You are on page 1of 5

American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2011, 101:3, 233–237

http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/aer.101.3.233

Moving Beyond Deregulation †

Why Can’t US Airlines Make Money?

By Severin Borenstein*

The US domestic airline industry was effec- 2001, aircraft and aircraft-seats declined from the
tively deregulated in the fall of 1978 with elimi- end of 2001 to the end of 2008, 1.7 percent and
nation of most economic restrictions on new 1.4 percent per year respectively.
entry and pricing. The industry lost $10 billion There is no conventional long-run equilib-
from 1979 to 1989, made $5 billion in the 1990s rium explanation for an industry that perpetu-
and lost $54 billion from 2000 to 2009 (all fig- ally loses money, but there are a number of
ures in 2009 dollars).1 To put these figures in disequilibrium theories that have been suggested
context, at the end of 2000, after six consecu- by industry participants, financial analysts, and
tive profitable years, the entire book value of US researchers. In this short paper I discuss some of
passenger carriers’ assets was $159 billion and these theories and attempt to narrow down the
shareholder equity was $40 billion. range of plausible explanations.
This dismal financial record isn’t what econo-
mists, analysts, or industry participants predicted I.  Exogenous Cost Drivers: Taxes and Fuel
in 1978. It is a puzzle to industrial organization
economists and a challenge to the views of dereg- Industry leaders argue that taxes on airline
ulation advocates. The puzzle is compounded by tickets have risen drastically and are a sig-
the fact that the industry saw robust investment nificant contributor to the airlines’ losses. The
until 2001 and has seen only modest disinvest- ticket tax today includes a 7.5 percent excise tax
ment in the financially disastrous 2000s. From and fees of $6.20 per segment flown. In addi-
1979 to 2001, the US airline passenger fleet grew tion, many airports impose passenger facilities
in every year, by an average of 4.9 percent per charges (PFCs) of up to $4.50 on each passenger
year measured by aircraft and 3.6 percent per boarding a flight at the airport. One can argue
year measured by aircraft-seats. After peaking in about whether these taxes are excessive given
the government costs of supporting the industry,
but it is difficult to see how these would lead to
long-run losses. The average tax (including fed-

Discussants: Catherine Wolfram, University of California-
Berkeley and NBER; Nancy L. Rose, Massachusetts Institute
of Technology. eral ticket taxes and PFCs) as a percentage of
* Haas School of Business, University of California,
the base ticket price has climbed steadily and is
Berkeley, CA 94720-1900 (e-mail: borenste@haas.berke- today about twice as high as when it was 8 per-
ley.edu). For helpful comments, I thank Silke Forbes, cent through most of the 1980s. But the average
Will Gillespie, Ken Heyer, Paul Joskow, Nancy Rose, and dollar tax per ticket is today about $43 ($2009),
Catherine Wolfram. This paper is dedicated to the memory just a dollar or two more than it was in the late
of Alfred E. Kahn, who passed away on December 27, 2010.
I was lucky enough to work for Fred at the Civil Aeronautics 1990s, the industry’s most profitable years.
Board in 1978 and to speak with him occasionally since Over the last 30 years, the form of taxation has
then about the airline industry and government regulation. changed. In the 1980s, the entire ticket tax was a
His approach to industrial organization and regulation, and percentage of the ticket value. Today, about half of
the application of research to nonpartisan policymaking,
set a standard to which all IO economists should aspire.
ticket tax revenues come from fixed per-­segment
His insights continue to influence the best research on eco- fees. PFCs were added in the early 1990s, the
nomic regulation. He was the very model of a modern (and segment tax in 1997, and the September 11 secu-
thoughtful) IO economist.
1
rity fee in early 2002, all based on the number
I focus on net income before extraordinary charges and of flights the passenger boards, regardless of the
gains. Including such adjustments doesn’t alter the basic
analysis but for some carriers causes large profit swings fare paid. As a result, as real fares have declined
from one year to the next. For a more detailed description 28 percent since 1992, dropping significantly
of the analysis reported here, see Severin Borenstein (2011).  after the September 11 attacks, the tax burden has
233
234 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2011

increased as a percentage of the base fare. But the 240%


implied shift of demand (or marginal cost) that
Airline demand Real GDP
220%
airlines face due to ticket taxation is today about
the same as it was just before 9/11. 200%

While taxes and fees have changed incremen- 180%


tally, the industry scale has changed massively.
160%
In the standard long-run adjustment dynamics,
it seems that the industry should have been able 140%
to achieve the scale change necessary to incor- 120%
porate and pass through these taxes. My own
research (in progress) suggests that changes in 100%

1979
1981
1983
1985
1987
1989
1991
1993
1995
1997
1999
2001
2003
2005
2007
2009
passenger facilities charges are nearly entirely
passed through to customers within two quarters.
Fuel cost increases have certainly been a Figure 1. Airline Demand and Real GDP,
significant component of losses in some years, Relative to 1979
most obviously 2008. Over the deregulation
era, however, oil costs were highest in the first
seven years and the most recent five years—over Demand increased by 110 percent from 1979
$40 per barrel in 2009 dollars—but in the 19 to 2000, growing in 16 of those 21 years. Yet,
intervening years—1986 to 2004—real oil and the industry made money in only eight of those
jet fuel prices were relatively stable and much years and overall lost $3 billion (2009 dollars)
lower than in the early period of deregulation. over this period. The intermittent economic
Yet, the industry still lost money in 13 of those downturns during this period certainly affected
19 years and on net lost $31 billion ($2009). airline industry profits, but it’s very unlikely
When shocks do occur, there doesn’t appear to that investors expected demand growth would
be any barrier to capacity adjustment over three be completely constant and steady. It is hard to
to six months in response, as occurred in the see how unanticipated demand shocks during
second half of 2008. Still, whether in response this time could be a credible explanation for the
to higher taxes or oil prices, reducing flight overall poor performance before 9/11.
schedules doesn’t eliminate costs if those costs Demand shocks are a more plausible explana-
are fixed or sticky. In times of growing demand, tion for the losses of the 2000s. The post-9/11
carriers can adjust fairly smoothly to unantici- demand drop, which was about 20 percent from
pated cost increases by growing more slowly, 2000 to 2002, was unprecedented. By 2008,
without having to ground aircraft or reduce work demand was still about 3 percent lower than it had
force size. When demand is stagnant or declin- been in 2000, and then it fell 11 percent in 2009.
ing, however, rescaling operations in response to Because of the fixed capital costs and sticky
upward cost shocks is more difficult and costly. labor costs, the decade of depressed demand was
accompanied by a decade of depressed prices. In
II.  Exogenous Demand Shocks real terms, prices were 20 percent lower in 2009
than in 2000 despite the fact that jet fuel prices
The role of demand shocks in airline losses were about $0.59 per gallon (52 percent) higher,
is most notable in 2001–02 and in 2008–09. which, based on 2009 revenue passenger-miles
Prior to 9/11, however, it appears that domestic per gallon of fuel, raised overall costs by about
demand grew fairly steadily. Inferring demand 9 percent.
shifts from average price (adjusted for trip dis-
tance) and revenue passenger-miles, demand III.  Entry and Expansion of Low-Cost Carriers
changes are presented in Figure 1 along with
the change in US real GDP for comparison.2 Many industry observers and participants
point to low-cost (and low-fare) carriers (LCCs)

2
Following Borenstein and Nancy L. Rose (2007),
demand is assumed to be Q = AP ε, where Q is domestic (adjusted for trip distance) and ε = −1. Figure 1 tracks A
revenue passenger-miles, P is an index of domestic yield over time. See Borenstein (2011) for details. 
VOL. 101 NO. 3 Why Can’t US Airlines Make Money? 235

700,000 prone to overinvestment relative to the growth of


600,000 their traffic. Figure 2 also shows that the changes
in LCC fleet size are dwarfed by the variation of
500,000
the non-LCC fleet, suggesting that LCC invest-
400,000 ment decisions have not been the primary driver
in industry capacity changes.
300,000
An alternate view of LCCs is that they have
200,000 been gradually chipping away at the entrenched
100,000
positions of legacy carriers that have much higher
costs. The change has been gradual, because the
0
legacy carriers are also protected by network
1979
1981
1983
1985
1987
1989
1991
1993
1995
1997
1999
2001
2003
2005
2007
marketing programs and other activities that
Legacy & regional carriers Low-cost carriers
raise barriers to entry by more efficient firms.
Potentially exclusionary activities of legacy car-
riers include frequent-flyer programs (FFPs)
Figure 2. Aircraft-Seats in Fleet
and corporate discount programs that exchange
discounts for customer loyalty on a portfolio of
unrelated routes,4 as well as relationships with
as part of the reason for low industry profits, airports that allow large incumbents to restrict
but there is wide disagreement on what the con- the availability of gates, landing slots, and other
nection is. If LCCs are simply offering a lower- resources to potential entrants.
quality product, then their differentiated product LCCs have been growing steadily since
should find its niche in the market if there is the early 1990s, from about 10 percent mar-
sufficient demand for that quality level, yielding ket share in 1994 to about 24 percent in 2009,
an equilibrium with both types earning normal with Southwest accounting for about half of
returns. LCC traffic in most years. LCCs now compete
Among industry and labor leaders, a com- (defined as at least 10 percent passenger share)
mon view is that new low-cost entrants and on over 60 percent of all airport pairs. And LCCs
LCC incumbents have made excessive capac- have maintained much lower costs than the leg-
ity investments during growth periods, and acy carriers. Figure 3 shows that, adjusted for
sometimes even during downturns, that have the average flight distance, legacy carrier costs
depressed prices for all. In order to discourage have remained 30 percent to 60 percent higher
excessive investment, the largest airline pilots than the LCCs’ for nearly all of the deregulation
union has called for increasing capital require- era, averaging about 40 percent higher in the last
ments as part of FAA licensing of new airlines. decade.
But the evidence doesn’t appear to support the While the cost differential between LCCs
idea that new entrants or older LCCs are more and non-LCCs has remained large, the average
prone to overinvestment than the legacy airlines. price differential has been shrinking, as shown
Figure 2 presents the aircraft-seat fleet size of in Figure 4. Figure 4 is adjusted for the average
LCCs and non-LCCs (including legacy carri- trip distance of passengers flying on each type of
ers and regional carriers who generally operate carrier. LCC fares have declined much less than
as codeshare partners to the legacy carriers). It those of legacy carriers in the 2000s, reflecting
shows that LCCs in aggregate have experienced their lower burden of excess aircraft capacity.
no more erratic fleet size adjustments despite This is no doubt a large part of the reason that
being less well-established on average.3 In fact, LCCs have suffered much milder losses in the
they continued to grow gradually even after 9/11 2000s, as shown in Figure 5.
while remaining much less unprofitable than the
legacy carriers, as shown below. If anything, it
appears to be the legacy carriers who are more
4
Borenstein (1996) discusses the potential anticompeti-
tive effects of such repeat-buyer programs in more detail.
3
The declines in 1987, 1988, and 2007 were due to a Mara Lederman (2007, 2008) presents evidence on the
legacy carrier absorbing an LCC.  impact of FFPs. 
236 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2011

20 1.5
18
1
16
14 0.5
12
0
10

2003

2005

2007

2009
1979

1981

1983

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

2001
8 −0.5
6
−1
4
2 −1.5
0
−2
1979
1981
1983
1985
1987
1989
1991
1993
1995
1997
1999
2001
2003
2005
2007
2009
−2.5
Legacy & regional carriers Low-cost carriers Legacy & regional carriers Low-cost carriers

Figure 3. Operating Cost per Available Seat-Mile Figure 5. Net Income per Available Seat-Mile
(2009 cents, adjusted for flight distance) (2009 cents)

last 20 years.5 As a result, while the exogenous


demand and cost shocks have affected all carri-
100% ers, the legacy airlines have fared much worse
90% financially, and LCCs have grown steadily.
80% The response of legacy carriers has been to
70% expand their networks through mergers and alli-
60% ances. There is little evidence that such moves
50% narrow the cost gap with LCCs, but network
40%
expansion may help differentiate their prod-
30%
ucts and improve service. It also may increase
their ability to use network marketing devices to
20%
dampen LCC competition.6
10%
The financial results for legacy airlines and
0% LCCs have improved substantially in 2010, and
1979
1981
1983
1985
1987
1989
1991
1993
1995
1997
1999
2001
2003
2005
2007
2009

the industry seems likely to be closer to break-


even on domestic operations. Still, the experi-
Figure 4. Price Premium of Legacy Carriers ence of the last decade suggests that until legacy
(adjusted for trip distance)
carriers can either close the cost gap with LCCs
or increase the price premium they can maintain,
they will likely have difficulty earning consis-
IV.  A Series of Unfortunate Events? tent profits through the typical cycles in the air-
line business environment.
Demand and cost shocks have certainly This short paper obviously doesn’t settle the
played a significant role in the airline industry’s issues surrounding airline profitability. The topic
poor financial results, but there is little reason would benefit from much more investigation by
to think those disruptions will be less frequent industrial organization economists.
in the future. After more than 30 years, it seems
unlikely that airline losses are due entirely to a
series of unfortunate exogenous events relative
to what management and investors should have
expected. 5
All price calculations in this paper include average bag-
Throughout deregulation, the legacy carriers gage fees and cancellation fees by airline and so account for
the recent rise in revenues from these sources. 
have maintained much higher costs than LCCs, 6
There is a lengthy literature on the impact of airline alli-
but the price premia they have been able to charge ances that expand network effects. See Olivier Armantier
have declined by more than 60 percent over the and Oliver Richard (2008) and citations therein. 
VOL. 101 NO. 3 Why Can’t US Airlines Make Money? 237

REFERENCES ­Economic Research Working Paper 16744.


Borenstein, Severin, and Nancy L. Rose. 2007.
Armantier, Olivier, and Richard Olivier. 2008. “How Airline Markets Work . . . Or Do They?
“Domestic Airline Alliances and Consumer Regulatory Reform in the Airline Industry.”
Welfare.” RAND Journal of Economics, 39(3), National Bureau of Economic Research Work-
875–904. ing Paper 13452.
Borenstein, Severin. 1996. “Repeat-Buyer Pro- Lederman, Mara. 2007. “Do Enhancements to
grams in Network Industries.” In Networks, Loyalty Programs Affect Demand? The Impact
Infrastructure, and the New Task for Regula- of International Frequent Flyer Partnerships on
tion, ed. Werner Sichel and Donald L. Alex- Domestic Airline Demand.” RAND Journal of
ander, 137–62. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Economics, 38(4): 1134–58.
Michigan Press. Lederman, Mara. 2008. “Are Frequent-Flyer Pro-
Borenstein, Severin. 2011. “On the Persistent grams a Cause of The “Hub Premium”?” Jour-
Financial Losses of U.S. Airlines: A Pre- nal of Economics and Management Strategy,
liminary Exploration.” National Bureau of 17(1): 35–66.

You might also like