expressly tries
desirable. Yet, these effects cannot per se boost judicial to capture the effect of the 2008 Ministerial Decree, i.e. to detect
any causal relation between the reduction in sections and changes
38 G. Falavigna et al. / Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 62 (2018) 31e43

Table 3
Descriptive statistics of the Malmquist index and sections variation.

Region Macro-area Malmquist Change in Efficiency Change in Technology Frequency (CTPs) Sections variation

Aosta Valley North-West 0.996 0.993 1.003 1 0


Liguria North-West 0.982 0.972 1.011 4 5
Lombardy North-West 1.017 1.019 0.998 11 16
Piedmont North-West 1.011 1.007 1.003 8 9
Autonomous Province of Bolzano North-East 0.941 0.982 0.958 1 1
Autonomous Province of Trento North-East 0.972 0.962 1.010 1 1
Emilia Romagna North-East 0.999 0.994 1.005 9 8
Friuli Venetia Giulia North-East 0.982 0.986 0.997 4 2
Veneto North-East 0.988 0.993 0.996 7 11
Lazio Center 1.020 1.004 1.016 5 7
Marche Center 0.973 0.966 1.006 4 5
Tuscany Center 1.018 1.007 1.011 10 11
Umbria Center 0.976 0.984 0.991 2 2
Abruzzi South 1.063 1.068 0.995 4 2
Apulia South 0.993 0.982 1.011 5 10
Basilicata South 1.010 0.999 1.011 2 2
Calabria South 0.972 0.980 0.993 5 3
Campania South 0.998 0.992 1.005 5 10
Molise South 1.011 1.004 1.007 2 1
Sardinia Islands 0.964 0.948 1.018 4 2
Sicily Islands 1.028 1.019 1.009 9 3
Total 1.003 0.999 1.004 103 106

Table 4
Descriptive statistics of dependent and independent variables, Malmquist and DEA analyses. Italian 1st instance courts (2009e11).

Variables Malmquist analysis DEA analysis

Mean Std. Dev. Mean Std. Dev.

Dependent Malmquist index 1.003 0.041


Efficiency change 0.999 0.041
Technical change 1.004 0.014
Technical efficiency scores 1.604 0.646
Independent Sections variation 1.024 1.221 6.298 6.976
Hearings per judge 3.839 5.595 22.930 8.701
Cases per judge 26.997 38.920 133.294 81.755
North-West 0.233 0.425 0.233 0.425
North-East 0.214 0.412 0.214 0.412
Center 0.204 0.405 0.204 0.405
South 0.223 0.418 0.223 0.418
Islands 0.126 0.334 0.126 0.334

in productivity, as well as changes in technology and efficiency. foster productivity, considering the geographical location of each
The second (hearings per judge) and third (cases per judge) var- court and controlling for the judges' performance. The part of the
iables are proxies related to the judges' productivity and the in- variance explained by the model (i.e. R2) is between 16% (change in
ternal organization of the courts. Hearings per judge is given by the technology) and 27% (change in efficiency as dependent variable).
number of times judges attend hearings (i.e. total number of Finally, the mean variance inflation factor shows an acceptable
hearings multiplied by three, which is the number of judges in a result (2.03).
section) divided by the (total) number of judges in a CTP. Cases per It is easy to see that the coefficients regarding sections reduction
judge is given by the (total) number of cases discussed divided by are statistically significant, although they are positive for the
the (total) number of judges in a CTP.11 These variables are good change in efficiency and negative for the change in technology, and
proxies for the effort judges put into their work, since they measure the magnitude of the former is larger than that of the latter. On the
both the amount of time spent and the quantity of cases discussed. whole, this means that a reduction in the number of active sections
The other independent variables concern the classification by has had a negative impact on the overall performance of the courts,
macro-areas (North-West, North-East, Center, South, and Islands of although the reorganization of the residual sections has possibly
Italy) and they attempt to capture heterogeneity among CTPs as- determined a more effective use of the remaining resources. Hence,
cribable to their geographical location. technology does not fully replace the productive role of the judges,
confirming the findings showed in Table 3 and successive figures.
Indeed, findings show that the change in technology can partially
6.1. Results for the Malmquist index compensate for the reduction in sections, and this effect is greater
in the macro-areas in which the organization of work was originally
Table 5 proposes a multiple regression model with the robust weaker. In this regard, the smaller coefficient for the South prob-
option. The model is statistically significant (F test) and it is aimed ably implies a greater need for catching up in the organization of
at testing whether improvements in the organization of the courts work compared to the other macro-areas. In other words, sup-
porting technical change seems to be more appropriate in this area
than elsewhere. Moreover, our findings indicate that fostering
11
Note that these indexes are directly calculated by the MEF and published in its
improvements in the organization of the courts should be the
annual report on the activities of tax courts.
G. Falavigna et al. / Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 62 (2018) 31e43 39

Table 5 Table 6
Variation in active CTP sections, 2009e11 OLS Model e robust option. Variation in active CTP sections, 2009e11. Truncated regression Model e bootstrap
option (200 replacements), lower level 1, higher level 2.5.
Variables Malmquist Change in Efficiency Change in Technology
Variables TE Score
Sections variationa 0.00749** 0.0103*** 0.00285***
(0.00285) (0.00315) (0.000984) eq1 Sigma
Hearings per judgea 0.000934 0.000900 2.75e-05
Sections variation 0.00906***
(0.000969) (0.000970) (0.000374)
(0.00201)
Cases per judgea 0.000335*** 0.000292** 3.97e-05
Hearings per judge 0.00742***
(0.000116) (0.000124) (6.49e-05)
(0.00286)
North-West 0.0208 0.0315* 0.0111***
Cases per judge 0.00100***
(0.0154) (0.0161) (0.00417)
(0.000305)
North-East 0.00226 0.0154 0.0134***
North-West 0.490***
(0.0138) (0.0152) (0.00495)
(0.0909)
Center 0.0210 0.0238 0.00346
North-East 0.388***
(0.0151) (0.0152) (0.00436)
(0.0926)
South 0.0150 0.0250 0.0102**
Center 0.291***
(0.0159) (0.0164) (0.00423)
(0.0870)
Constant 0.985*** 0.977*** 1.008***
South 0.255***
(0.0141) (0.0154) (0.00425)
(0.0768)
2010 0.211***
F (7,95) 4.68 4.55 2.61 (0.0510)
Prob > F 0.000 0.000 0.016 2011 0.0193
(0.0445)
Number of Courts 103 103 103 Constant 2.089*** 0.321***
R-squared 0.258 0.267 0.158 (0.120) (0.0150)
Robust standard errors in parentheses.
***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1. Wald chi2 (9) 65.73
a
These variables estimate the change in the considered period, i.e. the difference Prob > chi2 0.0000
between 2009 and 2011.
Observations 289

Bootstrapped standard errors in parentheses.


target of the policy in selected regions, while in other areas where ***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
work is already efficiently organized it would be more appropriate
to leave the number of sections and judges unchanged. The uneven
results for the various regions (Table 3) strongly suggest avoiding The model confirms the key role of judges within the courts, as
‘one size fits all’ conclusions, since the expected outcomes seem to well as the negative impact of the policy. As indicated by the results,
be heavily dependent on local characteristics. As clearly indicated there is a negative relation between the decreasing number of
by Table 3, the policy has worked in the expected direction in 8 out active sections and the technical efficiency of the CTPs. The data
of 21 regions, meaning that the organization of the courts and of also show that the productivity of judges, in terms of number of
the judges' work in those regions was probably suboptimal. The cases and hearings, is vital for CTP efficiency, coherently with the
opposite has happened in other regions, which seems to suggest previous results. However, no specific effects brought about by
that the outcome is mostly a random event. Table 5 presents a technical change can be identified.
general overview and underlines that a reduction in sections has Finally, the aspect of heterogeneity among macro-areas is even
had a negative impact due to the inability of technical change to more important. The impact of the geographical location of a court
fully compensate for the judges' work. Interestingly, as far as is statistically significant and extremely high, with major differ-
geographical heterogeneity is concerned, only the change in tech- ences between the North and the South of Italy. Also referring to the
nology shows significant coefficients. As mentioned above, this results proposed in Table 5 about change in technology, we can
seems to suggest that, while the main production input, the judges, support the hypothesis that the North of Italy is more efficient than
has similar effects across different macro-areas, the organization of the South but the reorganization triggered by the policy has started
the courts is mostly affected by local socio-economic factors. to reduce the gap.
Table 7 further confirms the key role played by judges within the
courts, as well as the negative impact of the policy and the influ-
6.2. Results for the technical efficiency score ence of geographic location on technical efficiency. As previously
explained, the figures presented here, obtained through a multiple
The analysis regresses the technical efficiency score on the regression model applying the panel option, provide clear evidence
covariates. Table 6 uses a truncated regression model on a pooled of strong causality [43]. The model in column 1 implements the
sample with dummy variables for each year, while Table 7 regards a bootstrap option with 200 replacements, while the model in col-
multiple regression model on panel data. In both cases the boot- umn 2 applies the robust option. The model is statistically signifi-
strap option with 200 replacements is applied and, as a robustness cant (F test), and the part of the variance explained by the model is
check, Table 7 also proposes a model with the robust option (col- 18% (between) and 13% (overall).
umn 2). The use of a truncated regression model in Table 6 follows
the two-stage approach according to Simar and Wilson [73]. Once
again, it is worth reminding that, on the basis of the DEA estimation 6.3. Discussion
performed, efficiency is attained when the score is equal to 1, while
inefficiency grows as the score increases, being the highest value Our results confirm the key role of judges within the courts, as
observed in our sample equal to 2.5. According to the approach well as the negative impact of the policy (i.e., a statistically signif-
proposed here, 289 observations are analyzed in the empirical icant negative relation between the decreasing number of active
model. The model is statistically significant (F test), and the dis- sections and the efficiency of the CTPs). Moreover, our findings
tribution of residuals is checked with acceptable results. clearly show that the productivity of judges is vital for CTP
40 G. Falavigna et al. / Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 62 (2018) 31e43

Table 7 known, while Baumol's cost disease predicts the disappearance of


Variation in active CTP sections, 2009e11. OLS Model with panel option (model 1 labor-intensive activities, this cannot be accepted for the case of
with bootstrap option - 200 replacements; model 2 with robust option).
adjudication, or similar activities, whose role is relevant and not
Variables (1) (2) substitutable for society and the market.
TE Scorea TE Scorea Hence, from a policy viewpoint, there are two options for
solving the conundrum and these are suggested by the observation
Sections variation 0.00989*** 0.00989***
(0.00193) (0.00256) of the Malmquist index. The first viable option is to design a policy
Hearings per judge 0.00630* 0.00630** able to overcome the productivity gap of the courts by promoting,
(0.00326) (0.00295) where possible, the attainment of economies of scales in their in-
Cases per judge 0.000955** 0.000955***
ternal organization. However, as discussed above, there are
(0.000417) (0.000305)
North-West 0.461*** 0.461*** intrinsic limits and the shift in technical change can, at best, apply
(0.0879) (0.104) to activities that are ancillary to judicial decision, i.e. the activities
North-East 0.346*** 0.346*** performed by court staff to prepare and manage cases. Yet, as
(0.0887) (0.112) observed, this type of technical change also seems to have an upper
Center 0.257*** 0.257***
boundary. Therefore, another type of technical change might be
(0.0750) (0.0989)
South 0.233*** 0.233*** considered, i.e. a change able to maximize the essentially steady
(0.0630) (0.0867) productivity of judges, which would, per se, remain the same. This
Constant 2.111*** 2.111*** change will not affect the number of decisions reached per judge
(0.124) (0.138)
but the scope that every decision has by changing the legal ma-
chinery (and not only the internal organization of the courts). The
Wald chi2 (7) 70.40 41.46
Prob > chi2 0.0000 0.0000 basic idea is that, if attaining economies of scale within the courts is
not possible, a viable approach might be to foster the emergence of
R-squared: what has been called “judicial economy” outside the courts, in
Between 0.1809 general via procedural amendment [5]. A seminal case of this is
Overall 0.1259
found in civil procedure: introducing the possibility of aggregating
distinct legal claims or specific parts of a litigation can lead courts to
Observations 289
Number of courts 101 the attainment of something similar to economies of scale. While
the main example of this is class action e a device allowing the joint
Standard errors in parentheses.
***p < 0.01, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1.
vindication of a large number of claims e, other procedural solu-
a
Observations with a score between 1 and 2.5. tions exist, bringing together legal actions which “involve a com-
mon question of law or fact [and in which] the court may: (1) join
for hearing or trial any or all matters at issue in the actions; (2)
efficiency, in terms of number of cases and hearings, as well as the consolidate the actions; or (3) issue any other orders to avoid un-
existence of a strong geographical heterogeneity. necessary cost or delay” (Rule 42a, US Code of Civil Procedure, 2009
These results are robust since they are coherent with all the edition). The simple idea here is that, by redrawing the boundaries
proposed models. In other words, although different techniques of litigation, although the inputs are kept constant, adjudication
have been adopted (OLS and Truncated regression model, TE scores offers scope for alternative solutions designed to achieve adequate
and Malmquist indexes), the same significant relations are “productive” configurations [7]. This would provide courts with the
confirmed. However, there are also limits and shortcomings, since means to attain economies of scales and overcome Baumol's cost
the results rely on the proposed inputs and their availability, as disease.
highlighted in the methodology section. Indeed, CTP staff numbers The validity of the above approach clearly emerges when the
are not available and, for this reason, they have not been introduced workings of the courts are unraveled and thoroughly investigated
in the model as input. Further studies might support our analysis by by means of the Malmquist index. The data observed allow us to
including clerks among the inputs, provided that data become conclude that the EU recommendation that the judiciary should be
available. provided with “adequate financial and human resources”12 appears
What about the meaning of these results in comparison with to be a necessary yet insufficient condition. Simply increasing
literature findings? The overall results illustrated above perfectly fit expenditure or resources will plausibly be as ineffective as reducing
with our hypothesis that adjudication is a labor-intensive activity them. These hypotheses might be tested more extensively by
and, although fine-tuning their organization can indeed enhance comparing the behavior and strategies of non-professional judges
the productivity of the courts, the role of the judges still remains with respect to opportunity costs (i.e., a proxy of the aforemen-
pivotal, as supported by the evidence gathered so far. There might tioned economic incentives). This might be a significant research
indeed be ways to increase the efforts made by judges and a suit- extension of our analysis, able to shed new light on this sensitive
able policy should create incentives aimed at boosting their pro- topic and to lead policy makers to more effective reforms. Taking
ductivity. As Beenstock and Haitovsky [3] observe, fostering the proposed methodology into account, another potential research
productivity only by increasing the number of judges is as inef- stream might concern the adoption of the Malmquist indexes in
fective as reducing the number of sections, due to the judges' other areas of the judiciary such as, for example, civil or criminal
aversion to effort (they are, after all, economic agents like everyone courts. This might be extremely significant in all those countries
else). Without suitable incentive schemes, the appointment of new where structural reforms have been introduced (e.g., [24,42].
judges would simply lead to a reduction in their efforts [62].
Therefore, there is an upper limit beyond which their productivity 7. Conclusions
cannot increase any further. Said limit is inherently connected with
the human nature of the input, which cannot keep up with the This paper applies the technical efficiency score and Malmquist
productivity growth of an economy where capital intensive inputs
are relevant. This phenomenon is known as Baumol's cost disease,
which positively applies to the scenario analyzed here [2]. As is well 12
COM(2013) 160 final, p. 16.
G. Falavigna et al. / Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 62 (2018) 31e43 41

index to evaluate the impact of a public policy (involving cuts to the result also emerges: the application of the tools of production
courts' production lines) on the productivity of the Italian tax theory to tax courts and more generally to the workings of the
judiciary. In particular, the use of the Malmquist index allows public administration is a crucial step for drafting sensible public
decomposing productivity change into its main components in policies, relying upon the proper premises and considering the
order to ‘access the black box’ of adjudication and provide valuable relevant mechanisms of the production activity.
insights that are essential for policy-making. By contrast, the
absence of these elements can negatively affect policy-making,
which thus fails to grasp the core of the problem and is unable to Appendix
implement actions consistent with its objectives.

Table 1
Descriptive statistics of the Malmquist index

Region Macro- Malmquist Change in Change in Change in Pure Change in Scale Pure Technical Change in Scale SCH
area Efficiency Technology efficiency efficiency change Technology

Aosta Valley North- 0.996 0.993 1.003 1.000 0.993 e e e


West
Liguria North- 0.982 0.972 1.011 0.979 0.993 1.005 1.005 0.999
West
Lombardy North- 1.017 1.019 0.998 1.017 1.003 0.994 1.004 1.007
West
Piedmont North- 1.011 1.007 1.003 1.012 0.995 1.007 1.001 0.995
West
Autonomous Province of North- 0.941 0.982 0.958 0.990 0.993 0.955 1.003 0.996
Bolzano East
Autonomous Province of North- 0.972 0.962 1.010 0.953 1.009 1.012 0.998 1.008
Trento East
Emilia Romagna North- 0.999 0.994 1.005 1.000 0.994 0.998 1.007 1.001
East
Friuli Venetia Giulia North- 0.982 0.986 0.997 0.979 1.006 1.003 1.001 1.002
East
Veneto North- 0.988 0.993 0.996 0.998 0.994 0.991 1.005 0.999
East
Lazio Center 1.020 1.004 1.016 1.011 0.993 1.003 1.013 1.005
Marche Center 0.973 0.966 1.006 0.977 0.989 0.998 1.008 0.997
Tuscany Center 1.018 1.007 1.011 1.008 0.999 1.004 1.007 1.006
Umbria Center 0.976 0.984 0.991 0.991 0.993 0.977 1.015 1.008
Abruzzi South 1.063 1.068 0.995 1.074 0.995 0.988 1.007 1.002
Apulia South 0.993 0.982 1.011 0.998 0.984 0.992 1.019 1.003
Basilicata South 1.010 0.999 1.011 0.996 1.004 1.010 1.001 1.004
Calabria South 0.972 0.980 0.993 0.986 0.993 0.995 1.005 0.996
Campania South 0.998 0.992 1.005 1.006 0.986 0.991 1.014 1.001
Molise South 1.011 1.004 1.007 1.006 0.998 1.005 1.003 1.001
Sardinia Islands 0.964 0.948 1.018 0.962 0.986 1.005 1.013 0.998
Sicily Islands 1.028 1.019 1.009 1.041 0.979 0.994 1.015 0.994
Total 1.003 0.999 1.004 1.005 0.994 0.997 1.008 1.001

Our findings suggest that it is indeed possible to increase judi- References


cial productivity by reorganizing the courts (change in technology)
and/or by using the main input (the judges' work) more effectively. [1] Badunenko O, Kumbhakar SC. Economies of scale, technical change and
persistent and time-varying cost efficiency in Indian banking: do ownership,
These two components are complementary rather than substitut- regulation and heterogeneity matter? Eur J Oper Res 2017;260(2):789e803.
able. Furthermore, however improved, technology cannot replace [2] Baumol WJ, Bowen WG. Performing arts: the economic dilemma. New York:
the pivotal role of judges in producing decisions, as adjudication The Twentieth Century Fund; 1966.
[3] Beenstock M, Haitovsky Y. Does the appointment of judges increase the
mainly remains a labor-intensive activity, suffering the typical output of the judiciary? Int Rev Law Econ 2004;24:351e69.
problems caused by Baumol's cost disease. In other words, the [4] Berg SA, Førsund FR, Jansen ES. Malmquist indices of productivity growth
analysis based on the Malmquist method clearly shows the limits of during the deregulation of Norwegian banking, 1980-89. Scand J Econ 1992:
S211e28.
both components in enhancing productivity and provides guide- [5] Bernstein R. Judicial economy and class action. J Leg Stud 1977;7:349e70.
lines to develop policies relying on a different approach. If it proves [6] Binford WH, Greene PC, Schmidlkofer MC, Wilsey RM, Taylor HA. Seeking best
impossible to attain economies of scale within the production fa- practices among intermediate courts of appeal: a nascent journey. J Appellate
Pract Process 2007;9:37e119.
cilities, given the peculiar nature of adjudication and its complex
[7] Cassone A, Ramello GB. The simple economics of class action: private provi-
organization, policy-makers must necessarily look for new ap- sion of club and public goods. Eur J Law Econ 2011;32:205e24.
proaches to introduce productivity shocks from the outside, such as [8] CEPEJ. Report on the evaluation of the judicial system. 2012. Council of
Europe’s European Commission for the Efficiency of Justice e Report 2012.
procedures able to maximize the effect of every single decision,
[9] Chaparro PF, Jimenez SJ. An assessment of the efficiency of Spanish courts
thus reintroducing economies of scale in an unusual way. using DEA. Appl Econ 1996;28:1391e403.
This study confirms that generalized policy measures are most [10] Charnes A, Cooper WW, Rhodes E. Measuring the efficiency of decision
likely unable to lead to consistent results, since the outcome of the making units. Eur J Oper Res 1978;2:429e44.
[11] Chavas JP. An international analysis of agricultural productivity. FAO Econ Soc
policy analyzed here displays different signs for different local court Dev Pap 2001:21e38.
systems. It also shows that the lack of appropriate analytical tools [12] Cheng A, Hwang Y, Shao B. Measurement and sources of overall and input
makes it impossible to grasp the deeper meaning of changes in inefficiencies: evidences and implications in hospital services. Eur J Oper Res
2005;161:447e68.
productivity and can lead to ambiguous choices. An additional
42 G. Falavigna et al. / Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 62 (2018) 31e43

[13] Choi SJ, Gulati M, Posner EA. What do federal district judges want? An analysis efficiency in education. Ann Oper Res 2011;221(1):197e210.
of publications, citations, and reversals. University of Chicago Law School, Law [47] Kao C, Hwang SN. Multi-period efficiency and Malmquist productivity index
& Economics Working Paper; 2010 January. in two-stage production systems. Eur J Oper Res 2014;232(3):512e21.
[14] Coelli T. A guide to DEAP version 2.1: a data envelopment analysis (computer) [48] Kittelsen SAC, Førsund FR. Efficiency analysis of Norwegian district courts.
program. 1996. CEPA working paper, 96/08. J Prod Anal 1992;3:277e306.
[15] Coelli T, Rao Prasada DS, Battese GE. An introduction to efficiency and pro- [49] Lambert DK. Scale and the Malmquist productivity index. Appl Econ Lett
ductivity analysis. Noerwell. Kluwer Academic Publishers; 1998. 1999;6(9):593e6.
[16] Cook WD, Seiford LM. Data envelopment analysis (DEA) e thirty years on. Eur [50] Landes WM, Lessig L, Solimine ME. Judicial influence: a citation analysis of
J Oper Res 2009;192:1e17. federal courts of appeals judges. J Leg Stud 1998;27:271e332.
[17] Cooper WW, Seidorf LM, Tone K. Data envelopment analysis. A comprehen- [51] Lewin AL, Morey RC, Cook TC. Evaluating the administrative efficiency of
sive text with models. Application references and DEA-solver software. sec- courts. Omega 1982;10:401e11.
ond ed. Berlin: Springer Edition; 2007. chap. 1e2 and 11. [52] Lindquist SA. Bureaucratization and balkanization: the origins and effects of
[18] Cooter RD. The objectives of private and public judges. Public Choice 1983;41: decision-making norms in the federal appellate courts. Univ Richmond Law
107e37. Rev 2007;41:659e706.
[19] Daraio C, Simar L. Advanced robust and nonparametric methods in efficiency [53] Lo€ thgren M, Tambour M. Productivity and customer satisfaction in Swedish
analysis: methodology and application. Berlin: Springer; 2007. pharmacies: a DEA network model. Eur J Oper Res 1999;115(3):449e58.
[20] Deyneli F. Analysis of relationship between efficiency of justice services and [54] Lovell CK. The decomposition of Malmquist productivity indexes. J Prod Anal
salaries of judges with two-stage DEA method. Eur J Law Econ 2012;34: 2003;20(3):437e58.
477e93. [55] Maniadakis N, Thanassoulis E. A cost Malmquist productivity index. Eur J Oper
[21] Dimitrova-Grajzl V, Grajzl P, Sustersic J, Zajc K. Court output, judicial staffing, Res 2004;154(2):396e409.
and the demand for court services: evidence from Slovenian courts of first [56] Marselli R, Vannini M. L'Efficienza Tecnica dei Distretti di Corte di Appello
instance. Int Rev Law Econ 2012;32:19e29. Italiani: aspetti Metodologici, Benchmarking e Arretrato Smaltibile. CRENOS
[22] Emrouznejad A, Yang GL. CO 2 emissions reduction of Chinese light Working Paper. 2004.
manufacturing industries: a novel RAM-based global MalmquisteLuenberger [57] Mussard S, Peypoch N. On multi-decomposition of the aggregate Malmquist
productivity index. Energy Policy 2016a;96:397e410. productivity index. Econ Lett 2006;91(3):436e43.
[23] Emrouznejad A, Yang GL. A framework for measuring global Malm- [58] Nin A, Arndt C, Preckel PV. Is agricultural productivity in developing countries
quisteLuenberger productivity index with CO 2 emissions on Chinese really shrinking? New evidence using a modified nonparametric approach.
manufacturing industries. Energy 2016b;115:840e56. J Dev Econ 2003;71(2):395e415.
[24] Espinosa R, Desrieux C, Wan H. Fewer courts, less justice? Evidence from the [59] Odeck J. Assessing the relative efficiency and productivity growth of vehicle
2008 French reform of labor courts. Eur J Law Econ 2017;43(2):195e237. inspection services: an application of DEA and Malmquist indices. Eur J Oper
[25] Esposito G, Lanau S, Pompe S. Judicial system reform in Italy e a key to Res 2000;126(3):501e14.
growth. 2014. IMF Working Paper, WP/14/32. [60] OECD. What makes civil justice effective?. OECD Economics Department
[26] European Commission. Combating tax fraud and evasion. 2013. Commission Policy Notes, No. 18 June 2013. 2013.
contribution to the European Council of 22 May 2013. [61] Ouellette P, Vierstraete V. Malmquist indexes with quasi-fixed inputs: an
[27] European Commission. General government data: revenue, expenditure, application to school districts in Quebec. Ann Oper Res 2010;173(1):57e76.
balances and gross debt. Directorate General Ecfin - Economic and Financial [62] Posner RA. What do judges and justices maximize? (the same as everybody
Affairs. 2016. else does). Supreme Court Econ Rev 1993;3:1e41.
[28] Fabbri D. Law enforcement and firm financing: theory and evidence. J Eur [63] Prior D. Efficiency and total quality management in health care organizations:
Econ Assoc 2010;8(4):776e816. a dynamic frontier approach. Ann Oper Res 2006;145(1):281e99.
[29] Falavigna G, Ippoliti R, Manello A. Judicial efficiency and immigrant entre- [64] Pulina M, Detotto C, Paba A. An investigation into the relationship between
preneurs. J Small Bus Manag 2017. forthcoming. size and efficiency of the Italian hospitality sector: a window DEA approach.
[30] Falavigna G, Ippoliti R, Manello A, Ramello G. Judicial productivity, delay and Eur J Oper Res 2010;204:613e20.
efficiency: a Directional Distance Function (DDF) approach. Eur J Oper Res [65] Ramseyer JM. Talent matters: judicial productivity and speed in Japan. Int Rev
2015;240(2015):592e601. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2014.07.014. Law Econ 2012;32:38e48.
[31] Fa€re R, Grosskopf S. Intertemporal production frontiers: with dynamic DEA. [66] Ray SC, Desli E. Productivity growth, technical progress, and efficiency change
Boston Kluwer Academic Publishers; 1996. in industrialized countries: Comment. Am Econ Rev 1997;87:1033e9.
[32] Fare R, Grosskopf S, Lindgren B, Roos P. Productivity changes in Swedish [67] Ray SC, Das A. Distribution of cost and profit efficiency: evidence from Indian
pharmacies 1980e1989: a non-parametric Malmquist approach. J Prod Anal banking. Eur J Oper Res 2010;201:297e307.
1992;3:85e101. [68] Santos SP, Amado CAF. On the need for reform of the Portuguese judicial
[33] Fare R, Grosskopf S, Norris M, Zhang Z. Productivity growth, technical prog- system e does Data Envelopment Analysis assessment support it? Omega
ress, and efficiency change in industrialized countries. Am Econ Rev 1994;84: 2014;47(2014):1e16.
66e83. [69] Schneider MR. Judicial career incentives and court performance: an Empirical
[34] Farrell Michael J. The measurement of productive efficiency. J R Stat Soc study of the German labour courts of appeal. Eur J Law Econ 2005;20:127e44.
1957;120(3):253e90. [70] Simar L, Wilson PW. Estimating and bootstrapping Malmquist indices. Eur J
[35] Fethi MD, Pasiouras F. Assessing bank efficiency and performance with Oper Res 1999;115:459e71.
operational research and artificial intelligence techniques: a survey. Eur J Oper [71] Simar L, Wilson PW. Productivity growth in industrialized countries. Uni-
Res 2010;204:189e98. versite Catholique de Louvain - Center for Operations Research and Econo-
[36] Fragkiadakis G, Doumpos M, Zopounidis C, Germain C. Operational and eco- metrics [CORE]; 1998.
nomic efficiency analysis of public hospitals in Greece. Ann Oper Res 2014: [72] Simar L, Wilson PW. Stochastics and Statistics Non-parametric tests of returns
1e20. to scale. Eur J Oper Res 2002;139(2002):115e32.
[37] Gitto S. Efficiency change, technological change and capital accumulation in [73] Simar L, Wilson PW. Estimation and inference in two-stage, semi-parametric
Italian regions: a sectoral study. Int Rev Appl Econ 2017;31(2):191e207. models of production processes. J Econ 2007;136:321e64.
 E, Lovell CK. A note on the Malmquist productivity index. Econ
[38] Grifell-Tatje [74] Staub R, da Silva e Souza G, Tabak BM. Evolution of bank efficiency in Brazil: a
Lett 1995;47(2):169e75. DEA approach. Eur J Oper Res 2010;202:204e13.
[39] Grosskopf S. Some remarks on productivity and its decompositions. J Prod [75] Taha AE. Publish or Paris? Evidence of how judges allocate their time. Am Law
Anal 2003;20(3):459e74. Econ Rev 2004;6:1e27.
[40] Haidar JI. Investor protection and economics growth. Econ Lett 2009;103:1e4. [76] Tortosa-Ausina E, Grifell-Tatje E, Armero C, Conesa D. Sensitivity analysis of
[41] Ippoliti R. The competitiveness of the market for legal services and judicial efficiency and Malmquist productivity indices: an application to Spanish
efficiency. Italian J Public Econ 2014;2:53e90. http://dx.doi.org/10.3280/ savings banks. Eur J Oper Res 2008;184(3):1062e84.
EP2014-002003. [77] Tulkens H. On FDH efficiency analysis: some methodological issues and ap-
[42] Ippoliti R. The reform of judicial geography: technical efficiency and demand plications to retail banking, courts, and urban transit. J Prod Anal 1993;4:
of justice. Italian J Public Econ 2015;2:91e124. http://dx.doi.org/10.3280/ 183e210.
EP2015-002003. [78] Wendong L, Xiaoxin H, Kuangnan F. Chinese regional energy efficiency change
[43] Ippoliti R, Falavigna G. Efficiency of medical care industry: evidence from the and its determinants analysis: Malmquist index and Tobit model. Ann Oper
Italian regional system. Eur J Oper Res 2012;217:643e52. http://dx.doi.org/ Res 2012;228(1):9e22.
10.1016/j.ejor.2011.10.010. [79] Wheelock DC, Wilson PW. Technical progress, inefficiency, and productivity
[44] Ippoliti R, Melcarne A, Ramello G. Judicial efficiency and entrepreneurs' ex- change in U.S. banking, 1984e1993. J Money, Credit, Bank 1999;31:212e34.
pectations on the reliability of european legal systems. Eur J Law Econ 2014. [80] Yeung LL, Azevedo PF. Measuring efficiency of Brazilian courts with data
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10657-014-9456-x. envelopment analysis (DEA). IMA J Manag Math 2011;2011(22):343e56.
[45] Isik I, Hassan MK. Financial deregulation and total factor productivity change: [81] Zhou P, Ang BW, Poh KL. A survey of data envelopment analysis in energy and
an empirical study of Turkish commercial banks. J Bank Finance 2003;27(8): environmental studies. Eur J Oper Res 2008;189:1e18.
1455e85. [82] Emrouznejad A, Yang GL. A survey and analysis of the first 40 years of
[46] Johnson AL, Ruggiero J. Nonparametric measurement of productivity and scholarly literature in DEA: 1978e2016. Socio-Econ Plan Sci 2017.
G. Falavigna et al. / Socio-Economic Planning Sciences 62 (2018) 31e43 43

[83] Ho W, Xu X, Dey PK. Multi-criteria decision making approaches for supplier [85] Cooper WW, Tone K. Measures of inefficiency in data envelopment analysis
evaluation and selection: a literature review. Eur J Oper Res 2010;202(1): and stochastic frontier estimation. Eur J Oper Res 1997;99(1):72e88.
16e24. [86] Banker RD, Charnes A, Cooper WW. Some models for estimating technical and
[84] Cook WD, Liang L, Zhu J. Measuring performance of two-stage network scale inefficiencies in data envelopment analysis. Manag Sci 1984;30(9):
structures by DEA: a review and future perspective. Omega 2010;38(6): 1078e92.
423e30.

You might also like